The Income Tax - Root of All Evil
The Income Tax - Root of All Evil
The Income Tax - Root of All Evil
by Frank Chodorov
Introduction by J. Bracken Lee
Governor of Utah
To the Memory of
ALBERT J. NOCK
Foreword
THIS WAS, to be sure, "the home of the free and the land of the
brave." Americans were free simply because the government was too
weak to intervene in the private affairs of the people—it did not have the
money to do so—and they were brave because a free people is always
venturesome. The obligation of freedom is a willingness to stand on your
own feet.
The early American wanted it that way. He was wary of government,
especially one that was out of his reach. He had just rid himself of far-
away and self- sufficient political establishment and he was not going to
tolerate anything like it in his newly founded country. He recognized the
need of some sort of government, to keep order, to protect him in the
exercise of his rights, and to look after his interests in foreign lands. But,
he wanted it understood that the powers of that government would be
clearly defined and be limited; it could not go beyond specified limits. It
was in recognition of this fear of centralized power that the Founding
Fathers put into the Constitution—it never would have been ratified
without them—very specific restraints on the federal government.
In other matters, the early American was willing to put his faith in
home government, in a government of neighbors, in a government that one
could keep one's eyes on and, if necessary, lay one's hands on. For that
reason, the United States was founded as a Union of separate and
autonomous commonwealths. The states could go in for any political
experiments the folks might want to try out—even socialism, for that
matter—but the federal government had no such leeway. After all, there
were other states nearby, and if a citizen did not like the way one state
government was managing its affairs, he could move across the border;
that threat of competition would keep each state from going too far in
making changes or in intervening in the lives of the citizens.
iv The Income Tax
The Constitution, then, kept the federal government off balance and
weak. And a weak government is the corollary of a strong people.
The Sixteenth Amendment changed all that. In the first place, by
enabling the federal government to put its hands into the pockets and pay
envelopes of the people, it drew their allegiance away from their local
governments. It made them citizens of the United States rather than of
their respective states. Theft loyalty followed theft money, which was now
taken from them not by their local representatives, over whom they had
some control, but by the representatives of the other forty-seven states.
They became subject to the will of the central government, and their state
of subjection was emphasized by every increase in the income-tax levies.
The state governments likewise lost more and more of their autonomy.
Not only was their source of revenue being dried up by federal
preemption, so that they had less and less for the social services a
government should provide, but they were compelled in their extremity to
apply to the central authorities for help. In so doing they necessarily gave
up some of their independence. They found it difficult to stand up to the
institution from which they had to beg grants-in-aid. Furthermore, the
federal government was in position to demand subservience from the state
governments as a condition for subventions. It has now become politically
wise for governors, legislators, and Congressmen to "play ball" with the
central government; they have been reduced to being procurement officers
for the citizens who elect them. The economic power which the federal
government secured by the Sixteenth Amendment enabled it to bribe the
state governments, as well as the citizens, into submission to its will.
In that way, the whole spirit of the Union and of its Constitution has
been liquidated. Income taxation has made of the United States as
completely centralized a nation as any that went before it; the very kind of
establishment the Founding Fathers abhorred was set up by this simple
change in the tax laws. This is no longer the "home of the free," and what
bravery remains is traceable to a tradition that is fast losing ground.
For those of us who still believe that freedom is best, the way is clear:
we must concentrate on the correction of the mistake of 1913. The
Sixteenth Amendment must be repealed. Nothing less will do. For it is
only because it has this enormous revenue that the federal government is
able to institute procedures that violate the individual's right to himself and
his property; enforcement agencies must be paid. With the repeal of the
amendment, the socialistic measures visited upon us these past thirty years
will vanish.
Foreword v
Tradition has a way of hanging on even after it is, for all practical
purposes, dead. We in this country still use individualistic terms—as, for
instance, the rights of man—when, as a matter of fact, we think and
behave in the framework of collectivistic doctrine. We support and
advocate such practices as farm-support prices, social security,
government housing, socialized medicine, conscription, and all sorts of
ideas that stem from the thesis that man has no rights except those given
him by government.
Despite this growing tendency to look to political power as the source
of material betterment and as the guide to our personal destinies, we still
talk of limited government, states rights, checks and balances, and of the
personal virtues of thrift, industry, and initiative. Thanks to our literature,
the tradition hangs on even though it has lost force.
But there are many Americans to whom the new trend is distasteful,
partly because they are traditionalists, partly because they find it
personally unpleasant, partly because reason tells that it must lead to the
complete subjugation of the individual, as in Nazi Germany or Communist
Russia, and they don't like the prospect. It is for these Americans that this
book was written. For their opposition to the trend takes the shape of
reform, while nothing will turn it but revo lution. And by "revolution" I
mean the return to the people of that sovereignty which our tradition
assumes them to have. I mean the return to them of the power which
government confiscated by way of the Sixteenth Amendment.
Argument vii
Table of Contents
Foreword .................................................................................................... iii
Argument ....................................................................................................vi
Solomon's Yoke .......................................................................................... 1
Politically Speaking, What Is "Evil"? ......................................................... 3
Yours Is Not Your Own.............................................................................. 7
How It Came Upon Us.............................................................................. 15
The Revolution of 1913 ............................................................................ 24
Soak the Poor ............................................................................................ 36
Corruption and Corruption........................................................................ 44
A Possible Way Out .................................................................................. 54
Competition in Government ..................................................................... 57
Union Forever ........................................................................................... 64
For Freedom's Sake ................................................................................... 74
CHAPTER I
Solomon's Yoke
levy on the incomes of his subjects but on the incomes of public officials;
since the latter had nothing of their own to tax—public officials are not
producers—their taxable funds consisted of what they had mulcted from
the producing public. It was tax farming. There is something to be said in
favor of that system. Since the tax collector gets his "cut" first, before
turning over the balance to the central government, he can never be
accused of accepting bribes—a charge that is sometimes levied against
agents of our Internal Revenue Bureau.
Even evasion of the income tax, by way of false income-tax returns, is
not a modern invention. Gibbon makes mention of the use of racks and
scourges in ancient Rome, up to the fourth century of the Christian era, to
get the truth out of suspected evaders. We have not, at any rate, come to
that, although we do on occasions cast a tax dodger into durance vile.
For something really different and quite startling in the income-tax
business, we must again refer to the biblical story. Some of the Israelites
were so resentful about the "yoke" that when Rehoboam's chief tax
collector, one called Hadoram, made his round among them, they
unceremoniously met him with such a hail of stones "that he died." This
was rather hard on Hadoram and his family, and is not to be recommended
for agents of the Internal Revenue Bureau. In the latter part of this book—
which concerns itself with the immorality of the income tax—a more
orderly and effective way of getting rid of the "yoke" that Americans have
been suffered to wear since 1913 will be suggested. Provided, of course,
they want to get rid of it; provided they have the sense of self-respect and
human dignity that characterized those stone-throwing Israelites.
CHAPTER II
political action which attempts to violate these rights violates his human-
ness, and thus becomes "evil." Putting it another way, any political action
which disregards man's inalienable rights disregards God.
transformation of our political and social attitudes, for a people who are
denied rights, or who relinquish their claim to rights, are likely to put little
worth on personality.
THERE ARE taxes and taxes. All are alike in two respects: they are
compulsory and they are part of production. "Taxa tion, says the
Encyclopedia Britannica, is "that part of the revenue of the State which is
obtained by compulsory dues and charges upon its subjects."
Nevertheless, the "compulsory dues and charges" are usually divided
into two major categories: direct and indirect. The reason for the
classification is the method of collection; but the effect of direct taxes on
public affairs makes them different in kind.
Indirect taxes are so called because the government does not get them
directly from the payer; they are collected for the government by
manufacturers and merchants, who recoup their outlay from their
customers in the price of goods and services. All indirect taxes are added
to price.
The most important of these indirect taxes are tariffs and excise levies.
Tariffs are paid by the importer, who transfers the charge to his customer,
who in turn adds the cost to the price he charges the next processor, and so
on down until the ultimate consumer absorbs the original importer's
outlay, plus all the profits that have accrued to each handler. Excise taxes,
like those paid on tobacco and liquor, are collected through the sale of
stamps and licenses. Sales taxes are likewise found in the price of goods.
Indirect taxes are mere money raisers; there is nothing in the character
of these taxes that involves any other purpose. In levying them, the
government does not call on any principle other than that the citizen must
pay for the upkeep of his government, in proportion to the amount of
goods he consumes. It is as if the government were saying to the citizen:
"Sorry, old man, but we need money with which to carry on this political
establishment, and we don't have any other source of money but you; we
will, however, ease the pain of payment by hiding these taxes in the price
of the goods you buy." The government does not question the right of the
citizen to his property. The citizen need not pay these taxes; he can go
without.
8 The Income Tax
This alternative does not apply to direct taxes. The principal direct
taxes are those levied on inheritances and incomes. (Another is the tax on
land values, which we shall disregard because it has no bearing on the
thesis of this book.) Except for payroll deductions, which is a device
employed by government for the easy and certain collection of taxes on
wages, direct taxes are paid directly to the government. They are not
charged against the consumer in price, although, as we shall see later, they
affect his standard of living even more materially.
Income and inheritance taxes imply the denial of private property, and
in that are different in principle from all other taxes.
The government says to the citizen: "Your earnings are not exclusively
your own; we have a claim on them, and our claim precedes yours; we
will allow you to keep some of it, because we recognize your need, not
your right; but whatever we grant you for yourself is for us to decide."
This is no exaggeration. Take a look at the income-tax report that you
are required by law to make out, and you will see that the government
arbitrarily sets down the amount of your income you may have for your
living, for your business requirements, for the maintenance of your family,
for medical expenses, and so on. After granting these exemptions, with a
flourish of generosity, the government decides what percentage of the
remainder it will appropriate. The rest you may have.
The percentage of the appropriation may be (and has been) raised from
year to year, and the exemptions may be (and have been) lowered from
year to year.1 The amount of your earnings that you may retain for
yourself is determined by the needs of government, and you have nothing
to say about it. The right of decision as to the disposition of your property
rests in the government by virtue of the Sixteenth Amendment of the
Constitution, which reads as follows:
"The Congress shall have power to lay and collect taxes on incomes,
from whatever source derived, without apportionment among the
several states, and without regard to any census or enumeration." 2
1
In 1913, a single person, not entitled to any exemptions for dependencies or anything
else, paid a tax of $20 on an income of $5000. A person similarly situated in 1951 paid
$964. The comparison is even more striking when the purchasing power of the dollar in
the two years is taken into consideration.
2
The apportionment of taxes among the states according to population was originally put
into the Constitution in order to prevent a combination of states from forcing through a
Yours Is Not Your Own 9
levy that would hit the more opulent states harder than themselves. Also, it prevented the
more populous states from raiding the citizens of the sparsely settled states. In both
instances, this provision compelled the levying of taxes on individuals equally, according
to their consumption, and prevented the levying on citizens according to their wealth or,
for that matter, according to their religion, political affiliation, or other personal
identification. This provision was a bar to the introduction of the income tax.
3
Progressive income and inheritance taxation was first advocated as a means of
destroying private property by Karl Marcx, in the Communist Manifesto, published in
1848. Thereafter, every socialist party platform included this plank.
10 The Income Tax
road of socialism. We shall also see that many institutions, such as states'
rights and free enterprise, that were long considered peculiar to our politi-
cal and social order, have lost value with the American citizen. Even the
abhorrence attached to the word "socialism" in this country before 1913 is
wearing off, and an increasing number of the citizenry (perhaps the
majority) use it as the symbol of a great ideal. All these changes in our
culture are directly traceable to the abandonment of the doctrine of private
property—that is, to the Sixteenth Amendment.
So long as the confiscation of private property is legalized, this country
is not immune to the advent of ultimate socialism, which is communism.
The basic tenet of communism is the vesting of all property rights in
the state. Already nearly one third of our national income is being taxed
away from us.4 One or two more national "emergencies" can well bring
about the confiscation of the other two thirds, and thus effect the final
transition to communism. We could slither into it quite without being
aware of it.
Any effort to reverse the trend must begin with the reestablishment in
the American culture of the inviolability of private property. If Americans
were again to put that right at the pinnacle of their values, the repeal of the
Sixteenth Amendment would follow as a matter of course. Therefore, it is
necessary that we digress in this inquiry for a moment to consider the
philosophic support of the axiom—that the individual has an inalienable
right to his property.
Even a thief will justify his way of life. The human being must have a
moral code of some kind to ease the difficulty of living with himself. And
there is no difficulty in making up a code to fit any given condition,
4
This estimate is based on figures published by the United States Treasury. It includes
local, state, and federal taxes. Exactness of computation is made difficult by the method
of arriving at the “national income.” The government figure includes income of all kinds,
that earned by the worker or the corporation and that paid to the government official. The
latter’s salary is of course paid out of taxes taken from producers and is therefore a
duplication. This is the same as computing the family’s income by adding to the
breadwinner’s wages the amount he gives his wife for household expenses. The official
“national income” includes the subsidies paid to the farmer and the taxes paid by the
farmer to make these subsidies possible. If government handouts and government salaries
were deducted from this official figure, and only income from production were included,
the “national income” would be far less than the official figure, and the percentage taken
by taxes would be greater.
Yours Is Not Your Own 11
right if I thrash you; the fact that I did thrash you is proof that I had the
right to do so. On the other hand, if you can intimidate me with a gun, then
right returns to your side. All of which comes to mere nonsense. And a
social order based on the socialistic axiom—which makes the government
the final judge of all morality—is a nonsensical society. It is a society in
which the highest value is the acquisition of power—as exemplified in a
Hitler or a Stalin—and the fate of those who cannot acquire it is
subservience as a condition of existence.
The senselessness of the socialistic axiom is that there would be no
society, and therefore no government, if there were no individuals. The
human being is the unit of all social institutions; without a man there
cannot be a crowd. Hence, we are compelled to look to the individual to
find an axiom on which to build a nonsocialistic moral code. What does he
tell us about himself?
In the first place, he tells us that above all things he wants to live. He
tells us this even when he first comes into this world and lets out a yell.
Because of that primordial desire, he maintains, he has a right to live.
Certainly, nobody else can establish a valid claim to his life, and for that
reason he traces his own title to an authority that transcends all men, to
God. That title makes sense.
When the individual says he has a valid title to life, he means that all
that is he, is his own; his body, his mind, his faculties. Maybe there is
something else to life, such as a soul, but without going into that realm, he
is willing to settle on what he knows about himself—his consciousness.
All that is "I" is "mine." That implies, of course, that all that is "you" is
"yours"—for, every "you" is an "I." Rights work both ways.
But, while just wanting to live gives the individual a title to life, it is an
empty title unless he can acquire the things that make life livable,
beginning with food, raiment, and shelter. These things do not come to
you because you want them; they come as the result of putting labor to
raw materials. You have to give something of yourself—your brawn or
your brain—to make the necessary things available. Even wild berries
have to be picked before they can be eaten. But the energy you put out to
make the necessary things is part of you; it is you. Therefore, when you
cause these things to exist, your title to yourself, your labor, is extended to
the things. You have a right to them simply because you have a right to
life.
That is the moral basis of the right of property. "I own it because I
made it" is a title that proves itself. The recognition of that title is implied
Yours Is Not Your Own 13
in the statement that "I make so many dollars a week." That is literally
true.
But what do you mean when you say you own the thing you produced?
Say it is a bushel of wheat. You produced it to satisfy your desire for
bread. You can grind the wheat into flour, bake the loaf of bread, eat it, or
share it with your family or a friend. Or you give part of the wheat to the
miller in payment for his labor; the part you give him, in the form of
wages, is his because he gave you labor in exchange. Or you sell half the
bushel of wheat for money, which you exchange for butter, to go with the
bread. Or you put the money in the bank so that you can have something
else later on, when you want it.
In other words, your ownership entitles you to use your judgment as to
what you will do with the product of your labor—consume it, give it away,
sell it, save it. Freedom of disposition is the substance of property rights.
Interference with this freedom of disposition is, in the final analysis,
interference with your right to life. At least, that is your reaction to such
interference, for you describe such interference with a word that expresses
a deep emo tion: you call it "robbery." What's more, if you find that this
robbery persists, if you are regularly deprived of the fruits of your labor,
you lose interest in laboring. The only reason you work is to satisfy your
desires, and if experience shows that despite your efforts your desires go
unsatisfied, you become stingy about laboring. You become a "poor"
producer.
Suppose the freedom of disposition is taken away from you entirely.
That is, you become a slave; you have no right of property. Whatever you
produce is taken by somebody else, and though a good part of it is
returned to you, in the way of sustenance, medical care, housing, you
cannot under the law dispose of your output; if you try to, you become the
legal "robber." Your concern in production wanes and you develop an
attitude toward laboring that is called a "slave" psychology. Your interest
in yourself also drops because you sense that without the right of property
you are not much different from the other living things in the barn. The
clergyman may tell you you are a man, with a soul, but you sense that
without the right of property you are somewhat less of a man than the one
who can dispose of your production as he wills. If you are a human, how
human are you?
It is silly, then, to prate of human rights being superior to property
rights, because the right of ownership is traceable to the right to life,
14 The Income Tax
which is certainly inherent in the human being. Property rights are in fact
human rights.
A society built around the denial of this fact is, or must become, a slave
society—although the socialists describe it differently. It is a society in
which some produce and others dispose of their output. The laborer is not
stimulated by the prospect of satisfying his desires but by fear of pun-
ishment. When his ownership is not interfered with, when he works for
himself, he is inclined to develop his faculties of production, because he
has unlimited desires. He wo rks for food, as a matter of necessity, but
when he has a sufficiency of food he begins to think of fancy dishes, a
tablecloth, and music with his meals. There is no end of desires the human
being can conjure up, and will work for, provided he feels reasonably sure
that his labor will not be in vain. Contrariwise, when the law deprives him
of the incentive of enjoyment, he will work only as necessity compels him.
What use is there in putting out more effort?
Therefore, the general production of a socialistic society must tend to
decline to the point of mere subsistence.
The economic decline of a society without property rights is followed
by the loss of other values. It is only when we have a sufficiency of
necessaries that we give thought to nonmaterial things, to what is called
culture. On the other hand, we find we can do without books, or even
moving pictures, when existence is at stake. Even more than that, we who
have no right to own certainly have no right to give and charity becomes
an empty word; in a socialistic order no one need give thought to an
unfortunate neighbor because it is the duty of the government, the only
property owner, to take care of him; it might even become a crime to give
a "bum" a dime. When the denial of the right of the individual is negated
through the denial of ownership, the sense of personal pride, which
distinguishes man from beast, must decay from disuse.
The income tax is not only a tax; it is an instrument that has the
potentiality of destroying a society of humans.
CHAPTER IV
funding and paying off of the Continental debts. He asked for the privilege
of sharing internal taxes with the states. He specifically rejected the idea
of income taxation, both because it would yield little and because it would
be repulsive to the people.
And so, the government of the United States got along with what it
could get out of tariffs and a few excise taxes until the Civil War; it is
interesting to note that the excise levies were dropped in 1817, and not
restored until the Civil War. As a consequence, it was a weak government,
in the sense that it could not become bothersome; and the freedom of the
people made them strong, so that wealth multiplied and the country
flourished. The government did lead the nation into two stupid wars, but
these were cut short mainly by lack of funds; the national credit, thanks to
low taxes, was weak and federal borrowing was extremely limited. Under
the doctrine of eminent domain, the government did create a privileged
class—which it always does when it steps into the economic picture—by
handing out land grants.
But, on the whole, previous to the Civil War the government of the
United States confined itself to the business for which it was created, that
of protecting people in the enjoyment of their God-given rights. It should
not be forgotten that the Founding Fathers, agreeing with John Locke,
with whose writings they were familiar, thought of government principally
as an instrument for safeguarding private property; and that was
considered the prime business of the United States government until 1860.
In 1862, Lincoln instituted the first income-tax law in American
history. The debate in Congress over this major change in our fiscal policy
makes curious reading. It was tacitly agreed that the law was
unconstitutional, because it was a direct tax. A few Congressmen tried to
stick the "excise" label on the proposed tax, thus forcing it into the
formula of the Constitution. But, on the whole, the argument for it rested
on the need for money to carry on the war. It was a matter of expediency
only. The Constitution was set aside.
That is as it should be. If there is any moral justification for war, it is
the need of safeguarding the life of the community. When the existence of
the nation is at stake, the natural inclination of a people is to suspend their
claim to rights. Their lives are forfeit in the common cause, and so should
be their property. The only practical way for putting the property of the
people to the common effort is to confiscate it, and income taxation is the
perfect confiscatory instrument. But, since defense of the homeland is in
the interests of all, both necessity and equity demand that there should be
18 The Income Tax
Since all bonds are claims on production, what really happens when
bonds are issued is—let's call it by its right name—counterfeiting; the
amount of purchasing power, or money, is increased.
There are several ways by which bonds are monetized, but that is not
germane to the present subject; the point is that all bonds add to the fund
of money in circulation, and unless the additional money is accompanied
by an additional amount of goods in the market, we have inflatio n.
Inflation is simply a greater amount of money bidding for the same
amount of goods. The dollar looks like the old dollar, but it buys less.
Hence, even the bond buyers are eventually cheated. The dollars they put
into the bonds could have bought them mo re goods than the dollars they
earn after the bonds have been issued, or the dollars they get from the
government when the bonds mature. It takes a violent wrench of logic to
say that we pay for past wars by depreciating the value of the dollar.
Government borrows on its ability to tax, because taxes are its only
source of revenue, the only security it has to offer the lender.
Thanks to its low taxing power, the Lincoln administration had
difficulty in disposing an issue of bonds bearing twelve percent interest.
That means that its credit was very poor, and it had to resort to
confiscation. Its first income-tax law called for a flat three percent of net
income over $600 a year; this was quite an exemption in itself, since at
that time a man could buy an all- wool suit of clothes for $6. The method
of collection was simplicity itself: the citizen declared his income on his
own estimate, unchecked, and his estimate was published in the
newspapers, the idea being that public opinion would compel a degree of
honesty.
However, the amount brought in by this tax was not enough to carry on
the war, and within two years Lincoln got around to the graduated income
tax. Thus was brought into our fiscal policy the ability-to-pay doctrine.
This doctrine, new at the time, has since attained the dignity of an axiom
of taxation. Yet, when we examine it under the light of ethics it does not
shine so well; and it is a complete denial of the equality principle that
guided the Fathers in establishing the Republic. The taxing power of the
federal government was thus limited in the Constitution:
1
Ability-to-pay is now taught as a sound basis of taxation in most college economics
textbooks. One book that has achieved wide circulation is Economics, by John Ise.
Typical of the line of reasoning which is fed to our youth is the following quotation from
this book:
“Students of political science insist, however, that an economic oligarchy like the United
States cannot be a political democracy in the best sense; that inevitably a few powerful
capitalists and financiers will assume power in political affairs, which is inconsistent with
genuine democracy; and the only way to maintain a real political democracy is to restore
economic democracy though progressive taxation or otherwise.” (Page 619.)
Despite such devious logic, the professor cannot avoid a gleam of sense. On the very next
page of his textbook he says: “Any tax on man-made wealth or on income therefrom is a
penalty on industry and thrift and an encouragement to laziness, improvidence and
incompetence.” Then he adds, “Yet it is inevitable that taxes should be levied in this way
because the state must get revenues from people who have the money.” So, our students
are being taught that it is right to get where the getting is good.
How It Came Upon Us 21
of government and therefore ought to pay more of its expenses. Is that so?
Did the government make them rich? If so, then the government is at fault;
the only way the government can enrich a citizen is by giving him a
special advantage over other citizens, and in that case the government
violates its trust.
The government has nothing of its own to give, for it is not a producer
of wealth. In granting one citizen a special advantage it automatically
creates a disadvantage for other citizens. Thus, if it grants me tariff
protection, it compels those who buy my merchandise to pay a higher
price than they would have had to pay for similar merchandise from
abroad; that extra price is my advantage, my customers' disadvantage. Or,
if the government subsidizes my rent, it simply takes from other citizens
what it hands me; it enriches me at the expense of other citizens.
It is obvious that in handing out special privileges the government is
doing what it ought not to do; it is using its power not for the purpose of
dispensing justice, but for the purpose of creating injustice. This is in
violation of the principle of equality, and the violation is not corrected by
taxing some of the proceeds of privilege; the privileges should be
abolished. If I have acquired wealth by way of a special privilege granted
me by the government, then when it lays a tax on my ill- gotten wealth it is
sharing my unfair advantage; it is, so to say, a partner in my loot.
The advocates of ability-to-pay, however, do not distinguish between
wealth obtained by production and wealth obtained by privilege. They
simply assert that one could not get rich unless one operated under a
government. This is true only in the sense that if there were no
government to maintain order and protect property no one would try to
acquire property; in a society where thievery is prevalent, production must
fall to the point of mere subsistence. But the protection afforded to any
one citizen is afforded to all; that is why men institute governments.
It is not police protection that makes one rich, the other poor. The
differences in personal wealth that arise in any society—barring special
privileges granted by government—are due either to accident or to
qualities inherent in the individual: industry, thrift, abstinence. But it so
happens that those who have and exercise these qualities do not injure
others; their very substance indicates that in acquiring it they have
benefited their fellowmen. If I become rich by making and selling shoes, it
follows that many people have found my shoes desirable, and they have
thus profited by my efforts. The wealth of society is in proportion to the
productive efforts of the individuals who compose that society, and
22 The Income Tax
live on. Of course, it can then try to use the capital it confiscated to
produce goods, something to tax; it can go into business to replace the
vacuum it created. That is socialism, which might be all right if it worked.
It is not our province here to prove that state capitalism (socialism) is
inefficient, that it produces very little besides deficits; wit ness, our Post
Office Department. When all the capital in the country is in the hands of
the government, then all of us must work for the government under the
conditions it prescribes—and that is slavery. Which is the end product of
ability-to-pay.
Despite all the long words and moral platitudes that have been used to
shore up ability-to-pay, the fact is that this doctrine is closely related to the
rule of highwaymanry: take where the taking is good. Those who practice
that trade have the good grace not to moralize about it; they pick on the
traveler who looks opulent and pass up the obvious bum. The government
does likewise, and like the highwayman it does not quibble over how the
victim came by his wealth.
The Sixteenth Amendment specifically says that the government may
tax incomes "from whatever source derived." That means it may tax the
earner, the gambler, the second-story man, the highjacker, the housemaid,
the prostitute. The highwayman is also undiscriminating, save as to ability
to come across.2
2
“In this country we neither create nor tolerate any distinction of rank, race or color, and
should not tolerate anything else than entire equality in our taxes. So, then, I think the
proposition [progressive income taxation] cannot be justified on any sound principle of
morals. It can only be justified on the same ground that the highwayman defends his acts.
It is saying to the man of wealth, ‘you have got the money and we will take it because we
can make better use of it than you will.’” Representative Morrill, May 23, 1866.
CHAPTER V
It is not difficult to see that the boom and the bust were stimulated, if
not caused, by acts of government, aided and abetted by the natural
cupidity of people. But a people who feel a sense of hurt are not likely to
look for basic causes, and are surely not inclined to blame themselves.
They must have a "villain" on whom to vent their spleen; just as a child is
satisfied when the mother spanks the wall against which the child has
struck its head.
So, during the latter part of the nineteenth century, Americans took to
the class-war doctrine recently imported by the socialists; here was a
plausible cause of all their misfortunes, a logical scapegoat for their
dissatisfaction. And the words that hung on the lips of the country were
"plutocracy" and "robber barons" and "bloated rich" and "money bags,"
with suitable overtones. Also, since the opulence of the country was
concentrated in the East, sectionalism added fire to the class-war doctrine,
and "Wall Street" became the ultimate cause of all the economic ills of the
country. 1
The socialists had also imported the idea of a graduated income tax.
Their prophet had written that this is the ideal instrument for destroying
the hated capitalistic system, and they were in duty bound to promote it. It
took Americans a long time to see eye-to-eye with the socialists on this
matter of abolishing capitalism, for the tradition of private property was
too strongly imbedded in their culture; but the income tax appealed to
them as a means of wreaking their vengeance on those they hated—that is,
those who had more than they had. By 1891, the Populists, who had by
that time coagulated into the People's Party, included an income-tax plank
in their platform; the Democratic Party later appropriated it.
Lots of learned treatises have been written on income taxation, and a
wealth of erudition has been expended in its support. But when one looks
to bottom causes one finds them quite simple:
1
A typical remark in the debate on income taxation in the debate of 1894 is the following
from the speech by Sen. Wm. A. Peffer, on June 21:
“The only object we have in view in presenting this amendment [graduated income tax] is
to rake in where there is something to rake in not to throw out the dragnet where there is
nothing to catch. The West and the South have made you people rich.”
The Revolution Of 1913 27
In 1893 the country had a new depression and a new president. Grover
Cleveland, though endowed with more integrity than the run-of-the- mill
politician, nevertheless had to "do something" to satisfy the dissident
elements. He asked Congress to lower tariffs and to make up this loss of
government revenue with a tax on corporation incomes. Congress, heeding
the screams of the Populists and the bombast of William Jennings Bryan,
put through a bill calling for a two-percent tax on all incomes, with
variations, and a deeper cut in tariffs than the president requested. This bill
(which became law without Cleveland's signature) was declared
unconstitutional by the Supreme Court before it became effective. The
arguments for and against the bill, and some comments by the Court, are
worth noting in the light of our later experience. But we might digress for
a moment to examine the use of a demand for tariff reduction to introduce
income taxation.
A tariff duty is a tax on consumption, and it is a tax from which the
protected manufacturers derive a profit. The Populists, representing areas
that had no manufactures quite soundly denounced tariffs as an imposition
on farmers and wage earners and as a special privilege conferred upon a
small class in the East. The argument had too much weight to be easily
ignored. Yet, the fact was that the government depended on tariffs for
nearly half its revenue, and a cut in tariffs was a threat to the United States
Treasury. For this argument the Populists were prepared with their
cherished "soak the rich" proposal, the income tax. Hence, the bill of 1894
and the several income-tax bills introduced later, linked tariff reduction
with income taxation. Not until the constitutional amendment was passed
by Congress was the fiction dropped that tariff reduction and income
taxation are related.
28 The Income Tax
"The passage of the [Wilson] bill will mark the dawn of a brighter day,
with more sunshine, more of the songs of birds, more of that sweetest
music, the laughter of children, well fed, well clothed, well housed.
Can we doubt that in the bright, happier days to come, good, even-
handed Democracy shall be triumphant? God hasten the era of equality
in taxation and in opportunity. And God prosper the Wilson bill, the
first leaf in the book of reform in taxa tion, the promise of a brightening
future for those whose genius and labor create the wealth of the land,
and whose courage and patriotism are the only sure bulwark and
defense of the Republic."
The do-gooding promises of such bilge, with which the debate was
liberally sprinkled, were not implemented with specific "social"
legislation, the kind that came upon the country when income taxation
attained fulfillment. But, they bespoke the secret desire for a golden calf to
lead Americans to the promised land. They prepared the ground for Big
Government.
It should be pointed out, however, that throughout the debate emphasis
was placed on raising money only for the proper expense of government.3
None of the advocates of income taxation spoke of expanding the
functions of government, and while the opposition mentioned "socialism"
it seems doubtful that they had any idea of a New Deal. The American
mind of the nineteenth century was incapable of comprehending
paternalism, regulation, and control; it was too strongly rooted in the past
for that. Even those who advocated the tax method of undermining private
property were not aware of what they were doing, and would probably
have stopped in their tracks if they could have foreseen the consequences
of their proposal. It was not any urgency for Big Government—which they
could not even have understood—that prompted them to advocate income
taxation. It was simply an urgency to "soak the rich" —the very common
sin of envy.
The debate is heavily spiced with the desire to pare down fortunes, and
for further relish there was a generous dash of sectionalism. For the
3
Even the staunchest advocates of income taxation, in those days, stressed only the need
of revenue, though they suspected the possibility of the taxation-for-social-purposes
doctrine that followed the adoption of the Sixteenth Amendment. Thus, Sen. Williams, on
August 26, 1913: “we do not want to collect any more revenue than we need…. Having
concluded that we had enough, we are not taxing people’s income even for fun, nor are
we taxing them for the purpose of building up a system.”
30 The Income Tax
fortunes that irritated their envy were located in the East; they were after
"foreigners," not neighbors. For example, Senator William A. Peffer, of
Kansas, who, by the way, was even more "advanced" than the bill in that
he advocated a graduated income tax, expostulated thus:
"Gentlemen have denounced the income tax as class legis lation because
it will affect more people in one section of the country than in another.
Because the wealth of the country is, to a large extent, centered in
certain cities and states does not make a bill sectional which imposes a
tax in proportion to wealth. If New York and Massachusetts pay more
tax under this law than other states, it will be because they have more
taxable incomes within their borders. And why should not those
sections pay most which enjoy most?"
In reading these speeches one wonders whether there ever would have
been an income tax in this country if the advo cates of it could have held
off until Chicago was able to stand up to New York, and Nebraska
farmers, sporting limousines, became the envy of Boston workers. Even
the opponents of the bill seemed little aware of the concentration of
political power that income taxation would generate, and directed their
arguments mostly to the principle of private property, to the
unconstitutionality of the bill, to the doctrine of class legislation. Bourke
Cockran, Representative from New York, almost touched on the vital sub-
ject when he said:
After the bill was passed, and it came to the Supreme Court, some
references to the subject of individual rights and limited government were
made; there seemed to be no awareness that income taxation might destroy
the American tradition of freedom.4 Thus, Justice Field, in a brilliant
argument supporting the majority opinion declaring the bill
unconstitutional, quotes approvingly the point brought up by counsel:
The seed of class hatred that had been planted during the Civil War
proved fertile. Its sprout was merely stunted by the 1895 decision of the
Supreme Court. In the years following, it continued to send forth shoots
that circumvented the Constitution, for under the guise of "excise"
taxation, levies were laid on some corporation incomes and on inheri-
tances. The Spanish-American War created a climate favorable to these
taxes, and the Supreme Court, in 1900, did some major logic-chopping to
justify the legislation; in fact, the decision of 1900, which was a piece of
legislation in itself, was of great help later to those who wanted general
income taxation.
The drumfire of "soak the rich" was having its effect. Even the rich
began to join in the chorus. The wealthy are of course no more motivated
by principle than the poor; expediency and convenience shape the
thoughts and guide the behavior of the millionaire as well as the worker's.
Even as "Park Avenue," in our times, mouths communistic phrases in
order to appear "advanced," so in the early part of the century some of the
wealthy assumed a "democratic" pose and spoke nice words about income
taxation. 5 Professors of economics would not be left behind; the
"progressive" thing to do was to write erudite articles in support of ability-
to-pay. The mob had captured the intelligentsia, even as it led the
4
It was not until 1937 that the Supreme Court, through the mouth of Justice Benjamin
Cardozo, had the forthrightness to declare that “natural rights, so-called, are as much a
subject of taxation as rights of lesser importance.”
5
“I know that some of the wealthiest men in this country support it [income taxation]. I
know that Mr. Gould in an interview favored it, and I am told by the gentleman from
Missouri that Mr. Carnegie favors it.” Rep. Bourke Cockran, Jan. 30, 1894.
32 The Income Tax
the propaganda issued by the bureaucrats, in their own behalf, and paid for
by the voters themselves.
With America's immunity of property went the immunity of body.
Notice that Mr. Lincoln had great difficulty in enforcing a moderate form
of conscription, even in wartime; now we have peacetime conscription,
apparently as a permanent policy. Mr. Lincoln had difficulty with his draft
because he did not have the wherewithal to hire an army of enforcement
agents. Thanks to the income tax, our present government is not so
handicapped. Resistance is so dangerous that we have made a virtue of
compliance; the conscript army is described as a "democratic" army, and
the conscientious objector is often looked down upon as little better than a
traitor. So completely have we become adjusted to this detestable practice
of the Czars, that every mother is reconciled to the fact that her newborn
son will be a soldier if, unfortunately, he grows up sound of mind and
body.
While we are on this subject of immunity of the body, we should
mention the fact that though we long ago abolished debtors' prisons, we do
have prisons for those who violate the income-tax laws. We can cheat one
another with impunity, but not the government. So thorough and so
ruthless is the machinery of tax collections that it is used to catch and
incarcerate suspected criminals against whom legal evidence of
criminality cannot be adduced. Professional gamblers, hoodlums, and
racketeers of all sorts, aware of the swift and certain punishment dealt out
by the minions of the income-tax law, are scrupulous in the making out of
their tax reports. Thus, the Sixteenth Amendment, enacted to increase the
government's revenues, has spawned another police department, another
means of forcing the citizen into line.
The third great immunity is that of the mind, the freedom to think as
one wishes. The impairment of this immunity is not easy to detect, for the
operation can be conducted in such a way that the victim is never aware of
it. It is necessary to look at the methods employed by the government to
shape thought, to know that the shaping is being done; when the job is
completed it takes a keen observer to realize that people think differently
from the way they used to think.
Thus, the farmer who receives checks for not planting does not realize
that his grandfather would have thought the practice immoral; he accepts
the taking of gratuities as the regular order of things, as quite proper,
because government propaganda has got him into that frame of mind. Free
school lunches do not strike the modern mother as an insult, as suggesting
34 The Income Tax
thing in the world, that he has rights which come from a higher source
than the bureaucracy.
1
For a number of years between 1801 and 1890, except during the Civil War, the
revenues of the country equaled its expenses or sometimes showed an embarrassing
surplus.
Soak The Poor 37
opulent workers, and finally the wealth of housemaids and the tips of
waitresses.
This is all in line with the ability-to-pay doctrine. The poor, simply
because there are more of them, have more ability to pay than the rich.
The national pay envelope contains more money than the combined
treasuries of all the corporations of the country. The government could not
for long overlook this rich mine. Political considerations however, made
the tapping of the pay envelope difficult. The wage earners have votes,
many votes, and in order not to alienate these votes, it was necessary to
devise some means for making the taxation of their incomes palatable.
They had to be lulled into acceptance of "soak the poor."
The drug that was concocted for this purpose was "social security." The
worker was told that he was not paying an income tax when his pay
envelope was opened and robbed; he was simply making a "contribution"
to "insurance" against the inevitable disabilities of old age. He would get it
all back, when he could no longer work, and with a profit.
This is sheer fraud, as can be readily seen when comparison between
social security and legitimate insurance is made. When you pay a premium
on an insurance policy, the company keeps part of it in reserve. The
amount thus set aside is based on actuarial experience; the company
knows from long study how much money it must keep on hand to meet
probable claims. Most of your premium is invested in productive business,
and out of the earnings from such investment the company pays its
running expenses and builds up a surplus to meet unexpected strains; or it
pays the policy holders a share of this extra income, in dividends. Without
going into the intricate details of the insurance business, the guiding
principle is that benefits are paid out of the reserve or the company's
earnings from investments.
Is that what happens to your "contribution" to social security? Not a bit
of it.
Every cent taken from wages is thrown into the till of the United States
Treasury, and is spent for anything the government decides upon. So, too,
are the "contributions" from the employer. That is to say, social-security
taxes are taxes, pure and simple; they are "forced dues and charges"
levied by the sovereign on his subjects for the expenses of state. None of
the money is held in reserve, none of it is invested in business. All is spent,
and it is spent long before the "insured" is entitled to benefits.
To give some plausibility to the "insurance" advertisement, the
government sets up a so-called reserve fund. In place of the money it
38 The Income Tax
One does not have to be an economist to know that in 1937 the dollar
bought more bread and shoes than it does in 1954. The man who in 1954
begins drawing old-age benefits gets dollars that will fetch him less of the
things he needs than the dollars he was compelled to "contribute" in 1937
and during the years that followed.
When the law was put into effect, the social-security doctors figured
out that the fund will have to reach fifty billions of dollars before the
interest on the bonds will be enough to pay the stipulated benefits to all
who are entitled to it. That is, if the stipulated benefits are not increased.
However, for political reasons there have been changes in both the
benefits and the number of people who have been forced into the scheme.
The "premiums" have also been raised. These changes have been made
under the name of "insurance," but the plain fact is that the government
made the m in order to increase its spendable funds. It wanted more taxes,
and it dipped further into the pay envelope; that is the real purpose of the
social-security laws.2
At this writing, the fictitious reserve fund has accumulated fifteen
billions in bonds. Already some economists are beginning to wonder how
the government will be able to pay benefits to all those who during the
past sixteen years have been making "contributions" when they will have
reached the age of sixty- five. Figurers have shown that the interest will not
be sufficient to keep the aged barely alive, if they have to depend on these
stipends; and under the law they are deprived of these stipends if they earn
more than $75 a month extra. This is the answer:
The government will meet its obligations by handing out brand-
new printed dollars, with declining purchasing power, and the old
folks will have to depend on what support they can beg from their tax-
ridden children.
This book deals with income taxation, not with social security, which
needs a book in itself. But we started out with the purpose of showing how
the Sixteenth Amendment changed our country economically, politically,
2
Initially, the “social security” tax was 1 percent of all taxable wages up to $3,000 per
annum, paid by both employer and employee. In 1951, the tax was extended to wages of
$3,600. In 1951, also, “self-employed” persons were pulled in; now they too must pay for
“social security,” whether they want the “insurance” or not, and the rate, which was set at
2 ¼ percent in 1951, rises each year until it reaches the maximum of 4 7/8 percent in
1970. The rates on employer and employee also rise from the initial rate of I percent to
the 1970 limit of 3 ¼ percent.
40 The Income Tax
and morally, and there is no better example of this change than the oper-
ation of the social-security branch of income taxation and its effects on the
character of the nation.
Despite the fact that social security is a fraud in every respect, there are
many who, ignoring the evidence, support it because "we must not let the
old folks suffer destitution." This implies that before 1937 it was habitual
for children to cast their nonproductive parents into the gutter. There is no
evidence for that, and there are no records supporting the implication that
all over sixty-five regularly died of hunger. The present crop of children
are just as considerate of their old folks as were the pre-1937 vintage, and
it is a certainty that if their envelopes were not tapped they would be in
better position to show their filial devotion. Besides, if the government did
not take so much of our earnings, we would be better able to save for our
later days.
The fact is, there is no such thing as social security; only the individual
grows old and is in need. Society is never in want and never grows old,
simply because society is not a person. Security against the exigencies of
old age has always been a problem of life, and each person in his own way
has tried to solve it. Paying up the mortgage on the old home so that one
would always have a roof over one's head was one way; laying up a nest
egg was another; annuity insurance is the most recent form of security.
These methods of taking care of oneself through thrift, however, call
for self-reliance, and that is exactly what the advocates of social security
would destroy. It is contrary to the whole philosophy of socialism. If the
individual is allowed to shift for himself, there is no need for the services
of the self-anointed do- gooders. Hence it is necessary to develop a slave
psychology, a feeling of helpless dependence on the group. If this calls for
the use of police power—and it always does—so much the better; that
means the organization of a bureaucracy with a vested interest in
continuing poverty.
Lurking in the background of social-security thinking is a concept of
organized society that is gall and wormwood to fundamental
Americanism. It is the idea that in the nature of things some men are
destined to rule and others to obey. As a matter of fact, social-security
advocates must take resort in the caste system of society to support their
"insurance" scheme. They maintain that social security is necessary
because most wage earners are incontinent and must be secured against
their own weakness. Who is best qualified to look after them? Why, those
Soak The Poor 41
who have been anointed with the proper college degrees and are crowned
with the power of the State.
It was exactly this father-child concept of society that Bismarck held,
and for that very reason he took to social security. In his political
philosophy it was axiomatic that the Junker class was ordained by God to
rule over Germany. As a correlative, it was an obligation of that class to
look after the welfare of the ruled.3
In a feudal society, where the economy is almost wholly agricultural
and people do not move from place to place, it was quite simple for the
ruling lord to see that his sick and old tenants were provided for. But this
direct relationship between ruler and ruled could not be maintained in an
industrial economy, and in Bismarck's time, industry was upsetting the
comfortable feudal system. Social security came to his rescue; it was just
what he needed to make his feudal concept of government work.
If anybody could make social security work, it would have been the
Junkers. They were by tradition and economic independence free from the
petty temptations of office; they were not beholden to an electorate for
either their income or their position. And yet, they were unable to build a
healthy society upon social security.
The reason for the failure of social security in Germany, and wherever
else it has been tried, is psychological, not political. When the individual is
relieved of the obligation of self-respect, he acquires the habits of
helplessness; he is inclined to retreat to the security of the prenatal state.
The more he is taken care of the more he wants care.
In the past twenty years, thanks to the prevailing social-security
philosophy, it has become a habit of mind with American youth to look
upon government as its permanent guardian; the idea that one is
responsible for oneself is sneered at as "reaction." It is nearly impossible
to convince a young man born after 1920 that to accept a government
3
Said Bismarck: “I acknowledge unconditionally a right to work and I will stand for it as
long as I am in this place. But here I do not stand upon the ground of Socialism… but on
that of Prussian common law.” Prussian common law, drawn up during several reigns,
and finally codified and promulgated by Frederick II, contained the following:
1. It is the duty of the State to provide sustenance and support of its citizens who
cannot… provide subsistence for themselves.
2. Work adapted to theft strength and capacities shall be supplied….
6. The State is entitled and is bound to take such measures as will prevent destitution of
its citizens and check excessive extravagance.
42 The Income Tax
"The imposition of the [income] tax will corrupt the people. It will
bring in its train the spy and the informer. It will necessitate a swarm of
officials with inquisitorial powers. It will be a step toward
centralization…. It breaks another canon of taxation in that it is expensive
in its collection and cannot be fairly imposed;… and, finally, it is contrary
to the traditions and principles of republican government." —
REPRESENTATIVE ROBERT ADAMS, January 26, 1894.
of a "corruption" issue for the coming election, has made much of what it
could dig up.
It would be miraculous if things were otherwise. The Internal Revenue
Bureau is charged with the task of enforcing an immoral law, a law that
violates the principle of private property. The taxpayer, even though he
prates about his willingness to pay his "just share" of government
expenses, always finds his "just share" unjust. And so it is. Even the
doctrinaire socialist, while decrying the iniquity of private property,
resents being deprived of his own; after all, the socialist is a human. It is
written into our consciousness that "mine is mine," and all the tomes in
support of income taxation cannot wipe out that thought.
The Internal Revenue Bureau quite sensibly takes the view that every
one of us is a potential lawbreaker, as far as the income-tax law is
concerned. To approach its task with any other point of view would
undermine its effectiveness. It has a war against society on its hands, and
to win that war it must make use of the artifices of war, such as espionage,
deception, and force. Society, on the other hand, though necessarily on the
defensive, is not entirely helpless. It knows that the weakness of the
Internal Revenue Bureau is the fact that its operatives are also human.
They too are always on the lookout for an easy dollar. Thus, the natural
inclination of the agent blends with the natural inclination of the taxpayer
to form a setting for the circumvention of the unnatural law. Why expect
anything else? If this setting produces corruption, we must look to the law,
not to the human beings involved, for cause.
Aiding the agent in his collusion with the taxpayer is the disparity of
numbers in this struggle; the potential lawbreakers are entirely too
numerous for the handful of collectors. If the number of enforcement
agents were to be increased to a proper balance, the cost would eat into the
"profits" of the operation. For political reasons, it is necessary for the IRB
to show that the cost of collection is little, compared to the amount
collected. Knowing this, and knowing also that his usefulness to the
Bureau is measured by the amount of the collections he is able to effect,
the agent is inc lined to settle a disputed tax case; if, incidentally, the
settlement is topped with a clandestine gratuity, so much the better. One
senator is currently making a name for himself by bringing to light
settlements amounting to as little as a few cents on the dollar, when the
taxpayer, although admitting his indebtedness to the government, proves
he is virtually bankrupt. The Bureau's answer is that "something is better
46 The Income Tax
1
A deliberate and most lucrative “loophole” is the exemption enjoyed by educational and
religious organizations. It is common practice for these organizations to buy real estate
and then rent the properties to the seller. The seller gets a long-term, low-rent lease,
which the buyer is able to give because the income to a “nonprofit” institution is tax
exempt. The American Council of Education recently estimated that 40 percent of all
university and college endowments are now invested in private enterprises, the earnings
of which are nontaxable because they are put to educational use. The earnings of
businesses operated by labor unions are also free of taxes, as are the earnings from the
extensive real estate operations of the churches. Thus, a powerful vested interest in
exemptions has grown up.
Corruption and Corruption 47
are legitimate expenses of business may differ from his. Was too much
deducted for depreciation? Was the inventory taken at true value, and what
is true value? How about those large expense accounts, that costly public-
relations program? Are they necessary to the conduct of the business? The
agent says this, the taxpayer says that, and thus we have the makings of a
costly lawsuit. The natural inclination of the taxpayer is to seek some
other way out, and sometimes the agent is quite amenable to "reason." The
corruption is written into the law.
However, if corruption were limited to the mere giving or taking of
bribes, direct and indirect, we could write it off as of secondary
importance; it is simply the inevitable consequence incident to the
operation of an immoral law. Of far greater concern is the use of income
taxation to undermine the principles of republican government and to
make a mockery of our tradition of freedom.
This is what the late Senator Schall of Minnesota had to say about this
phase of corruption:
Nor is that all. There have been cases—for obvious reasons not many
have received publicity—where citizens who have offended the party in
power were suddenly visited by agents of the Bureau and subjected to
interrogation and examination. Of course, the Bureau is entirely within its
legal right to do so, and there is no proof that the citizens' views prompted
these special investigations. It cannot be proved that the purpose was to
silence opposition. But the practice is so well known that men of means
have scrupulously avoided involvement in movements critical of the
Administration, even though privately they are in sympathy with such
movements.
2
The notorious Buchanan Committee. Edward A. Rumely, executive secretary of the
Committee for Constitutional Government, was cited for contempt of Congress, and
sentenced to jail, for refusing to give this committee a list of the buyers of its
publications. He was finally exonerated in a higher court; but the cost of litigation, plus
the losses sustained by cancellation of book orders from frightened buyers, came to
$150,000, he reported. The Buchanan Committee achieved its purpose of reducing the
revenues of a dissident organization.
52 The Income Tax
Avoidance or evasion of the levies has become the great American game,
and talents of the highest order are employed in the effort to save
something from the clutches of the State. People who in their private lives
are above reproach will resort to the meanest devices to effect some
saving and will even brag of their ingenuity. The necessity of trying to get
along under the income tax has made us a corrupt people.
CHAPTER VIII
the American in its grip; and the improvers were confined to expounding
theories in their papers, or haranguing crowds from a soapbox.
World War I, with its tremendous costs, opened up the door a little; the
politician acquired the habit of increasing the levies, and a few regulators
of society were pulled in by the draught. It was not until the depression of
1929 that the opportunity to remake American presented itself. This was
the opportunity long hoped for. The distress caused by the depression
made a shambles of the tradition of freedom; hunger, and the fear of it,
have a way of wiping out the value of everything but food. Americans
were willing to forget everything they had prized for centuries in exchange
for even the promise of an improved economy. The planners were ready
with promises. They never made good, of course, and finally had to resort
to war to stir up some economic activity; but they had acquired power, and
that was all that counted.
If it had not been Mr. Roosevelt and his horde of self-seeking
visionaries, it would have been somebody else. The New Deal, or
something like it, was planted when the Sixteenth Amendment was put
into the Constitution. It needed only the fertilization of the depression to
bring it to flower. Whatever politician happened to be at the helm at the
propitious mo ment would have done more or less what Mr. Roosevelt did.
That is because the business he is in, politics, drives the politician toward
the acquisition of more and more power, and a good politician is one who
takes advantage of every contingency to increase his power. Mr.
Roosevelt was an excellent politician.
Once socialism gets hold of a country, there seems to be nothing that
will pry it loose except a complete collapse of the political setup, either as
the result of a disastrous war or by way of revolution. The revolutionary
way is the least promising, simply because under socialism the will to
resist weakens in proportion to the people's adjustment to regula tion,
control, and domination. Because that is the only way to rub along, they
make peace with the conditions imposed on them; they lose the habit of
sell-respect.
Thus, in this country it has become quite proper for bankers and
industrialists to stand in the Washington line with "tin cups" in their
hands, for veterans and the unemployed to press for handouts, for farmers
to expect subsidies, for the educational fraternity and the ministry to
maintain bounty-begging lobbies. All this is the regular order of things;
freedom, which demands self-reliance, is out of style. If the miraculous
politician should come along, and urge that all this paternalism should be
56 The Income Tax
Competition in Government
1
One device for invading the authority of the states, under cover of the “general
welfare,” is the establishment of “authorities,” of which the Tennessee Valley Authority
is the prototype. Putting aside the economic desira bility of these agencies, or their ability
to do a job that might be better done by private industry, they are a distinct threat to the
autonomy of the states. They are, in fact, “authorities,” in that the land they occupy,
which is extensive, is federal land and under the jurisdiction of Washington. They are
politically alienated from the states. The states, of course collect no taxes from the federal
government, and they also lose the revenue that the private users of this land once paid to
them. (The TVA generously makes a “donation” to the states, in lieu of the lost taxes.)
2
To the early American his state government was at least on a par with the federal
government in his esteem. Illustrative is the following incident:
President Washington was about to arrive at Boston on a visit, and Governor Hancock
was perturbed over a matter of protocol; would he be compromising the dignity of the
Commonwealth of Massachusetts if he went to meet the “father of his country” on
arrival, or would it be more proper that the President call at the state Capitol? The
Governor finally settled the problem by pleading illness…. The sequel to that incident is
worth noting. President Washington was asked to review the Massachusetts militia; he
refused on the ground that the militia was the military arm of the state, not the federal
government; after all, the tacit understanding in those days was that the militia might be
called upon to face the federal army.
Competition In Government 59
3
In number 45 of The Federalist, Madison writes: “The powers delegated by the
proposed Constitution to the federal government are few and defined. Those which
remain in the state governments are numerous and indefinite. The former will be
exercised principally on external objects, as war, peace, negotiation and foreign
commerce…. The powers reserved to the several states will extend to all objects which,
in the ordinary course of affairs, concern the lives, liberties and properties of the people,
and the internal order, improvement and prosperity of the state.” And so The Federalist
goes on; promise after promise that the state governments will be free in all respects
except to deal with foreign governments. At one time, Madison described the federal
government as the foreign department for the state governments.
60 The Income Tax
life and property—the customer is the citizen. 4 The government will serve
him best only if it cannot set its own standards, when it does not enjoy a
complete monopoly of power.
This brings up a contradiction. The theory is that government must
have a monopoly of coercion to prevent us from using coercion
indiscriminately on one another; we institute government, and endow it
with sole police power, for the purpose of maintaining order.
Nevertheless, experience has shown that the monopoly we give
government can work for disorder; the power can be used to create
disharmony and promote injustice. That, in fact is the record. Throughout
history, those to whom the job of rulership has fallen, whether by heredity
or popular selection, have shown a tendency to use their position to
dominate, not serve, the ruled. Hence, unless the monopoly of power can
be checkmated, freedom is always in danger.
Recognition of that fact gave rise to the idea of constitutional
government, with limited powers. And as further restraint on government,
popular suffrage was instituted. The vote is presumed to keep the
government from getting out of hand; the threat of being turned out at the
next election is supposed to hold down the arrogance and ambition of
those in whom the power is vested. However, during its incumbency the
elected government does enjoy a monopoly position, and it can use that
position to solidify, enlarge upon, and perpetuate its power; it can even use
the citizens' tax money to "buy up" the next election, either by bribery or
by propaganda.
Popular suffrage is in itself no guarantee of freedom. People can vote
themselves into slavery.
The only way, then, to prevent the monopoly of power from becoming
absolute is to create a competitive market for government; to give the
citizens, the customers, a choice of jurisdiction. That is exactly what our
peculiar American system of divided authority, between states and federal
government, accomplished. The Constitution, as originally conceived, set
up independent nations within an independ ent nation—imperium in
imperio—each with delimited powers. In that way, it was hoped, the
polarization of power that undermines freedom would be prevented. The
4
“The first object of government,” says Madison in the tenth number of The Federalist,
is the protection of “the diversity in the faculties of men, from which the rights of private
property originate.” The conception of government held by the Founding Fathers was
quite the opposite of what has been gaining currency in this country in recent years.
62 The Income Tax
central government was given certain specified chores to do; it could not
intervene in local affairs, unless the state governments were not able to
maintain order. If the state government got rough with its customers, they
could easily transfer their allegiance to another state.
This division of powers established the nearest thing to competition in
government the world has ever known. As long as it held up, or until the
federal government invaded the state lines (though the powers it acquired
under the Sixteenth Amendment), the American citizen was as free as it is
possible to be in organized society. Except with excise taxes, or during
war, the central government never annoyed him. Sometimes the state
governments went in for political innovations, including socialism, that
violated his freedom. But they did not get far with these schemes, simply
because the citizen could march off to a state more to his liking, or
immigration from other states was discouraged; no government likes to
lose taxpayers.
Thus, before the Prohibition Amendment, several states and localities
went in for this kind of sumptuary legislation. This was indeed an invasion
of individual rights, but it never amounted to much more than a nuisance.
There was no monopoly of power behind it. The citizen could and did
import liquor from contiguous territory, or manufactured his own. Until
the prohibitory power was monopolized by the federal government, so that
escape was fraught with danger, the individual's right to make a drunken
fool of himself was not effectively infringed by state laws.
From the very beginning the states had the power to impose income
taxes and a number of them exercised it. None of these states ever went as
far as the federal government has gone, and for obvious reasons. In the
first place, the neighborly relations between local tax collectors and
taxpayers made for evasion of this infringement of property rights; the
state governments could not import "foreigners" from Washington to do
the unpleasant work. Then, the local politician is more sensitive to the
likelihood of retribution at the polls than is the national politician, and he
knows that nothing will stir up the people more violently than excessive
taxation. Most important is the fact that, other things being equal, capital,
without which production is impossible, is attracted to areas where low tax
rates obtain; it was regular practice, before the Sixteenth Amendment, for
chambers of commerce to advertise the freedom from income taxes in
their states as an enticement to industry, and it was not unusual for men of
means to migrate to those states that did not tax inheritances. Running
away from taxes is an ancient custom, and no state government wants to
Competition In Government 63
see its area depopulated. For these reasons some of the states dropped their
income taxes, and none of them went in for oppressive rates.
Sometimes it is urged that we federalize our divorce laws, which would
indeed be an invasion of our personal lives. So long as there are different
legal jurisdictions covering divorce, the morality of it is left where it
should be, in the conscience of the parties involved. A federal law would
not prevent the breaking of conjugal ties, but if it were stringent enough it
would certainly encourage the practice of living together out of wedlock,
with a consequent increase of illegitimacy. Thus, immorality would be
multiplied, as every law to eradicate it does. The more affluent would
migrate to other countries to effect their purpose. More important, from
the viewpoint of freedom, a federal law would put upon us another flock
of enforcement agents, snoopers, and bribe takers.
Right now there is an urgency to have the federal government eradicate
by forcible means the stupidity of racial and religious bigotry, particularly
in employment practices. This is another example of the fatuous
undertaking to make men "good" by law—the socialistic program. It
cannot be done. A "fair employment practices" law can only result in
intensifying bigotry, by concentrating attention on it. A New York State
law of that kind has done nothing more than stimulate the ingenuity of
employers and employment agencies to invent methods of evasion;
discrimination is as preva lent as ever. But if the federal government is
given the power of a "fair employment practices" act, we can expect an
army or corruptible police swarming all over our national industry. That is
not freedom.
Union Forever
THE CIVIL WAR did not abolish the autonomy of the states. All that
was settled by that conflict was the questions of secession and
nullification; no state could pull out of the Union or disregard a regularly
enacted national law. After 1865, as before, the states were still the
depositories of all powers not specifically delegated to the federal
government, as stipulated in the Constitution.
After 1913, however, and without either a war or a change in the law of
the land, the states were gradually and almost imperceptibly rid of their
sovereign position and reduced in importance to dependent subdivisions
of the nation. It was done by the subtle arts of bribery and blackmail,
made possible by the Sixteenth Amendment.
From the very beginning of the Union it has been cus tomary for
Congressmen to try to wangle out of the federal government some special
privilege for their more influential supporters, or some appropriation of
federal funds for spend ing in their states. "Pork barrel" legislation did not
begin with the Sixteenth Amendment. However, before 1913 the best the
party in power could do for a Congressman (or a state governor), by way
of a bribe, was to let him hand out a judgeship or a postmastership, an
occasional franchise or perhaps a land grant.1 Such favors helped the state
machines to see eye to eye with the federal government and win their
support for its programs; but the total of such patronage was not enough to
reduce the states to subserviency. The manna that fell from Washington
was hardly enough to buy up the independence of the states or the votes of
1
During recent years, the federal government has regained by purchase or state grant a
good portion of the land it so lavishly distributed for political purposes during the
nineteenth century. It now owns about one fourth of the land of the country. Since this is
federal land, the states cannot collect any taxes from its users. This is practically “foreign
soil” as far as the states are concerned, outside their jurisdiction and yielding them no
land tax.
Union Forever 65
their citizens. No candidate for Congress could offer his constit uents gifts
paid for by the citizens of other states.
The ink was hardly dry on the Sixteenth Amendment before the
heretofore picayune federal patronage began to blossom into the program
of grants-in-aid. The first of these came in 1914, when the Agricultural
Extension Service was inaugurated with an appropriation of $480,000—
not so inconsiderable an amount in those days. Each year thereafter
Congress found reason to pass "general welfare" legislation, with
appropriations increasing in importance. Whether the "general welfare"
prospered by these expenditures is questionable, but it is certain that the
political fortunes of the politicians who could boast of "bringing home the
bacon" did not suffer.
The laws multiplied and the appropriations grew bigger. It is a curious
fact that as the government's revenues increase so do its needs.
Before 1913, the country was in difficulty several times, but it never
suffered from an "emergency"; t hat national disease is a product of the
income tax, and as the levies increased, the affliction recurred with
greater frequency and greater intensity.
War, or the threat of it, is a most important "emergency," and since
1913 we have had two major wars, a "punitive expedition" and at least one
"police action." We finally got around to permanent peacetime
conscription, thanks to an "emergency," with its costs. In between all this
a depression came upon us, even as did "hard times" several times before
the Sixteenth Amendment. The country managed to get out of these
former economic disasters without federal intervention; but the depression
of 1929 was not allowed to cure itself; it had to be ministered to with
taxes.
Every post-Sixteenth Amendment "emergency" became an occasion for
raising the rates of taxes on incomes and of lowering the exemptions; that
is, for taking more of the incomes of more persons. The odd thing about
these "emergency" taxes is that they hang on after the original occasion
for them disappears. Just by way of illustration, first-class postage before
World War II was two cents an ounce; the rate was raised to three cents
"for the duration." Later legislation made the increase permanent. Perhaps
other factors, like inflation, made continuation of the increased rate neces-
sary, although that is a debatable question; the point is that the promise of
the original legislation was never kept. In like manner, a great "need"
ushered in every increase in income taxes, with the tacit or explicit
66 The Income Tax
understanding that the levies would be dropped when the "need" no longer
existed; but every "need" hardened into a permanent necessity.
Popular suffrage fosters government by and for pressure groups. The
first concern of a politician is to be elected, the second is to be reelected.
No matter how noble he is at heart, no matter how sincere his desire to
serve his country, practical considerations force him to cater to individuals
or groups who can "deliver the vote"; he cannot do anything for the good
of his country unless he is in office. Hence, he is inclined to make
promises to do this or that for the benefit of those who can help him at the
polls. Since an office holder has nothing to offer but laws, his preelection
promises amount to the pledging of the political power with which he is
invested. But the patriotic citizens who enter into the bargain are not
interested in political power in itself; what they are after is an economic
advantage that political power can confer upon them. They are interested
in sinecures on the public payroll, franchises, public works and contracts
that bring jobs to the community and profits for the contractors, handouts,
and so on.
This practice of buying votes with political favors is inherent in
popular government. It is the weakness of democracy. It is not due so
much to the depravity of the politician as to the human hunger for
something-for-nothing.
However, this weakness of democracy is only as dangerous as the
amount of the citizens' wealth the government has at its disposal. Before
1913 the American government was comparatively poor and political
jobbery was correspondingly limited in scope. When the government
acquired this power of confiscating the national wealth, the corrup tion was
limited only by the amount that expediency would permit it to confiscate.
At this writing the confiscation amounts to one third of the production of
the citizenry. That is a lot of "pork" with which to buy votes. And so, as
the Sixteenth Amendment gradually achieved its fulfillment, the
politician's attention was more and more directed toward the "barrel"; so
was the attention of those who are compelled to keep it filled.
The dependence of the state political machinery on the coffers of the
federal government carries an obligation: to support and acquiesce in the
policies and purposes of the ruling regime. If a governor asks for or
accepts a school subvention, he cannot very well object to the curriculum
or textbooks "recommended" by the Bureau of Education. And a
Congressman who tries to become a liaison officer between his voters and
the United States Treasury will probably vote for any program the regime
Union Forever 67
greed, pressed for legislation that would bring them dollars mulcted
mainly from the citizens of the seven rich states. That is the bald fact,
though the legislation was glamorized with the "public interest" label.
According to the label, New York profits by its forced contribution to
Arizona irrigation projects or Montana roads. However that might be, the
immediate beneficiary of federal grants to local projects is the politician
who solicits it, and the ultimate beneficiary is the federal bureaucracy.
Everybody else pays.
Today, every state in the Union pays into the income-tax fund more
than it gets back. (See table at the end of this chapter.) This outcome was
inevitable. The Sixteenth Amendment gives the federal government power
to levy on incomes "from any source derived." This includes the incomes
of citizens in the poorer states, and the federal government had to get
around to them in time.
But the fact that every state is now a loser gives them all a common
interest in the repeal of the Amendment. They all have an economic
motive for raising the banner of States' Rights, for reestablishing their
sovereignty; they would all profit by repeal of income taxation. How could
they lose?
Twice in the history of the country the doctrine of home rule was called
from retirement to lead a secessionist move ment, and each time the
motivation was economic. In 1814, when the British fleet had all but
ruined New England industry and commerce, delegates from these states
met to consider ways and means, not excluding secession from the Union.
What might have come from the Hartford Convention must remain
conjecture, for "Mr. Madison's War" was called off before the proposed
second gathering was convened. The renewal of business activity put the
doctrine back into the textbooks.
States' Rights became the battle cry of the South only because the
planters felt the pinch of protective tariffs. No one would ever have heard
of nullification and secession, and certainly not of war, if Calhoun's plea
for lower tariffs had been heeded—or if the government had been able to
buy off the planters with "parity" prices, which it could not do for lack of
an income tax. After the war had destroyed the economic interest which
had inspired it, States' Rights was again interred.
The fires of freedom are stoked by the will to be free. It is not the
promise of bread alone that will spur a people to shed their shackles, but
rather the hope that they may attain the dignity of self- respecting
Union Forever 69
2
A striking instance of how the federal government has built up a vested interest in
income taxes is the case of the Reconstruction Finance Corpora tion. This agency, set up
in the Hoover Administration on a “temporary” basis, makes loans to companies who can
prove that private financial institutions have rejected their applications; that is, to
companies that are not entitled, on the basis of their financial statements or their
performance, to loans. Some 14,000 of such presumably unsafe companies, in 1950, had
obtained funds from the RFC; the citizens of the United States were compelled to loan
money to people whom the banks had turned down. Obviously, the borrowers were
grateful. The Sixteenth Amendment was very good to them. Since this was written,
Congress has terminated the life of the RFC, and has replaced it with the Small Business
Loan Corporation.
3
The condition of the banks is worth commenting upon, because of the importance of
these institutions to the general economy. The banks, as a whole, now hold government
bonds in an amount equal to upwards of sixty percent of their total assets. A sizable drop
in the value of these bonds could wipe out their net worth and bring on an insolvent
position. Repeal of income taxation would certainly affect the value of these bonds
adversely. The banks must be against it. Furthermore, they are in the peculiar position of
not being able to refuse to take more bonds, because such refusal would be tantamount to
repudiating the soundness of their main borrower and thus casting reflection on their own
70 The Income Tax
backlog of government orders likewise see no reason for repeal. Nor can
the farmers work up any interest in the matter since it is out of income-tax
revenues that they get "parity" support as well as checks for not
producing. College professors whose salaries depend on government
subsidies, veterans whose incomes are augmented by gratuities from the
federal treasury, dentists who pull teeth at government expense, tenants
whose rent is more or less paid by the government, two and a half million
who are on the public payroll—probably half the population of America
are wholly or in part dependent on income taxes for their livelihood, have
made a comfortable adjustment with it, and though they grumble about the
part they have to pay, would not like to have their adjustment disturbed.
Among these beneficiaries of the income tax are the type of people who
could be the backbone of a revolt. In time, they will be, for it cannot be
long before their benefits will be more than offset by the taxes they have
to pay; the "take" of the government, increasing as a percentage, must ulti-
mately wipe out the winnings of all the players. When that time comes, or
when they become aware of it, those who are now for income taxation will
discover that they have been robbed not only of their property but also of
their freedom, and will kick up a fuss. Meanwhile, they are content to keep
their snouts in the public trough.
That part of the population who get no return on their income-tax
payments—obviously, the government cannot subsidize everybody—are
too preoccupied with the problem of making ends meet to do anything but
grumble. Were a leadership to appear, explaining that repeal of the Six-
teenth Amendment would do away with withholding taxes, that the
waitress would not have to share her tips with the tax collector, that the
grocer would no longer have to hire an accountant to keep him out of jail,
that the housewife would not have to conspire with her housemaid to
evade the law, a goodly crowd would join up.
The only group that could logically furnish that leadership are the
governors and legislators of the states. Repeal of federal income taxes
would not only reestablish their importance and dignity, but would also
put them in the way of increasing the revenues of the states for the
carrying on of such social services as the citizens call for. The states
would set themselves up in business again. And some degree of
soundness. Thus, the banks have slipped into the position of dependence on and
subservience to the United States Treasury; to all intents and purposes they constitute the
bank of the government.
Union Forever 71
1
In 1932 the programs in effect totaled $269,425,252. During the wartime fiscal year
1946, the grants-in-aid and checks to individuals totaled $1,290,107,183. As these figures
were compiled, there were 80 programs and activities under which federal revenues were
shared with or funneled back to the states and local governments, or as direct payments to
individ uals. (Payments to individuals were exclusive of payments to civilian employees
of the federal government who at this time numbered more than 2,530,000, with payrolls
at an annual rate of over $10 billion a year.)
72 The Income Tax
2
Maryland receipts include revenues from the District of Columbia and Puerto Rico. For
fiscal 1951 the District received a total of $34,384,443 in federal aid and Puerto Rico
received $54,412,416. The actual Maryland figure is $51,378,383.
Union Forever 73
Author's note: The preliminary summary of this table states that the
average percentage of total collections returned to the states and
individuals is 9.42. This is an incorrect and misleading figure, and is a
perfect example of how easily statistics may be used to state an untruth. It
is indeed true that, of the lump sum collected by the federal government
from all the states, a lump-sum percentage of 9.42 was returned to the
states. But it is no t true that the average percentage returned to each state
and individual was 9.42. Actually, the average percentage returned to each
state was 22.64. This correct percentage is arrived at by averaging the 49
percentages listed in the table.
You can't take 566,957,101 (Delaware), lump it together with
113,976,845 (Mississippi), divide the lump sum into the lump sum of the
amounts returned to these two states, then draw an average of the
percentages returned to the states. You can't do this because the separate
sums are of different amounts, and percentages drawn from two different
amounts cannot be averaged. For your average percent ages returned to
these states, you have to take the two percentages given—1.47 and
93.58—and average them.
3
Figures on collections for Washington include Alaska. Amounts have not been shown
separately by the Treasurers annual report. Federal aid reported for Alaska for fiscal 1951
totaled $5,789,295.
CHAPTER XI
independent of the will of the people. The elections do not alter that fact;
these are merely periodic changes of the guard. Whoever is elected retains
the power vested in the office and, as usual, tries to augment it. The end in
clear sight is the liquidation of all social power and the advent of a regime
of absolutism.
This, it cannot too often be repeated, was an inevitable consequence of
income taxation. The citizen is sovereign only when he can retain and
enjoy the fruits of his labor. If the government has first claim on his
property he must learn to genuflect before it. When the right of property is
abrogated, all the other rights of the individual are undermined, and to
speak of the sovereign citizen who has no absolute right of property is to
talk nonsense. It is like saying that the slave is free because he is allowed
to do anything he wants to do (even vote, if you wish) except to own what
he produces.
The proposal to repeal the Sixteenth Amendment is really a proposal to
restore the sovereignty of the American citizen. To use a modern term, it
is a counterrevolutionary proposal, in that it aims to restore to society the
power that the Amend ment gave to the government. Judging by the
grumbling over income taxes—to say nothing of the wholesale evasion
that even the Treasury Department admits—it would seem that the
revolutionary tinder box is full and needs only leadership to ignite it.
Particularly is this truculence strong among workers and housewives,
professional and small businessmen; the big industrialists, bankers, and
commercial interests, for the reasons aforementioned, have no reason to
favor repeal. But whether this mass dissatisfaction can be channeled into a
dynamic movement depends on the underlying cause of it; is it economic
or spiritual?
It needs no proving that the country, the people, would be better off if
income taxation were abolished. But no movement based on economic
grounds alone will stir a people into action; a movement so based can be
bought off.
into an American thought pattern long before it was written. It had become
the American ethos. John Adams, writing in 1818, put it this way: "the
Revolution was in the hearts of men"... it was effected "before the war
commenced." That is to say, when Jefferson wrote about "unalienable
rights" he simply put into words what Americans instinctively felt. They
opposed the British Crown because they could not do otherwise.
When we try to define "Americanism"—of which there is much loose
talk these days—we find it necessary to look to our beginnings for the
essential ingredient. Whatever special character this country can lay claim
to, it was the habit of freedom that was acquired before the country was
formally organized. And it was an acquired, not an inherited characteristic,
for the American was ethnologically as heterogene ous as his forebears.
His ancestry gave him nothing that the peoples of Europe did not have. He
had come by freedom through trouble and toil; he meant to hold on to it.
When he got around to establishing a political establishment of his
own, the American had sense enough not to put too much trust in it. He
had learned—without the help of a textbook on political science—that
inherent in government, any government, is the tendency to rob the
individual of his freedom. Hence, while recognizing the need of gov-
ernment for orderly gregarious living, he was against giving any setup a
free hand; it must be hamstrung. The Constitution was, for that reason,
that distrust of government, heavily underlined with prohibitions and with
"checks and balances."
The Constitution was tailor made for and by Americans; it was fitted to
their particular habit of thought. That point was emphasized by one of its
makers, Gouverneur Morris, when he was Minister to France, during the
Reign of Terror. "The French," he wrote, "want an American Constitution
without reflecting that they have not American citizens to support it."
Missing from our original Constitution was a "check" that was all the
more potent because of its omission. The straight-thinking pioneer knew
full well that the power of the government is in direct ratio to its income,
and he was therefore all for cutting its income to the bone; that way it
could not get out of hand. About all he would allow it was what it could
pick up from tariffs on imports. Grudgingly, because, as Hamilton pointed
out, tariffs could not produce enough to pay the running expenses of the
proposed government, he allowed it some excise taxes. More than that he
would not give, and more than excise and tariff taxes did not get into the
Constitution.
For Freedom’s Sake 77
In the circumstances, those who put a value on freedom, who know that
the loss of interest in freedom is the sure mark of national and individual
decadence, are in deep despair. Many, too many, have resigned themselves
to what they call the inevitable. Let the country have its bellyful of
socialism, they say, and be done with the struggle to stop it. The human
animal can adjust itself to any condition that permits him a meal and a
mate; Americans are no different from any other people that in times past
have swapped their souls for a mess of pottage. They, too, will find that
the only "security" is that provided by a penal institution, but by the time
they find it out they will have made their adjustment to prison bars and
barbed wire. After a century or two of that kind of living, some Moses will
come along to remind them that they are in fact men, and a new exodus to
freedom will be started. By that time, these prophets of gloom maintain,
and not without good reason, the State itself will be in a starved condition
and unable to stop the exodus. A handful of resolute men will easily topple
it over.
There is historic support for such resignation. Every civilization on
record has followed the same pattern. In the beginning, the civilization
rose and flourished in the sunshine of freedom. And, in the beginning, the
civilization was poor. Always some kind of government attached itself to
society, but because of the general lack of goods, the government
remained quiescent and even rendered service in the maintenance of order.
But the human urge is always away from poverty, and that urge, while
it improves his circumstances and widens his horizon, also is man's
downfall. As soon as a general abundance appears, the passion for power
is enflamed, and the political establishment changes its character; it
gradually shifts its position from a protective to a predatory institution. It
levies taxes. And the more the general economy improves the larger its
levies, always, of course, in the "general interest." So it was in the time of
the Caesars, so it is now.
The general welfare is not improved by the increasing load of taxation.
On the contrary, the upward climb of civilization is retarded in exact
proportion to the levies, and when they reach the point of discouraging
production, the parabola of civilization turns downward.
Returning to first principles, the object of productive effort is
consumption; men work to satisfy their desires, and for no other reason.
They don't want work, they want satis factions. Their aversion to labor is
such that they are constantly inventing labor-saving devices. And the more
labor they save the more labor they invest in the gratification of new
For Freedom’s Sake 79
are impelled by their natures to do, not by what history dictates. The stars
in the heavens attend to their eternal business, while we mortals must
travel within our own specific orbits.
It was no historical imperative that directed the pens of those who
signed the Declaration of Independence; it was an inner force. There were
many at the time—the Tories— who deemed the Revolution a foolhardy
venture, from which no good could come greater than that which might
ensue from a compromise with King George; if they were alive today
these Tories could point to Canada in support of their argument.
Nevertheless, the rebels, none of whom were driven to it by economic
necessity, put their signatures to what at the time seemed to be their own
death warrant. Why? For lack of a better answer, let us say they were
made of a peculiar kind of stuff and could not do otherwise.
Whether there are any mystic forces pushing men along a path from
which there is no escape, is a moot question. But there is no questioning
the fact that throughout history men have regularly made excursions in
quest of freedom, and that every one of these excursions was identified by
its leadership. It is a logical inference therefore that when men of that
stripe appear on the scene the cause of freedom is not neglected. Perhaps,
after all, the present plight of freedom in America is due to lack of
leadership.
If, for instance, those who prate about "free enterprise" were willing to
risk bankruptcy for it, even as the men of the Declaration risked their
necks for independence, the present drive for the collectivization of capital
would not have such easy going. Assuming that they are fully aware of the
implications of the phrase they mouth, and are sincere in their
protestations, the fact that they are unwilling to suffer mortification of the
flesh disqualifies them for leadership, and the case for "free enterprise" is
hopeless.
The present low estate of freedom in this country must be laid to lack
of the proper leadership—to men who know what freedom is and who do
not equate it with their own "stand ard of living." Whether or not
leadership could have averted, or can still stop, the trend toward socialism,
may be open to question; that a glorious fight for freedom might yet
enliven the American scene is not. Whether a fight for freedom will be
crowned with success, is less important than the fight itself, for if nothing
comes of it, the improvement in the spirit of the fighters will be a gain,
and they cannot help but keep alive the values that will make America a
better climate for their offspring to live in.
For Freedom’s Sake 81