Class in Soweto
Class in Soweto
Class in Soweto
iii
Contents
v
10 Conclusion 234
Peter Alexander
Bibliography 274
Notes on Contributors 295
Index 297
vi
Affordability and action 1
Peter Alexander
‘The discrepancies in livelihoods across the world are so large that they are without
historical precedent and without conceivable justification’ (Pieterse 2002: 1–2). This
gulf has fed commentary about ‘class’ both in the popular media and among political
analysts. In many countries, the expansion of a new middle class has attracted
attention, and this has sometimes been matched by concern about the plight of the
poor and the working class. Academic research on class has lagged behind, but even
here there has been renewed interest over recent years. However, this scholarship
emanates overwhelmingly from the global North, where class structures and social
dynamics are different from those in the majority of the world. This book enriches
the debate through a study conducted in Soweto, South Africa’s largest black
township, which provides a home for about one in 30 of the country’s 50.6 million
inhabitants (Stats SA 2011a).1
In South Africa, income inequality and unemployment have reached extreme
levels. In terms of Gini co-efficients for income, it is the most unequal country in
the world (with the exception of a few with small populations), and Johannesburg
– which is where Soweto is located – is the most unequal major city (with a Gini
co-efficient of 0.75) (UN HABITAT 2010: 73, 193). The county’s unemployment
levels are also among the worst in the world, with the official figure standing at
24.9 in early 2012 (Stats SA 2012b). However, a very high proportion of adults is
‘not in the labour force’, so excluded from this statistic, and others are engaged in
survivalist activities. All this may lead one to dismiss South Africa as so exceptional
that its class structures and identities can be written off as unique, and thus extraneous
to a wider analysis of class. Our view, however, is that the intensity of the contrast
1
2 Peter Alexander
between rich and poor in South Africa and the magnitude of joblessness in Soweto
and elsewhere, can assist us to comprehend the class nature of those who are excluded
by occupation-related analyses or marginalised by a focus on direct relationships
to production. In other words, it can contribute to the study of class, not only in
lower-income countries, but also in much of the global North, where unemployment
and underemployment are now significant issues, both socially and theoretically.
In Spain, the second quarter 2012 official rate of unemployment was 24.6 per cent,
only 0.3 per cent lower than South Africa’s for the same period (Washington Post
2012). The urgency of such analysis was underlined by, for instance, the 2011 ‘riots’
in Britain, in which the majority of the participants were outside the labour force
and viewed their actions in terms that were diametrically opposed to the majority
of the population (Roberts 2011: locations 545, 638).
Our research was motivated by two concerns. In addition to interest in the
impact of heightened inequality, there was a related political question. While this
had broader implications, we posed it locally. Earlier research had revealed that the
more radical of South Africa’s social movements were composed overwhelmingly
of people who were jobless (Alexander 2006a: 49). In contrast, trade union member-
ship invariably excludes those without jobs. Since 2004 this gap has been highlighted
by the development of, on the one hand, ‘a rebellion of the poor’, in which workers
are peripheral, and, on the other hand, a level of strike action that, measured in days
lost per capita, was among the highest in the world. Furthermore, there have been
political differences between leaders of the Congress of South African Trade Unions
(COSATU) and the social movements, and there has sometimes been friction between
employed workers and rebelling youth. In this context, we pondered the following
question: Is it possible that workers and the poor constitute distinct classes?
We have called this book Class in Soweto, a title intended to convey a sense of
how people see themselves in class terms, as well as the differences in employment,
housing, income and culture we discerned as researchers. The project from which
the book emanates was known as ‘Classifying Soweto’, with this name embodying
an understanding of ‘classifying’ in line with academic usage that signals the
importance of social class for analysis of social change. Recognising that apartheid
discourse still has purchase and that ‘classifying’ might be acssociated with racial
classification, we decided on a new title. The chapters in this volume were written
by different authors, all of whom were engaged in the project and participated in
discussions on how to interpret its findings. This opening chapter outlines the
project’s theoretical and methodological framework, comments on some relevant
literature, summarises the various chapters, and then draws on all of these to highlight
novel aspects of our account.
Affordability and action 3
There are three theoretical issues that require clarification before proceeding.
First, one of the strengths of Marx’s ‘class’ is that it was principally an abstraction
(part of his theorisation of the laws of motion of the capitalist mode of production
and a prediction about a socialist future). In this sense, there were ‘two great classes’,
capitalists and workers, each internally united by their antagonistic relationship to
exploitation. Because class was abstract and exploitation remains central to social
dynamics in capitalist society, the concept has continuing salience in the form in
which it was initially advanced. However, Marx never formally defined ‘class’, and
he (and Frederick Engels) also used the same word in ways that were historically
specific (that is more sociologically and/or politically concrete) (see also Wolpe
1986).5
The second issue is this. At the more concrete level, class is about production,
but it is also about aspects of social reproduction.6 The importance of reproduction
was acknowledged, especially by Engels (1884: preface), and Marx (1954: 603) writes,
for example, about the way the unemployed were ‘thrown’ onto the ‘shoulders’ of
the working class and lower middle class. Today, there is often a larger gap than in
Marx’s time between classes defined in terms of (1) production and (2) distinctions
within the space of reproduction (that is, consumption as well as the reproduction
of labour). This arises from a growth in the size of the middle classes, and, in cases
like South Africa, an increase in the proportion of people who are either unemployed
or underemployed. Consumption can encourage quiescence, but absence of things
such as housing of a certain quality can be an important source of struggle. Action
may occur in the sphere of production (for instance, a strike) but may also occur in
the sphere of reproduction (such as a service delivery protest). Understood in this
way, Marxism provides us with the greater flexibility we need to make sense of
contemporary society.
The third issue concerns the importance of subjectivity (which Wright does
not stress but we do). Here my concern has three components. (1) Changing the
world involves agency, and to address this we need to understand how people see
themselves consciously and behave unconsciously in class terms. The emphasis
on agency derives from the weight Marx and Engels placed on working-class
action. This comes, in particular, in the formulation: ‘the emancipation of the
working class must be the act of the working class itself’ (Engels 1969: preface to
the English edition of 1888, though similar formulations exist elsewhere). (2) As
Alex Callinicos (2006: 2–3) argues, Marx’s distinction between class-in-itself and
class-for-itself is closely related to one between class as something objective, what
Callinicos terms simply ‘class’, and subjectivity. In this formulation, subjectivity
could include subjectivities related to race, gender and so on, but we focused
6 Peter Alexander
‘classes’ (in any sense). While there was a theoretical basis to the ECs, they were
modified to some extent by an iterative engagement with the data. One can see
them as defined in terms of relationships to production, whether direct or indirect,
and of relationships between the different categories. However, the categorisation
should be regarded as provisional, because an acceptable theorisation would require
a broader frame of reference, both geographically and in terms of the questions
being posed. A further explication of the distinctions and the procedure for allocating
individuals to the various categories – a complex and time-consuming process – is
provided by Claire Ceruti in Chapter 4.
We ended up with nine ECs. First, there are the capitalists, the exploiters.
Secondly, there are regularly employed workers who stand on the other side of the
main class divide within capitalist society. We lumped all workers together, whether
or not they directly produce surplus value. The third group, managers and
supervisors, were employees who exercised some measure of control and surveillance
over workers (albeit, in practice, with limited powers). Fourthly, there was the
petty bourgeoisie (which included self-employed workers), who owned their own
business but exploited themselves and employed no more than a handful of staff
(commonly family members). The fifth group, the unemployed, resemble Marx’s
‘reserve army of labour’ (see Chapters 4 and 10). The next two groups are akin to
that part of Marx’s ‘surplus population’ engaged in some kind of work (so not
actually part of the reserve army). They include the survivalist self-employed, who,
unlike the pretty bourgeoisie, would have preferred to be regularly employed. Then
there are partial workers, whose precise relationships to exploitation varied, but
whose conditions were always inferior to those of the regularly employed. In
practice, most were engaged on a short-term basis (for example, as day labourers),
but we also included people working just a few hours per week, who might, literally,
be regularly employed, but were actually unemployed for more than half of what
one can regard as a normal working week (that is, 40 hours). Finally, there were
two groups that were outside the labour force (in other words, neither employed
nor available for employment). These were, eighthly, students and, ninthly, pensioners
and others not in the labour force (for instance, disabled). In some respects these
two categories were similar, but they had contrasting expectations of joining the
labour force (that is, making themselves available for exploitation).
For our identity theme, we learned from initial qualitative research that people
could hold more than one class identity. While this was a surprise, it seemed plausible
theoretically.8 For the survey, the discovery enabled us to ask our key identity
question in a novel way – one that moved beyond expecting respondents to select
just one identity from a predetermined list. We asked ‘would you call yourself . . .
8 Peter Alexander
[followed, in turn, by one of eight labels, all of which were derived from the
qualitative interviews]’. Our other themes do not require further elucidation at
this stage. For ‘reproduction’ and ‘culture’, colleagues drew together responses to
several, sometimes many, questions in our survey. This was linked with data from
qualitative interviews.
A case study of the kind undertaken was suitable for developing and testing
concepts and relationships, which is what we needed in order to provide a response
to our opening questions. But, why select Soweto? Firstly, it was accessible (indeed,
during most of the research, our team was situated on the university’s Soweto
campus). Secondly, linked to this, we had some prior knowledge of the township’s
geography and political life. Thirdly, its size, location, leadership and past events
meant that it was – and still is – politically important. Fourthly, related to this,
there was literature that helped with historical context. Fifthly, its size also meant
that it provided a reasonable cross-section of class backgrounds (although this proved
to be more limited than anticipated). Sixthly, we wanted to undertake a study that
was comprehensive and representative, and Soweto is sufficiently compact and
geographically defined to make this possible. Lastly, it provided the possibility to,
albeit cautiously, draw out some implications for South Africa as a whole.
Appendix 1 provides a detailed account of our research design and its
implementation. The main component was a survey conducted in Soweto in June
and July 2006 (which covered adults of sixteen years and over). This included a
representative sample of 2 340 respondents and had a response rate which exceeded
90 per cent (that is, very high). Quantitative research was sandwiched between two
main rounds of qualitative fieldwork (with some chapters, especially the one on
churches, involving further research). Additional data was collected for our research
documentary, Phakathi. We regarded our approach as broadly Marxist, albeit
heterodox. It was intended to capture a particular situation in which those officially
regarded as employed were a minority of the adult population (less than one-third
if one excludes the underemployed). However, we planned the survey in a way
that left open a range of interpretations.
What were the limitations? Firstly, we did not survey Johannesburg’s ‘suburbs’.
This has three significant implications. (1) In the course of our research, it became
clear that there had been significant out-migration of better-paid Sowetans, and
these were not captured in the survey.9 (2) There were no white or Indian
respondents in our survey and only a few so-called ‘coloureds’, so the significance
of racial differences is largely absent. (3) The research misses out on the wealthy in
general and capitalists specifically (though this would probably have been true of
Affordability and action 9
and paid a wage, and, on the other hand, cases in which work requires greater
autonomy, and pay and conditions reflect the need for loyalty) (2000: 206–29).
Arguably, Wright moved closer to Weberian formulations and Goldthorpe shifted
nearer to Marxism (Roberts 2001: 27–31). While Wright’s revised approach has,
perhaps, made less impact than the earlier one (Roberts 2001: 37; Seekings 2005:
27–8), Goldthorpe’s new scheme has had significant influence in Britain, shaping
the socio-economic classes used by its Office of National Statistics (ONS). The
ONS, however, made one important change. It added an eighth category to
Goldthorpe’s seven (ONS 2008). This included the long-term unemployed and
students, a so-called ‘residual’, thus recognising the growing importance of these
segments of the population and the need to move beyond specific employment
relationships. The approaches of both Wright and Goldthorpe have merits. The
former contributes to our understanding of class conflict and social transformation,
while the latter reveals the extent to which educational achievement, social mobility
and voting behaviour are linked to ‘class’. However, both have the limitation of
seeing class as something rooted only in work relationships, what Rosemary
Crompton (2008) termed an ‘employment aggregate approach’.
In contrast, there is ‘culturalist class analysis’, influenced to a greater or lesser
degree by different readings (perhaps misreadings) of Bourdieu (who actually placed
a good deal of emphasis on production relations) (for example, 1984: 372). The
value of this literature is that it challenges one to think about the way in which
culture marks out class boundaries, albeit in ways that are often ‘ambiguous’ and
‘fuzzy’ (Skeggs 2004: 5). While methodologies have generally been ethnographic –
limited in scope, if insightful – Tony Bennett et al. (2009) drew on some of Bourdieu’s
quantitative work to produce a statistically sophisticated study, conducted in 2003/
04, which covered the whole of Britain. They found that cultural variables – covering
participation, knowledge and taste – were associated with respondents’ ‘class’, gender
and age. While there were no homologies (that is, clearly defined groupings of a
Bordieuvian kind), the categorical midpoints were distinct in each case.13 The class
model that best fitted the data – that is, that best described how people in Britain
practice class – was one that distinguished the middle class, an intermediate class
and the working class. The research found that the working class ‘neither likes nor
is interested in legitimate [high] culture’ (Bennett et al. 2009: 252) and that the
middle class, especially its higher levels, simply engages in more cultural activity
(its members are ‘omnivores’). In reading this account, one might conclude that
the lack of homologies and the need for an intermediate class reflect the importance
of ‘ambivalence’ (the same might be said of ‘fuzziness’).
Affordability and action 11
Given that Bennett et al. (2009) use Goldthorpian economic categories (albeit
modified), it is perhaps hardly surprising that their conclusions had much in
common with those advanced by Goldthorpe. Moreover, both are consonant with
a model that recognises that, while people in Britain frequently have difficulties in
consciously positioning themselves (in other words, they are often ambivalent),
their cultural practices still recognise a distinction between working class and middle
class.
In terms of class identity labels, the existing literature makes interesting reading.
From 1983 until 1991 the British Social Attitudes Survey (BSAS) included a question
about the class people ‘belonged’ to (Jowell et al. 1993). In 1991 the figures were
29 per cent for the middle classes, 64 per cent for the working classes, and 4 per cent
for ‘poor’. Regrettably, the series was discontinued, but more recent studies still
show that a majority of Britons regard themselves as working class.15 The US
data is better. For instance, American National Election Studies (2010) has asked
about class identification since 1956. It requests respondents to select one of four
classes, with the followings result in the most recent survey: average working class –
41 per cent; upper working class – 10 per cent; average middle class – 39 per cent;
upper middle class – 10 per cent. While the numbers contradict much public
discourse about the archaic nature of working-class identification, they go some
way to explaining why politicians, especially in the US, but now also in Britain,
are concerned about the working-class vote.16
However, simple choices of the kind offered in these studies miss the problem
of ‘ambivalence’, discussion on which was initiated by Mike Savage (2000). His
interpretation of 200 interviews conducted in Manchester was that, although about
two-thirds of respondents could define themselves in class terms, ‘identification is
12 Peter Alexander
usually ambivalent, defensive and hesitant’ (see also Savage, Bagnall and Longhurst
2001). He argued: ‘class does not seem to be a deeply held personal identity, nor
does “class belonging” appear to invoke strong senses of group or collective
allegiance. In so far as class is significant, it is largely with respect to politics.’
However, Geoff Payne and Clare Grew (2005) re-evaluated the Manchester data
and combined this with their own fieldwork, which used similar questions but
was conducted in a rural area. They concluded that hesitations and qualifications
do not reflect unease about class as such, but rather the genuine difficulties that
exist in reaching conclusions about a complex phenomenon. For their respondents,
they argued, class was not a simple matter of occupations, but involved assessments
about income, attitudes, housing, education and much more.
Discussion about the nature of such ambivalence was taken up in a US study
by Michael Hout (2008), which draws on data from the General Social Survey.17 In
this he distinguishes between people who were unambiguously working or middle
class and those whose class position was ambiguous. The latter included individuals
who were ‘living on the border’, that is, lower professionals, routine white-collar
workers and self-employed manual workers, and/or those subject to ‘status
inconsistency’, such as people with a low-status job and a high income. Among
employed people who were unambiguously working class, 71 per cent identified
themselves as working class, with a further 8 per cent saying they were lower class;
and among those in unambiguously middle-class positions, 77 per cent said they
were middle class, with a further 9 per cent self-identifying as upper class. For
those in ambiguous positions, the split was 47 per cent middle class, 53 per cent
working class and less than one per cent for each of the other two options. Thus,
Hout’s study suggests that class ambiguity is an important source of ambivalent
class identity.
A further twist is provided by Paula Surridge (2007), who probed responses to
a question on self-identity asked in the 2003 BSAS. This offered respondents a list
of sixteen possible identities from which they were asked to choose three, placing
them in order of importance. While those who were most obviously disadvantaged
were strongly attracted to a working-class identity, the ‘salariat’ had a preference
for non-class identities. This should be linked with evidence from Bennett et al.
(2009: 178), who observed that, while the higher echelon of the middle class was
culturally dominant, it rejected any clear class identity, as doing so might invite
‘contestation’.18 So, one might hypothesise that in Britain there is a tendency for
different classes to be constituted differently. From a functionalist perspective, this
would make sense. For workers, an emphasis on economic boundaries adds
Affordability and action 13
Pierre van den Bergh (1965: 52–9) reasoned along similar lines, arguing that ‘ “race”
is by far the most important criterion of status’ and that four ‘colour castes’ (whites,
coloureds, Indians and Africans) were each sub-divided by class. Asserting that
there was a lack of class consciousness among white workers, he dismisses – in one
sentence – the applicability of a Marxist theory of class to South Africa, adding
that the South African labour movement ‘has always defined its function as that of
protecting the White manual worker against non-White competition’.20 While ‘race’
posed a challenge for Marxist analysis, Van den Bergh misread the labour history,
which shows that white trade unionists, many of them Marxists, frequently acted
in sympathy with black workers (see Alexander 2000: 63, 120–3).
As Jeremy Seekings (2009: 877) observes, in the early 1970s ‘Weberian social
science was eclipsed, totally and quickly’. It collapsed under pressure from a Marxist
critique, which demonstrated that, rather than apartheid being ‘non-rational’, it
was functional to the development of capitalism. The migrant labour system had
delivered ‘cheap labour’ to South African employers and institutionalised racial
divisions among workers, thereby boosting profits (Wolpe 1972; Johnstone 1976).
The problem for the Weberians was largely political: following Weber, race and
class inhabited separate domains, and in the South African case the former was said
to be undermining economic development associated with the latter. As a
consequence, the Weberians appeared to be shielding capital at a moment when
class struggle was growing in importance and when solidarity movements were
challenging international businesses that had South African interests.21
But how would Marxists handle historical divisions between black and white
workers? One approach treated white miners as foremen and then assumed them
Affordability and action 15
An abstract analysis of class is required, because it can reveal processes that are
otherwise hidden, but it is not sufficient. The significance of Wolpe’s approach is
not only historical (associated with the ‘white working class’ and so on), but also
relates directly to our own study. That is, one should not expect to find a direct
and simple relationship between class – as something objective – and its subjective
manifestations (whether self-identity, culture or struggle).24
16 Peter Alexander
attendants and, interestingly, domestic servants; and the ‘lower’ class comprised
herbalists, labourers, shebeen queens and, at the very bottom, latrine workers.
Mayer’s analysis, which is particularly pertinent (and is considered again in
Chapters 2 and 8), adds a new dimension to Brandel-Syrier’s notion of ‘point of
view’. He shows that, whereas the ‘class model’ – which identified an exploitative
relationship between white capitalists and black workers – was articulated by
‘ordinary working people’, educated respondents tended to express themselves in
terms of racial domination (Mayer 1977: 23–32).25 Within Soweto, working people
saw themselves as near the ‘middle’, but the educated and better off also placed
themselves at the centre, pushing ‘ordinary people’ towards the bottom (Mayer
1977: 123–4). The ‘educated rich’ were sometimes distinguished from the ‘rich
rich’, referred to as ‘tycoons’, who, Mayer (1977: 106) writes, were often no more
than shopkeepers. Lower down the hierarchy than factory workers came labourers
and domestic servants, who considered themselves, and were considered by others,
to be ‘poor people’; and beneath them there were the ‘very poor’, the destitute,
‘people who live through suffering’ (Mayer 1977: 111).26
We can add a few further points that provide valuable context for understanding
Soweto today – sometimes suggesting a counterpoint, more often a continuity.
Firstly, in all these cases, prestige was linked more to education than to money, but
in practice the better off were nearly always the better educated (although this was
already changing in Soweto before 1976). Moreover, education and income were
related to occupation, so one can have sympathy for writers who, in neo-Weberian
terms, muddled class and status.27 Secondly, the top stratum was marked off by
two kinds of cultural difference: (1) refinement, in particular the use of English
(even for conversations between friends), and (2) conspicuous consumption in the
form of housing, cars, furniture, fashionable clothes and appearance (for instance,
hair straightening) (for examples, see Wilson and Mafeje 1963: 137–8; Kuper 1965:
112, 138; Brandel-Syrier 1971: 87, 94; Mayer 1977: 68). Traders might have the
income required for consumption, but they rarely achieved refinement. Thirdly,
this top stratum was small. In Brandel-Syrier’s (1971: 94) case, the educated elite
was as small as half a per cent of the township’s total population and the business
elite was smaller still. Numerically, teachers were the largest educated group, but
there were social distinctions among them and not all were considered part of the
elite (Brandel-Syrier 1971: 64–5; Nyquist 1983: 44). Fourthly, while small, the elite
– at least at its higher level – was relatively cohesive, engaging in common social
activities and often intermarrying (Wilson and Mafeje 1963: 138–40; Nyquist 1983:
96–110). The elite generally preferred the old mission churches (Methodist, Anglican,
Catholic, etc.), which had higher status than the Zionist and Ethiopian churches
18 Peter Alexander
(Kuper 1965: 99, 137; Nyquist 1983: 69). Fifthly, the unemployed are barely
mentioned in these studies – which is not surprising, given that unemployment
had not yet become a visible problem – but Mayer (1977: 102) notes that ‘the poor
suffer from spells of unemployment’. Lastly, with the exception of a few activists,
class divisions among Africans were regarded as separate from those among whites
and only a few Africans were better off than the poorest whites.
The reader will find commonalities between these accounts and our own,
including the prevalence of a three-class model, the association between church
type and status, the use of the word ‘tycoon’ and the prevalence of the phrase ‘live
through suffering’. These studies also show that there is nothing new about
consumerism, even if its relative importance has increased as a marker of status;
this at the expense of education, which, though, is still important. The combination
of exploitation and hierarchical models of class remains widespread in Soweto.
bourgeoisie might be differently formed, come under different influences and play
a different role in history.28
His account was followed by a more theoretical dispute about the growth of
the African petty bourgeoisie from the 1960s onwards. In attempting to assess the
extent and character of this expansion, Owen Crankshaw (1986) engaged with
contrasting theories offered by Wright and Nicos Poulantzas. We have already
encountered the former. The upshot of Poulantzas’s (1975) position was that all
those not engaged in direct production of surplus value – including, for instance,
routine white-collar workers – should be included as part of a ‘new petty bour-
geoisie’.29 Crankshaw’s (1986) estimate was that this ‘new petty bourgeoisie’
numbered about 35 per cent of wage earners by 1983. According to him, Wright
would have placed all but about 9 per cent of these among the proletariat or ‘semi-
autonomous employees’. The wider significance of the argument was that, if one
accepted the broad (that is, Poulantzian) definition, it helped justify the working
class holding back on its own demands in order to develop a broader alliance.
Actually, many of the ‘semi-autonomous employees’ could have been included as
part of the proletariat. This was specifically true of school teachers, who, by 1980 –
following the massification of African schooling and the transformation of teaching
into a mainly black occupation – were busy converting professional associations
into unions (Crankshaw 1997: 89; Amoako 2012).30 A further problem with the
statistics is that they refer to employees, thus excluding the unemployed, and hence
giving an inflated impression of the proportion of the African population who
could be regarded as petty bourgeois under any definition.
Bonginkosi ‘Blade’ Nzimande (1990; 1991) advanced the debate by distinguishing
divergent interests within the African petty bourgeoisie. For Nzimande (1990: 181–
209), there were four ‘strata’ (his term). The first was the bureaucratic petty
bourgeoisie, the senior functionaries in the Bantustans and townships. Secondly,
there was the civil petty bourgeoisie, that is, state employees (mostly teachers, nurses
and clerks), which was the largest of the four strata. Thirdly, there was a corporate
petty bourgeoisie, which ‘closely identifies with a free market’, was hostile to the
apartheid state and under pressure from the militancy of the working class. Finally,
there was the trading petty bourgeoisie, which included one component that was
closely associated with the bureaucratic petty bourgeoisie and another that was
said to be ‘autonomous’.31 Under the right conditions, the civil petty bourgeoisie,
part of the corporate petty bourgeoisie and the autonomous trading petty
bourgeoisie might ally with the working class. Nzimande’s categorisation had much
to offer. In particular, it took us beyond the horizons of the township, created a
better sense of diversity within the African petty bourgeoisie, and drew attention
20 Peter Alexander
to the impact of the state, as well as capital and labour. However, fundamental
changes have occurred since the study was completed in 1991, and one doubts
whether the ‘African petty bourgeoisie’, in the form described by Nzimande, still
exists in a meaningful way. While one element emerged as capitalists and rulers, a
much larger component is identifiable as workers.32
Recent academic research on the petty bourgeoisie is limited. However, an
interview-based study of black corporate managers by Geoffrey Modisha (2007)
yielded insights that are particularly relevant for our own account. All the managers
lived in the suburbs, but whereas the more junior ones came from trade union
backgrounds, lacked formal qualifications and had parents in traditional working-
class occupations, the more senior had formal qualifications and most had parents
in professional positions. An important experience that most of these managers
had in common, and which distinguished them from their white colleagues, was a
need to negotiate relationships with kin who were generally poorer and living in
townships. One explained: ‘I can’t actually get rich in a short period of time, because
I share the money with members of my extended families because they are not
working.’ Respondents who maintained links with their families living in townships
said things like: ‘People are always looking for employment from me . . . Some
people are crying in front of me.’ By contrast, the managers who came from a
professional background tended to cut ties with their relatives, with one explaining:
‘I struggle to live with those people because of my interpretation of reality.’
Modisha’s analysis recognises the importance of ‘levels’ within corporate
hierarchies, and his contrast between black and white managers shows how people
from dissimilar backgrounds experience the same class location in different ways.
Thus, he adds further complexity to the account of politically salient class
characteristics provided by Bonner, Nzimande and others. In sum, one’s specific
‘position’ within the petty bourgeoisie shapes one’s judgements, but so too does
personal history and the ‘pull’ of external forces (capital, labour and the state). In
the second decade of the twentieth century and in the 1980s, powerful working-
class movements were able to radicalise important sections of the petty bourgeoisie,
but is the working class still sufficiently coherent to have a similar impact today?
off and had grown in size.35 The approach is responsive to South African conditions,
and as a means of describing significant aspects of social transformation it is helpful.
But if one wants to explore the relationship of ‘classes’ to subjectivities, we need an
account that recognises that people are individuals as well as members of households.
Further, the dominance principle undervalues the size and impact of poverty by
allocating many of the unemployed, for instance, to a ‘higher’ class. Moreover,
what individuals can ‘afford’ will be determined by the composition of the whole
household (particularly its size and number of income earners) and not just the
occupation of its dominant member and income from wealth and entrepreneurship.
Seekings and Nattrass (2005) also took up the issue of whether or not part of
the unemployed constituted an underclass. Their response disaggregated their
residual, defining as ‘underclass’ only ‘households with no employed members
and thus no social capital’ (Seekings and Nattrass 2005: 289). This solution is elegant
but, as with Wright’s (1978: 93) attempt to grapple with the same issue, it is also
problematic.36 Lack of employment in a household is not the same as absence of
social capital – people can be jobless and still have friends, go to church, attend the
weddings and funerals of their extended family, and receive remittances from a
mother or father who works away from home.37 Being part of a poverty-stricken
household is likely to have an adverse impact on life chances, but poverty is
widespread and cannot be reduced to households without any employed members.
In a recent reflection, Seekings (2008a: 23) insists that there is ‘a discrete “underclass”
or lower class separate from the “working class” ’, but acknowledges that this ‘can
be identified by any number of criteria’ and ‘the appropriate label for this class can
be debated’. It would seem, then, that a problem remains. I would certainly not
wish to suggest that this is an easy matter but, from the perspective of the questions
we are asking, it is possible to simply recognise that some people are unemployed.
Difficulties arise when one merges ‘class’ and what are essentially occupation-based
categories.38
An alternative theorisation was advanced by Karl von Holdt and Edward
Webster (2005), who represent their position diagrammatically in the form of an
onion (reproduced in Chapter 4). This includes a core of full-time workers; a ring
of outsourced, temporary, part-time and domestic workers; a further ring of informal
workers; and an outer layer comprising the unemployed (Von Holdt and Webster
2005: 28; see also Webster 2006; May and Meth 2007). This model refocuses attention
on individuals, it shows movement between the different layers and it avoids slicing
off a separate underclass. However, while households are mentioned, they are not
integrated into the model and the two in five South African adults ‘not in the
labour force’ are missing. The strength of the argument – and it is considerable – is
Affordability and action 23
its concern with organisational questions. The limitation of trade unions (specifically
COSATU) in failing to move beyond the core is recognised, and the authors advocate
the importance of community-based movements that mobilise people outside the
nucleus. For ‘a counter movement to truly be effective’, they argue, it should link
workplace and community struggles, adding: ‘in other words, uniting the trade
union movement and social movements in a broad coalition against the destructive
impact of the market on society’ (Von Holdt and Webster 2005: 38). Unfortunately,
their view of organisation is somewhat formalistic, with social movements seen as
the equivalent of trade unions. Mass organisation among the jobless is far more
difficult to sustain than among workers, and successful mobilisation tends to be
short term, thus posing critical strategic and tactical dilemmas.
Von Holdt (2011: 6) has now broadened his analysis, proposing that ‘a rapid
process of class formation’ is underway in South Africa. He points to an important
shift: among black people, in particular, there is a growing gulf between those
who, at the one end of the spectrum, have become part of the ruling class, either as
capitalists (still far smaller in numbers and less wealthy than their white counterparts)
or as part of the governing elite, and, at the other end, those who Von Holdt
describes as the ‘unemployed and precariously employed’. One aspect of this
phenomenon is migration from townships to suburbs, involving, according to a
2008 study, some 12 000 black families per month, in the six largest cities alone
(National Planning Commission 2011).39 An associated process is access to better-
performing schools, which has implications for entry to better-paid jobs (Simkins
2005). But it is difficult to see how these processes amount to the creation of new
classes.
Main findings
We now consider how our own research adds to the literature discussed above.
In Chapter 2 Kim Wale provides an overview of the history of ‘class’ in Soweto.
The township’s origins were as a residential area designed mainly for workers living
in married circumstances. In 1946 the council provided space for the educated elite
in an area known as Dube, and from the late 1950s hostels were built for migrant
workers, adding another component to Soweto’s social mix. While restrictions on
the development of the black middle class led to a measure of ‘class compression’,
the Soweto uprising of 1976 was followed by attempts to improve the position of
better-off urbanites and to lock the new unions, growing apace, into state-sponsored
negotiating procedures. But the plan backfired. Throughout the 1980s, the elite
provided leadership for a community whose school students and unemployed youth
were becoming increasingly militant. Meanwhile, workers advanced a class struggle
24 Peter Alexander
that merged with activity in the township to create a force that was central to the
overthrow of apartheid. In the post-apartheid years, there has been significant class
differentiation, with better-off people generally moving out of the township and
increased poverty occurring within it. Before the end of apartheid, growing numbers
of people were living in shacks, and many people still live in such conditions.
In Chapter 3 Ceruti paints a picture of contemporary Soweto that draws mainly
on quantitative data, much of it gathered as part of our 2006 survey. She shows that
the population of the township was growing, in part because of continuing in-
migration. On a number of indicators, its residents tended to be a little better off
than other South Africans, but the rates of unemployment were higher than the
average for the country. Housing provides the main focus of the chapter. Here the
evidence lends support to findings from other researchers that there is growing
differentiation. A minority live in relatively costly new houses or in substantially
improved older ones, while the majority reside in former council houses that have
not been upgraded, backyard rooms, shacks and hostels. However, Ceruti cautions
against an oversimplified view that equates better housing types with work status
or higher income, showing that other factors contribute to the differentiation,
including household size and when people came to Soweto. Significantly, people
without work live in close proximity to others with regular salaries. Indeed, among
our respondents, those living in backyard shacks were more likely to be receiving
a regular wage than to be unemployed, and the proportion of unemployed was
above average for Soweto among those living in unrenovated former council houses
(which are superior in quality to shacks).
In Chapter 4 Ceruti extends her account onto the terrain of employment and
unemployment. Drawing on the survey, she shows that only 24 per cent of Sowetans
were ‘regularly employed workers’, with a further 7 per cent categorised as petty
bourgeoisie, managers or capitalists. The remaining 69 per cent were either fully
unemployed, engaged in survivalist activities, or outside the labour force by virtue
of being students or pensioners. In these circumstances, an occupation-aggregate
approach to class analysis is unhelpful, because it leaves a large majority of the
population ‘unclassed’, unless, perhaps, they are treated as appendages of people
with jobs (which, as we have seen, creates further problems). Ceruti opts for an
approach that emphasises the ‘community of fate’ that exists between those who
are employed and those without regular jobs. The critical issue is the role played
by households in ensuring survival through the redistribution of resources, with
the effect that the ratio of earners to dependants can have a considerable impact on
experiences of poverty. Ceruti develops Marx’s concept of the labour reserve and
surplus population to propose a dynamic-systemic model of class, where different
Affordability and action 25
Summary
The volume’s conclusions are presented in the final chapter. Here I draw together
aspects of the theoretical framework, relevant literature and chapter outlines as a
means of signalling key issues.
Our ‘anchoring question’ was about emancipation – posed in the context of
South Africa’s acute social inequalities and intense but separate struggles by workers
and the poor. The methodology, broadly Marxist in character, aimed at exploring
the relationship between an objective marker of employment relations, aspects of
28 Peter Alexander
suffering (the lower class, poor etc.). ‘Affordability’ provides a link from subjective
experiences (including classed culture and verbalised class identities), through income,
to occupation (or lack of occupation). Thus, it connects consumption and
production. In addition, while people mention individual attributes and cultural
associations when they look ‘upwards’ in class terms, they refer to lack of basic
resources when they look ‘down’. This reinforces suggestions in some sociological
literature that the way people define ‘class’ might be affected by their class location,
with those defined as ‘middle class’ mainly concerned with cultural referents and
the ‘working class’ and ‘poor’ emphasising the importance of economic markers.
An important twist in our account of class identity arose when considering the
mother-tongue terms that were available when people were translating class-related
words into English. Notably, this showed that when people use the term ‘middle
class’, they are very often translating from a word that means ‘in the middle’,
which is far more inclusive. This, in turn, helps to explain why ‘middle class’ was
the most popular class identity.
With regularly employed workers tending to identify themselves as ‘working
class’, and pensioners, the underemployed and unemployed more likely to describe
themselves as ‘poor’, it might seem that there is a firm basis for distinguishing a
working class from a poor or lower class. But this is not the position we adopted.
Within Soweto, there was little evidence of antagonism associated with ECs or
class identity, and better-off people were generally sympathetic to those who were
poorer. This reflected life histories and the close physical proximity of workers
and the unemployed. Households tended to re-distribute resources from better-
placed family members to those who were poorer. Kin, friends, neighbours, churches
and so on provided material support in the form of things like food, school fees
and loans, but also, for instance, information about job opportunities. In terms of
accommodation, there were no sharp divisions between the kind of housing occupied
by, for example, the unemployed and the regularly waged. In terms of identity,
most people were not either ‘working class’ or ‘poor’, rather they described
themselves as ‘middle class’ or accepted more than one class label. So, while there is
a gap between ‘workers’ and ‘the poor’, it is mitigated by a range of factors.
In the sense that Sowetans, bar a small minority, are either workers, ‘wannabe’
workers (including subsistence self-employed), retired workers or directly dependent
on workers (including most students), Soweto is predominantly a proletarian
township. However, there is considerable variation. It is a differentiated unity.
Common interests are cut through by different daily experiences of work, survival
and inter-personal relationships, and by the different capacities to mobilise to change
30 Peter Alexander
those experiences. But the long-term interests of workers and the poor are similar,
unlike those of workers and capitalists.
Our research was framed by concerns about divisions between workers and
the poor that existed in the face of massive inequality, and it was informed by
theoretical assumptions and a methodological stance derived from Marxism. How
well does Marxism stand up to challenges posed by the findings and analysis
presented in the chapters that follow? A response to this question is offered in
Chapter 10. Here, though, we can acknowledge that for Marx and Engels tasks of
the kind we have undertaken were not merely about defining and theorising
problems, they were also about helping to chart a solution. Their conclusions
recognised the importance of ‘class’ as part of the struggle for a classless society. We
make no pretence to have produced a book with a different ending, but I hope the
reader finds merit in the evidence and argument we use to get there.
Notes
1. This ratio assumes that the population of Soweto at the time of writing (August 2012)
was nearly 1.5 million, which is a very rough approximation based on figures presented
in Chapter 3 and a measure of subsequent growth similar to that for Gauteng (the
province in which Soweto is located). More reliable numbers will be available once
the results of the national census conducted in October 2011 are published. For the
broader Johannesburg context, see Beall, Crankshaw and Parnell (2002b).
2. In a Cape Town study, where respondents were asked to choose between one of four
classes, only 2 per cent failed to choose one of the four (Seekings 2007a: 14).
3. Wright regards ‘life chances’ as a secondary anchor, reflecting, perhaps, the influence
of Max Weber.
4. There is no intention here to equate Weber’s ‘Class, status, party’ and Bourdieu’s
Distinction (where the concepts of, respectively, ‘status group’ and ‘habitus’ are
explained). The former is vast and unspecific in its reach (though short in length); the
latter is time and place specific (though very long). ‘Class, status, party’ appeared as a
chapter in Economy and Society, first published in 1921, but was probably written
before the First World War according to Dagmar Waters et al. (Weber 2010). Distinction
was not published until 1979 (in French), but it is based on survey data from 1963 and
1967–68 and, according to Richard Jenkins (2002: 74), Bourdieu’s use of habitus dates
from 1967. Bourdieu (1984: xi, 513), himself, drew attention to the fact that his survey
‘measured relatively stable dispositions’ and also to the ‘Frenchness’ of his book.
5. For instance, Engels’s (1969) descriptions of various components of the working class
in The Condition of the Working Class in England, his and Marx’s (1965) discussion of
‘petty-bourgeois socialism’ in the Communist Manifesto, and Marx’s (1954: 617)
references to ‘lower middle class housing’.
Affordability and action 31
class or upper class?’ Even so, it complained that there was ‘confusion’ among people
about which class they belonged to (for example, bank managers who said they were
working class) and it decried a tendency towards the ‘muddle class’ [sic]. Even so,
people who said they were middle class had twice the level of savings and three times
the level of investments than those who said they were working class. Unfortunately,
the sample was small – only 1 000 people for the whole country – but the figures were
similar to those of the British Household Panel Study.
16. This is not to say that a high level of working-class identification exists everywhere.
For instance, it has been reported that in Japan, about 90 per cent of people regard
themselves as middle class (Savage 2000: 35), while for India, Deshpande (2003: 129–
31) suggests that ‘middle class’ is a desirable identity to which even those who are
‘ineligible’ lay claim. It is possible that, as in South Africa, language and translation
play at least some part in the construction of class identity.
17. The General Social Survey poses the following question: ‘If you were asked to use one
of four names for your social class, which would you say you belong in: the lower
class, the working class, the middle class, or the upper class?’ According to Hout
(2008: 29), for the years 2000–04 the question received a 99.4 per cent response rate and
yielded the following replies: lower, 5 per cent; middle, 47 per cent; working, 44 per
cent; upper, 4 per cent. Hout adds that when the exact same question was asked by
Richard Centers in 1949, 49 per cent self-identified as working class and 45 per cent as
middle class. It is remarkable how little US class identifications have changed over
more than half a century.
18. Similarly, Deshpande (2003: 140) makes the point that ‘the middle class more than
any other is defined by its ownership and control of cultural capital’.
19. We might reasonably be criticised for underestimating the importance of southern
literature in this introduction. However, the purpose here has been to consider the
most influential texts. Separately, in 2009, we held a conference on ‘Comprehending
Class’ in Johannesburg. This produced three volumes of papers and led to a special
issue of the South African Review of Sociology, which included, in addition to two articles
on South Africa (Phadi and Manda 2010; Moodie 2010), papers on Brazil, India and
China (respectively, Santos 2010; Dhawan 2010; Chan 2010).
20. Van den Bergh was not always consistent. At one point, he envisions the possibility of
a revolution led by the black proletariat, but adds, perspicaciously, that this was unlikely
‘to result in rapidly rising living standards for the African masses . . . [and] the
intelligentsia probably stands most to gain through change’ (Van den Bergh 1965:
210).
21. Seekings (2009: 878) makes the further point that key figures either emigrated (including
Kuper) or died. Sandwiched between the state and the movement, the environment
was harsh for liberals, Weberians included.
22. I have argued against the free/unfree thesis elsewhere (Alexander 2006b). This distinction
is not grounded in Marxism, and the account assumes, wrongly, that all black workers
were like slaves or serfs.
Affordability and action 33
23. This history was strongly influenced by Thompson (1968). Attempts to apply his
notion of ‘class experience’ – which mediated consciousness and exploitation – could
have made a valuable contribution to the debate (Alexander 1999: 32). The distinction
between Marxists and Weberians – or, at least, between some Marxists and some
Weberians – can be drawn too sharply. For example, the Weberian John Rex (1986:
66–7) distinguished between black workers and white workers in terms of a ‘differential
relationship . . . to the means of production’, with the former ‘unfree’ and the latter
‘[part of a] community . . . able to defend real privileges’. This was only a shade different
from the Marxism countered by Wolpe (1976: 200–3; Rex 1986: 68).
24. Unfortunately, Wolpe had blind spots. In particular, because he tended to be dismissive
of history and loyal to the main wing of the liberation struggle, his analysis of
conjuncture was impaired. His new thinking fed into a book, completed in February
1987, that reached a pessimistic conclusion about the possibility of ending apartheid
rule, yet eight months later, and before the book was published (Wolpe 1988), he was
himself involved in negotiations that would bring apartheid to an end (Alexander
2007: 114).
25. It is not always clear whether Mayer is writing about 1965 or 1976 or both, but here he
is referring to 1965.
26. Mayer’s monograph, which exists only as a manuscript, was not available to us when
we completed our main fieldwork, so similarities between his findings and our own
are all the more remarkable.
27. Weber’s (1924: 181) economic classes consisted of ‘people [who] have in common a
specific causal component of their life chances, in so far as this component is represented
exclusively by economic interests’. These economic classes were aggregated into four
major social classes: the working class, petty bourgeoisie, technicians and lower managers,
and propertied elite (Breen 2005: 32; Crompton 2008: 33). Seekings (2009: 868) notes:
‘[E]ven Weber himself tended to elide class and status in practice.’
28. The role of the petty bourgeoisie has been a continuing interest of Bonner’s (see Bonner
and Nieftagodien: 2008). For a history of the black petty bourgeoisie, see Alan Cobley
(1990).
29. Although not discussed here, Poulantzas’s work provided a point of departure for
many South African Marxists, including Rob Davies (1979). In the 1980s, Wolpe (1988)
came to see value in Poulantzas’s approach, but was highly critical of Davies’s
interpretation.
30. According to Seekings and Nattrass (2005: 104), ‘In greater Soweto . . . there were
only eight secondary schools until 1972. By 1976 there were twenty, with three times
as many students as in 1972. By the end of 1984 there were fifty-five [schools].’ Transvaal
African teachers had established their first association by 1920, and held a strike as far
back as 1944 (Amoako 2012).
31. Nzimande (1990: 197) reports that there were 3 000 small shopkeepers in Soweto in
the late 1980s.
34 Peter Alexander