Crisis Summaries
Crisis Summaries
Crisis Summaries
Both the crisis and the apparent boom before it were caused by the change in private debt. Rising
aggregate private debt adds to demand, and falling debt subtracts from it. This point is
vehemently denied on conventional theoretical grounds by economists like Paul Krugman, but it
is obvious in the empirical data. The crisis itself began in 2008, precisely when the growth of
private debt plunged from its peak of almost 30% of GDP p.a. down to its depth of minus 20% in
2010. The recovery, such as it was, began when the rate of decline of debt slowed. Across
recession, boom and bust between 1990 and 2012, the correlation between the annual change in
private debt and the unemployment rate was -0.92.
0
30
25
20
15
10
6 0
10
15
10
11
Unemploy ment
Debt Change
20
25
30
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
www.debtdeflation.com/blogs
The causation behind this correlation is that money is created endogenously when the banking
sector creates loans, and this newly created money adds to aggregate demandas argued by
non-orthodox economists from Schumpeter through to Minsky. When this debt finances genuine
investment, it is a necessary part of a growing capitalist economy, it grows but shows no trend
relative to GDP, and leads to modest profits by the financial sector. But when it finances
speculation on asset prices, it grows faster than GDP, leads obscene profits by the financial
sector and generates Ponzi Schemes which are to sustainable economic growth as cancer is to
biological growth.
When those Ponzi Schemes unravel, the rate of growth of debt collapses and the boost to demand
from rising debt becomes a drag on demand as debt falls. In all other post-WWII downturns,
growth resumed when debt began to rise relative to GDP once more. However the bubble we
have just been through has pushed debt levels past anything in recorded history, triggering a
deleveraging process that is the hallmark of a Depression.
www.debtdeflation.com/blog s
The last Depression saw debt levels fall from 240% to 45% of GDP over a 13 year period, and
the ensuing period of low debt led to the longest boom in Americas history. We commenced
deleveraging from 303% of GDP. After 3 years it is still 10% higher than the peak reached
during the Great Depression. On current trends it will take till 2027 to bring the level back to that
which applied in the early 1970s, when America had already exited what Minsky described as
the robust financial society that underpinned the Golden Age that ended in 1966.
While we delever, investment by American corporations will be timid, and economic growth will
be faltering at best. The stimulus imparted by government deficits will attenuate the downturn
and the much larger scale of government spending now than in the 1930s explains why this far
greater deleveraging process has not led to as severe a Depressionbut deficits alone will not be
enough. If America is to avoid two lost decades, the level of private debt has to be reduced by
deliberate cancellation, as well as by the slow processes of deleveraging and bankruptcy.
In ancient times, this was done by a Jubilee, but the securitization of debt since the 1980s has
complicated this enormously. Whereas only the moneylenders lost under an ancient Jubilee, debt
cancellation today would bankrupt many pension funds, municipalities and the like who
purchased securitized debt instruments from banks. I have therefore proposed that a Modern
Debt Jubilee should take the form of Quantitative Easing for the Public: monetary injections
by the Federal Reserve not into the reserve accounts of banks, but into the bank accounts of the
publicbut on condition that its first function must be to pay debts down. This would reduce
debt directly, but not advantage debtors over savers, and would reduce the profitability of the
financial sector while not affecting its solvency.
Without a policy of this nature, America is destined to spend up to two decades learning the truth
of Michael Hudsons simple aphorism that Debts that cant be repaid, wont be repaid.
The economy remains seriously weak, 4 years after the Great Recession began, and 3 years
after the financial crisis ended. This indicates that the economic slump is not due only to the
financial crisis. Just as more lay behind the Great Depression of the 1930s than a stock-market
crash, more lies behind the Great Recession and the persistent economic malaise than the
collapse of a home-price bubble. This idea is the starting point of my book, The Failure of
Capitalist Production: Underlying Causes of the Great Recession (Pluto Press, 2012).
Actually, the book isnt something I set out to write. At the start of 2009, I was researching a
rather narrow topic, and discovered something surprising. So I began to dig deeper. The more I
dug, the more I found that was surprising. Eventually, I had material for a whole book.
What I uncovered was surprising because it contradicts key pillars of the conventional left
account of the economic history of the last several decades. According to the conventional left
account, the turning-point was the early 1980s, the start of a new stage of capitalist expansion
brought about by neoliberalism. The neoliberals succeeded in increasing the degree of
exploitation. Workers share of income and real (inflation-adjusted) pay declined, and this
caused the rate of profit to rebound. So the economy could have grown rapidly, if this extra
profit had been invested in production. But that didnt happen, because of financialization: profit
was diverted from productive investment toward financial uses. The slowdown in investment led
to a slowdown in economic growth, which in turn led to a slowdown in income growth of
income. And since the slowdown in income growth made it harder to repay debt, it led to rising
debt burdens. This chain of events set the stage for the financial crisis and the Great Recession.
However, I uncovered several facts (from U.S. government and other official data) that
contradict the conventional left account. First, the turning-point of recent U.S. economic history
was the 1970s before the rise of neoliberalism. Many important trends that continued began in
the 1970s or before. And the neoliberal period wasnt really a new expansionary stage, but a
period of relative stagnation. The economy never fully recovered from the recession of the mid1970s. The long-term rise in income inequality and the long-term fall in the growth rate of public
infrastructure spending began in 1969. The long-term rise in government and household
borrowing/GDP ratios began in 1970. The Bretton Woods gold-exchange system collapsed in
1971, and this led to the 3d World sovereign-debt crisis and a marked increase in financial
instability ever since. The serious and long-term fall in the growth rate of GDP, here and
globally, began with the recession of the mid-1970s, as did other long-term trends: the fall in the
growth of industrial production, the slowdown in the growth of employees pay, a more-serious
labor-force-dropout problem, and the rise in the average duration of unemployment started.
Since all these things began during Keynesianism, they arent merely effects of neoliberalism.
Second, U.S. corporations rate of profit (rate of return on the actual amount of money invested
in fixed capital, minus depreciation), never recovered in a sustained manner during the neoliberal
period. When profit is defined broadly, as all of the output (net value added) of corporations that
their employees dont receive, the rate of profit continued to trend markedly downward, while
the narrower before-tax rate of profit stagnated. The former rate of profit continued to trend after
we remove the effect of inflation. Moreover, U.S. multinational corporations rate of return on
their foreign direct investment also trended markedly downward.
Third, the cause of the slowdown in productive investment was the fall in the (actual) rate of
profit, not financialization or neoliberalism. Between 1970 and 2009, variations in the rate of
profit (based on the broad definition) account for 83% of the variations in the rate of
accumulation fall in the rate of accumulation, and changes in the rate of profit preceded changes
in the rate of accumulation, so its clear what caused what. Almost all of the fall in the rate of
accumulation that took place during the neoliberal period occurred between 1981 (the start of the
Reagan presidency) and 2001, and during this period there was certainly no diversion of profit
from productive investment to finance. A greater share of profit was invested in production
during this period than was invested between 1947 and 1980, no matter how one defines profit.
Finally, and to me, most surprisingly, the neoliberals did not succeed in reducing working
peoples pay or their share of national income. Compensation of employees, as a share of
corporate output, has been trendless since 1970. Compensation of managers has increased only
modestly faster than average since the mid-1980s, so non-managerial workers share of corporate
output fell by roughly one-half percentage point, not much. The income of the working class
total compensation plus government-provided social benefits (minus workers and employers
Social Security and Medicare tax contributions)has been basically constant for 40 years. It was
just as great in 2007 as it was in 1970, and it was much greater than in the early 1960s. (So
claims that the Great Recession is an underconsumption crisis are wrong).
So why have many on the left reached contrary conclusions? Actually, they havent done so.
They say things that seem to contradict the above findings, but actually dont, things that are
technically correct but extremely misleading (e.g., wages have fallen as a share of GDP). I
dont have space here to discuss this further, but its documented in detail in my book.
Thus, what the facts suggest is that the underlying causes of the Great Recession and the
continuing malaise are rooted in capitalist production. The rate of profit fell from the mid-1950s
onward and never recovered in a sustained manner. This led to a long-term slowdown in
productive investment (when less profit is generated, theres less profit that can be invested), and
the slowdown in investment in turn led to a slowdown in economic growth. And the growth
slowdownplus artificially stimulative government policies that were pursued in an effort to
manage and maybe reverse the profitability, investment, and growth problemsled to a longterm buildup of debt, and ultimately to the Great Recession and current malaise.
The political implications of this controversy are profound. The conventional left account
implies that the only causes of the crisis are neoliberalism policies and financialization; its
supposedly a crisis of neoliberalism, not capitalism. To prevent such crises from recurring, all
just need to end neoliberalism and financialized capitalismperhaps by means of the class
collaboration that some Marxist economists call for! A change in the character of the socioeconomic system is not necessary. However, if the crisis is a crisis of capitalism, rooted in its
system of value production, we need to change the character of the socio-economic system; we
need to end value production. Financial reform, activist fiscal and monetary polies, and
nationalization will, at best, only delay the next crisis. And as long as the underlying problems
plaguing capitalist production that led to this crisis persist, artificial stimulus of the economy
through even more debt build-up threatens to make the next crisis worse when it comes.
I view the crisis that began in 2008 as a structural crisis of capitalism. It is not a business cycle
recession that happens to be particularly severe, which could be corrected by expansionary fiscal
and monetary policies. It is not essentially a financial crisis, which had secondary effects on the
real sector. It is rather a crisis of the structural form that capitalism has taken since around 1980
in much, although not all, of the world.
The best, most comprehensive characterization of this form of capitalism is neoliberal capitalism,
not "globalization" or "financialization" which, although both are important features of this form
of capitalism, fail to capture the full range of inter-related institutions that constitute neoliberal
capitalism. The main features of neoliberal capitalism are the following: 1) a particular form of
the capital-labor relation, entailing extreme capitalist domination of labor; 2) a particular state
role in the economy based on deregulation of business and markets, privatization, and attacks on
social programs; 3) a capital-capital relation of unrestrained competition; and 4) a new relation
between financial and productive capital, known as financialization.
At the most abstract level, the cause of the current crisis is the exhaustion of neoliberal
capitalism, which means that it can no longer promote high profits and relatively stable
accumulation over the long run. As the social structure of accumulation (SSA) theory argues,
every institutional form of capitalism, or SSA, has contradictions that eventually render it unfit
for the role of promoting high profits and stable accumulation.
At a more concrete level, neoliberal capitalism was able to bring a long period of high profit and
stable accumulation only by giving rise to unsustainable trends, which were leading to a financial
and real sector collapse at some point. All of the institutions of neoliberal capitalism contributed
to high and growing inequality -- a rising gap between profits and wages and between rich
households and the rest. This encouraged accumulation but simultaneously produced a problem
of realization -- who could buy the growing output of an expanding economy? In neoliberal
capitalism this problem was resolved by growing consumer spending financed by household
borrowing. Despite stagnating or falling real wages, consumer spending rose from 62% to 70%
of GDP from 1979 to 2007.
Such borrowing was made possible by the asset bubbles of increasing size produced by
neoliberal capitalism and by a financial sector willing and eager to lend to households, in
increasingly "creative" (and profitable) ways, with the growing asset bubble wealth serving as
security for the loans. This process occurred in the second half of the 1990s, during the stock
market bubble, and on a larger scale in the 2000s during the real estate bubble. From 1980 to
2007 household debt more than doubled relative to disposable income. Once the real estate
bubble burst, as all bubbles eventually must, the high level of household debt was rendered
unsustainable. This led to a crash of both the real and the financial sectors, made more severe by
the collapse of the high-risk derivatives created by financial institutions.
In relation to Marxist crisis theory, this crisis can be understood as an asset-bubble induced overinvestment crisis. Neoliberal capitalism promoted three long expansions, one in each decade of
the neoliberal era, by driving consumption upward relative to disposable income. Business
responded by creating the necessary productive capacity to satisfy the elevated level of consumer
demand. In addition, the asset bubbles instilled a sense of euphoria among corporate decisionmakers, leading to over-optimistic expectations of future profits, which promoted excessive
investment. The latter effect showed up in a long-run downward trend in capacity utilization in
industry. Once the last big asset bubble burst, consumer spending fell sharply relative to
disposable income while profit expectations reversed, leading to a very rapid fall in business
fixed investment that started one quarter after consumer spending began to decline.
The above interpretation of the crisis suggests that policy changes alone, such as fiscal stimulus
or tighter regulation of the banks, cannot resolve it. If the crisis is to be resolved within
capitalism, a new institutional structure must be created that will again promote long-run profitmaking and stable accumulation. Both historical precedent and theoretical considerations suggest
that such a new SSA would be of the interventionist variety rather than another liberal SSA.
However, any new SSA emerges from complex struggles among various classes and groups,
influenced by the character of the crisis during which the new SSA is constructed. It is
impossible to predict in advance the details of a new SSA, but one can identify two broad types
of capitalist SSA that might emerge.
First, if popular movements remain relatively weak, we may see the emergence of a "corporatist"
SSA -- that is, a capitalist-dominated statist form. This would continue a neoliberal labor market
but resolve the demand problem through rising state spending for military-national security
purposes along with rebuilding of infrastructure (transportation, power). Such a corporatist SSA
would be both repressive and militarily aggressive.
Second, if popular movements grow in strength, a social-democratic SSA based on compromise
between capital and labor might arise. This would allow wages to rise in step with labor
productivity, while state spending for social purposes also rose. However, social democratic
capitalism requires a continuing increase in commodity output, since rising profits and wages
under capitalism require rising output. This would face severe environmental and natural
resource constraints.
If popular movements become strong enough, and radical enough, to force capital to compromise
with labor, that suggests the socialist movement would also revive. This holds out the possibility
of transcending capitalism entirely by replacing it with socialism. Socialism can bring rapid
growth in output, but it has no such internal compulsion, and in developed countries a socialist
planned economy could bring a constant or declining level of output, a declining workweek, a
shift from private to public goods and services, and technological change directed at making
work a more satisfying experience. Thus, human development without economic growth in a
sustainable relation to the natural environment would become possible.
both charging excessive prices (high interest rates) for loans and making loans that they knew
could not be repaid. The makers of the loans didnt worry about the fact that they couldnt be
repaid because they sold these loans to others, pocketing hefty fees in the process. Without
proper oversight by regulators, buyers of these loans thought they were good investments.
Then, when housing prices started falling, everything came apart. Some big financial firms
failed. Others were saved by billions of dollars of support from the governmenti.e., from the
public. The financial firms stopped making loans, and other firms, without financing from the
banks, got in trouble. Layoffs and lack of new investment followed. The crisis took hold, and
in the summer of 2012 we still have not recovered.
So the parallel to the situation of the late 1920s in terms of income inequality has a good deal of
significance. As the great inequality then led into the Great Depression, the inequality of recent
years led us into the Great Recession.
Moving in a Better Direction. Because a nexus of inequality, elite power, and leave-it-to-themarket ideology formed a vicious circle that lies behind the financial and economic crisis,
effective reform depends on breaking that nexus. The last section of our book addresses the
possibilities and limits of reform. We look closely at three foundations for reforms: expanding
universal social programs, redeveloping the labor movement, and changes in the global
economy. Each of these reforms can contribute to transforming the inequality-power-ideology
nexus into a virtuous circle of progressive change.
Health care provides an example of how universal social programs could change the inequalitypower-ideology nexus. Universal health care (Medicare for all) would be a good thing in
itself. Also, providing everyone with healthcare in a public program would have a profound
impact on the distribution of income, directly assuring people of this real benefit and indirectly
protecting people from the huge income losses that can accompany serious illness. Such a
universal program would also redistribute power in society because it would provide people with
optionsfor example, the option of switching jobs without risking the loss of healthcare. And it
would shift ideology from an each-on-their-own outlook toward mutual responsibility for one
another.
We also assess the ways that re-creating the labor movement offers substantial possibilities for
improvement. Finally we explore the interdependence of national reform and global reform, the
need to redefine globalization, and the continuing constraint of global inequality.
We hope that readers of our book are convinced that the inequality-power-ideology nexus we
describe is indeed at the center for the economic crisis, and that changes in income and wealth
distribution, in who has power in our society, and in the ideology of how we view the operation
of the economy are at the center of a lasting solution to the problems of our economic lives.
The U.S. Economic Crisis: Profitability Crisis and Household Debt Crisis Combined
Fred Moseley
The fundamental causes of the current economic crisis in the US go back to the early postwar
period, when the rate of profit in the US economy declined by approximately 50% from the
1950s to the 1970s. This very significant decline in the rate of profit was part of a global trend in
almost all major countries.
Capitalists in the US and around the world responded to this profitability crisis by attempting to
restore their rate of profit back up to early postwar levels by any and all means possible,
including: wages and benefit cuts, inflation, speed-up on the job, globalization, NAFTA, etc.
All these familiar phenomena of recent decades are the results of capitalist attempts to restore the
rate of profit. US workers are working harder today than they did 40 years ago, but their real
wages have not increased and their benefits have been cut.
In spite of all this pain and suffering by workers, the rate of profit has been only partially
restored; only about half of the previous decline has been recovered. So business investment has
remained at a low rate and growth has remained slow in recent decades.
In depressions of the past, the rate of profit was restored primarily by widespread bankruptcies,
which devalued capital for the surviving firms. Wages were also cut and the intensity of labor
increased, which also contributed to the restoration of the rate of profit, but most of the
restoration in these earlier depressions was due to the devaluation of capital. In the postwar
period, the US government (and other governments) is doing all it can to avoid bankruptcies and
a deeper depression, and have been at least somewhat successful in postponing a worse
depression (so far) But this limited success in avoiding bankruptcies also has meant that there
has been very little devaluation of capital and thus very little restoration of the rate of profit by
this usual means. Instead, the recovery of the rate of profit (such as it has been) has come almost
entirely by increasing the intensity of exploitation of workers.
An important consequence of this decades-long stagnation of wages is that workers became more
and more in debt in order to buy a house or a car or or send your kids to college or even basic
necessities. The ratio of household debt to disposable income almost tripled from 50% in 1980
to 130% in 2007, reaching unprecedented levels (this household debt ratio was 30% in 1929).
US capitalism was being kept afloat by ever-increasing levels of debt for both households and
firms. Eventually, the household debt bubble burst, and the crisis of US capitalism entered a
new more serious phase. As Marx emphasized, increasing debt can prolong an expansion, but it
also makes the eventual depression worse.
So what started out as a profitability crisis has evolved due to wage suppression into a
potential underconsumption crisis, which was postponed for a while by ever-increasing
household debt. But household debt cant go on increasing forever. So eventually the household
debt bubble burst (starting with subprime mortgages and moving progressively into prime
mortgages) and the general crisis ensued. The profitability crisis remains and has been only
partially resolved, and now we have a serious household debt crisis on top of that. As Marx said
many times, attempts to solve one contradiction in capitalism lead to other contradictions.
In addition to the above dynamics, structural changes in the financial sector of the economy has
greatly increased the instability of that sector and thus of the economy as a whole. Changes such
as: deregulation (especially repeal of Glass-Steagal in 1999), increasing concentration (leading to
too big to fail), increasing debt as source of funds (especially the largest banks), an unregulated
shadow banking system (hedge funds, etc.), innovative securities (such as mortgage-based
securities, derivatives, etc.). All these recent changes in the financial sector have greatly increased
the instability of the US economy.
The financialization of the economy is itself a result of the prior decline of the rate of profit in
the early postwar period. Because of the lower profitability, industrial capitalists were less
willing to invest in expanding productive capacity and instead invested in financial assets.
According to Marxian theory, this diversion of a greater share of the total capital in the economy
to the financial sector means that less total profit is produced, because profit for the economy as
a whole is produced only in the productive sector (the income of the financial sector comes from
the total profit produced in the productive sector). Therefore, the increasing share of capital going
to the financial sector has exacerbated the profitability problem for the economy as a whole.
The best way to at least partially solve the economic crisis in a worker-friendly way is to
reduce household mortgage debt to the current market value of the house. This would result in
an average of about a 20% reduction in the amount owed. Household debt levels would still be
high, but they would be less high and more manageable. But of course the banks and other
mortgage investors have strongly opposed such mandatory write-down policies, because it
would mean that they have to recognize their losses. And both the Bush and the Obama
administrations have given in to the banks, and both administrations mortgage modification
programs have been voluntary on the part of the banks, and so far very few banks have
volunteered, and both programs have been failures.
Under current conditions and government policies, the best we can hope for in the years ahead is
many years of slow growth and depression-level unemployment. Eventually it appears likely
that there will be more mortgage defaults and another serious banking crisis, which will threaten
to turn into deeper depression.
If another banking crisis does occur, then the government should definitely not bail out the failing
banks (never again), but should instead nationalize any large bank that is failing, and operate
these banks as public banks (i.e. a public option for banking to serve the public interests).
However, even the nationalization of failing banks might not be enough to reduce the current
very high debt/GDP ratios to sustainable levels, and the economy could still eventually fall into a
deeper depression. In that case, the only way to avoid a deep and prolonged depression would be
a fundamental change in the economic system, from a profit-making capitalist economy, to a
democratic socialist economy, whose main goal would be to produce what people need, rather
than produce profit for a minority elite. I hope there will be a broad social movement to
accomplish that fundamental change in the US economy, and I hope we will all participate in
building that movement.
From Financial Crisis to Stagnation: The Destruction of Shared Prosperity and the Role of Economics
Thomas I. Palley
Many countries are now debating the causes of the global economic crisis and what should be
done. That debate is critical for how we explain the crisis will influence what we do.
Broadly speaking, there exist three different perspectives. Perspective # 1 is the hardcore
neoliberal position, which can be labeled the government failure hypothesis. In the U.S. it is
identified with the Republican Party and Chicago school economics. Perspective # 2 is the
softcore neoliberal position, which can be labeled the market failure hypothesis. It is identified
with the Obama administration and MIT economics. Perspective # 3 is the progressive position
which can be labeled the destruction of shared prosperity hypothesis. It is identified with the
New Deal wing of the Democratic Party and labor movement, but it has no standing within
major economics departments owing to their suppression of alternatives to orthodox theory.
The government failure argument holds the crisis is rooted in the U.S. housing bubble and bust
which was due to failure of monetary policy and government intervention in the housing market.
With regard to monetary policy, the Federal Reserve pushed interest rates too low for too long in
the prior recession. With regard to the housing market, government intervention drove up house
prices by encouraging homeownership beyond peoples means. The hardcore perspective
therefore characterizes the crisis as essentially a U.S. phenomenon.
The softcore neoliberal market failure argument holds the crisis is due to inadequate financial
regulation. First, regulators allowed excessive risk-taking by banks. Second, regulators allowed
perverse incentive pay structures within banks that encouraged management to engage in loan
pushing rather than good lending. Third, regulators pushed both deregulation and selfregulation too far. Together, these failures contributed to financial misallocation, including
misallocation of foreign saving provided through the trade deficit. The softcore perspective is
therefore more global but it views the crisis as essentially a financial phenomenon.
The progressive destruction of shared prosperity argument holds the crisis is rooted in the
neoliberal economic paradigm that has guided economic policy for the past thirty years. Though
the U.S. is the epicenter of the crisis, all countries are implicated as they all adopted the
paradigm. That paradigm infected finance via inadequate regulation and via faulty incentive pay
arrangements, but financial market regulatory failure was just one element.
The neoliberal economic paradigm was adopted in the late 1970s and early 1980s. From 1945 1975 the U.S. economy was characterized by a virtuous circle Keynesian model built on full
employment and wage growth tied to productivity growth. Productivity growth drove wage
growth, which fuelled demand growth and full employment. That provided an incentive for
investment, which drove further productivity growth and higher wages. This model held in the
U.S. and, subject to local modifications, it also held throughout the global economy - in Western
Europe, Canada, Japan, Mexico, Brazil and Argentina.
After 1980 the virtuous circle Keynesian model was replaced by a neoliberal growth model that
severed the link between wages and productivity growth and created a new economic dynamic.
Before 1980, wages were the engine of U.S. demand growth. After 1980, debt and asset price
inflation became the engine.
The new model was rooted in neoliberal economics and can be described as a neoliberal policy
box that pressures workers from all sides. Corporate globalization put workers in international
competition via global production networks supported by free trade agreements and capital
mobility. The small government agenda attacked the legitimacy of government and pushed
deregulation regardless of dangers. The labor market flexibility agenda attacked unions and labor
market supports and protections such as the minimum wage. Finally, the abandonment of full
employment created employment insecurity and weakened worker bargaining power.
This model was implemented globally, in North and South, which multiplied its impact. That
explains the significance of the Washington Consensus which was enforced in developing
economies by the International Monetary Fund and World Bank by making financial assistance
conditional on adopting neoliberal policies.
The new model created a growing demand gap by gradually undermining the income and
demand generation process. The role of finance was to fill that gap. Within the U.S.,
deregulation, financial innovation, and speculation enabled finance to fill the gap by lending to
consumers and spurring asset inflation. U.S. consumers in turn filled the global demand gap.
These three different perspectives make clear what is at stake as each recommends its own
different policy response. For hardcore neoliberal government failure proponents the
recommended policy response is to double-down on neoliberal policies by further deregulating
financial and labor markets; deepening central bank independence and the commitment to low
inflation; and further limiting government via fiscal austerity.
For softcore neoliberal market failure proponents the response is tighten financial regulation but
continue with the rest of the existing neoliberal policy paradigm. That means continued support
for corporate globalization, labor market flexibility, low inflation targeting, and fiscal austerity.
For proponents of the destruction of shared prosperity hypothesis the challenge is to replace the
neoliberal paradigm with a structural Keynesian paradigm that repacks the policy box and
restores the link between wage and productivity growth. The goal is to take workers out of the
box and put corporations and financial markets in so that they serve the broader public interest.
That requires replacing corporate globalization with managed globalization; restoring
commitment to full employment; replacing the anti-government agenda with a social democratic
government agenda; and replacing labor market flexibility with solidarity based labor markets.
The critical insight is each perspective carries its own policy prescriptions. Consequently, the
explanation which prevails will strongly impact the course of policy. That places economics at
the center of the political struggle as it influences which explanation prevails, and it explains
why powerful elites and orthodox economists have an interest in blocking other perspectives.
The modern world economy is dominated by the capitalist mode of production. Under
capitalism, money is used to make more money. Profit drives production, not social need. And
capitalist production does not proceed in a straight line upwards. It is subject to recurrent crises
of booms and slumps that destroy and waste much of the value previously created by society
(workers). The 1880s and 1890s saw a massive destruction of US production and wealth; the
Great Depression of the 1930s also. Now we have suffered the first Great Recession and are still
in the Long Depression of the 21st century.
The capitalist mode of production has recurrent crises because it has two major fault-lines. First,
in a monetary economy, of which capitalism is the epitome, there is always the possibility of
crisis. Holders of money may not always spend it or invest it, but hoard it. If they do so for
whatever reason, it can cause a dislocation of the exchange process and create a crisis in buying
and selling.
Second, the capitalist system of production for profit will falter if not enough profit is created to
satisfy the owners of the means of production. And there is an inherent tendency for the rate of
profit to fall. This is the underlying cause of all slumps.
Individual capitalist businesses do not cooperate to produce the things and services that society
needs. On the contrary, they compete with each other to sustain and increase their profit. To do
so, they make workers worker longer or harder, but they also increasingly use new technology to
boost the productivity of labour to get more value. But this is capitalisms Achilles heel. The
accumulated cost of investing in new plant, equipment etc inexorably rises compared to the size
and cost of the labour force. As only labour can create new value (machines on their own cannot
do it), the profitability of each new unit of investment begins to fall. If profitability falls
consistently, eventually it will cause a fall in the mass of profit. Then capitalists stop investing
and go on strike. A crisis of production ensues.
Capitalists try to avoid this crisis in various ways: by trying to exploit workers more; by looking
for cheaper forms of new technology; and by speculating in unproductive areas of the economy
i.e. the stock market, banking and finance, where they gamble for gain. But these things can
only work for a while. Eventually, the law of falling profitability will operate.
Which way profitability goes tells you which way capitalism goes:
US rate of profit 1948-2011 (%)
25.0
CRISIS
23.0
17 yrs
CRISIS
15 yrs
17 yrs
17 yrs?
21.0
19.0
17.0
NEO LIBERAL
BOOM
GOLDEN AGE
15.0
13.0
2013
2008
2003
1998
1993
1988
1983
1978
1973
1968
1963
1958
1953
1948
The rate of profit in the US is well below where it was in 1948. But it has not moved in a
straight line. After the war, it was high in the so-called Golden Age from 1948-65. This was
also the fastest period of economic growth in American history.
Then profitability fell consistently from 1965 to 1982. GDP growth was much slower and
American capitalism (like elsewhere) suffered severe slumps in 1974-5 and 1980-2.
Then in the era of what is called neoliberalism, from1982 to 1997, profitability rose.
Capitalism managed to get counteracting factors to falling profitability into play i.e. greater
exploitation of the American workforce (falling wage share); wider exploitation of the labour
force elsewhere (globalisation) and speculation in unproductive sectors (real estate and the rise
of finance capital). This neoliberal period had less severe slumps, although economic growth
was still slower than in the Golden Age because much of the profit was diverted away from real
investment.
Profitability peaked in 1997 and began to decline. This laid the basis for the Great Recession of
2008-9. That slump and the ensuing Long Depression that we are still in was more severe than
anything seen since the 1930s, because of the huge build-up of debt and financial assets in the
previous two decades that did not create real value. Instead, there were credit-fuelled bubbles
first in hi-tech stocks (crash in 2000) and then in housing (crash 2007). The unproductive
financial sector contributed 40% of all capitalist profit. Finally, this credit bubble burst, bringing
down the banking sector and the economy.
The high level of private sector debt was compounded by the state having to bail out the banks.
Until this overhang of debt is cleared (deleveraged), profitability cannot be restored sufficiently
to get investment and economic growth going again. Indeed, it is likely that another huge slump
will be necessary to cleanse the system of this dead (toxic) capital. The Long Depression will
continue until then.
Ending the Long Depression will not be possible by more government spending through
increased borrowing and/or taxes, as this eats into the profitability of the capitalist sector. While
that sector remains dominant, lower profitability means that new investment will not take place
to restore lost jobs and incomes. The New Deal in the 1930s did not succeed in ending the Great
Depression, even though it was much more radical than any measures now proposed by Obama.
It was watered down by capitalist opposition. But also it did not work because it could not
restore profitability - on the contrary. In the end, only a World War that put the labour force
onto a military footing (while killing millions globally) did the trick.
Under capitalism, terrible slumps will reoccur and inequality will remain. The end of poverty
and prosperity for the majority can only come through replacing private production for profit
with democratically-planned production for social need.
Causes
The global capitalist economy is experiencing its worst crisis since 1929 Great Depression.
Crises of this magnitude are regular events in the history of capitalism. They are reflections of
systemic tendencies which periodically express themselves as events we have come to all
Depressions, such as those of the 1840s, 1870s, and 1930s. I have argued that the period of the
1970s, the so-called Great Stagflation, was one such event, and that we are now experiencing yet
another episode of this recurrent phenomenon. I consider the present crisis to be the first Great
Depression of the twenty-first century. Crises of this sort are generally resolved by a new set of
(global) institutions, a new balance of power between the contending forces within and across
nations, and most of all, by a recovery in profitability for the surviving businesses as they acquire
the assets of their failed competitors at bargain prices. The balance between real wages and
productivity also typically shifts in favour of businesses in the face of the unemployment induced
by a crisis, although the institutional balance may subsequently shift in the opposite direction in
the aftermath.
The profit motive that drives capitalism has its own dynamics. In this regard, what is crucial is
the excess of the profit rate over the interest rate, since it is this net rate which motivates active
investment (as opposed to the passive holding of interest bearing assets). On the side of the
profit rate, the long term trend arises from structural factors such as a rising capital intensity of
production driven by the relentless competition to increase productivity and reduce costs. This
tends to produce a downward trend in the general rate of profit. At the same time, it spurs
renewed efforts to reverse this trend. In the latter domain falls the search for cheaper raw
materials and most of all, for cheaper labor. Hence the great push for globalisation, accompanied
by the mantra that free trade is good for all. But cheaper labor is not just found abroad. It can be
imported, and most crucially, it can be created at home by undermining labor strength and
institutions that support working people. Reagan and Thatcher ushered in a new era at the
beginning of the 1980s with their successful attacks on labor. As I show in Figure 3 of my paper
called The First Great Depression of the 21st Century (Socialist Register 2011), the resulting
stagnation of real wages and acceleration of productivity converted a steadily falling rate of
profit into a merely stagnant one.
But a stagnant rate of profit does not provide much fuel for a boom. What really supercharged
the great boom that began in the 1980s in the US was a dramatic fall in the (T-bill, 3 month)
interest rate, which went from 14% in 1981 to a little above 1 % in 2003 (Figure 4 of this same
paper). This greatly increased the net profit rate, which in turn accelerated growth in the two
decades after 1982. But falling interest rate also spurred a corresponding rise in debt-financing
expenditures by businesses and consumers. As a result, the growth boom in the production went
hand-in-hand with bubbles in real estate and in financial markets. Interest rates also fell in other
parts of the world, sometimes even faster, and this fuelled a similar international boom in
accumulation and an international bubble in finance.
The sub-prime mortgage crisis in the US was the trigger, not the cause, of the present crisis. The
gradual reversal of regulations which had previously restrained financial institutions made it all
the worse when it hit. Deregulation has been the mantra of the worldwide neoliberal agenda for
more than two decades, enforced by the power of the WTO, the World Bank, and the IMF, of
course by the prescriptions of orthodox economists, bankers, and world leaders. We are reaping
the fruit that they have sown.
Consequences
I believe that the crisis will last a long time, a decade or more. The structural changes which it
will bring about are still being negotiated, and the struggle over the future is only beginning. In
Europe this process could take even longer, which is a good thing because its social and political
structures (such as the family in Spain and Italy, and the welfare state in most European
countries) act as important shock absorbers while the new social agenda is being established.
This crisis is primarily due to the inner workings of the market system and to conjunctural
factors such as the world wide reduction in interest rates which fueled the bubble which has yet
to subside. The Keynesian Left tends to look to the State as the solution. But capitalists
themselves have always known that the state is essential for "proper" workings of the market.
The real debate is, proper for whom? Large businesses have lined up for bailouts, handouts
and bonuses without any hint of shame or chagrin. Worse yet, they are abandoning the very
economists who so faithfully served their cause in the past. Even former cheerleaders of
neoliberalism like the Financial Times and The Economist have (quite rightly) unleashed sharp
criticisms of orthodox economic doctrines. In the immortal words of Tom Lehrer, this has left
orthodox economists terminally bewildered.
The crisis is "paid for" by the hundreds of millions of working people who suffer its
consequences through no fault of their own, as well numbers of business people who do not
possess "golden parachutes". The wisdom of Keynes is that in times such s this, the State can
ameliorate the worst effects of the crisis. The wisdom of Marx is that this does not abolish future
crises, since these are rooted in the profit motive. Regulations put in place in one era to protect
the system from capitalist excesses become obstacles to profits when the recovery is underway.
Then comes a chorus decrying regulations, from capital, from academics, and from some
quarters of the State itself. And to a greater or lesser degree, the regulations are undermined. As
long as profit rules, crises will recur. But even within the confines of the capitalist system, the
institutional conditions are not given in advance. If State spending is to be the focus, then let it be
on direct employment, direct provision of health, education and welfare, direct reduction of
poverty and hunger, so that there is a stronger social base from which to resist. And lest we
forget, let there be a reckoning of the culpability of the economics orthodoxy for its market
worship and endless incantations about perfect markets, perfect knowledge and perfect foresight
the holy trinity of perfect nonsense.
As the Global Financial Crisis rumbles along in its fifth year, we read the latest revelations of
bankster fraud, the LIBOR scandal. In times like these, I always recall Robert Sherrills 1990
statement about the S&L crisis: thievery is what unregulated capitalism is all about. Over the
next decade, we then deregulated the financial system, and we are shocked, SHOCKED!, that
thieves took over. They screwed workers out of their jobs, homeowners out of their houses,
retirees out of their pensions, and municipalities out of their revenues.
And since theyve bought the politicians, the policy-makers, and the courts, no one will stop the
fraud. Few will even discuss it, since most university administrations have similarly been bought
offuniversities are even headed by corporate leaders--and their professors are on Wall
Streets payrolls.
Were screwed.
This crisis is like Shreks Onion, with fraud in every layer, which cannot be reduced much less
eliminated. First, there are no regulators to stop it, and no prosecutors to punish it. But, more
importantly, fraud is the business model. Even if a bank bucked the trend it would fail. As my
colleague Bill Black says, fraud is always the most profitable game in town. So Greshams Law
dynamics ensure that fraud is the only game in town.
Veblen analyzed religion as the quintessential capitalist undertaking. It sells an inherently
ephemeral product whose value exists only in the minds of purchasers, and mostly cannot be
realized until death. A defective product cannot be returned to the sellersthere is no explicit
money back guarantee and in any event, most of the dissatisfied have already been undertaken.
The value of the undertakers institution is similarly ephemeral goodwill--aside from a fancy
building, very little in the way of productive facilities is actually required.
Today, modern finance replaces religion as the supreme capitalistic undertaking. Again, it has no
need for production facilitiesa fancy building, a few Bloomberg screens, greasy snake-oil
salesmen, and rapacious traders is all that is required to separate widows and orphans from their
lifesavings and homes. There is rarely any recourse for dissatisfied customers--few understand
what they are buying from Wall Streets undertakers, a product more complicated than the
Theory of the Trinity advanced by Theophilus of Antioch, let alone the Temple Garments (called
Magic Underwear by nonbelievers). That facilitates screwing customers and hiding fraud.
A handful of Wall Street thieves can run up $2 trillion in ephemeral assets whose worth is mostly
determined by whatever value the thieves assign to them. They also place tens of trillions of
dollars of derivative bets so the thieves get paid when something goes wrongthe death of a
homeowner, worker, firm, or country triggers payments on Death Settlements, Peasant
Insurance, or Credit Default Swaps. And the value of the Wall Street undertakers firm is almost
wholly determined by goodwillas if there is any good will in betting on death.
With these undertakers running the show, it is no wonder that we are buried under mountains of
crushing debtunderwater mortgages, home equity loans, credit card debt, student loans,
healthcare debts, and auto-related finance. Everything is financialized as Wall Street has its hand