The Savers-Spenders Theory of Fiscal Policy: by N. G
The Savers-Spenders Theory of Fiscal Policy: by N. G
By N. GREGORY MANKIW*
The literature on the macroeconomic effects
of fiscal policy and, in particular, of government
debt is founded on two canonical models. The
purpose of this paper is to suggest that both
models are deficient and to propose a new
model to take their place.
The first canonical model is the Barro-Ramsey
model of infinitely-lived families (Robert Barro,
1974). According to this model, the governments
debt policy redistributes the tax burden among
generations, but families, who want to smooth
their consumption over time, reverse the effects of
this redistribution through their bequests. Government debt is completely neutrala proposition
called Ricardian equivalence.
The second canonical model of government
debt is the Diamond-Samuelson model of overlapping generations (Peter Diamond, 1965). In
this model, people smooth consumption over
their own lifetimes, but there is no bequest
motive. When the government issues debt, it
enriches some generations at the expense of
others, crowds out capital, and reduces steadystate living standards.
In this paper, I first discuss the facts that lead
me to reject these canonical models. I then
propose an alternative model and develop
briefly its implications for fiscal policy.
VOL. 90 NO. 2
121
Samuelson models of fiscal policy. Acknowledging the prevalence of these low-wealth households
helps explain why consumption tracks current income as strongly as it does.
C. Bequests Are an Important Factor
in Wealth Accumulation
While many people have almost no wealth, a
few have much. The top 5 percent of the income
distribution has historically earned 1520 percent of all income. But the top 5 percent of the
wealth distribution holds 60 percent of the economys wealth and 72 percent of financial wealth
(i.e., wealth excluding home equity). This great
accumulation by a small part of the population
suggests that some households have motives
beyond normal life-cycle smoothing. A bequest
motive is the obvious candidate.
As a matter of accounting, each dollar of
wealth that a person holds will either be spent
during his lifetime or left as a bequest after he
dies. Laurence Kotlikoff and Lawrence Summers (1981) estimated the relative importance
of the two kinds of wealth. They concluded (p.
706) that intergenerational transfers account
for the vast majority of aggregate U.S. capital
formation. Any model that attempts to explain
how fiscal policy affects the economy must
come to grips with this fact.
II. A New Model
122
their descendants, while others live paycheckto-paycheck. To see what might be learned from
such a model, I sketch a simple example in the
rest of this paper.
Imagine that the economy is populated by
two sorts of people. One group, which I will call
savers, has behavior that is described by the
Barro-Ramsey model: they have an operative
intergenerational bequest motive and, thus, infinite horizons. A second group, which I will
call spenders, consumes their entire after-tax
labor income in every period. This savers
spenders model of fiscal policy is extraordinarily simple (and its antecedents in my empirical
paper with Campbell are obvious). But its policy implications could not be more radical, as
the following propositions make clear.
PROPOSITION 1: Temporary tax changes have
large effects on the demand for goods and services.
In early 1992, President George Bush pursued a novel policy to deal with the lingering
recession in the United States. By executive
order, he lowered the amount of income taxes
that were being withheld from spenders paychecks. The order did not reduce the amount of
taxes that spenders owed; it merely delayed
payment. The higher take-home pay that spenders received during 1992 was to be offset by
higher tax payments, or smaller tax refunds,
when income taxes were due in April 1993.
What effect should this policy have? According to the logic of either the Barro-Ramsey or
Diamond-Samuelson model of fiscal policy,
consumers should realize that their lifetime resources were unchanged and, therefore, save the
extra take-home pay to meet the upcoming tax
liability. By contrast, President Bush claimed
that his policy would provide money people
can use to help pay for clothing, college, or to
get a new car. That is, he believed that consumers would spend the extra income, thereby
stimulating aggregate demand and helping the
economy recover from the recession.
Evidence supports Bushs conjecture. Shortly
after the policy was announced, Matthew Shapiro and Joel Slemrod (1995) asked people what
they would do with the extra income. Fiftyseven percent of the respondents said they
would save it, use it to repay debts, or adjust
MAY 2000
VOL. 90 NO. 2
y rD g
r f k
1 r
where the notation is standard. The first equation is the production function. The second
equation states that tax revenue ( y) equals the
interest on the debt (rD) plus government
spending ( g). The third equation states that the
interest rate (r) equals the marginal product of
capital. (Both interest income and capital income are assumed to be taxed at the same rate,
so the tax does not affect this equation.) The
123
124
subject to
w fk f kk
w f kk g
1 f k .
The objective here is simply to maximize the
after-tax wage, (1 )w. In pursuing this goal,
the spender majority faces three constraints.
The first constraint says that labor earns its
marginal product, which by Eulers theorem
equals output left after capital is paid its marginal product. The second constraint is a government budget constraint, which says that
revenue from labor taxes plus revenue from
capital taxes must equal government spending.
The third constraint is the steady-state condition
stating that the after-tax marginal product of
capital equals the savers discount rate.
I will skip the details of the solution and go
straight to the result: 0. That is, the optimal
tax on capital income is zero. This is true even
though I have been doing the optimal tax problem from the standpoint of the spenders, who
hold no capital.
Why do spenders want to exempt capital income from taxation? The reason is that the
supply of capital is highly elastic in this model.
In the long run, it is infinitely elastic at rate .
When capital is taxed, the quantity falls, which
in turn depresses the real wage. This effect is
large enough to make any tax on capital income
undesirable, even from the perspective of people who own no capital.
In light of this result, one might wonder why
the populace is not clamoring to eliminate the
MAY 2000
VOL. 90 NO. 2
125
21. Gnter Coenen, Roland Straub, Mathias Trabandt. 2013. Gauging the effects of fiscal stimulus
packages in the euro area. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, 367-386. [CrossRef]
22. Florin O. Bilbiie, Tommaso Monacelli, Roberto Perotti. 2013. Public Debt and Redistribution
with Borrowing Constraints. The Economic Journal 123:10.1111/ecoj.2013.123.issue-566, F64-F98.
[CrossRef]
23. Shafik Hebous, Tom Zimmermann. 2013. Estimating the effects of coordinated fiscal actions in the
euro area. European Economic Review 58, 110-121. [CrossRef]
24. Robert Kollmann, Marco Ratto, Werner Roeger, Jan int Veld. 2013. Fiscal policy, banks and the
financial crisis. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, 387-403. [CrossRef]
25. Carlos J. Garca, Wildo D. Gonzlez. 2013. Exchange rate intervention in small open economies: The
role of risk premium and commodity price shocks. International Review of Economics & Finance 25,
424-447. [CrossRef]
26. Suman S Basu, Jan Gottschalk, Werner Schule, Nikhil Vellodi, Shu-Chun S. Yang. 2013. The
Macroeconomic Effects of Natural Resource Extraction: Applications to Papua New Guinea. IMF
Working Papers 13, 1. [CrossRef]
27. Gisle James Natvik. 2012. Government Spending Shocks and Rule-of-Thumb Consumers with
Steady-State Inequality*. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 114:10.1111/sjoe.2012.114.issue-4,
1414-1436. [CrossRef]
28. Raymond G. Batina. 2012. Capital tax competition and social security. International Tax and Public
Finance 19, 819-843. [CrossRef]
29. Florin O. Bilbiie, Roland Straub. 2012. Changes in the output Euler equation and asset markets
participation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 36, 1659-1672. [CrossRef]
30. WEI-KANG WONG. 2012. CONSUMPTION RESPONSE TO GOVERNMENT TRANSFERS:
BEHAVIORAL MOTIVES REVEALED BY SAVERS AND SPENDERS. Contemporary Economic
Policy 30:10.1111/coep.2012.30.issue-4, 489-501. [CrossRef]
31. GIORGIO MOTTA, PATRIZIO TIRELLI. 2012. Optimal Simple Monetary and Fiscal Rules
under Limited Asset Market Participation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44:10.1111/
jmcb.2012.44.issue-7, 1351-1374. [CrossRef]
32. Robert Kollmann. 2012. Limited asset market participation and the consumption-real exchange
rate anomaly. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'conomique 45:10.1111/
caje.2012.45.issue-2, 566-584. [CrossRef]
33. Francesco Furlanetto, Martin Seneca. 2012. Rule-of-Thumb Consumers, Productivity, and Hours*.
The Scandinavian Journal of Economics no-no. [CrossRef]
34. Wenyi Shen, Shu-Chun S. Yang. 2012. The Effects of Government Spending Under Limited Capital
Mobility. IMF Working Papers 12, 1. [CrossRef]
35. Carlos J. Garcia, Jorge E. Restrepo, Scott Roger. 2011. Hybrid Inflation Targeting Regimes. Journal
of International Money and Finance . [CrossRef]
36. ANDREA COLCIAGO. 2011. Rule-of-Thumb Consumers Meet Sticky Wages. Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 43:10.1111/jmcb.2011.43.issue-2-3, 325-353. [CrossRef]
37. Steven G. Craig, Edward C. Hoang. 2011. State government response to income fluctuations:
Consumption, insurance, and capital expenditures. Regional Science and Urban Economics . [CrossRef]
38. Carlos J. Garcia, Jorge E. Restrepo, Evan Tanner. 2011. Fiscal rules in a volatile world: A welfarebased approach. Journal of Policy Modeling . [CrossRef]
39. Jorge Restrepo, Carlos Garcia, Evan Tanner. 2011. Fiscal Rules in a Volatile World: A Welfare-Based
Approach. IMF Working Papers 11, 1. [CrossRef]
40. Lars Kunze. 2010. Capital taxation, long-run growth, and bequests. Journal of Macroeconomics 32,
1067-1082. [CrossRef]
41. Shafik Hebous. 2010. THE EFFECTS OF DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY ON
MACROECONOMIC AGGREGATES: A REAPPRAISAL. Journal of Economic Surveys no-no.
[CrossRef]
42. Pierre Pestieau, Emmanuel Thibault. 2010. Love thy children or money. Economic Theory . [CrossRef]
43. Stefan Khn, Joan Muysken, Tom Van Veen. 2010. THE ADVERSE EFFECT OF
GOVERNMENT SPENDING ON PRIVATE CONSUMPTION IN NEW KEYNESIAN
MODELS. Metroeconomica 61:10.1111/meca.2010.61.issue-4, 621-639. [CrossRef]
44. Christopher Tsoukis, Frederic Tournemaine. 2010. SOCIAL CONFLICT, GROWTH AND
FACTOR SHARES. Metroeconomica no-no. [CrossRef]
45. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Marco Manzo. 2010. FISCAL POLICY UNDER BALANCED BUDGET
AND INDETERMINACY: A NEW KEYNESIAN PERSPECTIVE. Scottish Journal of Political
Economy 57:10.1111/sjpe.2010.57.issue-4, 455-472. [CrossRef]
46. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Lorenza Rossi, Massimiliano Tancioni. 2010. Monetary policy, rule-ofthumb consumers and external habits: a G7 comparison. Applied Economics 1-18. [CrossRef]
47. Naomi E Feldman. 2010. Mental Accounting Effects of Income Tax Shifting. Review of Economics
and Statistics 92, 70-86. [CrossRef]
48. Thomas Palley. 2010. The Relative Permanent Income Theory of Consumption: A Synthetic KeynesDuesenberry-Friedman Model. Review of Political Economy 22, 41-56. [CrossRef]
49. Manmohan S. Kumar, Emanuele Baldacci. 2010. Fiscal Deficits, Public Debt, and Sovereign Bond
Yields. IMF Working Papers 10, 1. [CrossRef]
50. Mankiw N. Gregory, Weinzierl Matthew, Yagan Danny. 2009. Optimal Taxation in Theory and
Practice. Journal of Economic Perspectives 23:4, 147-174. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
51. Michal Horvath. 2009. The effects of government spending shocks on consumption under optimal
stabilization. European Economic Review 53, 815-829. [CrossRef]
52. Kirill Borissov, Stphane Lambrecht. 2009. Growth and distribution in an AK-model with endogenous
impatience. Economic Theory 39, 93-112. [CrossRef]
53. Stefano Bosi, Thomas Seegmuller. 2009. On local indeterminacy and endogenous cycles in Ramsey
models with heterogeneous households. Portuguese Economic Journal 8, 53-58. [CrossRef]
54. GISLE JAMES NATVIK. 2009. Government Spending and the Taylor Principle. Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 41:10.1111/jmcb.2009.41.issue-1, 57-77. [CrossRef]
55. Carlos Garcia, Jorge Restrepo, Scott Roger. 2009. Hybrid Inflation Targeting Regimes. IMF Working
Papers 09, 1. [CrossRef]
56. Gernot Mller, Giancarlo Corsetti, Andr Meier. 2009. Fiscal Stimulus with Spending Reversals. IMF
Working Papers 09, 1. [CrossRef]
57. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Lorenza Rossi. 2007. Effectiveness of monetary policy and limited asset
market participation: Neoclassical versus Keynesian effects. International Journal of Economic Theory
3:10.1111/ijet.2007.3.issue-3, 213-218. [CrossRef]
58. Jordi Gal, J. David Lpez-Salido, Javier Valls. 2007. Understanding the Effects of
Government Spending on Consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association 5:10.1162/
jeea.2007.5.issue-1, 227-270. [CrossRef]
59. Dennis Fredriksen, Kim Massey Heide, Erling Holmy, Ingeborg Foldy SolliChapter 5
Macroeconomic Effects of Proposed Pension Reforms in Norway 107-142. [CrossRef]