Public Financial Support For Commercial Innovation in ECA Countries
Public Financial Support For Commercial Innovation in ECA Countries
Public Financial Support For Commercial Innovation in ECA Countries
Itzhak Goldberg, Manuel Trajtenberg, Adam Jaffe, Thomas Muller, Julie Sunderland, and Enrique Blanco Armas the centrality of innovation and knowledge creation in the growth process and, on the other hand, the understanding that these are economic factors that may be shaped and influenced by properly designed economic policies. For the purpose of this Knowledge Brief, innovation can be defined as the development and commercialization of new unproven technologies and untested processes and products, and absorption as the application of existing technologies, processes, and products. The ability of an economy to research and develop new technologies increases its ability to understand and apply existing technologies. Vice versa, the absorption of cutting-edge technology inspires new ideas and innovations. However, the adoption of existing technology via trade, Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) or licensing is not guaranteed or cost free. Firms and countries need to invest in developing absorptive or national learning capacity, which in turn is a function of spending on research and development (R&D); domestic R&D has a role in developing a firms ability to identify, assimilate, and exploit knowledge from the environment, that is, enhance the absorptive capacity of the economy.
Key Messages1
Commercial innovation and R&D are key factors driving self-sustained, long-term economic growth. These factors are generated from within the economic system, responding to economic incentives. Translating research into economically productive commercial applications is a critical missing link in Europe and Central Asia (ECA) countries. Typically, the bulk of R&D spending in ECA, as much as two-thirds of the 0.9 percent of GDP, is financed by governments whereas only about one-third is financed by the private sector. The utilization of instruments such as matching grants and venture capitalwith as much private sector participation in risk sharing and selection as possiblewill be needed in ECA countries to ensure transparency and commercial viability and mitigate the risks of government failure.
Innovation in ECA
Scarcity of capital and the high cost of labor in ECA countries, relative to their Asian competitors, limit costbased competitiveness. The crisis exposed the limits of growth fueled by external financing or natural resource exports. Revitalizing growth requires new strategies to raise competitiveness: export-led sectoral diversification; investments in skills and infrastructure; and innovation and absorption of technologies from the world. The ECA region has a fairly high human capital stock and well-developed research institutions, with an average of nearly 2,000 R&D researchers per million; Russia has the highest ratio of researchers to its populationmore than 3,400 per one million people. In Figure 1, the gross
Innovation
versus
Technology
Key factors driving self-sustained, long-term economic growth are innovation and technology absorption; these factors are generated from within the economic system, responding to economic incentives. This conceptual framework molds our analysis: on the one hand, the view of
1
This Knowledge Brief is based on a Knowledge Economy Study that is part of an ongoing Regional Working Paper Series sponsored by the Chief Economists Office in Europe and Central Asia Region of the World Bank.
investments in R&D in their respective countries. The European Unions (EU) Lisbon Strategy has prompted the new member states and other ECA countries to consider implementing financial instruments to promote innovation, especially venture capital schemes. However, this is being done with little consideration for the necessary institutional requisites or appropriateness of the instruments. In a number of countries in the former Soviet Union (for example, Russia, Ukraine, Kazakhstan) and its satellites and in the former Yugoslavia (Serbia, Croatia), the legacy of research and human capital also provides an incentive to revive their research capacity. But absorptive capacity remains an issue in all ECA countries. Some of the countries are likely to have higher productivity returns from investments in building absorptive capacity than in commercial innovation.
In recent years, policy makers in the ECA region have increasingly directed their attention towards enhancing
Josh Lerner, Boulevard of Broken Dreams: Why Public Efforts to Boost Entrepreneurship and Venture Capital Have Failed--and What to Do About It, Princeton Press, 2009.
One of the major problems of the innovation system is in the sequencing of support for early stage vis--vis support for growth stage innovation, mainly VC. Effective sequencing should aim at building a significant deal flow of early stage projects before supporting VC. The success of the growth stage of the commercialization cycle depends on a deal flow of attractive companies coming out of the early stage. For example, in Israel, the VC boom in the 1990s would not have been possible without the projects which had been supported by matching grants for 20 years by the Office of the Chief Scientist Program. The more traditional approach to R&D support for firms has been through tax incentives or subsidized loans. However, since the 1980s, there has been an increasing awareness among OECD countries of the benefits of matching grants in encouraging firms to share and manage risk. A number of historically successful grant programs, such as Australias R&D Start Program and the U.S. SBIR Program, have an implicit matching component in that firms are expected to support a portion of the research budget. Figure 2 shows an estimated breakdown of actual funding sources for early stage technological development (ESTD) in the United States.
Figure 2: Funding For Early Development in the United States Stage Technological
Government interventions need to be carefully designed to promote private risk-taking instead of rent seeking and to stimulate markets for private risk capital, so as not to crowd out private investment and other funding sources. The government should also not decide ex ante which technological sectors, firms or projects to support, but respond to the demands coming from the market. Especially in ECA countries, the institutional design should aim to immunize, as much as possible, the funding allocation from interference by political actors, corruption, and other state or specific interests capture. An active innovation policy government program in support of innovation should span the entire commercialization cycle. The three different stages of the innovation cycle require different policy instruments: Early stage building of a deal flow: incubators, angel investors or matching grants, as well as spinoffs and other spillovers from multinational companies (MNCs). Growth stage: government support for private venture capital (VC) via risk sharing.
Source: Auerswald and Branscomb 2003. Valleys of Death and Darwinian Seas: Financing the Invention to Innovation Transition in the United States. Journal of Technology Transfer 28 (34): 22739.
Theoretically, the importance of matching stems from the fact that its effect is to reduce the marginal cost of research to the firm. A firm facing a downward sloping marginal research returns schedule will always increase total expenditure when the marginal cost falls, precluding the dollar-for-dollar crowding-out.
About the Authors Itzhak Goldberg, Former Advisor, Private and Financial Sector Development Sector, Europe and Central Asia Region, World Bank; Manuel Trajtenberg, Professor, TelAviv University; Adam Jaffe, Professor, Brandeis University; Thomas Muller, Program Coordinator, GTZ; Enrique Blanco Armas, Senior Economist, East Asia Pacific Region, World Bank; and Julie Sunderland, Consultant.