Exhibit G Securitization
Exhibit G Securitization
Exhibit G Securitization
Abstract
Under US laws, securitization is illegal, primarily because its fraudulent and
causes specific violations of RICO, usury, and antitrust laws. Securitization of many
types of assets (loans, credit cards, auto receivables, intellectual property, etc.) has
become more prevalent, particularly for financially distressed companies and companies
with low or mid-tier credit ratings. This article focuses on securitization as it pertains to
asset-backed securities and mortgage-backed securities, and analyzes critical legal and
Keywords:
Introduction
Under US laws, securitization is illegal. Indeed many authors have illustrated the
1
See: Yamazaki Kenji, What makes Asset Securitization Inefficient ? (2005); Berkeley
Electronic Press, Working paper #603.
See: Steven Schwarcz, Enron And The Use And Abuse Of Special Purpose Entities In Corporate
Structures, 70 U. Cin. L. Rev. 1309 (2002).
See: Carlson D. (1998). The Rotten Foundations of Securitization. William & Mary Law Review,
39:____________.
See: Lupica L (2000). Circumvention Of The Bankruptcy Process: The Statutory Institutionalization Of
Securitization. Connecticut Law Review, 33: 199-210.
See: Thomas Plank, 2004, The Security of Securitization And The Future Of Security, 25
Cardozo L. Rev. 1655 (2004).
2
On securitization, see: Eastgroup Properties v. Southern Motel Association, Ltd., 935 F.2d 245
(11th Cir. 1991); Union Savings Bank v. Augie/Restivo Baking Co. (In Re Augie/Restivo Baking
Co.), 860 F.2d 515 (2d Cir. 1988); In Re Bonham, 229 F.3d 750 (9th Cir. 2000); In Re Central
European Industrial Development Company LLC, 288 B.R. 572 (Bankr. N.D. Cal. 2003); Special
Report by the TriBar Opinion Committee, Opinions in the Bankruptcy Context: Rating Agency,
Structured Financing, and Chapter 11 Transactions, 46 Business Lawyer 717 (1991);
See: Sargent, Bankruptcy Remote Finance Subsidiaries: The Substantive Consolidation Issue, 44
Business Lawyer 1223 (1989).
See: In re Kingston Square Associates, 214 B.R. 713 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 1997).
On “True-sale” and “assignment” distinctions, see: Major's Furniture Mart, Inc. v. Castle Credit
Corporation, Inc., 602 F.2d 538 (3rd Cir. 1979); In re Major Funding Corporation, 82 B.R. 443
(Bankr. S.D. Tex. 1987); Fox v. Peck Iron and Metal Company, Inc., 25 B.R. 674 (Bankr. S.D.
Cal. 1982); Carter v. Four Seasons Funding Corporation, 97 S.W.3d. 387 (Ark. 2003); A.B.
Lewis Co. v. Nat'l Investment Co. of Houston, 421 S.W.2d 723 (Tex. Civ. App. - 14th Dist. 1967);
Resolution Trust Corp. v. Aetna Casualty and Surety Co. of Illinois, 25 F.3d 570, 578 (7th Cir.
1994); In re Royal Crown Bottlers of North Alabama, Inc., 23 B.R. 28 (Bankr. N.D. Ala. 1982)
(addressing 'reasonably equivalent value' in transfer by parent to subsidiary); Butner v. United
States, 440 U.S. 48 (U.S. 1979); In re Schick, 246 B.R. 41, 44 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 2000); (state law
determines the extent of the debtor's interest; bankruptcy law determines whether that interest is
"property of the estate").
See: Homburger & Andre, Real Estate Sale and Leaseback Transactions and the Risk of
Recharacterization in Bankruptcy, 24 Real Property, Probate and Trust Journal 95, (1989).
See: In re Integrated Health Services, Inc., 260 B.R. 71 (Bankr. Del. 2001).
See: HSBC Bank v. United Air Lines, Inc., 317 B.R. 335 (N.D. Ill. 2004).
See: Jonathan C. Lipson, Enron, Asset Securitization and Bankruptcy Reform: Dead or
Dormant?, 11 J. Bankr. L. & Prac. 1 (2002).
See: Peter J. Lahny IV, Asset Securitization: A Discussion of the Traditional Bankrupt Attacks
and an Analysis of the Next Potential Attack, Substantive Consolidation, 9 Am. Bankr. Inst. L.
Rev. 815 (2001).
See: Lois R. Lupica, Revised Article 9, Securitization Transactions and the Bankruptcy Dynamic,
9 Am. Bankr. Inst. L. Rev. 287 (2001).
See: Lois R. Lupica, Circumvention of the Bankruptcy Process: The Statutory Institutionalization
of Securitization, 33 Conn. L. Rev. 199 (2000).
See: Lois R. Lupica, Asset Securitization: The Unsecured Creditors Perspective, 76
Tex. L. Rev. 595 (1998)
See: Stephen I. Glover, Structured Finance Goes Chapter 11: Asset Securitization by the
Reorganizing Companies, 47 Bus. Law 611, 627 (1992).
See: Thomas J. Gordon, Securitization of Executory Future Flows as Bankruptcy-Remote True
Sales, 67 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1317, 1322-23 (2000).
See: In Re Kingston Square Assocs., 214 B.R. 713 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 1997)(creditors brought an
involuntary petition against an SPV).
3
On Corporate governance issues pertaining to SPVs and securitization see the following
materials:
See: In Re Buckhead America Corp., #s 91-978 through 91-986 (Bankr. D. Del, Aug. 13, 1992);
In Re Minor Emergency Center Of Tamarac Inc., 45 BR 310 (Bankr. SD.FL., 1985); Revlon Inc.
v. Mac Andrews & Forbes Holdings, 506 A2d 173 (Del. 1986); In Re Kingston Square
Associates, 214 BR 713 (Bnakr. SDNY 197).
See: Sheryl Gussset, A Not-So-Independent Director In A Bankruptcy Remote Structure, 17 Am.
Bankr. Inst. J. 24 (1998). .
and corporate governance issues pertaining to securitization is extensive, but has several
violations.
See: Roberg Dean Ellis, Securitization, Fiduciary Duties And Bondholders Rights, 24 J. Corp. L.
295 (1999).
See: Richard Graf, Use Of LLCs As Bankruptcy Proof Entities Widens, National L. J. , April 10,
1995 at B16.
See: Schwarcz Steven, Enron And The Use And Abuse Of Special Purpose Entities In Corporate
Structures, 70 U. Cin. L. Rev. 1309 (2002).
See: Schwarcz, Steven, Securitization Post-Enron, 25 Cardozo L. Rev. 1539 (2004).
See: Thomas Plank, 2004 Symposium: The Security Of Securitization And The Future Of
Security, 25 Cardozo L. Rev. 1655 (2004).
See: Thomas H, Effects Of Asset Securitization On Seller Claimants, Journal Of financial
Intermediation, 10: 306-330.
See: Nolan, Anthony, Synthetic Securitizations And Derivatives Transactions BY Banks:
Selected Regulatory Issues, Journal of Structured Finance, Fall 2006, pp. 40-46.
See: American Securitization Forum, ASF Securitization Institute: The Securitization Legal And
Regulatory Framework, 2006.
See: Yamazaki, Kenji, What makes Asset Securitization “Inefficient” ? Working Paper # 603,
Berkeley Electronic Press.
This article seeks to fill these significant gaps in the literature. Although the
following analysis is supported with US case law, the principles derived are applicable to
processes, and current practices. Carlson (1998), Janger (2002) and Lupica (2000) 4
traces the history of securitization to direct and specific efforts/collaborations to avoid the
impact of US bankruptcy laws. Klee & Butler (_____) and other authors have traced the
4
See: Schwarcz S. (1999). Rethinking Freedom Of Contract: A Bankruptcy Paradigm. Texas
Law Review, 77: 515-599.
See: Klee K & Butler B (_____). Asset-Backed Securitization, Special Purpose Vehicles And
Other Securitization Issues. Uniform Commercial Code Law Journal, 35(2):.
See: Carlson D (1998). The Rotten Foundations Of Securitization. William & Mary Law Review,
39:
See: Janger, Edward J, Muddy Rules For Securitizations, Fordham Journal of Corporate &
Financial Law, 2002.
See: Lois R. Lupica, Circumvention of the Bankruptcy Process: The Statutory Institutionalization
of Securitization, 33 CONN. L. REV. 199 (2000).
See: Steven L. Schwarcz, The Inherent Irrationality of Judgment Proofing, 52 STAN. L. REV. 1
(1999).
See: S. 420, 107th Cong. 912 (2001); H.R. 333, 107th Cong. 912 (2001)
See: Steven L. Schwarcz, The Impact on Securitization of Revised UCC Article 9, 74 Cm. -
KENT L. REV. 947 (1999) ("Revised Article 9 attempts to broaden its coverage to virtually all
securitized assets.").
See: Claire A. Hill, Securitization: A Low-Cost Sweetener for Lemons, 74 WASH. U. L.Q. 1061
(1996).
See: Yamazaki Kenji, What makes Asset Securitization Inefficient ? (2005); Berkeley Electronic
Press, Working paper #603.
See: Saayman, Andrea, Securitization And Bank Liquidity In South Africa, Working Paper,
Potchefstroom University, South Africa.
See: Sargent Patrick, Structural and Legal Issues in Commercial Mortgage Securitization
Transactions, November 1, 2004.
Purposes, wording and scope of applicable laws – state contract laws, state trusts
laws, US bankruptcy code, and state/federal securities laws. The legislative intent
The usefulness of existing (if any), possible and proposed (if any) deterrence
Transaction costs.
Securitization violates usury laws, because the resulting effective interest rate
typically exceeds legally allowable rates (set by state usury laws).5 There is substantial
also within some judicial jurisdictions, about some issues and these conflicts have not
been resolved by the US Supreme Court 6. On these issues, even the cases for which the
5
See: Schwarcz S (2004). Is Securitization Legitimate ? International Financial Law Review,
2004 Guide To Structured Finance, pp.115.
See: Schwarcz S (2002).. The Universal Language Of International Securitization. Duke Journal
Of Comparative And International Law, 12:285-300.
See: Frankel T (____). Cross-Border Securitization: Without Law But Not Lawless. Duke
Journal Of Comparative And International law, 8: 255-265.
See: Kanda H (_______). Securitization In Japan. Duke Journal Of Comparative And
International law, 8: 359-370.
See: Klee K & Butler B (________). Asset-Backed Scuritization, Special Purpose Vehicles And
Other Securitization Issues. Uniform Commercial Code Law Review, 35(3):23-33.
See: Higgin E & Mason J(2004). What Is The Value Of Recourse To ABS ? A Study Of The
Credit Card Bank ABS Rescue. Journal Of Banking & Finance, 28(4):857-874.
US Supreme Court denied certiorari, vary substantially in their holdings. The issues are
as follows:
See: Carlson D (1998). The Rotten Foundations Of Securitization. William & Mary Law Review,
39:
See: Elmer P (_____). Conduits: Their Structure And Risk. FDIC Banking Review, pp. 27-40.
See: Dawson P (_____). Ratings Games With Contingent Transfer: A Structured Finance
Illusion. Duke Journal OF Comparative & International Law, 8: 381-391.
6
See: Fogie v. Thorn, 95 F3d 645 (CA8, 1996)(cert. den.) 520 US 1166; Pollice v. Nationa;l Tax
Funding LP, 225 F3d 379 (CA3, 2000); Najarro v. SASI Intern. Ltd, 904 F2d 1002 (CA5,
1990)(cert. den.) 498 US 1048; Video Trax v. Nationsbank NA, 33 Fsupp2d 1041 (S.D.Fla.,
1998)(affirmed) 205 F3d 1358(cert. den.) 531 US 822; In Re Tammy Jewels, 116 BR 290
(M.D.Fla., 1990); ECE technologies v. Cherrington Corp., 168 F3d 201 (CA5, 1999); Colony
Creek Ltd. v. RTC, 941 F2d 1323 (CA5, 1991)(rehearing denied); Sterling Property Management
v. Texas Commerce Bank, 32 F3d 964 (CA5, 1994); Pearcy Marinev. Acadian Offshore Services,
832 Fsupp 192 (S.D.TX, 1993); In Re Venture Mortgage Fund LP, 245 BR 460 (SDNY, 2000);
In Re Donnay, 184 BR 767 (D.Minn, 1995); Johnson v. Telecash Inc., 82 FSupp2d 264 (D.Del.,
1999)(reversed in part) 225 F2d 366 (cert. denied) 531 US 1145; Shelton v. Mutual Savings &
Loan Asssociation, 738 FSupp 50 (E.D.Mich., 1990); S.E.C. v. Elmas Trading Corporation, 638
FSupp 743 (D.Nevada, 1987)(affirmed) 865 F2d 265; contrast: J2 Smoke Shop Inc. v. American
Commercial Capital Corp., 709 FSupp 422 (SDNY 1989)(cost of funds); In Re Powderburst
Corp., 154 BR 307 (E.D.Cal. 1993)(original issue discount); In Re Wright, 256 BR 626 (D.Mont.,
2000)(difference between face amount and amount actually recovered or owed by debtor); In Re
MCCorhill Pub. Inc., 86 BR 283 (SDNY 1988); In Re Marill Alarm Systems, 81 BR 119
(S.D.Fla., 1987)(affirmed) 861 F2d 725; In Re Dent, 130 BR 623 (S.D.GA, 1991); In Re Evans,
130 BR 357 (S.D.GA, 1991); contrast: In Re Cadillac Wildwood Development, 138 BR 854
(W.D.Mich., 1992)(closing costs are interest costs); In Re Brummer, 147 BR 552 (D.Mont.,
1992); In Re Sunde, 149 BR 552 (D.Minn., 1992); Matter Of Worldwide Trucks, 948 F2d 976
(CA5,1991)(agreement about applicable interest rate maybe established by course of conduct);
Lovick v. Ritemoney Ltd, 378 F3d 433 (CA5, 2004); In Re Shulman Transport, 744 F2d 293
(CA2, 1984); Torelli v. Esposito, 461 NYS2d 299 (1983)(reversed) 483 NYS2d 204; Reschke v.
Eadi, 447 NYS2d 59 (NYAD4, 1981); Elghanian v. Elghanian, 717 NYS2d 54( NYAD1,
2000)(leave to appeal denied) 729 NYS2d 410 (there was no consideration in exchange for loan,
and transaction violated usury laws); Karas v. Shur, 592 NYS2d 779 (NYAD2, 1993); Simsbury
Fund v. New St. Louis Associates, 611 NYS2d 557 (NYAD1, 1994); Rhee v. Dahan, 454 NYS2d
371 (NY.Sup., 1982); Hamilton v. HLT Check Exchange, LLP, 987 F. Supp. 953 (E.D. Ky.
1997); Turner v. E-Z Check Cashing of Cookeville, TN, Inc., 35 F.Supp.2d 1042 (M.D. Tenn.
1999); Hurt v. Crystal Ice & Cold Storage Co., 286 S.W. 1055, 1056-57 (Ky. 1926); Phanco v.
Dollar Financial Group., Case No. CV99-1281 DDP (C.D. Cal., filed Feb. 8, 1999).
See: Van Voris, B. (May 17, 1999) “’Payday’ Loans Under Scrutiny,” The National Law Journal,
page B1.
3. What types of forebearance qualify for applicability of usury laws.
of-funds for the securitization transaction is not the advertised interest cost (investor’s
coupon rate) of the ABS securities but the sum of the following:
the percentage annual cash yield from the collateral (in a situation where the
SPV’s corporate documents expressly state that the Excess Spread should be paid
to the sponsor, the Excess Spread should be subtracted from the resulting
percentage). The Excess Spread is defined as the Gross Cash Yield From The
Collateral, minus the interest paid to investors, minus the Servicing Expense (paid
The Amortized Value Difference. The difference between the Market Value of
the collateral, and the amount raised from the ABS offering (before bankers’
fees), which is then amortized over the average life of the ABS bonds (at a
discount rate equal to the US Treasury Bond ate of same maturity) and then
expressed as percentage of the market value of the collateral. This difference can
range from 10-30% of the Market Value of the collateral, and is highest where
credit enhancement.
Costs are amortized over the average life of the ABS, a rate equal to the interest
rate on an equivalent-term US treasury bond. The Periodic Transaction Costs
are then added to the Amortized Pre-Offering Transaction Costs to obtain Total
transfer agent, etc.), marketing costs, accountant’s fees, legal fees, etc.) and
etc.). The Periodic Transaction Costs include administrative costs, servicing fees,
The sum of these four elements is typically greater than state-law usury
benchmark rates.
offering is amortized over the life of the ABS, at a rate equal to the interest rate on
an equivalent term US treasury bond, and the result (the Amortized Pre-
Securitization Costs) is added to the Periodic Transaction Costs for only one
period to obtain the Total Periodic Transaction Cost, which is then expressed as a
percentage of the market value of the collateral is the Amortized Total Periodic
transfer agent, etc.), marketing costs, accountant’s fees, legal fees, etc.) and
etc.). The Periodic Transaction Costs include servicing fees, administrative fees,
The Value Difference. The difference between the Market Value of the
collateral, and the amount raised from the ABS offering (before bankers’ fees), is
amortized over the average life of the ABS bonds and the result is then expressed
as percentage of the Market Value of the collateral. This difference can range
from 10-30%, and is highest where the senior/junior structure is used and the
the collateral, is amortized over the estimated average life of the ABS, and the
result for one period is expressed as a percentage of the book value of the
collateral. Most ABS collateral are recorded in financial statements at the lower-
of-cost-or-market.
value of the collateral minus the interest rate on demand deposits, with the
The sum of these five elements is typically greater that the state-law usury benchmark
interest rates.
In the US, the applicable tax evasion staute is the US Internal Revenue Code Section
7201 7 which reads as follows: “…….Any person who willfully attempts in any manner to evade
or defeat any tax imposed by this title or the payment thereof shall, in addition to other penalties
provided by law, be guilty of a felony and, upon conviction thereof, shall be fined not more than
$100,000 ($500,000 in the case of a corporation), or imprisoned not more than 5 years, or both,
together with the costs of prosecution……….”. Under this statute and related case law,
1) the “actus reus” (the guilty conduct) — which consists of an affirmative act (and not merely an
omission or failure to act) that constitutes evasion or an attempt to evade either: a) the assessment
2) the “mens rea’ or "mental" element of willfulness — the specific intent to violate an actually
7
See: 26 U.S.C. § 7201. 26 USC Subtitle F, Chapter 75. See: Cheek v. United States, 498 U.S. 192
(1991).
3) the “attendant circumstance” of the existence of a tax deficiency — an unpaid tax liability.
In the case of ‘true sale’ transactions, the tax evasion 8 occurs because: a) the sponsor
determines the price at which the collateral is transferred to the SPV, and hence, can arbitrarily
lower/increase the price to avoid capital gains taxes – its assumed that the sponsor is a profit-
maximizing entity and will always act to minimize its tax liability and to avoid any tax
assessment; b) the sponsor typically retains a ‘residual’ interest in the SPV in the form of IOs,
POs and “junior piece”, which are typically taxed differently and at different tax-basis compared
to the original collateral - hence the sponsor can lower the price of the collateral upon transfer to
the SPV, and convert what would have been capital gains, into non-taxable basis (for tax
purposes) in the SPV “residual”; c) there is typically the requisite “intent” by the sponsor –
evidenced by the arrangement of the transaction and the transfer of assets to the SPV; d) before
securitization, collateral is typically reported in the sponsors’ financial statements at book value
accounts receivables are typically not re-valued to market-value unless there has been some major
impairment in value) which does not reflect true Market Values. and results in effective tax
evasion upon transfer of the collateral to the SPV because any unrealized gain is not taxed; e) the
Actus Reus is manifested by the execution of the securitization transaction and transfer of assets
to the SPV; f) the Mens Rea or specific intent is manifested by the elaborate arrangements
implicit in securitization transactions, the method of determination of the price of the collateral to
be transferred to the SPV, the objectives of securitization, and the sponsor’s transfer of assets to
the SPV; g) the unpaid tax liability consists of foregone tax on the capital gains from the
collateral (transaction is structured to avoid recognition of capital gains), and tax on any income
from the collateral which is ‘converted’ into basis or other non-taxable forms; h) income (from
the collateral) that would have been taxable in the sponsor’s financial statements, is converted
8
SEC v. Towers Financial Corp. et al., 93 Civ. 744 (WK) (S.D.N.Y.)
into non-taxable basis in the form of the SPV’s interest-only (IO) and principal-only (PO)
securities - part of the Interest-Spread (the difference between the SPV’s income and what it pays
as interest and operating costs) is paid out to PO-holders and this transforms interest into return-
In the case of ‘disguised loan’ or ‘assignment’ securitization transactions, the tax evasion
occurs because: a) the sponsor determines the price at which the collateral is transferred to the
SPV, and hence can lower/increase the price of the collateral to avoid capital gains taxes; b) the
sponsor typically retains a ‘residual’ interest in the SPV which is typically taxed differently and at
different tax-basis compared to the original collateral - hence the sponsor can lower the price
upon transfer to the SPV, and covert what would have been capital gains, into non-taxable basis
for tax purposes; c) the transfer of collateral to the SPV and the creation of interest-only and
principal-only securities essentially converts what would have been taxable capital gains into
non-taxable basis; d) any gain in the value of the collateral is not recognized for tax purposes,
because there has not been any ‘sale’; e) where the ABS is partly amortizing, any capital gains are
converted into interest payments; f) the Actus Reus is manifested by the execution of the
securitization transaction and transfer of assets to the SPV; g) the Mens Rea or specific intent is
securitization and the sponsor’s transfer of assets to the SPV; h) the unpaid tax liability consists
of tax on the capital gains from the transfer of the collateral (the transaction is structured to avoid
recognition of a sale, whereas the transfer to the SPV is effectively a sale), and tax on any income
from the collateral which is ‘converted’ into basis or other non-taxable forms (IOs and POs) , by
securitization.
C. In All “True-Sale”, “Disguised Loan” And “Assignment” Securitizations, The
In most securitization transactions, the sponsor eventually serves as the servicer of the SPV asset
pool. As servicer, the sponsor: a) determines when there has been impairment of collateral, and
To prove fraud, prosecutors must prove several elements beyond a reasonable doubt:
1) The “actus reus” (the guilty conduct) — which consists of an affirmative act (and not merely
sponsor typically makes material mispresentations: a) the sponsor/servicer selects the assets to be
transferred to the SPV, and the terms of the Offering Prospectus typically misrepresents the level
of objectivity and fairness of the servicer/sponsor; b) the sponsor/servicer selects collateral for
substitution where there are problems – the past and present disclosure statements and ABS
2) The “mens rea’ or "mental" element of willfulness — the specific intent to misrepresent the
sponsor/servicer which constitutes a conflict-of-interest. Mens Rea is also clearly inferable from
the facts and circumstances - the sponsor/servicer clearly has significant economic, psychological
and legal incentives to maximize its profits by: a) delaying substitution of collateral for as long as
with sub-standard collateral; all of which make the sponsor very un-suitable for the role of
servicer.
These form the primary source of knowledge and valuation terms for the investor.
4) The victim(s) suffers loss as a result of the misrepresentations (direct or proximate
of its obligations, fairness, objectivity and fiduciary duties – a) investors’ estimates of the
values of ABS are inaccurate and too high due to the servicer’s/sponsor’s
portfolios as the ABS becomes riskier, c) investors and the sponsor/servicer incurs
substitution. Furthermore, in the ABS sales process, the underwriter makes certain
Under certain conditions, investors relying on such representations may have a securities
The SPV Is A Trust, The Declaration of Trust Is Void Because Its For An Illegal
Purpose.
The declaration of trust relating to the SPV is void because the intent and purpose of
the SPV is illegal and unconstitutional as described in this article and in Nwogugu (2006).
Under present accounting rules in the US and most countries, if certain criteria were
met, the debt raised by the SPV in securitization can be treated as off-balance sheet debt — but
(ii) The sponsor’s transfer of the assets to the SPV should be a “true sale” and the sponsor
(iii) The form and substance should transparently be identical, and the structure should not
However, this off-balance-sheet treatment criteria has been recently reformed by changes in
accounting standards. The UK-based International Accounting Standards Board and the US
The off-balance sheet treatment of ABS debt in securitizations, constitutes fraud because:
1) The “mens rea’ or "mental" element of willfulness — the specific intent to misrepresent the
true “Trust” nature of the SPV debt is manifsted by the elaborate arrangements and structure of
2) The “actus reus” (the guilty conduct). This consists of the affirmative act of
misrepresentation of materials facts by not consolidating the SPV on the sponsor’s Balance Sheet.
because the sponsor: a) typically retains a residual economic interest in the SPV; b) functions as
servicer of the SPV asset pool – which grants the sponsor signifcant control over the assets and
the SPV’s operations, c) determines recognition of impairment of collateral, and selects and
provides assets for ‘substitution’ of collateral, d) typically misrepresents the level of objectivity
and fairness of the servicer/sponsor in disclosure statements. Taken together, these factors and
3) The reliance element. The sponsor’s current and prospective shareholders and other
securitizations, which are relatively complex. These form the primary source of
its obligations – a) investors’ estimates of the values of the sponsor’s equity are
inaccurate and too high due to the servicer’s/sponsor’s misrepresentations of the SPV
debt, b) investors incur unnecessary trading costs to re-balance their portfolios as the
sponsor is deemed more risky, c) the investor and the sponsor/servicer incurs additional
Fraudulent Conveyances.
Any transfer/conveyance of a debtor's assets that is deemed to be made for the purposes
fraudulent conveyance. 9 In the US, three sets of laws cover potential fraudulent conveyances:
b) Most states have adopted the Uniform Fraudulent Transfer Act (UFTA)10 or the older
9
See: Schwarcz Steven, Enron And The Use And Abuse Of Special Purpose Entities In
Corporate Structures, 70 U. Cin. L. Rev. 1309 (2002).
See: Schwarcz, Steven, Securitization Post-Enron, 25 Cardozo L. Rev. 1539 (2004).
See: Thomas Plank, 2004 Symposium: The Security Of Securitization And The Future Of
Security, 25 Cardozo L. Rev. 1655 (2004).
See: Thomas H, Effects Of Asset Securitization On Seller Claimants, Journal Of financial
Intermediation, 10: 306-330.
See: Yamazaki, Kenji, What Makes Asset Securitization “Inefficient” ? Working Paper # 603,
Berkeley Electronic Press.
10
The Uniform Fraudulent Transfer Act reads as follows:
SECTION 4. TRANSFERS FRAUDULENT AS TO PRESENT AND FUTURE CREDITORS:
(a) A transfer made or obligation incurred by a debtor is fraudulent as to a creditor, whether the
creditor's claim arose before or after the transfer was made or the obligation was incurred, if the
(1) with actual intent to hinder, delay, or defraud any creditor of the debtor; or
(2) without receiving a reasonably equivalent value in exchange for the transfer or obligation, and
the debtor: (i) was engaged or was about to engage in a business or a transaction for which the
remaining assets of the debtor were unreasonably small in relation to the business or transaction;
Or (ii) intended to incur, or believed or reasonably should have believed that he [or she] would
incur, debts beyond his [or her] ability to pay as they became due.
(b) In determining actual intent under subsection (a)(1), consideration may be given, among other
factors, to whether:
(1) the transfer or obligation was to an insider;
(2) the debtor retained possession or control of the property transferred after the transfer;
(3) the transfer or obligation was disclosed or concealed;
(4) before the transfer was made or obligation was incurred, the debtor had been sued or
threatened with suit;
(5) the transfer was of substantially all the debtor's assets;
(6) the debtor absconded;
(7) the debtor removed or concealed assets;
c) Fraudulent Transfers claims can also be made under a theory of constructive fraud, in
which circumstantial evidence may warrant a finding that fraudulent transfers were made with the
primary purpose of shielding assets from current or future creditors. Although each state has its
own laws regarding the appropriate elements of proof of constructive fraud, Section 548(a)(2) of
the US Bankruptcy Code permits an inference of constructive fraud if the following factors exist:
1) the debtor received less than reasonably equivalent value for the property transferred; and 2)
the debtor either: was insolvent or became insolvent as a result of the transfer, retained
unreasonably small capital after the transfer, or made the transfer with the intent or belief that it
The following are various theories of fraudulent conveyance within the context of
securitization.
(8) the value of the consideration received by the debtor was reasonably equivalent to the
value of the asset transferred or the amount of the obligation incurred;
(9) the debtor was insolvent or became insolvent shortly after the transfer was made or
the obligation was incurred;
(10) the transfer occurred shortly before or shortly after a substantial debt was incurred;
and
(11) the debtor transferred the essential assets of the business to a lienor who transferred
the assets to an insider of the debtor.
Under both the US Bankruptcy Code and UFTA (Section 544 of the US Bankruptcy Code also
allows unsecured creditors to sue in Federal Bankruptcy Court using applicable state), judges
must determine whether there has been fraudulent conveyance. Courts have developed a series of
factors as criteria for proving the requisite intent. The factors to be considered (“badges of
fraud”) in determining where there has been fraudulent conveyance include:
Whether the transfer represented substantially all of the debtor's assets.
Whether the transfer was made around the time a substantial debt was incurred.
Whether the debtor received reasonable consideration equivalent to the value of the assets
conveyed or the obligation incurred.
Whether the debtor became insolvent soon after the transfer.
Whether the transfer was made to insiders or family members.
Whether the transfer or the assets were concealed
All ‘true sale” and ‘assignment’ securitizations involve fraudulent conveyances
(as defined in the US Bankruptcy Code and the Uniform Fraudulent Transfer Act )
because the originator typically receives insufficient value for assets that it transfers to
the SPV11,12:
i) horizon mismatch – in the case of receivables and fixed income assets, since the
originator/sponsor sells these assets before their maturities, their effective yields and
values are much lower than their stated yields, and hence, the originator receives less-
ii) the Originator always incurs substantial cash and non-cash transaction costs in
such transfers, which reduces the net-value it receives from the transfer to the SPV –
these costs include legal fees, accounting fees, underwriting fees, monitoring costs,
11
See: Roman Dan, Sarlito M & Mukhtiar A (Winter 2007). Risks to Consider When
Purchasing Technology-based IP for Securitization. Working Paper.
See: Nolan Anthony, Synthetic Securitizations and Derivatives Transactions by Banks: Selected
Regulatory Issues. The Journal of Structured Finance, Fall 2006.
See: Lucas Douglas, Goodman Laurie & Fabozzi Frank, Hybrid Assets in an ABS CDO:
Structural Advantages and Cash Flow Mechanics, Journal Of Structured Finance (Fall 2006).
See: Prince, Jeffrey, A General Review of CDO Valuation Methods. Journal Of Structured And
Project Finance (Summer 2006).
12
See: Peter V. Pantaleo et al., Rethinking the Role of Recourse in the Sale of Financial Assets,
52 Bus. Law. 159, 159-63 (1996)(discussing types of permissible and impermissible recourse for
sale treatment).
See: Thomas E. Plank, The True Sale of Loans and the Role of Recourse, 14 GEO. MASON L.
Rev. 287 (1991).
See: Gordon T (2000). Securitization Of Executory Future Flows As bankruptcy-Remote True
Sales. University Of Chicago Law Review, 67:1317-1322.
See: Higgin E & Mason J (2004). What Is The value of Recourse To Asset-Backed Securities ? A
Study Of Credit Card Bank ABS Rescues. Journal Of Banking & Finance, 28(4); 857-874.
securitize has inherent negotiation costs, conflict costs and resource allocation costs),
etc.;
iii) in these asset transfers, the Originator looses all the future appreciation of the
transferred assets – the transfers are done at book values or stated adjusted costs – the
asset valuation for the transfers don’t consider future increases in asset value, and hence
iv) where the assets transferred have residual values (as in computer leases and
equipment leases), the originator often cannot accurately calculate such residual values
accurately and does not incorporate them in asset valuation, and looses such residual
value, and hence, receives less than normal value for the assets transferred; v) in some
securitizations, the Originator’s transfer of assets to the SPV is backed by recourse (to the
originator’s assets) and such recourse has economic value that reduces the net-value that
the Originator receives from the transfer – Higgin & Mason (2004), Pantaleo et al (1996)
and Plank (1991) 13 describe the basis for the value of such recourse.
the chosen form of financing, and under fraudulent conveyance laws, securitizations are
13
See: Peter V. Pantaleo et al., Rethinking the Role of Recourse in the Sale of Financial Assets,
52 Bus. Law. 159, 159-63 (1996)(discussing types of permissible and impermissible recourse for
sale treatment);
See: Thomas E. Plank, The True Sale of Loans and the Role of Recourse, 14 GEO. MASON L.
Rev. 287 (1991).
See: Higgin E & Mason J (2004). What Is The value of Recourse To Asset-Backed Securities ? A
Study Of Credit Card Bank ABS Rescues. Journal Of Banking & Finance, 28(4); 857-874.
See: Lois R. Lupica, Revised Article 9, Securitization Transactions and the Bankruptcy
Dynamic, 9 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 287, 291-92 (2001).
See: Carol M. Rose, Crystals and Mud in Property Law, 40 STAN. L. REV. 577, 600 (1988).
See: Louis Kaplow, Rules Versus Standards: An Economic Analysis, 42 DuKE L.J. 557 (1992).
2) the distressed company’s assets are typically valued at higher interest rates (which
yield lower asset values) and hence, the originator looses value in the transfers.
often significantly less than either the pre-transaction carrying value of the collateral, or the net
realizable value of the collateral (liquidation value in a supervised open auction) – primarily
conveyances (as defined in the US Bankruptcy Code and the Uniform Fraudulent Transfer Act )
because as described in this article, such securitizations are the equivalent of illegal pre-petition
waivers of the right to file bankruptcy, and the waiver of the bankruptcy stay – all of which are
sufficient evidence of “intent to hinder, delay, or defraud any creditor of the debtor”, which is the
major element of fraudulent conveyance under the UFTA and the US Bankruptcy Code.
Assets To SPV.
conveyances (as defined in the US Bankruptcy Code and the Uniform Fraudulent
SPV reduces the values of any of its un-secured creditor’s claims – ie. trade creditors,
holders of unsecured loans, holders of certain preferred stock, etc.. 14 Without such
14
See: Yamazaki, Kenichi, What makes Asset Securitization “Inefficient” ?,2005. Working
Paper #603, Berkeley Electronic Press.
transfers, un-secured creditors would have had access to such assets. This is sufficient
The originator’s transfer of assets to the SPV via a “true sale” or “assignment” is
the choice of appraised collateral, the corporate form and life of the SPV, and the
selection of the officers/trustees of the SPV. Hence, the originator can manipulate the
values of collateral for accounting and economic purposes. The originator typically
creates, funds and staffs the SPV – hires the SPV’s officers and directors and determines
the SPV’s corporate governance policies. The combination of such excessive control,
and the originator’s transfer of assets to the SPV is prima facie evidence of ‘intent to
Securitization can increase the bankruptcy risk of an originator 15, where: a) the cash
proceeds from the securitization transaction are significantly less than either the carrying value of
the collateral, or the net realizable value of the collateral (liquidation value in a supervised
auction); or b) management reinvests the cash proceeds of securitization in projects that yield
returns that are less than what the collateral would have yielded or less than the company’s cost
of debt.
15
See: Yamazaki (2005), supra.
Securitization via assignments or ‘disguised loans’ increases the risk of the
originator/sponsor, and also increases its post-transaction cost of capital primarily because: a) the
amount raised is less than the assets pledged, b) the pledge of assets to the SPV reduces the
originator’s borrowing capacity and financial flexibility, c) the pledge of assets to the SPV
reduces the originator’s ability to repay other debt. Hence, the originator/sponsor looses value in
Securitization undermines US federal bankruptcy policy, because its used (in lieu of
16
See: Schwarcz (2002), supra.
See: Schwarcz (2004), supra.
See: Klee & Butler, supra.
See: Lipson J C (2002). Enron, Asset Securitization And Bankruptcy Reform: Dead or Dormant
? Journal Of Bankruptcy Law & Practice, 11: 1-15.
See: Lupica L (2001). Revised Articles Nine, Securitization Transactions And The Bankruptcy
Dynamic. American Bankruptcy Institute Law Review, 9:287-299.
See: Garmaise M (2001). Rational Beliefs And Security Design. Review Of Financial Studies,
14(4):1183-1213.
See: David A (1997). Controlling Information Premia By Repackaging Asset Backed Securities.
Journal Of Risk & Insurance, 64(4):619-648.
See: DeMarzo P (2005).. The Pooling And Tranching Of Securities: A Model Of Informed
Intermediation. Review Of Financial Studies, 18(1):1-35.
See: Report By The Committee On Bankruptcy And Corporate Reorganization Of The
Association Of The Bar Of The City Of New York (2000). New Developments In Structured
Finance. The Business Lawyer, 56: 95-105.
See: Lupica L (2000). Circumvention Of The Bankruptcy Process: The Statutory
Institutionalization Of Securitization. Connecticut Law Review, 33:199-209.
See: Glover S (1992). Structured Finance Goes Chapter Eleven: Asset Securitization By The
Reorganizing Companies. The Business Lawyer, 47:611-621.
See: Gordon T (2000). Securitization Of Executory Future Flows As bankruptcy-Remote True
Sales. University Of Chicago Law Review, 67:1317-1322.
See: Elmer P (____). Conduits: Their Stricture And Risk. FDIC Banking Review, pp.27-40.
Available at http://www.lebow.drexel.edu/mason/fin650.elmer.pdf.
See: Lois R. Lupica, Revised Article 9, Securitization Transactions and the Bankruptcy
Dynamic, 9 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 287, 291-92 (2001).
See: Steven L. Schwarcz, The Inherent Irrationality of Judgment Proofing, 52 STAN. L. REV. 1
(1999).
securitization in the US can be traced directly to efforts by banks and financial institutions to
An analysis of the legislative intent of the US Congress with regard to the US Bankruptcy
Code confirms that securitization contravenes most policies of the US Bankruptcy Code 17. These
determination of claims and priorities of security interests; d) fair division of value; e) the
In most cases, Insolvency often occurs before management decides to file for
bankruptcy. Many firms that are either financially distressed and or technically insolvent
continue to operate as if they are normal companies, and enter into securitization transactions –
often securitization enables them to reduce the effect of actual and or perceived low credit ratings.
See: Lynn M. LoPucki, The Irrefutable Logic of Judgment Proofing: A Reply to Professor
Schwarcz, 52 STAN. L. REV. 55 (1999).
See: Steven L. Schwarcz, The Impact on Securitization of Revised UCC Article 9, 74 Cm. -
KENT L. REV. 947 (1999) ("Revised Article 9 attempts to broaden its coverage to virtually all
securitized assets.").
See: Christopher W. Frost, Asset Securitization and Corporate Risk Allocation, 72 TuL. L. REV.
101 (1997);
See: Claire A. Hill, Securitization: A Low-Cost Sweetener for Lemons, 74 WASH. U. L.Q. 1061
(1996).
See: Steven L. Schwarcz, Judgment Proofing: A Rejoinder, 52 STAN. L. REV. 77 (1999).
17
See: Reams B & Manz W (eds.), FEDERAL BANKRUPTCY LAW: A LEGISLATIVE
HISTORY OF THE BANKRUPTCY REFORM ACT OF 1994.
See: The Legislative History of the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act
of 2005; (FRB Leg. Hist); (S. 256 -LoC); Pub. L. 109-8, April 20, 2005, 119 Stat, 23.
http://www.llsdc.org/sourcebook/leg-hist.htm
See: Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978: A Legislative History, Hein.
See: Federal Bankruptcy Law: A Legislative History of The Bankruptcy Act of 1994; Pub. L. No.
103-394, 108 Stat. 4106, including the National Bankruptcy Commission Act and Bankruptcy
Amendments (1987-1993).
See: Ahern, Lawrence (Spring 2001). “Workouts” Under Revised Article Nine: A Review Of
Changes And Proposal For Study. American Bankruptcy Institute Law Review, 9:115-125.
See: Ribstein, Larry & Kobayashi, Bruce (1996). An Economic Analysis Of Uniform State
Laws. Journal Of Legal Studies, 25(1):131-199.
Securitization is often a major strategic choice for financially distressed companies. 18 Under the
bankruptcy-remote SPV and segregating the assets that otherwise would have been part of the
bankruptcy estate. 19,20 Securitization involves an implicit (and sometime express) waiver of the
18
See: Ashta A & Tolle L (200). Criteria For Selecting Restructuring Strategies For Distressed
Or Declining Enterprises. Cahners Du Ceren, 6:1-20.
See: Carlson D (1998). The Rotten Foundations Of Securitization. William & Mary Law Review,
39: .
See: Higgin E & Mason J (2004). What Is The value of Recourse To Asset-Backed Securities ? A
Study Of Credit Card Bank ABS Rescues. Journal Of Banking & Finance, 28(4); 857-874.
See: Albany Insurance v. Esses, 831 F2d 41 (CA2, 1987)(making false statements about value of
asset was a “predicate act”); Howell Hydrocarbons v. Adams, 897 F2d 183 (CA5 1990)(under
federal RICO statutes, making a company look solvent when its not, constitutes a ‘predicate act’);
Matter of Lewisville Properties, 849 F2d 946 (CA5, 1988)(under federal RICO, false pretenses
constitutes ‘predicate acts”).
See: Bens D & Monahan S (Feb. 2005). Altering Investment Decisions To Management
Financial Reporting Outcomes: Asset Backed Commercial Paper Conduits And FIN 46.
Working Paper.
19
In the following cases, courts held that pre-petition waivers of the right to file for
voluntary/involuntary bankruptcy, were unenforceable. See: In Re Huang, 275 F3d 1177 (CA9,
2002)(its is against public policy for a debtor to waive the pre-petition protection of the
Bankruptcy Code); In Re South East Financial Associates, 21 BR 1003 (M.D.Fla, 1997); In Re
Tru Block Concrete Products Ins, 27 BR 486 (E.D.Pa., 1995)(advance agreement to waive the
benefits of bankruptcy law is void as against public policy); In Re Madison, 184 BR 686, 690
(E.D.Pa, 1995)(even bargained-for and knowing waivers of the right to seek bankruptcy
protection must be deemed void); In Re Club Tower LP, 138 BR 307 at 312 (N.D.Ga, 1991); In
Re Graves, 212 BR 692 (BAP, CA1, 1997); In Re pease, 195 BR 431 (D.Neb., 1996); In Re
Jenkins Court Associates Ltd. Partnership, 181 BR 33 (E.D.Pa., 1995); In Re Sky Group
International Inc., 108 BR 86 (W.D.Pa., 1989); Association of St.Croix Condominium Owners v.
St. Croix Hotel Corp., 692 F2d 446 (CA3, 1982). But contrast: In Re University Commons LP,
200 BR 255 (M.D.Fla.)(debtors agreement that in the event debtor enters bankruptcy proceedings,
the secured lender shall be entitled to court order dismissing the case as ‘bad faith’ filing an
determining that: (i) no rehabilitation or reorganization is possible, and ii) dismissing all
creditor/ABS-investor’s right to file for involuntary bankruptcy21, 22 – US courts have repeatedly
proceedings is in the best interests of parties and all other creditors, is binding); In Re Little Creek
Development, 779 F2d 1068 (CA5, 1986).
See: Klee, Kenneth & Butler, Brendt (_____), Asset-backed Securitization, Special Purpose
Vehicles And Other Securitization. Working Paper. Cases that enforced pre-petition waivers of
the automatic stay focus upon: (i) the financial sophistication of the borrower; (ii) the creditor’s
demonstration that significant consideration was given for the pre-petition waiver; (iii) the effect
of the enforcement of the pre-petition waiver upon other parties having legitimate interests in the
outcome; (iv) circumstances of the parties at the time enforcement of the pre-petition waiver
is sought; (v) the enforcement of the pre-petition waiver being consistent with public policy of
encouraging out of court restructurings and settlements with creditors; and (vi) other indicia
which support granting relief from stay, such as “bad faith” criteria (i.e. single-asset case, two-
party dispute, long history of pre-petition workouts, newly formed entity, filing on eve of
foreclosure, no ongoing business to reorganize, few employees, no unencumbered funds,
etc.). Cases that held that pre-petition stay waivers were enforceable include: In Re Shady Grove
Tech Ctr. Assocs., L.P., 216 B.R.386, 390 (Bankr. D. Md. 1998); In Re Atrium High Point
L.P., 189 B.R. 599, 607 (Bankr. M.D.N.C. 1995); In Re Darrell Creek Assocs.,
L.P., 187 B.R. 908, 910 (Bankr. D.S.C. 1995); In Re Cheeks, 167 B.R. 817, 818
(Bankr. D.S.C. 1994); In Re Powers, 170 B.R. 480, 483 (Bankr. D. Mass. 1994); In
Re McBride Estates, Ltd., 154 B.R. 339, 343 (Bankr. N.D. Fla. 1993); In Re
Citadel Properties, Inc., 86 B.R. 275, 276 (Bankr. M.D. Fla. 1988); In Re Gulf
Beach Development Corp., 48 B.R. 40, 43 (Bankr. M.D. Fla. 1985). Several courts, however,
have refused to enforce pre-petition waivers for any of the following reasons: (i) the pre-petition
waiver is the equivalent to an ipso facto clause; (ii) such clause is void as against public policy by
depriving the debtor of the use and benefit of property upon the filing of a bankruptcy case; (iii)
the borrower lacks the capacity to act on behalf of the debtor in possession; (iv) the debtor has a
business with a reasonable chance at reorganization and enforcement of the waiver would
otherwise prejudice third-party creditors; (v) the automatic stay is designed to protect all creditors
and may not be waived by the debtor unilaterally to the detriment of creditors; and (vi) the waiver
was obtained by coercion, fraud or mutual mistake of facts. Courts that have refused to enforce
pre-petition waivers of the automatic stay have reasoned that the automatic stay protects not only
debtors but also other creditors. US Courts disagree sharply about the utility, benefits and
desirability of the enforcement of pre-petition waivers, and relevant criteria. Some courts have
held that a pre-petition automatic stay waiver may be considered as a factor in determining
whether cause exists for relief from the stay. See: In Re Darrell Creek Assocs., L.P., 187 B.R.
908, 913 (Bankr. D.S.C. 1995) (“out of court workouts are to be encouraged and are often
effective”); In Re Cheeks, 167 B.R. 817, 819 (Bankr. D.S.C. 1994) (“the most compelling reason
for enforcement of the forbearance agreement is to further the public policy in favor
of encouraging out of court restructuring and settlements”); In Re Club Tower
L.P., 138 B.R. 307, 312 (Bankr. N.D. Ga. 1991) (“enforcing pre-petition settlement agreements
furthers the legitimate public policy of encouraging out of court restructurings and settlements”).
Cases holding pre-petition automatic stay waivers unenforceable include: In Re Southeast
Financial Assocs., Inc., 212 B.R. 1003, 1005 (Bankr. M.D. Fla. 1997); In Re Graves, 212 B.R.
692, 694 (B.A.P. 1st Cir. 1997); In Re Pease, 195 B.R. 431, 433 (Bankr. D. Neb. 1996); In Re
Jenkins Court Assocs. L.P., 181 B.R. 33, 37 (Bankr. E.D. Pa. 1995);Farm Credit
of Cent. Fla., ACA v. Polk, 160 B.R. 870, 873-74 (M.D. Fla. 1993); Farm Credit of Cent. Fla.,
ACA v. Polk, 160 B.R. 870, 873-74 (M.D. Fla. 1993)(“The policy behind the automatic stay is to
protect the debtor’s estate from being depleted by creditor’s lawsuits and seizures of property
before the debtor has had a chance to marshal the estate’s assets and distribute them equitably
among creditors.”); In Re Sky Group Int’l, Inc., 108 B.R. 86, 89 (Bankr. W.D.
Pa. 1989) (“To grant a creditor relief from stay simply because the debtor elected to waive the
protection afforded the debtor by the automatic stay ignores the fact that it also is designed to
protect all creditors and to treat them equally”) (citing Assoc. of St. Croix Condominium Owners
v. St. Croix Hotel Corp., 682 F.2d 446 (3d Cir. 1982)). Also see: In re Shady Grove Tech Ctr.
Assocs., L.P., 216 B.R. 386, 393-94 (Bankr. D. Md. 1998); In re S.E. Fin.
Assocs., Inc., 212 B.R. 1003, 1005 (Bankr. M.D. Fla. 1997); In re Darrell Creek
Assocs., L.P., 187 B.R. 908, 910 (Bankr. D.S.C. 1995); In re Powers, 170 B.R.
held that such waivers are void as against public policy. In the absence of securitization, this
implicit waiver is achieved by using an SPV and segregating the assets that otherwise would have
been part of the bankruptcy estate; and by various forms of credit enhancement. Without the
automatic stay of the bankruptcy code, the debtor/sponsor would not need to transfer assets to an
SPV – Carlson (1998) traces the history of securitization to direct and specific
enforceability of pre-petition waivers (of rights to file for voluntary or involuntary bankruptcy)
which has not been resolved by the US Supreme Court 24 – however, the standard securitization
processes differ substantially from the conditions in cases where the courts held that pre-petition
480, 483 (Bankr. D. Mass. 1994); In re Cheeks, 167 B.R. 817, 819 (Bankr. D.S.C.
1994); In Re Shady Grove Tech Ctr. Assocs., L.P., 216 B.R. 386, 393-94 (Bankr.
D. Md. 1998) (granting stay relief for cause based upon finding which included
debtor’s pre-petition agreement not to contest request for stay relief given as
part of pre-petition restructuring in which debtor was afforded substantial
consideration).
23
See: Schwarcz S. (1999). Rethinking Freedom Of Contract: A Bankruptcy Paradigm. Texas
Law Review, 77: 515-599.
See: Klee K & Butler B (_____). Asset-Backed Securitization, Special Purpose Vehicles And
Other Securitization Issues. Uniform Commercial Code Law Journal, 35(2):.
See: Carlson D (1998). The Rotten Foundations Of Securitization. William & Mary Law Review,
39:
24
See notes 5, 6, 19 and 20, supra.
F2. The US Bankruptcy Code Expressly Invalidates Certain Pre-filing Transfers
Sections of the US bankruptcy code that expressly invalidate certain types of pre-filing
transfers, payments and transactions (that occur within a specific time period before the filing of
bankruptcy). Most securitizations fall under the classes of voidable pre-flinging transfers. Hence
under these foregoing circumstances/conditions, bankruptcy laws and associated principles are
implicated and apply where the firm has not filed for bankruptcy. Therefore, any pre-bankruptcy-
filing transactions that invalidate or contravene the principles of bankruptcy codes are illegal.
bankruptcy law.
The following are new theories that explain how securitization contravenes the principles
of US bankruptcy laws.
Securitization can result in fraudulent conveyance and illegal wealth transfer where the
fraudulently transfers value to the SPV (in the form of low collateral values) and then to the
ABS/MBS bond holders (in the form of low bond prices, and or high interest rates). 25 Courts
have held that stripping a company of the ability to pay judgment claims is a ‘predicate act’ that
is actionable under federal RICO statutes26. Securitization can also result in illegal wealth
25
See: Shakespeare C (20030. Do Managers Use Securitization Volume And Fair Value
Estimates To Hit Earning Targets ? Working Paper, University Of Michigan (School Of
Business)
See: Shakespeare C (2001). Accounting For Asset Securitizations: Complex Fair Values And
Earnings Management. Working Paper, University Of Michigan.
26
Wooten v. Loshbough, 649 Fsupp 531 (N.D.Ind. 1986)(on reconsideration) 738 Fsupp 314
(affirmed) 951 F2d 768 (under federal RICO statutes, stripping of company’s ability to pay
judgment claim was ‘predicate act’).
transfers to the intermediary bank where it retains a residual interest in the Trust/SPV (residual
To the extent that bankruptcy laws are designed to facilitate rehabilitation of troubled
companies, and increase efficient allocation of debtor assets to creditors, securitization enables
the debtor to defeat the Absolute-Priority principle; and to effectively re-arrange priorities of
claims, particularly where the debtor/originator does not have any secured claims (but has only
un-secured claims). This is achieved by securitizing un-encumbered assets and using credit
creditors.
distress, by supplying cash that typically lasts for short periods of time, and often at a high
effective cost of funds. This implicates the principles of ‘inefficient continuance’ (where an
court orders), and hence, the sections of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (“SOX”) - which require
certification of solvency of the company and adequacy of internal controls, and also carry
criminal penalties for non-compliance. 27 The question of whether ‘inefficient continuance’ has
occurred is a matter of law that should be decided by judges. Thus, all else remaining constant,
where the necessary elements occur, (a securitization and ‘inefficient continuance’ and
management’s certification of solvency and adequate internal controls), management and the
27
See: Kulzick R (2004). Sarbanes-Oxley: Effects on Financial Transparency. S.A.M. Advanced
Management Journal, 69(1): 43-49.
G4. The Information-Content Effect Theory –
insurance, etc.) are used to achieve a high credit rating for the SPV – which may be mis-
To the extent that all securities offerings have relevant information content and associated
signaling, then securitization by financially distressed companies effectively conveys the wrong
signals to capital markets and hence, changes the expectations of creditors and shareholders (and
in the case of bankruptcy, makes it more difficult to efficiently form consensus on a plan of
reorganization once the bankruptcy petition is filed). In this realm, investor and creditor
expectations are critical and have utility value and typically form the basis for
Courts have held that persons that create false impressions about the financial condition of a
To the extent that securitzation defers or eliminates a potential creditor’s rights to file for
involuntary bankruptcy, then securitization can be deemed to be fraudulent, and gives rise to
criminal causes of action such as deceit, conversion, etc. The creditor’s right to file for a debtor’s
involuntary bankruptcy is a valid property right that arises from state property law, state contract
law, state constitutional laws, and federal bankruptcy laws. 29 Deprivation of, or interference with
this property right is a violation of the US constitution. Securitization can defer or eliminate this
28
See: Albany Insurance v. Esses, 831 F2d 41 (CA2, 1987)(under federal RICO statutes, making
false statements about the value of asset was a ‘predicate act”); Howell Hydrocarbons v. Adams,
897 F2d 183 (CA5 1990)(under federal RICO statutes, making a company look solvent when its
not, constitutes a ‘predicate act’).
29
See: Lockheed Martin v. Boeing, 357 Fsupp2d 1350 (M.D.Fla., 2005)(bidder violated
competitor’s property rights to proprietary information by using that information to produce
wining bids).
property right, and hence violate the US constitution where the transaction: a) effectively re-
arranges priority of claims; or b) reduces the debtor-company’s borrowing capacity (value of un-
uses the proceeds of the transaction to pay-off some (but not all) members of a potential class of
transactions which serve as ‘predicate acts’ under federal RICO statutes30. The specific
sponsor/issuer and the intermediary bank and on occasion, the SPV’s trustees. This
presents opportunities for “predicate acts” (ie. fraud, conversion, etc.) because:
30
See: Colloff M (2005). The Role of the Trustee in Mitigating Fraud in Structured Financings.
Journal of Structured Finance, 10(4):73-85.
independent/certified trustees in securitization transactions. The parties involved are often
2. The trustees can be, and are influenced by the sponsor/originator and or
intermediary investment-bank.
include historical performance of collateral pools, b) does not include criteria for
4. Mail and wire are used extensively in communications with investors and
substantial incentives to under-price the securities, and to inflate/deflate the value of the
because:
See: Shakespeare C (20030. Do Managers Use Securitization Volume And Fair Value Estimates
To Hit Earning Targets ? Working Paper, University Of Michigan (School Of Business)
See: Shakespeare C (2001). Accounting For Asset Securitizations: Complex Fair Values And
Earnings Management. Working Paper, University Of Michigan.
See: Katyal K (2003). Conspiracy theory. The Yale Law Journal, 112(6):1307-1398.
See: Geary W (2002). The legislative recreation of RICO: Reinforcing The ''myth'' of organized
Crime. Crime, Law & Social Change, 38(4):311-315.
See: Kulzick R (2004). Sarbanes-Oxley: Effects On Financial Transparency. S.A.M. Advanced
Management Journal, 69(1): 43-49.
See: Painter R (2004). Convergence And Competition In Rules Governing Lawyers and
Auditors. Journal of Corporation Law, 29(2):397-426.
See: Jordans R (2003). The legal approach to investment advisers in different jurisdictions.
Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance, 11(2):169-171.
See: Blanque P (2003). Crisis and fraud. Journal of Financial Regulation & Compliance,
11(1):60-70.
1. There is the requisite criminal or civil “enterprise” – consisting of the
sponsor/issuer, the trustees and the intermediary bank. These three parties work closely
a) Mail fraud - using the mails for sending out materials among themselves and to
investors.
transaction.
See: Pickhjolz M & Pickholz J (2001). Manipulation. Journal of Financial Crime, 9(2):117-133.
See: Zey M(1999). The subsidiarization of the securities industry and the organization of
securities fraud networks to return profits in the 1980s. Work and Occupations, 26(1):50-76.
See: Aicher R, Cotton D & Khan T (2004). Credit Enhancement: Letters of Credit, Guaranties,
Insurance and Swaps. The Business Lawyer, 59(3):897-973.
See: Brief T & MsSweeney T (2003). Corporate Criminal Liability. The American Criminal
Review, 40(2): 337-366.
See: Landrum D (2003). Governance of limited liability companies - Contrasting California and
Delaware models. The Real Estate Finance Journal, 19(1):
31
See: 18 USC 1961-1968.
32
See: Alexander v. Thornbough, 713 FSupp 1271 (D.Minn. 1989)(appeal dismissed) 881 F2d
1081; Mira v. Nuclear Measurements Corp., 107 F3d 466 (CA7, 1997); US v. Manzella, 782 F2d
533 (CA5, 1986)(cert. Denied.) 476 US 1123; Cadle Co v. Flanagan, 271 Fsupp2d 379
(D.Conn., 2003); Seale v. Miller, 698 Fsupp 883 (N.D.G.A., 1988); Georgia Gulf Corp. v. Ward,
701 Fsupp 1556 (NDGA 1988); Wooten v. Loshbough, 649 FSupp. 531 (N.D.Ind. 1986)(on
reconsideration) 738 Fsupp 314 (affirmed) 951 F2d 768 (stripping of company’s ability to pay
judgment claim was ‘predicate act’ under RICO statutes); Formax v. Hostert, 841 F2d 388
(CAFed, 1988); Abell v. Potomac Insurance, 858 F2d 1104 (CA5, 1988) (appeal after remand)
946 F2d 1160 (cert. denied) 492 US 918; Aetna Ca. Ins. Co. v. P & B Autobody, 43 F3d 1546
(CA1, 1994); Albany Insurance v. Esses, 831 F2d 41 (CA2, 1987)(making false statements about
value of asset was a “predicate act”); Alfadda v. Fenn, 935 F2d 475 (CA2, 1991)(certiorari
denied) 502 US 1005; Laird v. Integrated Resources, 897 F2d 826 (CA5, 1990); Shearin v. E F
Hutton, 885 F2d 1162 (CA3, 1989); Bank One Of Cleveland v. Abbe, 916 F2d 1067 (CA6, 1990);
BancOklahoma Mortgage Corp. v. Capital Title Co., 194 F3d 1089 (CA10, 1999); Howell
Hydrocarbons v. Adams, 897 F2d 183 (CA5 1990)(under federal RICO statutes, making a
company look solvent when its not, constitutes a ‘predicate act’); Matter of Lewisville Properties,
849 F2d 946 (CA5, 1988)(false pretenses constitutes ‘predicate acts”).
e) Securities fraud – disclosure issues.
g) Making false statements and or misleading representations about the value of the
collateral.
h) Stripping the originator/issuer of the ability to pay debt claims or judgment claims in
bankruptcy court – this may apply where the sponsor is financially distressed and the
cash proceeds of the transaction are significantly less than the value of the collateral.
in knowledge (actual and inferable), acts, omissions, purpose (actual and inferable) and
results. Intent can be reasonably inferred from: a) existence of a sponsor that seeks to
raise capital – and obviously cannot raise such capital on better terms using other means,
b) existence of an investment bank that has very strong incentives to consummate the
Also See: Securities Investor Protection Corp. v. Vigman, 908 F2d 1461 (CA9, 1990);
International Data Bank v. Zepkin, 812 F2d 149 (CA4, 1987); Warner v. Alexander Grant & Co.,
828 F2d 14528 (CA11, 1987); Mauriber v. Shearson/American Express, 546 FSupp 391 (SDNY,
1982); Farmers Bank F Delaware v. Bell Mortgage Corp., 452 FSupp 1278 (D.Del, 1978); Moss
v. Morgan Stanley Inc., 719 F2d 5 (CA2, 1983); USACO Coal v. Carbomin Energy Inc., 689 F2d
94 (CA6, 1982); Binkley v. Shaeffer, 609 FSupp 601 (E.D.Pa., 1985); Sedima v. Imrex Co., 473
US 479 (1985); .
I1. Market Concentration: The US ABS and MBS markets are dominated by
relatively few large entities such as FNMA, Freddie Mac, the top-five investment banks
(all of which have conduit programs), the top-five credit card issuers (MBNA, AMEX,
Citigroup, etc.), etc.. Hence the top-five ABS/MBS issuers control more than 50% of the
laws.
I2. Market Integration: The ABS and MBS markets are essentially national and
presentations to investors in various cities – the cost of the roadshow is often paid by the
underwriter(s) before its fees are paid by the sponsor. In addition, there are printing,
mailing, traveling and administrative costs that increase with the greater geographical
See: Glanz M (1983). RICO And Securities Fraud: A Workable Limitation. Columbia Law
Review, 6:1513-1543.
See: Masella J (1991). Standing TO Sue In A Civil RICO Suit Predicated On Violation OF SEC
Rule 10b-5: The Purchase Or Sale Requirement. Columbia Law Review, 91(7):1793-1812.
See: Coffey P (1990). The Selection, Analysis And Approval OF Federal RICO Prosecutions.
Notre Dame Law Review, 65: 1035-1055.
See: Matthews A (1990). Shifting The Burden Of Loses In The Securities Markets: The Role OF
Civil RICO In Securities Litigation. Notre Dame Law Review, 65: 896-906.
33
See: Bradford National Clearing Corp. v. SEC, 590 F2d 1085 (DCCir, 1978); In Re Stock
Exchanges Options Trading Antitrust Litigation, 317 F3d 134 (CA2, 2003); Gordon v. NYSE, 422
US 659 (1975); National Gerimedical Hospital v. Blue Cross Of Kansas City, 452 US 378
(1981); Silver v. NYSE, 373 US 341 (1963)(no antitrust immunity); Strobl v. NY Mercantile
Exchange, 768 F2d 22 (CA2, 1985).
34
dispersion of investors. This has two main effects: a) it reduces competitive pressure on
dominant investment banks and groups of investment banks (to the detriment of smaller
conduct ‘road-shows’ for new offerings. Hence, the market integration created by the
I3. Syndicate Collusion: the syndicates (of investment banks) used in distributing
ABS/MBS essentially collude to determine: a) the price at which each ABS tranche is
a) In the typical ABS offering, the price determination process is not transparent
or democratic because the lead underwriters typically negotiate the offering price with the
originator/sponsor and the prospective investors (but some underwriters use auctions).
The lead underwriters purchase most of the new-issue ABS, and the balance is typically
sold to ‘junior’ syndicate members (who presumably can arrange to buy more ABS from
the lead underwriters than allocated to them). In essence, the true price-demand
hidden simply because of the structure of the underwriting/bidding process. Hence, the
existing syndicate-based ABS distribution system for new issue ABS distorts the true
demand for ABS, reduces competition, and facilitates and results in collusion, and
constitutes violations of the Sherman Act and the FTC Antitrust statutes.
b) Similarly, the ABS allocation process is not transparent. The lead underwriter
accepted major guidelines for such ‘in-house’ criteria and associated allocation. The lead
and junior underwriters can typically collude to determine that only certain investors
deemed appropriate are allocated ABS. Hence, the antitrust violation (collusion) occurs
solely by the underwriters’ discretionary choice of investors to whom ABS are allocated
– this is more evident where the investor pool consists of mostly institutional investors,
and thus, final offering prices are more sensitive to choice of investors, and prices can
accepted allocation criteria that have been approved by the NASD or other trade
associations.
I4. Price Formation: The price of ABS securities is often linked to the price/yields
Treasury bonds. This system distorts the true demand/supply balance for ABS/MBS, and
market, into the ABS/MBS markets. The key question then, is whether there are
conditions under which the US Treasury Bond market is completely de-coupled from the
ABS market, or phrased differently, whether there is sufficient justification for actual or
perceived de-coupling of the US Treasury Bond market and the US ABS market. These
those of the ABS market. The treasury market is much more sensitive to US Federal
etc.). The ABS market tends to be more sensitive to industry-specific and sometimes
company-specific risks/factors.
the differences in the credit trends/quality in the US treasury and ABS markets. In ABS
transactions, most forms of credit enhancement creates a floor, but does not limit or affect
3. The investor objectives in the US treasury bond markets differ from those of
investors in ABS markets. Hence, investors are very likely to view these two markets
and the underlying risks differently, and should value the securities differently.
I5. Vertical Foreclosure: In the ABS/MBS markets some investment banks and
commercial banks are active in almost all phases of the securitization process –
origination (through their in-house conduits), due diligence, disclosure and pricing, new-
issue securities offerings, and secondary-market trading. Similarly, non-bank entities can
use their own asset portfolios (origination of credit card receivables or mortgage
(pricing and new-issue offerings) and in-house trading desks (secondary-market trading)
have almost no incentive to, and are not required to make their infrastructure and
relationships available to competitors. Such vertical foreclosure constitutes violation of
antitrust laws.
I6. Tying36: a) the sponsor is sometimes formally or informally required to
Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade
or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal. Every
person who shall make any contract or engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby declared
to be illegal shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by
fine not exceeding $10,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other person, $350,000, or by
imprisonment not exceeding three years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the
court.
Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any
other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several
States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof,
shall be punished by fine not exceeding $10,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other person,
$350,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding three years, or by both said punishments, in the
discretion of the court.
investment bank, in order to effect the securitization transaction, b) the investors are
ABS in new offerings; c) the sponsor and or investment may formally or informally
order to get ‘allocations’ in future offerings. These acts constitute tying which is anti-
competitive.
It shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the course of such commerce, to
lease or make a sale or contract for sale of goods, wares, merchandise, machinery, supplies, or
other commodities, whether patented or unpatented, for use, consumption, or resale within the
United States or any Territory thereof or the District of Columbia or any insular possession or
other place under the jurisdiction of the United States, or fix a price charged therefor, or discount
from, or rebate upon, such price, on the condition, agreement, or understanding that the lessee or
purchaser thereof shall not use or deal in the goods, wares, merchandise, machinery, supplies, or
other commodities of a competitor or competitors of the lessor or seller, where the effect of such
lease, sale, or contract for sale or such condition, agreement, or understanding may be to
substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of commerce.
FTC Regulations
36
See: Eastman Kodak Co v. Image technical Services, 504 US 451 (1992); Jefferson parish
Hospital v. Hyde, 466 US 2 (1984); Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, 395 US 100
(1969).
I7. Price-Fixing37 – The Locus-shifting Theory is introduced here. Locus-shifting
occurs when a potential and obvious party to a price-fixing scheme is effectively replaced
(in pricing negotiations) by a third party that has the resources and willingness to
bank is central to ABS offerings, and associated pricing and negotiations, the price fixing
should be deemed to occur between the sponsor/originator and the investment bank (or
between two sponsors). Since each active investment bank typically underwrites many
offerings simultaneously, and essentially controls the pricing of each new-issue ABS, the
investment banks are the locus of said price fixing and are potentially liable for the
analyzing: a) the yield differentials of various ABS offerings in various asset classes (ie.
autos, home equity, mortgages, etc.) by different sponsors within a specific block of time,
b) the price differentials of various ABS offerings in various asset classes (autos, home
equity, credit cards, mortgages, etc.) with the same rating, within a specific block of time.
37
See: Business Electronics Corp. v. Sharp Electronics Corp, 485 US 717 (1988); Copperweld
Corp. v. Independence Tube, 467 US 752 (1984); Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465
US 752 (1984); US v. Arnold, Schwin et al, 388 US 365 (1967); USPS v. Flamingo Industries,
#02-1290 (2004); Brown v. Pro Football, 518 US 213 (1996); FTC v. Ticor Title Insurance
Company, 504 US 621 (1992); Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian head Inc., 486 US 492
(1988).
38
See: Standard Oil Co v. US, 337 US 293 (1949);
See: US v. Griffith, 334 US 100 (1948).
See: Brooke Group Ltd. V. Brown & Williamson Tobacco, 509 US 209 (1993).
Exclusive contracts facilitate and enhance anti-competitive behavior by
contractually restricting conduct by and trade among participants in the market. In the
prevent the intermediary investment bank from providing financial services to other
(by the sponsor, underwriter(s) or third parties) that prevent or limit the formation of a
syndicate of securities dealers; c) contracts that prevent the sponsor from selling
1) Securities that involve pure “pass-through” of cash flows, and hence rights to
payment of cash from the SPV pool, but no ownership interest in the pool to: a) IO –
interest only securities; b) PO – principal only securities; and c) traditional ABS that pay
interest only securities; b) PO – principal only securities; and c) traditional ABS that pay
39
See: Texaco v. Hasbrouck, 496 US 543 (1990); J Truet Payne Co v. Chrysler Motors, 451 US
557 (1981); Great Atlantic & Pacific Tea Co. v. Federal Trade Commission, 440 US 69 (1979);
US v. United States Gypsum, 438 US 422 (1978); FTC v. Sun Oil Co., 371 US 505 (1963).
3) Debt-type securities that involve a security interest in the underlying collateral
In many instances, the SPV offers many tranches in each of the above-mentioned
classes of ABS. The tranches within each class typically vary by term, interest rate,
duration, and bond-rating/risk-rating. Hence, in any situation where the tranches don’t
have any priority as to security interests or rights-to-payment of cash flows from the pool,
asset and risk is essentially the same, although different securities are being offered in the
same transaction (or series of transactions), at different prices to investors, based on the
same underlying pool of assets. The distinguishing and critical element is that there is no
This occurs when investment banks under-price ABS offerings in order to obtain
more investors, and to build name recognition for a particular issuer (that does or intends
to come to the ABS market regularly). Evidence of predatory pricing may be inferred or
established by:
40
See: Brooke Group Ltd. V. Brown & Williamson Tobacco, 509 US 209 (1993); Matsushita
Electric v. Zenith Radio, 475 US 574 (1986); Utah Pie Co. v. Continental Baking Co. et al, 386
US 685 (1967).
a) Comparing the offering prices of various new-issue ABS bonds sold by one
sponsor/originator, in the same asset class (auto loans, home equity, credit cards, etc.),
but at different times of the year, to offering prices of similar ABS bonds sold by other
between: 1) the difference in the yield of company XYZ’s ABS bond and the yields of
other similar ABS bonds, and 2) various independent variables such as yield, price, asset
type, bond rating, duration, industry, amount of offering, frequency of ABS offerings,
by one investment bank (in the same asset class, but at different times of the year) to
offering prices of similar ABS bonds underwritten by other investment banks in the same
time periods.
Most ABS offerings are done via allocations of securities by investment banks to their
brokerage customers.
1. Most sponsors issue ABS/MBS through bids by investment banks. Most bids for ABS
securities are won by a few investment banking firms. This may suggest that customers
have been “allocated” among investment banks. This is also an indication of collusion.
secondary underwriters.
J. Securitization Involves Void Contracts
The process of securitization involves several contracts that are either signed
simultaneously or are all signed within a short time frame. Many of these contracts are
effecting securitizations. Many of these contracts are unilateral executory promises and
The promise made by the SPV to payout periodic interest, whether contingent or
41
See: Parmenter v. FDIC, 925 F2d 1088 (CA8,1991); Ace-Federal Reporters v. Barram, 226
F3d 1329 (Ca.Fed., 2000)(on remand) 2002 WL 1292032; Workman v. UPS, 234 F3d 998 (CA7,
2000); Dibrell Brothers v. Banca Nazionale Del Lavorro, 383 F3d 1571 (CA11, 1999); Gibson v.
Neighborhood Health Clinics, 121 F3d 1126 (CA7, 1997); Floss v. Ryans Family Steakhouses,
211 F3d 306 (CA6, 2000)(cert. denied) 531 US 1072; Heinig Furs, 811 Fsupp 1546 (M.D.Ala.,
1993); Flanders Medeiros v. Bogosian, 88 Fsupp 412 (DRI, 1994)(affirmed in part) 65 F3d 198;
Johnson Enterprises v. FPl Group, 162 F3d 1290 (CA2, 1998); Hoffman v. Bankers Trust, 925
Fsupp 315 (M.D.Pa, 1995); Prudential Insurance v. Sipula, 776 F2d 157 (CA7, 1985); In Re
Sulakshma, 207 BR 422 (E.D.Pa, 1997).
42
See: Gordon T (2000). Securitization Of Executory Future Flows As bankruptcy-Remote True
Sales. University Of Chicago Law Review, 67:1317-1322.
Transfer Agreement. The sponsor agrees to transfer the collateral to the SPV, and
contract. The following are some illusory promises inherent in securitization transactions:
collateral with the cash raised from investors are essentially illusory promises.
These promises are embedded in the offering Prospectus, but are typically not
don’t state the exact steps in the SPV’s promised purchase of the collateral.
interests in the SPV or the SPV’s debt. These beneficial interest evidence: a)
of executing this agreement, the only consideration that the SPV can grant to
the collateral in the future, and to make payments from the SPV’s assets. Hence,
an existing asset is being exchanged for a future asset that does not exist as of the
43
See: Valdiviezo v. Phelps Dodge, 995 Fsupp 1060 (D.Ariz., 1997). Johnson enterprises v. FPL
Group, 162 F3d 1290 (CA2, 1998). Ryan v. Upchurch, 474 Fsupp 211 (SND, 1979)(reversed)
627 F2d 836.
See: Rose J & Dawson P (Sept. 1997). Contingent Transfer - The Illusory Promise Of Structured
Finance. S&P Structured Finance, page 10.
Furthermore, all securitization offerings are done pursuant to ‘Subscription
part of his/her purchase of the SPV’s ABS expressly incorporates the promises
The SPV’s promise to pay interest/dividends on ABS IOs, Preferreds and POs are
essentially illusory promises because the underlying collateral may not produce
any cash flows, in which case there wont be any interest or dividend payments.
iii) No Bargain – some courts have held that there is no consideration (and hence,
the contract is void) where one party was not allowed to bargain for the alleged
agreement. 44. In some securitizations, the process of setting offering prices for new ABS
issues does not afford all parties the opportunity to negotiate terms of the offering,
especially individual investors, because the price of the ABS is typically determined
originator sets the terms of the SPV (trust documents, articles of incorporation, Bylaws,
etc.).
44
Prudential Insurance v. Sipula, 776 F2d 157 (CA7, 1985)(no consideration where party to
contract could not bargain for alleged agreement).
2. No mutuality 45 – in the securitization context, for there to be mutuality: a) each
party must have firm control of the subject matters of the contract and the underlying
assets (consideration), and b) there should be a direct contractual relationship between the
parties. At time of the Subscription Agreement, the SPV typically does not own or have
rights to the collateral, and hence, there is not mutuality. Furthermore, the concept of
‘piercing the SPV veil’ is introduced here (and is similar to piercing the corporate veil)
to the SPV investors, in exchange for a loan to the sponsor. However, there is no
The sponsor typically controls the SPV before the ABS offering and determines
Since prospective ABS investors don’t have firm pre-offering control of the SPV
and cannot influence its post-offering policies, there is no mutuality between the
directors.
Thus, under contract law, the use of the SPV in securitization effectively eliminates
any mutuality between the two main contracting parties - the sponsor and the investors.
Secondly, there is no mutuality between the SPV and the investors: a) the SPV corporate
rights of each ABS investors and the group of ABS investors. Thirdly, there is no
45
See: Tampa Pipeline Transport v. Chase Manhattan Service Corp., 928 Fsupp 1568 (MD.Fla.,
1995)(affirmed) 87 F3d 1329.
mutuality between the SPV and the sponsor/originality because both entities are
essentially the same, and are controlled by the sponsor before and after the securitization.
and federal RICO statutes, and hence, the contracts used to effect securitizations are void
and illegal.
Conclusion
special federal securitization statutes; and changes in law enforcement patterns and
practices.
46
See: Imel v. laborer’s Pension Fund Trust, 904 F2d 1327 (CA9, 1990)(cert. den.) 498 US 939
(contract should not alter statutory duties); Truck Ins. Exchange v. Ashland Oil, 951 F2d 787
(CA7, 1992); Cramer v. Consolidated Freightways, 255 F3d 806 (CA9, 2001)(cert. denied) 122
SCt 806; Lake James Community v. Burke County NC, 149 F3d 277 (CA4, 198) (cert. denied)
525 US 1106; Davis v. Parker, 58 F3d 183 (CA5, 1995); In Re NWFx, 881 F2d 530 (on
rehearing) 904 F2d 469 (cert. denied) 498 US 941; Biomedical Systems v. GE Marquette, 287
F3d 707 (CA8, 2002)(cert. denied) 123 SCt 636 (post-contract formation failure to obtain statutorily
required license invalidated agreement).