Jump to content

Conspicuous consumption: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
CE. order, encyclopedic style, npov.
Tag: Reverted
→‎Solutions: CE. order, encyclopedic style, deleted off-topic text, npov.
Tag: Reverted
Line 68: Line 68:


== Solutions ==
== Solutions ==
In the case of conspicuous consumption, taxes upon luxury goods diminish societal expenditures on high-status goods, by rendering them more expensive than non-positional goods. In this sense, luxury taxes can be seen as a [[market failure]] correcting [[Pigovian tax]]—with an apparent negative [[deadweight loss]], these taxes are a more efficient mechanism for increasing revenue than 'distorting' labour or capital taxes.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Ng|first=Yew-Kwang|year=1987|title=Diamonds Are a Government's Best Friend: Burden-Free Taxes on Goods Valued for Their Values|journal=[[American Economic Review]]|volume=77|issue=1|pages=186–191|jstor=1806737}}</ref> A [[luxury tax]] applied to goods and services for conspicuous consumption is a type of progressive [[sales tax]] that at least partially corrects the negative [[externality]] associated with the conspicuous consumption of [[positional good]]s.<ref>{{cite journal |first=Daniel |last=Sámano |title=Optimal Linear Taxation of Positional Goods |journal=Working Paper |location=University of Minnesota |year=2009 |url=http://dsamano.weebly.com/uploads/1/2/8/7/1287492/draftlux05.pdf }}</ref> In ''Utility from Accumulation'' (2009), Louis Kaplow said that assets exercise an objective social-utility function, i.e. the rich man and the rich woman hoard material assets, because the hoard, itself, functions as status goods that establish his and her socio-economic position within society.<ref>{{Cite journal|doi=10.3386/w15595|title=Utility from Accumulation|year=2009|last1=Kaplow|first1=L.|doi-access=free}}</ref> When utility is derived directly from accumulation of assets, this lowers the dead weight loss associated with inheritance taxes and raises the optimal rate of inheritance taxation.<ref>{{Cite journal | doi = 10.1093/cesifo/ifr014| title = The Tax Treatment of Intergenerational Wealth Transfers| journal = CESifo Economic Studies| volume = 57| issue = 2| pages = 365–401| year = 2011| last1 = Cremer | first1 = H.| last2 = Pestieau | first2 = P.| url = https://orbi.uliege.be/bitstream/2268/118992/1/cesifo.ifr014.full.pdf}}</ref>

[[File:John Stuart Mill by John Watkins, 1865.jpg|thumb|right|300px|In the 19th century, the philosopher John Stuart Mill recommended taxing the practice of conspicuous consumption.]]
[[File:John Stuart Mill by John Watkins, 1865.jpg|thumb|right|300px|In the 19th century, the philosopher John Stuart Mill recommended taxing the practice of conspicuous consumption.]]
The case for the taxation of luxury goods was proposed in ''[[Principles of Political Economy|Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy]]'' (1848), wherein [[John Stuart Mill]] said:


{{Quotation|I disclaim all asceticism, and by no means wish to see discouraged, either by law or opinion, any indulgence which is sought from a genuine inclination for, any enjoyment of, the thing itself; but a great portion of the expenses of the higher and middle classes in most countries&nbsp;... is not incurred for the sake of the pleasure afforded by the things on which the money is spent, but from regard to opinion, and an idea that certain expenses are expected from them, as an appendage of station; and I cannot but think that expenditure of this sort is a most desirable subject of taxation. If taxation discourages it, some good is done, and if not, no harm; for in so far as taxes are levied on things which are desired and possessed from motives of this description, nobody is the worse for them. When a thing is bought not for its use but for its costliness, cheapness is no recommendation.<ref>John Stuart Mill, ''Principles of Political Economy with some of their Applications to Social Philosophy'', book 5, ch. 6, pt. 7 (W. J. Ashley, ed., Longmans, Green & Co. 1909) (1848)</ref>}}
In place of luxury taxes, economist [[Robert H. Frank]] proposed the application of a progressive consumption tax; in a 1998 ''[[The New York Times|New York Times]]'' article, [[John Tierney (journalist)|John Tierney]] said that as a remedy for the social and psychological malaise that is conspicuous consumption, the personal [[income tax]] should be replaced with a [[progressive tax]] upon the yearly sum of [[discretionary income]] spent on the conspicuous consumption of goods and services.<ref name="The Big City">{{cite news |last=Tierney |first=John |url=https://www.nytimes.com/1998/11/30/nyregion/the-big-city-rich-and-poor-consumed-by-consuming.html |title=The Big City; Rich and Poor, Consumed By Consuming |newspaper=The New York Times|date=1998-11-30|access-date=2011-10-20}}</ref> Another option is the [[redistribution of wealth]], either by means of an [[incomes policy]] – for example the conscious efforts to promote [[wage compression]] under variants of [[social corporatism]] such as the [[Rehn–Meidner model]] and/or by some mix of progressive taxation and transfer policies, and provision of public goods. When individuals are concerned with their relative income or consumption in comparison to their peers, the optimal degree of public good provision and of progression of the tax system is raised.<ref>{{cite journal |first=L. |last=Micheletto |title=Optimal Nonlinear Redistributive Taxation and Public Good Provision in an Economy with Veblen Effects |journal=Journal of Public Economic Theory |volume=13 |issue=1 |year=2011 |pages=71–96 |doi=10.1111/j.1467-9779.2010.01493.x |url=http://uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:211325/FULLTEXT01 }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |first1=Michael J. |last1=Boskin |first2=Eytan |last2=Sheshinski |title=Optimal Redistributive Taxation When Individual Welfare Depends Upon Relative Income |journal=[[Quarterly Journal of Economics]] |volume=92 |issue=4 |year=1978 |pages=589–601 |jstor=1883177 |doi=10.2307/1883177}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |first1=Thomas |last1=Aronsson |first2=Olof |last2=Johansson-Stenman |title=When the Joneses' Consumption Hurts: Optimal Public Good Provision and Nonlinear Income Taxation |journal=[[Journal of Public Economics]] |volume=92 |issue=5–6 |year=2008 |pages=986–997 |doi=10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.12.007 }}</ref> Because the activity of conspicuous consumption, itself, is a form of [[superior good]], diminishing the [[income inequality]] of the [[income distribution]] by way of an [[egalitarian]] policy reduces the conspicuous consumption of positional goods and services. In ''Wealth and Welfare'' (1912), the economist [[A. C. Pigou]] said that the redistribution of wealth might lead to great gains in [[Social welfare function|social welfare]]:

Another option is the [[redistribution of wealth]], either by means of an [[incomes policy]] – for example the conscious efforts to promote [[wage compression]] under variants of [[social corporatism]] such as the [[Rehn–Meidner model]] and/or by some mix of progressive taxation and transfer policies, and provision of public goods. When individuals are concerned with their relative income or consumption in comparison to their peers, the optimal degree of public good provision and of progression of the tax system is raised.<ref>{{cite journal |first=L. |last=Micheletto |title=Optimal Nonlinear Redistributive Taxation and Public Good Provision in an Economy with Veblen Effects |journal=Journal of Public Economic Theory |volume=13 |issue=1 |year=2011 |pages=71–96 |doi=10.1111/j.1467-9779.2010.01493.x |url=http://uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:211325/FULLTEXT01 }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |first1=Michael J. |last1=Boskin |first2=Eytan |last2=Sheshinski |title=Optimal Redistributive Taxation When Individual Welfare Depends Upon Relative Income |journal=[[Quarterly Journal of Economics]] |volume=92 |issue=4 |year=1978 |pages=589–601 |jstor=1883177 |doi=10.2307/1883177}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |first1=Thomas |last1=Aronsson |first2=Olof |last2=Johansson-Stenman |title=When the Joneses' Consumption Hurts: Optimal Public Good Provision and Nonlinear Income Taxation |journal=[[Journal of Public Economics]] |volume=92 |issue=5–6 |year=2008 |pages=986–997 |doi=10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.12.007 }}</ref> Because the activity of conspicuous consumption, itself, is a form of [[superior good]], diminishing the [[income inequality]] of the [[income distribution]] by way of an [[egalitarian]] policy reduces the conspicuous consumption of positional goods and services. In ''Wealth and Welfare'' (1912), the economist [[A. C. Pigou]] said that the redistribution of wealth might lead to great gains in [[Social welfare function|social welfare]]:


{{Quotation| Now the part played by comparative, as distinguished from absolute, income is likely to be small for incomes that only suffice to provide the necessaries and primary comforts of life, but to be large with large incomes. In other words, a larger proportion of the satisfaction yielded by the incomes of rich people comes from their relative, rather than from their absolute, amount. This part of it will not be destroyed if the incomes of all rich people are diminished together. The loss of economic welfare suffered by the rich when command over resources is transferred from them to the poor will, therefore, be substantially smaller relatively to the gain of economic welfare to the poor than a consideration of the law of diminishing utility taken by itself suggests.<ref>{{cite book |first=Arthur Cecil |last=Pigou |title=Wealth and Welfare |url=https://archive.org/details/in.ernet.dli.2015.187653 |year=1912 }}</ref>}}
{{Quotation| Now the part played by comparative, as distinguished from absolute, income is likely to be small for incomes that only suffice to provide the necessaries and primary comforts of life, but to be large with large incomes. In other words, a larger proportion of the satisfaction yielded by the incomes of rich people comes from their relative, rather than from their absolute, amount. This part of it will not be destroyed if the incomes of all rich people are diminished together. The loss of economic welfare suffered by the rich when command over resources is transferred from them to the poor will, therefore, be substantially smaller relatively to the gain of economic welfare to the poor than a consideration of the law of diminishing utility taken by itself suggests.<ref>{{cite book |first=Arthur Cecil |last=Pigou |title=Wealth and Welfare |url=https://archive.org/details/in.ernet.dli.2015.187653 |year=1912 }}</ref>}}

The economic case for the taxation of positional, luxury goods has a long history; in the mid-19th century, in ''[[Principles of Political Economy]] with some of their Applications to Social Philosophy'' (1848), [[John Stuart Mill]] said:

{{Quotation|I disclaim all asceticism, and by no means wish to see discouraged, either by law or opinion, any indulgence which is sought from a genuine inclination for, any enjoyment of, the thing itself; but a great portion of the expenses of the higher and middle classes in most countries&nbsp;... is not incurred for the sake of the pleasure afforded by the things on which the money is spent, but from regard to opinion, and an idea that certain expenses are expected from them, as an appendage of station; and I cannot but think that expenditure of this sort is a most desirable subject of taxation. If taxation discourages it, some good is done, and if not, no harm; for in so far as taxes are levied on things which are desired and possessed from motives of this description, nobody is the worse for them. When a thing is bought not for its use but for its costliness, cheapness is no recommendation.<ref>John Stuart Mill, ''Principles of Political Economy with some of their Applications to Social Philosophy'', book 5, ch. 6, pt. 7 (W. J. Ashley, ed., Longmans, Green & Co. 1909) (1848)</ref>}}

"Conspicuous non consumption" is a phrase used to describe a conscious choice to opt out of consumption with the intention of sending deliberate social signals.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Sørensen |first1=Elin Brandi |last2=Hjalager |first2=Anne-Mette |title=Conspicuous non-consumption in tourism: Non-innovation or the innovation of nothing? |journal=Tourist Studies |date=19 December 2019 |volume=20 |issue=2 |pages=222–247 |doi=10.1177/1468797619894463|s2cid=213042469 |url=https://findresearcher.sdu.dk:8443/ws/files/170914232/Brandi_S_rensen_and_Hjalager._Conspicuous_Non_consumption_in_Tourism._Tourism_Studies._2020.pdf }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Portwood-Stacer |first1=Laura |title=Media refusal and conspicuous non-consumption: The performative and political dimensions of Facebook abstention |journal=New Media & Society |date=5 December 2012 |volume=15 |issue=7 |pages=1041–1057 |doi=10.1177/1461444812465139|s2cid=40206877 }}</ref>


==See also==
==See also==

Revision as of 00:34, 17 November 2021

The sociologist and economist Thorstein Veblen coined the term "conspicuous consumption", and was a pioneer of the institutional economics movement.

In sociology and in economics, the term conspicuous consumption describes and explains the consumer practice of buying and using goods of a higher quality, price, or in greater quantity than practical.[1] The sociologist Thorstein Veblen coined the term conspicuous consumption to explain the spending of money on and the acquiring of luxury commodities (goods and services) specifically as a public display of economic power — the income and the accumulated wealth of the buyer. To the conspicuous consumer, the public display of discretionary income is an economic means of either attaining or of maintaining a given social status.[2][3]

The development of Veblen's sociology of conspicuous consumption also identified and described other economic behaviours such as invidious consumption, which is the ostentatious consumption of goods, an action meant to provoke the envy of other people; and conspicuous compassion, the ostentatious use of charity meant to enhance the reputation and social prestige of the donor;[4] thus the socio-economic practises of consumerism derive from conspicuous consumption.[5]

History

Socio-economic behaviours

In The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study in the Evolution of Institutions (1899), Thorstein Veblen identified, described, and explained the behavioural characteristics of the nouveau riche (new rich) social class that emerged from capital accumulation during the Second Industrial Revolution (1860–1914).[6] In the 19th-century, the term conspicuous consumption applied to the men, women, and families of the upper class who used their wealth to publicly flaunt their social and political power and their prestige, either real or perceived. That a person's reputation is directly related to the money possessed, displayed, and spent in activities that lead to "gaining and retaining a good name, [which] are leisure and conspicuous consumption."[7]

In the 1920s, economists such as Paul Nystrom said that the changes in the style of life of the working class led to the sociologic phenomenon of the workers' "pecuniary emulation" of the economic behaviours (spending habits) of the upper class. That such conspicuous consumption, as practised by every social class, had developed and instilled a "philosophy of futility" that would psychologically allow people to consume goods and services as a social fashion; consumption for the sake of consumption.[8]

About the psychology that motivates conspicuous consumption, in Income, Saving, and the Theory of Consumer Behavior (1949) James Duesenberry said that the "demonstration effect" and the "bandwagon effect" indicate that a person's conspicuous consumption depends upon both the actual spending of sums of money, and the person's competitiveness of degree in his or her discretionary spending, in relation to the discretionary sending of other people. That the conspicuous consumer is motivated by the importance to him or her of the opinion of the socio-economic groups for whom he or she performed the conspicuous consumption.[9][10]

Veblen said that conspicuous consumption comprised socio-economic behaviours practised by rich people as activities that are usual and exclusive to people with much disposable income, the upper class;[8] yet a variation of Veblen's theory is that the behaviours of conspicuous consumption are very common to the middle class and to the working class, regardless of the person's race and ethnic group. Such upper-class economic behaviour is especially common in the middle- and lower classes of societies with emerging economies, wherein the conspicuous consumption of goods and services ostentatiously signals that the buyer rose from poverty, and that he or she has something to prove to society.[11]

Consumerism

Conspicuous consumption explains the psychology behind the economics of a consumer society, and the increase in the types of goods and services that people consider necessary to and for their lives in a developed economy. Supporting interpretations and explanations of contemporary conspicuous consumption are presented in Consumer Culture (1996) by Celia Lury,[12] Consumer Culture and Modernity (1997) by Don Slater,[13] Symbolic Exchange and Death (1998) by Jean Baudrillard,[14] and Spent: Sex, Evolution, and the Secrets of Consumerism (2009) by Geoffrey Miller.[15]

Moreover, D. Hebdige, in Hiding in the Light (1994), proposes that conspicuous consumption is a form of displaying a personal identity,[13][16][17] and a consequent function of advertising, as proposed in Ads, Fads, and Consumer Culture (2000), by A. A. Berger.[18] Each variant interpretation and complementary explanation is derived from Veblen's original sociologic proposition in The Theory of the Leisure Class: that conspicuous consumption is a psychological end in itself, from which the practitioner (man, woman, family) derived the honour of superior social status.

In The Millionaire Next Door: The Surprising Secrets of America's Wealthy (1996), Thomas J. Stanley and William D. Danko reported conspicuous frugality, another variation of Veblen's social-class relation to conspicuous consumption. That Americans with a net worth of more than a million dollars usually avoid conspicuous consumption, and tend to practise frugality, such as paying cash for a used car rather using credit, in order to avoid material depreciation and paying interest upon a car loan.[19]

In An Examination of Materialism, Conspicuous Consumption and Gender Differences (2013), the researchers Brenda Segal and Jeffrey S. Podoshen reported great differences in the consumerism practised by men and women. The data about materialism and impulse purchases of 1,180 Americans indicate that men have greater scores for materialism and conspicuous consumption; and that women tended to buy goods and services on impulse; and both sexes were equally loyal to a given brand of goods and services.[20]

Distinctions of type

The term conspicuous consumption denotes the act of buying something, especially something expensive, that is not necessary to one's life, in a noticeable way.[21] Scholar Andrew Trigg (2001) defined conspicuous consumption as behaviour by which one can display great wealth, by means of idleness—expending much time in the practice of leisure activities, and spending much money to consume luxury goods and services.[22]

Conspicuous compassion, the practice of publicly donating large sums of money to charity to enhance the social prestige of the donor, is sometimes described as a type of conspicuous consumption.[4] This behaviour has long been recognised and sometimes attacked—for example, the New Testament story Lesson of the widow's mite criticises wealthy people who make large donations ostentatiously, while praising poorer people who make small but comparatively more difficult donations in private.[23]

The motivations for conspicuous consumption are:

  • Demonstration effect and the bandwagon effect — In Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior (1949), James Duesenberry said that a person's conspicuous consumption depend upon both the sums of money spent, and the degree of competitiveness of his or her spending in relation to the spending of other people; thus, conspicuous consumerism is a social competition among and between the social classes of a society.[9][10]
  • 'Aggressive ostentation — In a 2006 CBSNews.com article, Dick Meyer said that conspicuous consumption is a form of anger towards society, an "aggressive ostentation" that is an antisocial behaviour, which arose from the social alienation suffered by men, women, and families who feel they have become anonymous in and to their societies. This feeling of alienation is aggravated by the decay of the communitarian ethic essential to a person feeling him or herself part of the whole society.[24]
  • Shelter and transport — In the United States, the trend towards building houses that were larger than needed by a nuclear family began in the 1950s. Decades later, in the year 2000, that practice of conspicuous consumption resulted in people buying houses that were double the average size needed to comfortably house a nuclear family.[25] Negative consequences of either buying or building an oversized house might include:
    • the loss of or reduction in the family's domestic recreational space—the backyard and the front yard;
    • the spending of old-age retirement funds to pay for a too-big house;
    • over-long commuting time, from house to job, and vice versa, because the required plot of land was unavailable near a city.

Oversized houses facilitated other forms of conspicuous consumption, such as an oversized garage for the family's oversized motor vehicles or buying more clothing to fill larger clothes closets. Conspicuous consumption becomes a self-generating cycle of spending money for the sake of social prestige. Analogous to the consumer trend for oversized houses is the trend towards buying oversized light trucks, specifically the off-road sport utility vehicle type (cf. station wagon/estate car), as a form of psychologically comforting conspicuous consumption, because such large vehicles usually are bought by city-dwellers, an urban nuclear family.[25]

  • Prestige – In a 1999 article, Jacqueline Eastman, Ronald Goldsmith, and Leisa Reinecke Flynn said that status consumption is based upon conspicuous consumption; however, the literature of contemporary marketing does not establish definitive meanings for the terms status consumption and conspicuous consumption.[26][27] Moreover, A. O'Cass and H. Frost (2002) claim that sociologists often incorrectly used the two terms as interchangeable and equivalent terms. In a later study, O'Cass and Frost determined that, as sociological constructs, the terms status consumption and conspicuous consumption denote different sociological behaviours.[28] About the ambiguities of denotation and connotation of the term conspicuous consumption, R. Mason (1984) reported that the classical, general theories of consumer decision-processes do not readily accommodate the construct of "conspicuous consumption," because the nature of said socio-economic behaviours varies according to the social class and the economic group studied.[29]
  • Motivations — Paurav Shukla (2010) says that, whilst marketing and sales researchers recognise the importance of the buyer's social and psychological environment, the definition of the term status-directed consumption remains ambiguous, because the development of a comprehensive general theory requires that social scientists accept two fundamental assumptions, which usually do not concord. First, though the "rational" (economic) and the "irrational" (psychologic) elements of consumer decision-making often influence a person's decision to buy particular goods and services, marketing and sales researchers usually consider the rational element dominant in a person's decision to buy the particular goods and services. Second, the consumer perceives the utility of the product (the goods, the services) as a prime consideration in evaluating its usefulness, i.e. the reason to buy the product.[30] These assumptions, required for the development of a general theory of brand selection and brand purchase, are problematic, because the resultant theories tend either to misunderstand or to ignore the "irrational" element in the behaviour of the buyer-as-consumer; and because conspicuous consumption is a behaviour predominantly "psychological" in motivation and expression, Therefore, a comprehensive, general theory of conspicuous consumption would require a separate construct for the psychological (irrational) elements of the socio-economic phenomenon that is conspicuous consumption.

Examples

Conspicuous consumption is exemplified by purchasing goods that are exclusively designed to serve as symbols of wealth, such as luxury-brand clothing, high-tech tools, and vehicles.[5]

Conspicuous consumption: On 26 October 2017, this Rolex Daytona wristwatch was auctioned for 17.75 million US dollars for having been the personal property of the actor Paul Newman.[31]

Technology

Many technological devices have been marketed as luxury products while essentially offering the same core features as the more basic models. Although these devices are arguably the best available on the market, less expensive versions of the same product exist. Acquiring such products draws attention to the owner's extravagant purchase and creates conversation about the procurement of the item. An example of such a purchase is the sale of Paul Newman's Rolex Daytona, which sold for US$17.75 million in New York on October 26, 2017.[31]

Luxury fashion

Materialistic consumers are likely to engage in conspicuous luxury consumption.[32] The global yearly revenue of the luxury fashion industry was €1.64 trillion in 2019.[33] Buying of conspicuous goods is likely to be influenced by the spending habits of others. This view of luxury conspicuous consumption is being incorporated into social media platforms which is impacting consumer behaviour.[32]

Criticism

The journalist H. L. Mencken addressed the sociological and psychological particulars of the socio-economic behaviours that are conspicuous consumption, by asking:

Do I enjoy a decent bath because I know that John Smith cannot afford one — or because I delight in being clean? Do I admire Beethoven's Fifth Symphony because it is incomprehensible to Congressmen and Methodists — or because I genuinely love music? Do I prefer terrapin à la Maryland to fried liver because plowhands must put up with the liver — or because the terrapin is intrinsically a more charming dose? Do I prefer kissing a pretty girl to kissing a charwoman, because even a janitor may kiss a charwoman — or because the pretty girl looks better, smells better, and kisses better?[24]

Inequality and debt

In The Theory of the Leisure Class (1899) Veblen said that “among the motives which lead men to accumulate wealth, the primacy, both in scope and intensity, therefore, continues to belong to this motive of pecuniary emulation” of the rich.[2] In the study “Borrowing to Keep Up (with the Joneses): Inequality, Debt, and Conspicuous Consumption” (2020), Sheheryar Banuri and Ha Nguyen reported three findings:

  • Consumption tends to increase when the buying and the using of goods and services is conspicuous: Consumption signals status to other people.
  • Conspicuous consumption increases the frequency of borrowing money: Poor people take out loans in order to compete at consumption.
  • Economic inequality is worsened with access to credit: Poor people borrow money in order to signal status, which becomes a vicious circle.[34]

The findings that Banuri and Nguyen reported indicate that the cyclical effect of borrowing money for conspicuous consumption leads to and perpetuates economic inequality. That poor people imitate, try to match, and enulate the consumption patterns of rich people in order to increase their social status, and perhaps rise in society. That such socio-economic behaviours, facilitated by easy access to credit, generate macroeconomic volatility and support Veblen's concept of pecuniary emulation used to finance a person's social standing.[34]

Solutions

In the 19th century, the philosopher John Stuart Mill recommended taxing the practice of conspicuous consumption.

The case for the taxation of luxury goods was proposed in Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy (1848), wherein John Stuart Mill said:

I disclaim all asceticism, and by no means wish to see discouraged, either by law or opinion, any indulgence which is sought from a genuine inclination for, any enjoyment of, the thing itself; but a great portion of the expenses of the higher and middle classes in most countries ... is not incurred for the sake of the pleasure afforded by the things on which the money is spent, but from regard to opinion, and an idea that certain expenses are expected from them, as an appendage of station; and I cannot but think that expenditure of this sort is a most desirable subject of taxation. If taxation discourages it, some good is done, and if not, no harm; for in so far as taxes are levied on things which are desired and possessed from motives of this description, nobody is the worse for them. When a thing is bought not for its use but for its costliness, cheapness is no recommendation.[35]

Another option is the redistribution of wealth, either by means of an incomes policy – for example the conscious efforts to promote wage compression under variants of social corporatism such as the Rehn–Meidner model and/or by some mix of progressive taxation and transfer policies, and provision of public goods. When individuals are concerned with their relative income or consumption in comparison to their peers, the optimal degree of public good provision and of progression of the tax system is raised.[36][37][38] Because the activity of conspicuous consumption, itself, is a form of superior good, diminishing the income inequality of the income distribution by way of an egalitarian policy reduces the conspicuous consumption of positional goods and services. In Wealth and Welfare (1912), the economist A. C. Pigou said that the redistribution of wealth might lead to great gains in social welfare:

Now the part played by comparative, as distinguished from absolute, income is likely to be small for incomes that only suffice to provide the necessaries and primary comforts of life, but to be large with large incomes. In other words, a larger proportion of the satisfaction yielded by the incomes of rich people comes from their relative, rather than from their absolute, amount. This part of it will not be destroyed if the incomes of all rich people are diminished together. The loss of economic welfare suffered by the rich when command over resources is transferred from them to the poor will, therefore, be substantially smaller relatively to the gain of economic welfare to the poor than a consideration of the law of diminishing utility taken by itself suggests.[39]

See also

References

  1. ^ Phillips, Ronnie J. 2014 April 22. "Conspicuous consumption." Encyclopedia Britannica.
  2. ^ a b Veblen, Thorstein (1899). The Theory of the Leisure Class. Project Gutenberg.
  3. ^ The New Fontana Dictionary of Modern Thought, Third Edition, Alan Bullock, Stephen Trombley, Eds., 1993, p. 162.
  4. ^ a b West, Patrick (2004). Conspicuous Compassion: Why Sometimes It Really Is Cruel To Be Kind. London: Civitas, Institute for the Study of Civil Society. ISBN 978-1-903386-34-7.
  5. ^ a b Kenton, Will. "Conspicuous Consumption". Investopedia. Retrieved 2021-05-10.
  6. ^ Veblen, Thorstein. (1899) The Theory of the Leisure Class|Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study in the Evolution of Institutions. New York: Macmillan. (ISBN 0-486-28062-4, 1994 Dover pbk ed.; ISBN 0-14-018795-2, 1994 Penguin Classics ed.).
  7. ^ Veblen, Thorstein (1912), The Theory of the Leisure Class. New York: Macmillan Company. p. 4.
  8. ^ a b "Conspicuous Consumption: The Term, The Book, Examples". Retrieved 2021-05-10.
  9. ^ a b Duesenberry, James S. (1949), Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  10. ^ a b Shukla, Paurav (2008). "Conspicuous consumption among middle age consumers: Psychological and brand antecedents". Journal of Product & Brand Management. 17: 25–36. doi:10.1108/10610420810856495.
  11. ^ Postrel, Virginia. 2008 July/August. "Inconspicuous Consumption." The Atlantic. "Conspicuous consumption, this research suggests, is not an unambiguous signal of personal affluence. It's a sign of belonging to a relatively poor group."
  12. ^ Lury, Celia (1996). Consumer Culture. Polity Press. ISBN 9780745614410.
  13. ^ a b Slater, Don. (1997) Consumer Culture and Modernity. London: Polity.
  14. ^ Baudrillard, J. (1998b) Symbolic Exchange and Death. London: Sage.
  15. ^ Miller G, Spent: sex, evolution and the secrets of consumerism, Random House, London, 2009 (ISBN 9780670020621)
  16. ^ Hebdige, D. (1994) Hiding in the Light. London: Routledge.
  17. ^ Wilson, E. (ed.) Chic Thrills. A Fashion Reader. London: HarperCollins
  18. ^ Berger, A. A. (2000) Ads, Fads, and Consumer Culture. Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield.
  19. ^ Stanley, Thomas J.; Danko, William D. (1998). The Millionaire Next Door. Simon and Schuster. ISBN 9780671015206.
  20. ^ Segal, Brenda; Podoshen, Jeffrey S. (March 2013). "An Examination of Materialism, Conspicuous Consumption and Gender Differences". International Journal of Consumer Studies. 37 (2): 189–198. doi:10.1111/j.1470-6431.2012.01099.x.
  21. ^ Longman American Dictionary, 2000, p. 296.
  22. ^ Trigg, A. (2001). "Veblen, Bourdieu, and conspicuous consumption". Journal of Economic Issues. 35 (1): 99–115. doi:10.1080/00213624.2001.11506342. JSTOR 4227638. S2CID 55731706.
  23. ^ Robert L. Payton and Michael P. Moody (2008). Understanding Philanthropy: Its Meaning and Mission. p. 137. ISBN 978-0253000132.
  24. ^ a b Meyer, Dick (2009-02-11). "Aggressive Ostentation". CBS News. Retrieved 2021-05-10.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: url-status (link)
  25. ^ a b Lloyd, Carol (2005-10-14). "Monster Homes R Us: American homes are monuments to conspicuous consumption". SF Chronicle. Retrieved 2011-10-20.
  26. ^ Eastman, Jacqueline K., Ronald Goldsmith, and Leisa Reinecke Flynn (1999). "Status Consumption in Consumer Behaviour: Scale Development and Validation". Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice. 7 (3): 41–51. doi:10.1080/10696679.1999.11501839.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  27. ^ Shukla, Paurav (2010-01-09). "Status (luxury) consumption among British and Indian consumers". Paurav Shukla (Podcast). International Marketing Review. Retrieved 2011-10-20.
  28. ^ O'Cass, A.; Frost, H. (2002). "Status Brands: Examining the Effects of Non-product-related Brand Associations on Status and Conspicuous Consumption". Journal of Product & Brand Management. 11 (2): 67–88. doi:10.1108/10610420210423455.
  29. ^ Mason, R. (1984). "Conspicuous Consumption: A Literature Review". European Journal of Marketing. 18 (3): 26–39. doi:10.1108/eum0000000004779.
  30. ^ Shukla, P. (2010). "Status Consumption in Cross-national Context: Socio-psychological, Brand and Situational Antecedents". International Marketing Review. 27 (1): 108–129. doi:10.1108/02651331011020429.
  31. ^ a b "Paul Newman's 'Paul Newman' Rolex Daytona Sells for $17.8 Million, A Record for a Wristwatch at Auction".
  32. ^ a b Charoennan, Wanwisa; Huang, Kai-Ping (2018). "THE ANTECEDENTS AND CONSEQUENCES OF CONSPICUOUS CONSUMPTION OF LUXURY FASHION GOODS IN A SOCIAL MEDIA PLATFORM". International Journal of Organizational Innovation. 11: 1–21.
  33. ^ Cabigiosu, Anna (2020), "An Overview of the Luxury Fashion Industry", Digitalization in the Luxury Fashion Industry, Palgrave Advances in Luxury, Cham: Springer International Publishing: 9–31, doi:10.1007/978-3-030-48810-9_2, ISBN 978-3-030-48809-3, PMC 7355146
  34. ^ a b Sheheryar, Banuri; Ha, Nguyen (2020). "Borrowing to Keep Up (with the Joneses): Inequality, Debt, and Conspicuous Consumption". Policy Research Working Paper – via World Bank Group.
  35. ^ John Stuart Mill, Principles of Political Economy with some of their Applications to Social Philosophy, book 5, ch. 6, pt. 7 (W. J. Ashley, ed., Longmans, Green & Co. 1909) (1848)
  36. ^ Micheletto, L. (2011). "Optimal Nonlinear Redistributive Taxation and Public Good Provision in an Economy with Veblen Effects". Journal of Public Economic Theory. 13 (1): 71–96. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9779.2010.01493.x.
  37. ^ Boskin, Michael J.; Sheshinski, Eytan (1978). "Optimal Redistributive Taxation When Individual Welfare Depends Upon Relative Income". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 92 (4): 589–601. doi:10.2307/1883177. JSTOR 1883177.
  38. ^ Aronsson, Thomas; Johansson-Stenman, Olof (2008). "When the Joneses' Consumption Hurts: Optimal Public Good Provision and Nonlinear Income Taxation". Journal of Public Economics. 92 (5–6): 986–997. doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.12.007.
  39. ^ Pigou, Arthur Cecil (1912). Wealth and Welfare.

Further reading