Credit Derivatives: An Overview: David Mengle
Credit Derivatives: An Overview: David Mengle
Credit Derivatives:
An Overview
DAVID MENGLE
The author is the head of research at the International Swaps and Derivatives Association.
This paper was presented at the Atlanta Fed’s 2007 Financial Markets Conference, “Credit
Derivatives: Where’s the Risk?” held May 14–16.
A derivative is a bilateral agreement that shifts risk from one party to another; its
value is derived from the value of an underlying price, rate, index, or financial
instrument. A credit derivative is an agreement designed explicitly to shift credit risk
between the parties; its value is derived from the credit performance of one or more
corporations, sovereign entities, or debt obligations.
Credit derivatives arose in response to demand by financial institutions, mainly
banks, for a means of hedging and diversifying credit risks similar to those already
used for interest rate and currency risks. But credit derivatives also have grown in
response to demands for low-cost means of taking on credit exposure. The result has
been that credit has gradually changed from an illiquid risk that was not considered
suitable for trading to a risk that can be traded much the same as others.
This paper begins with a description of credit default swaps, total return swaps, and
asset swaps and then focuses on the mechanics and risks of credit default swaps. The
paper then describes the market for credit default swaps and how it evolved and pro-
vides an overview of pricing and the risk-management role of the dealer. Next, the dis-
cussion considers the costs and benefits of credit derivatives and outlines some recent
policy issues. The conclusion considers the possible future direction of the market.
Figure 1
Credit Default Swap
Default payment
Reference entity
notional amount, of reference entity debt. The reference entity is not a party to the
contract, and the buyer or seller need not obtain the reference entity’s consent to
enter into a CDS.
Risks associated with credit default swaps. In contrast to interest rate swaps
but similar to options, the risks assumed in a credit default swap by the protection
buyer and protection seller are not symmetrical. The protection buyer effectively takes
on a short position in the credit risk of the reference entity, which thereby relieves the
buyer of exposure to default.1 By giving up reference entity credit risk, the buyer effec-
tively gives up the opportunity to profit from exposure to the reference entity. In
return, the buyer takes on (1) counterparty default exposure to simultaneous default
by the reference entity and the protection seller (“double default”) and (2) counter-
party replacement risk of default by the protection seller only. In addition, the protec-
tion buyer takes on basis risk to the extent that the reference entity specified in the
CDS does not precisely match the hedged asset. A bank hedging a loan, for example,
might buy protection on a bond issued by the borrower instead of negotiating a more
customized, and potentially less liquid, CDS linked directly to the loan. Another exam-
ple would be a bank using a CDS with a five-year maturity to hedge a loan with four
years to maturity. Again, the reason for doing so is liquidity, although as CDS markets
expand the concentration of liquidity in specific maturities should lessen.
The protection seller, in contrast, takes on a long position in the credit risk of the
reference entity, which is essentially the same as the default risk taken on when lend-
ing directly to the reference entity. The main difference between the two is the need to
fund a loan but not a sale of protection. The protection seller also takes on counter-
party risk because the seller will lose expected premium income if the buyer defaults.
One exception to the above risk allocation is the funded CDS (also called a credit-
linked note), in which the protection seller lends the notional amount to the protec-
tion buyer in order to secure performance in the event of default. In a funded CDS
the protection buyer is relieved of counterparty exposure to the protection seller, but
the seller now has exposure to the buyer along with exposure to the reference entity.
In order to reduce the seller’s exposure to the buyer, the parties sometimes establish
1. Credit traders in fact refer to bought protection as a short position in the reference entity and to
sold protection as a long position.
Figure 2
Total Return Swap
TR of reference TR of reference
obligation obligation
actions, market participants will choose from a standard menu of contract terms that
have been developed collectively by ISDA member firms. As in all OTC derivatives,
however, the parties are free to negotiate terms that differ from market standards.
Following the execution of the trade, the parties will monitor for occurrence of
credit events. In addition, the parties will also have to amend trades to account for
succession events in which the reference entity changes form as mentioned previ-
ously. Finally, if a credit event occurs, the parties settle the CDS obligations according
to procedures set forth in the ISDA documentation.
Other credit derivatives. The credit default swap in various forms accounts
for the vast majority of credit derivatives activity. Three related products deserve
mention, however.
First, a total return swap transfers the total economic performance of a reference
obligation from one party (total return payer) to the other (total return receiver). In
contrast to a credit default swap, the total return swap transfers market risk along
with credit risk. As a result, a credit event is not necessary for payment to occur
between the parties.
A total return swap works as follows (Figure 2). The total return payer normally
owns the reference obligation and agrees to pay the total return on the reference
obligation to the receiver. The total return is generally equal to interest plus fees plus
the appreciation or depreciation of the reference obligation. The total return receiver,
for its part, will pay a money market rate, usually LIBOR (London Interbank Offered
Rate), plus a negotiated spread, which is generally independent of the reference obli-
gation performance. The spread is generally bounded by funding costs: The upper
bound is the receiver’s cost of funding, and the lower bound is the payer’s cost of
funding the reference obligation. If a credit event or a major decline in market value
occurs, the total return will become negative, so the receiver will end up compensat-
ing the payer. The end result of a total return swap is that the total return payer is
relieved of economic exposure to the reference obligation but has taken on counter-
party exposure to the total return receiver. The most common total return receivers
are hedge funds seeking exposure to the reference obligation on terms more favorable
Figure 3
Asset Swap
LIBOR 6.30%
Money Corporate
Investor note (5-year)
market
Dealer
Assume that
5-year U.S. dollar interest rate swap rate = 5.45%
Par bond coupon = 6.30%
⇒ Asset swap spread = 0.85%
than by funding a direct purchase of the obligation; this tactic is sometimes known
as “renting the balance sheet” of the total return payer, which is normally a well-
capitalized institution such as a bank.
In addition to total return swaps, asset swaps are sometimes classified as credit
derivatives although they are in fact interest rate derivatives. Whatever their classifica-
tion, they are relevant to credit derivatives because they are related by arbitrage to
credit default swaps. An asset swap combines a fixed-rate bond or note with an interest
rate swap (Figure 3). The party that owns the bond pays the coupon into an interest rate
swap with a similar maturity to the bond. Because the bond coupon is typically larger
than the current swap rate for that maturity, the LIBOR leg of the floating rate swap is
increased by a spread equal to the difference between the underlying bond coupon
rate and the interest rate swap rate prevailing on the trade date. Because the interest rate
swap effectively strips out the interest rate risk of the bond, the bondholder is left
mainly with the credit risk of the bond (along with some counterparty credit risk on the
swap). The asset swap spread compensates the bondholder for the credit risk; for
this reason, the asset swap spread should be related by arbitrage to the credit default
swap spread. This relationship will be discussed in more detail in the section on pricing.
One last type of credit derivative is the credit spread option, which gives the
buyer the right but not the obligation to pay or receive a specified credit spread for
a given period. Such products were never more than 5 percent of notional amounts
outstanding and are now about 1 percent (British Bankers Association [BBA] 2006),
so they are of mainly historical interest. Credit spread options appear to have given
way to swaptions on CDS, which give the buyer the right but not the obligation to buy
(put swaption) or sell (call swaption) CDS protection.
In the remainder of this paper, credit derivatives and credit default swaps will
mean the same thing unless otherwise specified.
Figure 4
Growth of Credit Derivatives
50,000
45,000
BBA
ISDA
40,000
35,000
30,000
$U.S. billion
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
Notional amounts outstanding
veys report higher numbers. ISDA, for example, began collecting CDS notional
amounts in 2001 and reports growth from $632 billion in 2001 to over $45 trillion by
midyear 2007; annual growth has exceeded 100 percent from 2004 through 2006 but
slowed to 75 percent by mid-2007. And the Bank for International Settlements, which
began collecting comprehensive statistics in 2004, reports growth of notional amount
from $6.4 trillion at the end of 2004 to almost $43 trillion as of June 2007 (BIS 2007).
Average notional amounts for individual deals range from $10 million to $20 million
for North American investment-grade credits and are about €10 million for European
investment-grade credits; sub-investment-grade credits have notionals that average
about half the amounts for investment grade (JPMorgan Chase 2006). The most liquid
maturities center on five years, but liquidity is increasing for shorter maturities and
for longer maturities out to ten years (BBA 2006).
Table 1 shows the credit derivative breakdown by product type. According to the
BBA, CDS on indices have recently passed CDS on single names as the dominant
product type (BBA 2006). Single-name CDS, which were 38 percent of notional
amount outstanding in 1999, grew to as high as 51 percent in 2004 and are 33 percent
as of 2006. CDS linked to indices and to tranches of indices have grown from virtually
nothing in 2003 to 38 percent of outstandings. Finally, CDS referencing portfolios of
names in synthetic securitization transactions have declined slightly from 18 percent
in 2000 to just over 16 percent in 2006. The “others” category includes total return
swaps and asset swaps, which are now less than 6 percent of outstandings; in 2000,
in contrast, total return swaps were 11 percent of outstanding amounts, and asset
swaps were 12 percent (BBA 2002).
Tables 2 and 3 show the breakdown of market participants by type. Banks and
securities firms were dominant in 2000, at 81 percent of protection buyers and 63 per-
cent of protection sellers. By 2006, they had declined in importance to 59 percent
of buyers and 44 percent of sellers. Recent data distinguish between banks’ trading
Table 1
Credit Derivative Product Mix
activities and credit portfolio management activities: Trading activities are roughly
balanced between buying and selling protection while credit portfolio managers
appear more likely to hedge by buying protection than to seek diversification through
selling protection. Insurance companies tend to be active as sellers of protection;
they were 23 percent of sellers in 2000 but dropped to 17 percent by 2006. The
most significant change has been in the importance of hedge funds, which tend to
function as both buyers and sellers: In 2000, hedge funds were 3 percent of buyers
and 5 percent of sellers but by 2006 had grown to 28 percent of buyers and 32 per-
cent of sellers.
Table 4 shows the most common CDS counterparties—essentially, the most
active dealers in the market—from 2003 through 2006. Table 5 shows the most com-
mon reference entities for single-name CDS, both by deal count and by underlying
notional amount, as of year-end 2006 (Fitch Ratings 2007).
Evolution of the market. Smithson (2003) identified three stages in the evolu-
tion of credit derivatives activity. The first, “defensive” stage, during the late 1980s
and early 1990s, was characterized by ad hoc attempts by banks to lay off some of
their credit exposures. In addition, products such as securitized asset swaps bore
some resemblance to credit default swaps in that they paid investors a credit spread
while providing for delivery of the underlying asset to the investor in the event of a
default (Cilia 1996).
Stage two, which began about 1991 and lasted through the mid-to-late 1990s,
saw the emergence of an intermediated market, in which dealers applied derivatives
technology to the transfer of credit risk while investors entered the markets to seek
exposure to credit risk (Spinner 1997). Examples of dealer applications of derivative
technology include two transactions by Bankers Trust (Das 2006, 269–70). The first
involved a total return swap with another bank client seeking to free up credit lines
with a major client. The swap enabled the bank to pass its credit risk to Bankers
Trust, which in turn hedged its risk by selling the client’s bonds short. The second
transaction involved a funded first-to-default CDS on several Japanese client banks,
against which Bankers Trust had substantial credit exposure in the form of in-the-
money options. Although defensive in nature from Bankers Trust’s viewpoint, the
Table 2
Buyers of Protection by Institution Type
Table 3
Sellers of Protection by Institution Type
Table 4
Twenty Largest CDS Counterparties, 2003–06
Table 5
Top Reference Entities, Gross Protection Bought and Sold, Year-End 2006
During this stage, the market encountered a series of challenges that led to calls
for further refinement to the documentation. One such problem was restructuring.
The 1999 definitions included debt restructuring—that is, actions such as lowering
coupon or extending maturity—as a credit event triggering payment under a CDS.
The definition was put to the test with the restructuring in 2000 of loans to Conseco.
Banks agreed to extend the maturity of Conseco’s senior secured loans in return for
higher coupon and collateral; protection was thereby triggered on about $2 billion of
CDS. Protection buyers then took advantage of an embedded “cheapest to deliver”
option in CDS by delivering long-dated senior unsecured bonds, which were deeply
from perceived mispricing. Finally, hedge funds engage in basis trading between
credit default swaps and assets swaps on cash bonds. All these activities serve to
increase liquidity, price discovery, and efficiency in the market.
between par value and postdefault price, while an investor who bought the bond
below par has lost only the difference between the below-par purchase price and the
postdefault price. The result of the above factors is that, even if asset swap spreads
will not in most cases converge to CDS spreads, they are a reasonable starting point
for calculating the spread.
As an alternative to relying on asset swap spreads, CDS pricing models seek to
calculate CDS spreads by calculating expected cash flows. In such models, the CDS
spread is an internal rate of return that equates present value of expected premium
payments to present value of expected loss payments; that is
Solving the model involves calculating the spread that equates net present value
to zero—that is, an internal rate of return—under an assumed LGD. The survival and
default probabilities come from outside the model; alternatively, market spreads can
be used to calculate implied probabilities of default under an assumed LGD. For sim-
plicity, the above equations ignore accrued spread, which in the event of default
would be payable by the buyer to the seller for the fraction of the period from the last
premium payment date to the default date.
After inception, the value of the CDS will depend mostly on changes in credit
quality as reflected in current credit spreads. Given that the CDS spread for a trans-
action remains fixed, the mark-to-market value of the CDS will be equal to the present
value of the spread differences over the life of the CDS, taking account of survival
probabilities and, again, ignoring the accrued premium. Letting Spread0 equal the
CDS spread fixed at inception and Spreadi equal the current market spread, mark-
to-market value from the buyer’s point of view is
n
MTMi = (Spreadi – Spread0) × i=1
Σ DCFi × PSi × PVi(N).
If the buyer were to unwind at this point (to be discussed in the section on novations),
the above equation represents the amount payable to the buyer.2
Just as difficulties exist using asset swap spreads, problems are associated with
models such as that described above. A major difficulty is that the model requires
that one assume an LGD and furnish exogenous probabilities of default to calculate
an implied CDS spread. Alternatively, one could use the current market CDS spread
to calculate an implied probability of default, but doing so would still require assum-
ing an LGD. Assumptions regarding recoveries therefore are important to CDS pricing
and valuation. In practice, market participants can model the effect of alternative
LGD assumptions and can set aside reserves against differences in assumptions
(JPMorgan Chase 2006, 92–93; Chaplin 2005, 105).
Risk management. The purpose of a derivatives dealer, along with making a two-
way market, is to earn profits by managing the risk of a portfolio of derivatives. For
credit derivatives, the risk management function is similar in form to that for other
types of derivatives. When a dealer takes on risk from a client, the dealer typically
hedges the risk but might elect to leave some of the risk uncovered. The willingness
of dealers to leave some risks uncovered—that is, to speculate—adds liquidity to the
market but requires close management.
Typically, however, dealers hedge their risks in some manner. Most simply, a dealer
might offset the risk of a new deal against that of other clients. Further, the dealer might
hedge the risk of a deal in the underlying market, that is, the cash bond market; for
that reason, credit derivatives and corporate bond risks are often managed together.
Finally, a dealer might choose to offset risks by means of offsetting transactions with
other dealers; this is a primary function of the interdealer market.
In the early stages of credit derivatives as described above, risk management
essentially consisted of laying off one’s own risks. As the market developed into a two-
sided market, dealers assumed the role of intermediaries between buyers and sellers,
taking on the basis risk between the two. In these early stages of development, deal-
ers tended to hedge new transactions with offsetting cash market positions to the
extent feasible or else with offsetting transactions.
As the market has developed, additional hedging alternatives have become avail-
able. The growth of index CDS, for example, has increased the flexibility of dealers
in their risk-management activities. After the advent of widely traded index CDS,
market liquidity increased significantly, and new market participants entered both as
buyers and sellers. In such an environment, the business has evolved into a “flow”
business: that is, traders tend to remain “flat” by buying and selling continually
instead of by taking large open long or short positions. But trading desks also can use
index CDS to hedge their single-name CDS. For example, on any given day spreads
tend to move in the same direction, so index swaps might be a reasonable hedge of a
diversified single-name CDS portfolio; as with other hedges, the dealer would assume
and manage the basis risk between the two.3
Along with the market risks of their deal portfolios and the accompanying basis
risks, dealers manage a host of other risks. First, counterparty credit risk is a major
component of all OTC derivatives activity. Counterparty risk management begins
with ISDA or other relevant transaction documentation, followed by measurement of
both current exposure and potential losses if default were to occur in the future and
finally by collateralization of net exposures. Second, dealers manage such risks as
time decay, in which deals lose value as they approach maturity. Finally, dealers man-
age model risks, which are associated with the simplifying assumptions as well as
unidentified errors in pricing models; to anticipate the possibility of model deficien-
cies, dealers calculate potential losses from modeling errors and set aside reserves to
cover them (Chaplin 2005, 100–106).
One unique aspect of credit derivatives activity compared with other OTC deriva-
tives is liquidity management. Credit derivatives are characterized by a higher degree
of standardization than are other forms of OTC derivatives, although the standard
2. For a more detailed practitioner-oriented discussion of CDS pricing, see Chaplin (2005).
3. This type of hedging is roughly equivalent to hedging interest rate swaps with Treasury bonds or
an equity portfolio with S&P 500 futures.
terms are not mandatory as in exchange-traded futures. As noted above, CDS involve
standard payment and maturity dates. Further, each type of reference entity involves
a standard set of credit events and other terms. Standard terms facilitate trading by
simplifying negotiation and tasks such as unwinds; they also make it easier for market
participants to engage in arbitrage between CDS indices and underlying names.
Credit derivatives participants have adopted a higher degree of standardization
because credit risk is different from other underlying risks. Unlike interest rate swaps,
in which the various risks of a customized transaction can be isolated by traders and
offset in liquid underlying money and currency markets, credit default swaps involve
“lumpy” credit risks that do not lend themselves to decomposition. Standardization
is therefore a substitute for decomposition. Yet despite the higher degree of standard-
ization, CDS retain their essential nature as OTC rather than standardized transac-
tions: Parties to CDS deals remain free to diverge from the market standard and to
customize transactions to whatever extent they agree.
Market participants can also use CDS to engage in arbitrage between markets. In
convertible bond arbitrage, for example, an investor buys a convertible bond in which
the embedded equity option is underpriced, uses an asset swap to hedge out the
interest rate risk, and then buys credit protection to hedge out the credit risk. The
investor is then left with a pure equity exposure, which is the object of the arbitrage.
With regard to sellers of protection, credit derivatives enable market participants to
attain exposure in the form of a long credit position. A financial institution seeking
to diversify its credit exposure might, for
example, sell CDS protection as an alterna- Unlike interest rate swaps, in which risks
tive to making loans or buying bonds. This can be isolated and offset in liquid under-
alternative is especially helpful to institu- lying money and currency markets,
tions that seek credit exposure but lack the
legal infrastructure for lending; it is also credit default swaps involve “lumpy”
helpful to banks seeking to diversify their credit risks that do not lend themselves
loan portfolios but lacking direct relation- to decomposition.
ships with desired credits. Further, selling
protection allows an investor with a high cost of funding to take on credit exposure
without incurring the cost of funding. It is important in such cases that the investor
realizes that the exposure to losses is the same as if it were lending directly.
The ability to sell protection also allows market participants to act on a view that
a reference entity’s credit quality will improve. In this case, the investor would sell
protection now in the hope of unwinding it later by purchasing it at a lower price. As
mentioned above, such activity adds liquidity to the market and increases the quality
of price discovery.
Another benefit of credit derivatives is that they add transparency to credit mar-
kets (Kroszner 2007). Prior to the existence of credit derivatives, determining a price
for credit risk was difficult, and no accepted benchmark existed for credit risk. As
credit derivatives become more liquid and cover a wider range of entities, however,
lenders and investors will be able to compare pricing of cash instruments such as
bonds and loans with credit derivatives. Further, investors will be able to engage in
relative value trades between markets, which will lead to further improvements
in efficiency and price discovery.
At a higher level, economic stability stands to benefit from the ability to transfer
credit risk by buying and selling protection. As with other derivatives, the cost of risk
transfer is reduced, so risk is dispersed more widely into deeper markets. The result
is that economic shocks should have less effect than was the case prior to the exis-
tence of derivatives. Several objections can be made to such an argument, however,
and these will be considered in the next section.
Costs. It is often argued that the flip side of wider and deeper risk transfer is that,
instead of exerting a stabilizing influence on markets, it is potentially destabilizing
because it transfers risk from participants that specialize in credit risk (that is, banks)
to participants with less experience in managing credit risk—for example, insurers
and hedge funds (“Risky business” 2005, for example). In addition, there is the dan-
ger that anything used to disperse risk can also be used by investors seeking yield
enhancement to concentrate risk. Finally, these new institutions generally fall outside
the regulatory reach of agencies that oversee various aspects of the credit markets.
Such arguments have weaknesses, however. While it is true that banks tradition-
ally specialize in managing credit risk, for example, it is also true that traditional lend-
ing has tended to concentrate credit exposures in a narrow class of institutions,
namely, commercial banks. Further, one could argue that nonbank institutions might
in many cases have liability structures that are more suitable than those of banks for
bearing credit risks (IMF 2006, chap. 2). But even if one were to accept the ques-
tionable argument that nonbank investors are inevitably less skilled than banks at
managing credit risk, it would also be the case that credit losses would have less
effect on any one institution than was the case when credit was limited mostly to
banks. Finally, the argument that credit derivatives increase overall risks by trans-
ferring credit risk outside strictly regulated institutions makes an implicit assumption
that government regulation automatically leads to more prudent risk-taking. But this
argument ignores the potential moral hazard associated with such an assumption.
Indeed, because less regulated institutions are less likely to be protected by an official
safety net, such institutions are likely to have substantial incentives to identify, mea-
sure, and manage credit exposures (Kroszner 2007).
Another commonly cited cost of credit derivatives is that they reduce incentives
for lenders to analyze and monitor credit quality because they now have the ability
to off-load credit risk (Jackson 2007, for example). The result is a decrease in over-
all credit quality. Again, there are weaknesses to such arguments, mainly that hedg-
ing is not costless. As is true with other risks, when one hedges away a risk, one also
hedges away the opportunity to profit. A possible exception to this rule would be sys-
tematic underpricing of CDS protection relative to loan risk, for which no evidence
exists. Another possible exception is a “lemons” argument that lenders use collater-
alized debt obligations to off-load risks to protection sellers, although one would
expect that such a practice, if widespread, would induce CDO note buyers to build
expectations of higher losses into the price of the credit protection they provide. Yet
another exception would be lenders’ possessing inside information about credit qual-
ity, on which they could act by buying underpriced protection. This issue has already
received extensive attention by the financial industry (Joint Market Practices Forum
2003), however, and one would not expect such activity to be a systematic feature of
credit derivatives markets.
A corollary to the argument that lenders with access to credit protection are
indifferent to risk is that credit derivatives, as do other forms of risk transfer,
inevitably involve a moral hazard effect that leads to higher risk overall (Plender
2006). In other words, risk reduction at the individual entity level can mean higher
risk at the system level. Such an argument has an element of plausibility in that, when
market participants are able to hedge certain risks, they are able to increase the
amount of risks they take overall. But even if firms do take on more risk than before,
one could argue that, as long as firms do not take on excessive amounts of risk, the
system is in fact safer because the individual institutions that hedge are less vulner-
able to market shocks.
4. Hedge funds generally post up-front collateral (known as the independent amount) with dealer
counterparties regardless of the direction of exposure. They then post additional collateral to
cover subsequent variations in exposure.
During August 2005, however, Federal Reserve Bank of New York President
Timothy Geithner invited fourteen major credit derivative dealers to a meeting to dis-
cuss CDS operations issues, with particular attention to confirmation backlogs. At the
meeting, which occurred the following month, the dealers agreed to reduce backlogs
and to report their progress periodically.
The effort to reduce backlogs led to increased efforts within ISDA to complete a
solution to the novations issue. The solution, known as the ISDA Novation Protocol,
was announced just before the New York Fed meeting in September (Raisler and
Teigland-Hunt 2006). The protocol entailed
extensive negotiation between dealers,
The entry of hedge funds and other
hedge funds, and other participants and
investors into credit derivatives has been specified a set of explicit duties for the
an important factor in the development parties to a novation. Under the protocol,
parties wishing to act as transferees are
of CDS market liquidity and efficiency.
required to obtain prior consent but are now
able to do so electronically. If the remain-
ing party provides consent prior to 6 PM New York time, the novation is complete; the
remaining party can respond by email. If the remaining party does not provide con-
sent prior to 6 PM, the transferor and transferee enter into an offsetting transaction
that obtains a similar economic result to the novation.
Market participants were given a deadline to sign on to the ISDA Novation
Protocol; dealers agreed not to transact novations with parties that did not agree. In
order to provide assurance that remaining parties would respond promptly to nova-
tion requests, dealers committed to specific standards for responding by the dead-
lines in the protocol. The result has been considered a success: 2,000 parties signed
on to the original Novation Protocol, and almost 190 entities have signed on to a
version designed for new participants.
Initial assessments of the protocol have been favorable. These assessments have
corresponded to reports that the industry has made considerable progress in reduc-
ing confirmation backlogs and increasing overall operational efficiency. According to
the New York Fed, by September 2006 the fourteen largest dealers had reduced the
number of all confirmations outstanding by 70 percent and of confirmations out-
standing past thirty days by 85 percent. Further, the dealers had doubled the share of
trades confirmed electronically to 80 percent of total trade volume (Federal Reserve
Bank of New York 2006).
The case of novations demonstrates that collective action problems can threaten
the feasibility of private sector efforts but that thoughtful regulatory action can facil-
itate a solution. Although all parties had an interest in a solution, none believed the
other side was willing to take the necessary steps. Further, competitive considera-
tions made dealers reluctant to exert pressure on one of their most active client groups.
The regulatory intervention provided sufficient cover for dealers to insist on adher-
ence by their clients. In this case, a relatively light touch by a regulator was sufficient
to bring about a solution.
CDS settlement following credit events. As mentioned earlier, credit deriva-
tive index trades have been the major factor in recent growth in credit derivatives.
The result of this growth was a new challenge, namely, that the amount of credit pro-
tection outstanding is far greater than the supply of underlying debt that could be
delivered if a credit event were to occur. The problem manifested itself in a series of
corporate bankruptcies in the North American auto parts companies (Collins & Aikman,
Delphi, Dana, and Dura), airlines (Delta and Northwest), and power companies
(Calpine). Because of the expanded interest in credit derivatives caused by the intro-
duction of indices, the amount of credit derivatives outstanding was in some cases
reported to be as much as ten times the amount of bonds actually available to settle
trades when a credit event occurs. This imbalance called into question the ability of
the industry to achieve traditional physical settlement in an orderly manner, which
led to calls by industry participants to substitute cash settlement for physical settle-
ment for index trades.
The problem was that existing CDS contracts called for physical settlement after
credit events. In addition, current documentation provides that the cash settlement
will be determined by dealer poll by each dealer, which was not considered feasible
given the large number of market participants that would be trying to buy deliverable
debt at the same time. With regard to the first problem, counterparties are free to
substitute cash for physical settlement if they so agree, but doing so on a large scale
could require bilateral negotiations between each pair of counterparties. Further,
developing an alternative to the dealer poll required a collective industry solution.
The solution proposed by ISDA was that firms move to cash settlement by means of
a protocol that allows market participants to amend their contracts on a multilateral
basis rather than engaging in bilateral negotiations. In essence, market participants
can agree to industrywide and standardized amendments to their contracts. Parties
that agree to be bound by the protocol’s terms effectively amend their credit deriva-
tive contracts without negotiating directly with other firms. In addition, the protocol
provided an alternative means by which a cash settlement price could be determined.
The protocol in this case allowed market participants to shift from physical set-
tlement to cash settlement using a price generated in an auction for the defaulted
bonds. In the first protocol, held in May 2005 for auto parts supplier Collins &
Aikman, there was a single deliverable obligation. The next protocol addressed the
bankruptcy filings of U.S. airlines Delta and Northwest, which offered multiple
deliverable obligations. Delphi, another auto parts company, was a particularly
challenging one as the volume of trades on the name was high: Merrill Lynch and
Fitch Ratings estimated that there was $28 billion of exposure on this name but
only $2.2 billion par value of bonds available and $3 billion in loans outstanding
(Fitch Ratings 2005).
Experience with subsequent credit events has led to what appears to be a long-
term solution. First, although cash settlement will be the standard, institutions will
have the option to settle physically with their dealers if they so choose. Second, the
cash settlement protocol will, unlike the early versions, apply to both index and
single-name CDS as well as other products such as swaptions. Third, the new system,
following further experience, will be incorporated into the next set of credit deriva-
tives definitions.
Remaining Issues
In considering the future of credit derivatives, two subjects come to mind. The first
is the potential for further innovation and growth of credit derivatives. The second is
the possibility that credit derivatives might evolve into a standardized, exchange-
traded product.
Growth and innovation could occur along several dimensions. One dimension is
type of contract. There have been some variations on the CDS such as credit swap-
tions and constant-maturity credit default swaps, but the CDS has proved to be an
adaptable product and is unlikely to be displaced. To the extent that product inno-
vation occurs, it is likely to take the form of structured finance applications tailored
to investor demands for tailored exposures. An example of such a product is the single
tranche CDO, which provides investors with exposure to credit risk through a cus-
tomized CDS portfolio.
Another dimension is type of risk. Until recently, CDS were written on entities or
groups of entities. But recent innovations have extended CDS protection to obligations
instead of industries. CDS on asset-backed securities, for example, have enabled
investors to access securitized risks without having to make a direct investment. As
a result, supply constraints are less of a factor. Other examples include CDS on lever-
aged loans and on preferred stock, which
again reference financial instruments of a
Growth and innovation of credit deriva-
particular type.
tives could occur along several dimensions: Yet another dimension is new market
type of contract, type of risk, and new participants. The major new entrant has
been hedge funds. Whether there are other
market participants.
significant entrants waiting in the wings is
not clear, however. Tables 2 and 3 suggest
that mutual funds and pension funds have shown some growth, but prudential
restrictions on allowable risks might continue to limit the role of such buy-side firms.
Second, retail investors might begin to participate, but the history of over-the-
counter derivatives, which have remained overwhelmingly wholesale in nature, sug-
gests that retail investors are unlikely to be a major factor. If retail investors do show
an appetite for credit investing, they will likely participate through banks and secu-
rities firms that serve as intermediaries. A third possibility is that regional banks will
increasingly participate in the market, possibly by selling protection as a means of
diversifying their portfolios. As Tables 2 and 3 show, however, bank portfolio man-
agers are significantly more likely to use credit derivatives to shed credit risk than to
take on credit risk.
A final possibility is that nonfinancial corporations might enter the market as they
have for interest rate, currency, and commodity derivatives, but so far they have not
done so in any significant way (Smithson and Mengle 2006). In the early days of credit
derivatives, corporations were considered a potential source of business because of
credit risks embedded in corporate balance sheets as receivables and supplier rela-
tionships. Further, corporate credit exposures could be a natural hedge for dealers’
exposures to investors and would help dealers balance their CDS portfolios at low
cost. Corporate activity did not materialize, however, largely because of basis risks:
The nature of corporate exposures is difficult to match with a specific amount of pro-
tection and possibly on a specific reference entity.
With regard to the evolution of credit default swaps into standardized, exchange-
traded futures contracts, several projects are under way as of this writing. First, futures
on the iTraxx Europe credit index began trading on Eurex on March 27, 2007. The
product is based on a five-year index with a fixed income; a new contract will be issued
every six months. The contract will be cash settled, with the payout based on the ISDA
CDS settlement auction. Second, the Chicago Mercantile Exchange is developing a
futures contract on single-name credit default swaps. Contracts will be written on three
reference entities chosen by the exchange. If a credit event occurs, the contracts will
have a fixed recovery rate. The CME is also developing an index contract. Third, the
Chicago Board Options Exchange is developing a credit default option, which involves
an up-front payment and a binary payout of $100,000 per contract if a credit event
occurs. Finally, the Chicago Board of Trade and Euronext.Liffe are each planning
futures contracts based on a credit index, but details are not yet available.
REFERENCES
Bank for International Settlements (BIS). 2007. Flannery, Mark. 1985. A portfolio view of loan selec-
Triennial and semiannual surveys on positions in tion and pricing. In Handbook for banking strategy,
global over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives markets edited by Robert A. Eisenbeis and Richard C. Aspinwall.
at end-June 2007, November. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
British Bankers Association (BBA). 2002. BBA credit International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2006. Global
derivatives report 2001/2002. London: BBA Enter- financial stability report, April.
prises Ltd.
Jackson, Tony. 2007. Derivative risk threatens private
———. 2006. BBA credit derivatives report 2006. equity. Financial Times, February 26.
London: BBA Enterprises Ltd.
Joint Market Practices Forum. 2003. Statement of prin-
Chaplin, Geoff. 2005. Credit derivatives: Risk man- ciples and recommendations regarding the handling of
agement, trading and investing. West Sussex, U.K.: material nonpublic information by credit market partic-
Wiley. ipants. International Association of Credit Portfolio
Managers, International Swaps and Derivatives Associa-
Choudhry, Moorad. 2004. Structured credit products: tion, Loan Sales and Trading Association, and the Bond
Credit derivatives and synthetic securitisation. Market Association.
Singapore: Wiley.
JPMorgan Chase. 2006. Credit derivatives handbook.
———. 2006. The credit default swap basis. New Corporate Quantitative Research, December.
York: Bloomberg Press.
Kroszner, Randall. 2007. Recent innovations in credit
Cilia, Joseph. 1996. Product summary: Asset swaps. markets. Credit Markets Symposium, Federal Reserve
Financial Markets Unit, Supervision and Regulation, Bank of Richmond, March 22.
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, August.
Plender, John. 2006. The credit business is more per-
Counterparty Risk Management Policy Group (CRMPG) ilous than ever. Financial Times, October 13.
II. 2005. Toward greater financial stability: A private
sector perspective, July. Raisler, Kenneth, and Lauren Teigland-Hunt. 2006. How
ISDA took on the confirmations backlog. International
Das, Satyajit. 2006. Traders, guns, and money. Financial Law Review, February.
Harlow, U.K.: Pearson.
Risky business. 2005. Economist, August 18.
Evans, Gay Huey. 2005. Operations and risk manage-
ment in credit derivatives markets. CEO Letter, Smithson, Charles. 2003. Credit portfolio manage-
Financial Services Authority, February. ment. Hoboken, N.J.: Wiley.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 2006. Statement Smithson, Charles, and David Mengle. 2006. The
regarding progress in credit derivatives markets, promise of credit derivatives in nonfinancial corpora-
September 27. tions (and why it’s failed to materialize). Journal of
Applied Corporate Finance 18, no. 4:54–60.
Fitch Ratings. 2005. Delphi, credit derivatives, and
bond trading behavior after a bankruptcy filing, Spinner, Karen. 1997. Building the credit derivatives
November 28. infrastructure. Derivatives Strategy, Credit Deriva-
tives Supplement, June.
———. 2006. Global credit derivatives survey: Indices
dominate growth as banks’ risk position shifts, Taksler, Glen. 2007. Credit default swap primer,
September 21. 2d ed. Debt research, Bank of America, January 5.
———. 2007. CDx Survey, July 16.