Stopping North Korea Inc - Park Walsh - FINAL

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 64

Stopping North Korea, Inc.

:
Sanctions Effectiveness and Unintended Consequences

John Park, Harvard University


Jim Walsh, Massachusetts Institute of Technology

MIT Security Studies Program


Cambridge, MA
August, 2016
2

Executive Summary

This study assesses the use of sanctions against North Korea, especially as they relate to
Pyongyang’s ongoing nuclear and missile programs. We address three main questions:

1) Do sanctions intended to reduce or halt WMD procurement work, and if not, why not?

2) What, if any, unintended consequences—positive or negative—do sanctions against


North Korea generate?

3) What can be done to improve the effectiveness of these and other sanctions?

To answer these questions, we focus on what we call “North Korea, Inc.,” the system of regime-
operated state trading companies (STCs) that the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea
(DPRK) employs to procure both licit and illicit goods. In particular, this study is based on
interviews over a three-year period with North Korean defectors who worked in these
procurement organizations. The primary objective of this inquiry has been to document North
Korea. Inc.’s practices, partners, and pathways, and in particular how the DPRK has innovated in
the face of international sanctions.

We conclude that sanctions intended to deny North Korea access to WMD-related materials have
not worked, and that in some ways, the sanctions have had the net effect of actually improving
DPRK procurement capabilities. We judge that some elements of its nuclear and missile
programs will continue to depend on procurement from other countries, that sanctions can be
improved, and that at least for the near and intermediate term, denial of weapons-related material
and technology is a worthy policy objective, if integrated into a broader political strategy.

The analysis begins by noting the fact that sanctions, and especially targeted financial sanctions,
have become an increasingly prominent foreign policy tool for nonproliferation and other policy
domains. This has occurred despite the fact that academic research on the effectiveness of
sanctions (and of sanctions on North Korea specifically) has generally raised questions about
their efficacy. In a departure from traditional research, this study considers the question of
effectiveness from two, new vantage points: 1) from the perspective of a North Korean STC
manager trying to evade sanctions and 2) with an eye to possible unintended consequences that
sanctions on the DPRK might generate (both negative and positive).

The study offers a number of new findings concerning how DPRK procurement has evolved over
time, most especially in the late 2000s. It finds that North Korean STC managers have shifted
their strategy by 1) hiring more capable Chinese middlemen who can more effectively handle
financing, logistics, and doing business with private Chinese firms and foreign firms operating in
China, 2) taking up residence and embedding themselves on the mainland, which increases their
effectiveness, 3) expanding the use of Hong Kong and Southeast Asian regional commercial
hubs, and 4) increasing the use of embassies as a vehicle for procurement.
3

The study considers ten potential unintended consequences that sanctions on North Korea might
induce, including six potentially negative effects, two potentially positive effects, and two that
could be either positive or negative, depending on the context. Of these, three are particularly
noteworthy.

A first and negative unintended consequence is what we call the “sanctions conundrum,” that the
net effect of sanctions has been to actually increase Pyongyang’s procurement capabilities. This
counter-intuitive result is a consequence of the fact that when sanctions have been imposed, they
have had the intended effect of raising the cost of doing business. Unfortunately, the DPRK has
responded by simply monetizing the risk and paying higher commission fees to Chinese brokers.
This, in turn, has drawn larger, more sophisticated partners.

A second but positive unintended consequence is that sanctions have helped spur the growth of a
“compliance culture” among larger Chinese financial firms that want to avoid transgressing
sanctions for fear of fines, damage to their business reputations, and downstream consequences
for their ability to do business in the U.S. and other non-Chinese markets.

A third unintended consequence is not yet evident in practice, but bears watching: increased
sanctions may have severe and negative consequences for the North Korean civilian, non-elite
population—a group whose economic status may be fragile.

The report offers a set of eleven policy recommendations covering a variety of policy areas,
including engaging China, capacity building, further encouraging a culture of corporate
compliance, disrupting North Korea, Inc., and new modes of information collection and analysis.

The policy recommendations include:

1) Encourage China to use its domestic laws as a vehicle to go after DPRK STCs.
2) Encourage China to send signals to its private industry: licit commerce is acceptable;
illicit WMD-related business is not.
3) Improve the capacity of national governments, especially in Southeast Asia to
implement sanctions.
4) Build the capacity of the U.S. government to respond to the misuse of DPRK
embassies for procurement.
5) Augment the capacity of the UN Panel of Experts on North Korea.
6) Encourage a culture of compliance by prosecuting high profile cases.
7) Experiment with the use of incentives.
8) Disrupt North Korea, Inc.’s operations in order to reduce scope, size, and tenure of
STC managers.
9) Analyze DPRK procurement as a business case study, including the use of game
simulations and testing potential sanction concepts with the STC defector community.
10) Employ new models for analysis, e.g., comparing DPRK illicit procurement against
other state and non-state entities that also seek to evade sanctions.
11) Adopt an evidence-based and outcomes-focused approach to evaluation of sanctions.
4

Table of Contents
I. Sanctions and the Challenge of North Korea’s Illicit Weapons Programs 6
The Central Role of Sanctions
Are Sanctions Effective? A Summary of the Social Science Research
Research on North Korea Sanctions
What’s Missing? Alternative Perspectives on North Korea Sanctions
How this Study was Conducted
II. North Korea, Inc.: The Evolution of North Korea’s State Trading Companies 18
The Origins of STCs in the 1980s
After the Fall of the Soviet Union
North Korean Procurement Practices After 2000
North Korea’s Adaptations
1) Employment of more capable Chinese middlemen
2) Embeddedness in China
3) Use of Hong Kong
4) Use of commercial hubs in Southeast Asian
5) Increased use of embassies and diplomatic personnel for procurement
The Evolving DPRK Revenue Stream
Jang Song-taek and North Korea’s Commercial Relations with China
The Evolution of DPRK Trading Practices over Time
III. The Unintended Consequences of Sanctions on North Korea 30
Conceptualizing Unintended Consequences
The Unintended Consequences of Sanctions on North Korea
Negative Unintended Consequences of Sanctions on North Korea
1) Strengthens North Korean capabilities (“sanctions conundrum”)
2) Incentivizes collaboration with illicit networks and states of concern
3) Hinders positive forms of engagement
4) Imposes costs on North Korean civilian population
5) Increases risk of triggering North Korean collapse
6) Increases risk of sanctions overreach that could backfire
Positive Unintended Consequences
1) Generates a market for compliance
2) Promotes North Korean elite engagement with the outside world
Unintended Consequences Whose Effect Could be Either Negative or Positive
1) Introduces North Korean elites to markets
2) Fosters corruption
Assessing the Unintended Consequences of North Korea Sanctions
Turning the Tables: The Unintended Consequences of Sanctions Evasion for North Korea
IV. Policy Recommendations 43
1) Encourage China to use its domestic laws to counter North Korea, Inc.
2) Encourage China to send strong signals to its private industry: licit commerce is acceptable; illicit
WMD-related business is not
3) Improve the capacity of national governments, especially in Southeast Asia to implement sanctions
4) Build the capacity of U.S. government to respond to the misuse of DPRK embassies for procurement
5) Augment the capacity of the UN Panel of Experts on North Korea
6) Prioritize the prosecution of high profile cases of sanctions violations
7) Experiment with the use of incentives
8) Disrupt North Korea, Inc.’s operations in order to reduce scope, size, and tenure of STC managers
9) Analyze DPRK procurement as a business case study
10) Employ new models for analysis
11) Adopt an evidence-based and outcomes-focused approach to evaluation
V. Answering the Questions, Changing the Mindset, and Addressing a Post-UNSCR 2270 World 57
Appendix I. U.S. and International Sanctions Against North Korea 61
5

Boxes, Tables, and Charts

Box 1. How Do Sanctions on North Korea Compare to Those Imposed on Iran? 11

Chart 1. North Korea Trade, 2001-2014 21

Box. 2. DPRK Adaptations 23

Table 1. Types of Unintended Consequences 30

Chart 2. Continuous Relationship Among Cost, Risk, and Broker Participation 32

Chart 3. Notional Estimated Relationship Among Cost, Risk, and Broker Participation 32

Table 2. Unintended Consequence of Sanctions on North Korea 42

Table 3. Possible Goals for Sanctions Against North Korea 44

Table 4. Policy Recommendations 45

Table 5. Responding to DPRK Procurement Counter-measures 53

Table 6. UN Security Council Resolutions on North Korea 63

Table 7. U.S. Executive Orders (E.O.s) on North Korea 64


6

I. Sanctions and the Challenge of North Korea’s Illicit Weapons Programs

This study assesses the use of sanctions against North Korea, especially as they relate to
Pyongyang’s ongoing nuclear and missile programs.1 We address three main questions:

1) Do sanctions intended to reduce or halt WMD procurement work, and if not, why not?

2) What, if any, unintended consequences—positive or negative—do sanctions against


North Korea generate?

3) What can be done to improve the effectiveness of these and other sanctions?

To answer these questions, we focus on what we call “North Korea, Inc.,” the system of regime-
operated state trading companies (STCs) that the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea
(DPRK) employs to procure both licit and illicit goods. In particular, this study is based on
interviews with North Korean defectors who worked in these procurement organizations. While
the primary object of inquiry are North Korea, Inc.’s practices, partners, and pathways, this
analysis is also more broadly concerned with nonproliferation policymaking, sanctions as an
instrument of foreign policy, and the future of the North’s weapons programs.

We conclude that sanctions intended to deny North Korea access to WMD-related materials have
not worked, and that in some ways, the sanctions have had the net effect of actually improving
DPRK procurement capabilities. We judge that some elements of its nuclear and missile
programs will continue to depend on procurement from other countries, that sanctions can be
improved, and that at least for the near and intermediate term, denial of weapons-related material
and technology is a worthy policy objective.

To be clear, a judgment as to whether sanctions are or can be effective depends very much on
how one defines the objective. As discussed in the section on recommendations, sanctions can
serve any number of objectives, including denial of materials, technology, and capabilities;
coercion; bargaining; punishment; and regime change. The focus of this study is denial, i.e.,
reducing and halting the ability of the DPRK to procure items that would advance its weapons
programs.

1
This study would not have been possible without significant research, editorial, and writing
contributions from Timothy MacDonnell, Lena Andrews, and Elsa Kania. Debt is also owed to
the many scholars and experts who reviewed this monograph (Aaron Arnold, Matthew Bunn,
Bryan Early, Gary Samore, Jacqueline Shire, Joshua Stanton, Daniel Wertz, and others), to the
Harvard-MIT Working Group on North Korea (especially the late Amb. Stephen Bosworth),
participants and speakers in the MIT North Korea seminar series, organizations that hosted
presentations of the study (e.g., U.S. Institute of Peace, Council on Foreign Relations, Peterson
Institute for International Economics, UN Panel of Experts, and National Bureau of Asian
Research), the MacArthur Foundation, the Stanton Foundation, as well as Angela Nichols and
Pamela Park. Reference to an individual or organization does not imply endorsement. Our
errors are our own despite their best efforts.
7

Even when effective, sanctions are not an answer unto themselves. They can be useful in
combination with other policy instruments, when they are integrated into a broader political
strategy. A “sanctions only” policy will not succeed. The purpose of this study, therefore, is to
better understand North Korea, Inc., so that the U.S. and its partners can pursue a more effective
sanctions strategy that, when incorporated into a broader strategy, can slow, freeze, and
ultimately reverse North Korea’s nuclear and missile programs.

This section provides the context. It begins by examining the increasingly prominent role that
sanctions play in American foreign policy and in nonproliferation policy, in particular. It
surveys the current state of scholarly research on sanctions, including sanctions on North Korea,
and concludes with a brief description of the research method used in this study.

Section II introduces North Korea, Inc. It discusses the evolution of these procurement
organizations and their role in subverting nonproliferation sanctions.

Section III highlights the potential positive and negative unintended consequences of North
Korea sanctions. Positive unintended consequences include the creation of a “market for
compliance” and North Korean elite engagement with the outside world. Negative unintended
consequences include improved North Korean capabilities for sanctions subversion and the
possibility that general sanctions on the economy would threaten a vulnerable civilian
population.

Section IV presents the project’s main policy recommendations. These cover several areas,
including engaging China, capacity building, further encouraging corporate “compliance
culture,” disrupting North Korea, Inc., and alternative approaches to information collection and
analysis.

Section V summarizes the findings.

The Central Role of Sanctions


Governments have long used sanctions to punish, to deny access to goods and services, and to
deter others who might contemplate objectionable behavior.2 Sanctions have been in use for at
least 2,400 years.3 In the modern era, they have evolved from a blunt instrument intended to hurt

2
For a useful overview of sanctions as an instrument of foreign policy, see Chan, Steve, and A.
Cooper Drury. Sanctions as economic statecraft: theory and practice. St. Martin’s Press, 2000;
and Kirschner, Jonathan. “The Microfoundations of Economic Sanctions,” Security Studies 6, no.
3 (March 1997): 32-64. For a discussion of the efficacy of sanctions, see Miller, Nicholas L.
“The Secret Success of Nonproliferation Sanctions.” International Organization 68, no. 4
(October 2014): 913–44. doi:10.1017/S0020818314000216; Elliott, Kimberly Ann. “The
Sanctions Glass: Half Full or Completely Empty?” International Security 23, No. 1 (Summer
1998): 50-65. For a recent survey of sanctions research, see Coercive Diplomacy, Sanctions and
International Law. Ronzitti, Natalino, ed. Leiden: Brill Nijhoff. 2016
3
See for example the discussion of the Megarian Decree in Thucydides. The History of the
Peloponnesian War, Warner, Rex, trans., Penguin, 1954, 1.139.
8

a country’s economy to increasingly targeted efforts aimed at individuals and organizations.4


They have been employed by national governments, unilaterally and multilaterally, to target an
array of entities—governments, non-state actors, individuals, corporations—and to address a
wide range of issues, including nonproliferation, democracy and human rights, counter-terrorism,
cyber-attacks, the trade in conflict diamonds, narcotics, and criminal activity.5

In recent years, the use of sanctions has become more common, more sophisticated, and more
fully institutionalized. This is particularly true in the United States.6 In an era when there is less
enthusiasm for large-scale applications of military force, and when diplomacy requires sitting
down with objectionable regimes, sanctions offer policymakers a relatively cheap and easy way
to “do something” about a problem, whether it is North Korea’s nuclear and missile tests or
Russia’s intervention in Ukraine. As one executive branch official noted, sanctions have
“…become even more important to coerce and constrain the behavior of non-state networks and
recalcitrant, rogue regimes, which often appear beyond the reach of classic U.S. power or
influence.”7

The growing importance of individuals, corporations, and other non-state actors in international
affairs provides a complementary explanation for the increasing popularity of sanctions. Entirely
new kinds of sanctions have been developed, and they have been applied in novel ways. In
particular, the U.S. has pursued authority for secondary or extraterritorial banking sanctions that
leverage the dominant role of the U.S. dollar in the international financial system. Washington
has twice used these sanctions to penalize foreign banks for doing business with a sanctioned
entity, but the threat of these sanctions has had an outsized impact on parts of the international
banking system.8

To implement these increasingly sophisticated sanctions, the Department of the Treasury has
built an unprecedented and formidable organization for sanctions enforcement.9 For its part, the

4
Friedman, Uri. “Smart Sanctions: A Short History.” Foreign Policy no. 193 (May 2012): 1-5.
5
Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, Jeffrey J. Schott, and Kimberly Ann Elliott. Economic sanctions
reconsidered: History and current policy. Vol. 1. Peterson Institute, 1990.
6
Giumelli, Francesco. “Understanding United Nations targeted sanctions: an empirical analysis.”
International Affairs 91, no. 6, 2015: 1351-1368; Drezner, Daniel W. “Off Target.” New
Republic 241, no. 8 (May 27, 2010): 5-8.
7
Zarate, Juan C. “Harnessing the Financial Furies: Smart Financial Power and National
Security.” Washington Quarterly 32, no. 4 (October 2009): 43.
8
The Bank of Kunlun (China) and the Elaf Islamic Bank (Iraq). Arnold Aaron. Communication
with the authors, July 2016.
9
The U.S. Treasury Department’s Office of Foreign Assets Control (OFAC) was established in
1950, but has grown considerably in size, capabilities, and influence in the past decade. See U.S.
Department of the Treasury, “Office of Foreign Assets Control,”
https://www.treasury.gov/about/organizational-structure/offices/Pages/Office-of-Foreign-Assets-
Control.aspx.
9

United Nations has augmented its sanctions architecture with the use of Panels of Experts that
report to the Security Council on sanctions implementation.10

Sanctions are particularly attractive to the American Congress. They represent an area where
Capitol Hill can take the lead in foreign policy, a domain traditionally dominated by the
executive branch. The perceived value of sanctions among Congressional policymakers has only
increased since the successful negotiations with Iran over its nuclear program. Most observers
credit sanctions for helping push Tehran to the negotiating table, but many in Congress went
further, arguing that additional sanctions would have forced Iran to capitulate.

In sum, a number of factors have contributed to what appears to be growing interest in sanctions.
In this environment, sanctions will likely continue to be a popular tool of foreign policy for
nonproliferation and a host of other issues.

Are Sanctions Effective? A Summary of the Social Science Research


Analysts trying to measure the impact of sanctions, including targeted sanctions, face a number
of difficult challenges. Fundamentally, there is the issue of defining what constitutes a “success”
and a “failure” and over what time horizon. In the case of North Korea, sanctions clearly have
not prevented progress in the North’s weapons programs, but advocates can, not unreasonably
speculate that sanctions may have slowed Pyongyang’s march, and that absent sanctions, the
DPRK regime’s arsenal would be larger and more sophisticated.11

Another complication is the dizzying variety of cases. Sanctions have been imposed across
disparate issues, with differing punishments, over various time spans, and by varying coalitions
of countries. There are also a wide variety of sanctions: trade-based sanctions, travel bans, and
arms embargos, to name a few.12 The variation across cases makes it difficult to generalize
about the efficacy of sanctions. And, of course, there are data problems. Entities targeted by
sanctions are often closed countries or organizations, where the available data for standard
measures is missing or unreliable.

These challenges have not prevented scholars from tackling the issue, however. There is a rich
and growing research literature on sanctions. Much of this research consists of case studies.13

10
The UN currently has several such panels, including one that focuses on North Korea. On the
UN panel for North Korea, see United Nations Security Council Resolution 1874. June 12, 2009.
http://www.un.org/ga/search/view_doc.asp?symbol=S/RES/1874%282009%29.
11
Some make the opposite argument, that ongoing negotiations with North Korea may have
slowed their nuclear and ballistic missile programs. By implication, sanctions may have done
more harm than good. See e.g., Wit, Joel S. “Enhancing U.S. Engagement with North Korea.”
Washington Quarterly 30, no. 2 (Spring 2007): 53-69.
12
Another issue is timing. Joshua Stanton has suggested that new types of sanctions developed
in the last decade make older studies of sanctions effectiveness less relevant. Communication
with the authors, July 2016.
13
Miller, Nicholas L. “The Secret Success of Nonproliferation Sanctions;” Hufbauer et
al. Economic sanctions reconsidered: History and current policy.
10

Scholarly research on the utility of sanctions can be plotted on a continuum between ‘sanctions
optimists’ and ‘sanctions skeptics.’ Optimists argue that sanctions are “underrated” and often are
“more effective than most analysts suggest.”14 Skeptics argue that sanctions are not particularly
useful, or that they may cause more harm than good.

Sanctions optimists point to several cases that appear to have been effective, including sanctions
on Libya (terrorism, proliferation), Iran (proliferation), South Africa (human rights), and a U.S.-
organized boycott of Iraqi oil after Saddam Hussein’s invasion of Kuwait.15

Lesser known cases of possible success include U.S. and Canadian sanctions on South Korea in
1975 that resulted in Seoul’s cancellation of a planned reprocessing plant; U.S. sanctions on El
Salvador in 1987, which successfully resulted in that country’s agreement not to release
prisoners accused of killing Americans;16 and Indian sanctions on Nepal in 1989, after which
Nepal subsequently agreed not to buy weapons from China.17 Liberia and Yugoslavia have also
been cited as UN sanctions successes.18

14
Rogers, Elizabeth S. “Using economic sanctions to control regional conflicts.” Security
Studies 5, no. 4 (1996): 43-72.
15
Martin, Lisa L. “Credibility, costs, and institutions: Cooperation on economic
sanctions.” World Politics 45, no. 03 (1993): 406-432.
16
Pape, Robert A. “Why economic sanctions do not work.” International Security 22, no. 2
(1997): 90-136.
17
Ibid.
18
McMahon, Robert. UN Sanctions: A Mixed Record (Backgrounder). Council on Foreign
Relations. November 17, 2006. http://www.cfr.org/international-organizations-and-alliances/un-
sanctions-mixed-record/p12045#p3.
11

Box 1. How Do Sanctions on North Korea Compare to Those Imposed on Iran?


Iran and North Korea have both faced U.S. and international sanctions. Sanctions on the two have varied,
in part, because of the countries’ different economic circumstances.19 Iran depends on international sales
of oil, while North Korea relies on the sale of coal and commodities to China. Because of the global
nature of oil sales and Iran’s close ties to the international financial system, Tehran was vulnerable to the
application of targeted sanctions.20
In contrast, North Korea’s coal and commodities trade is concentrated on a primary client nation—China.
Encouraging UN member states to refrain from purchases of North Korean coal has little impact, as most
countries do not buy North Korean coal. In addition, coal sales for the purpose of economic development
(rather than in support of prohibited weapons programs) are specifically exempted from international
sanctions, as codified in United Nations Security Council Resolution (UNSCR) 2270.
Recently, the U.S. government designated North Korea as a “primary money laundering concern,” thus
triggering a new set of financial sanctions. The European Union, Russia, and other countries have also
announced new financial sanctions, consistent with the obligations of UNSCR 2270.21
Many have welcomed these new measures, but North Korea’s reliance on the coal trade with China
minimizes its engagement with the global financial system. The North Korean regime’s onshore accounts
inside of the Chinese national economy place them largely outside of the reach of financial sanctions
related to SWIFT and other mechanisms. Chinese customers directly pay China-based North Korean
state trading companies for their purchase of North Korean coal. The North Korean entities then deposit
those funds into onshore accounts.22 The absence of transnational settlement of payments helps the North
avoid SWIFT-centered actions. Compared to North Korea, Iran’s greater integration into the global
economy makes it far more vulnerable to U.S. and international sanctions.23

19
Eckert, Sue and Thomas Biersteker. The Impacts And Effectiveness Of UN Nonproliferation
Sanctions: A Provisional Report on the Targeted Sanctions on Iran and North Korea.
International Security Research and Outreach Programme, International Security and Intelligence
Bureau. 2012. http://www.international.gc.ca/arms-armes/assets/pdfs/Report-
CCDP_Sanctions.pdf
20
Iran Project, “Weighing the Benefits and Cost of International Sanctions against Iran.” New
York: The Iran Project. December, 2012: 1-86.
https://www.scribd.com/document/115678817/IranReport2-120312-2; Gary Samore. Sanctions
Against Iran: A Guide to Targets, Terms, and Timetables. Report for Belfer Center for Science
and International Affairs, Harvard Kennedy School, June 2015.
http://belfercenter.ksg.harvard.edu/files/Iran%20Sanctions.pdf.
21
Perlez, Jane. “US Sanctions Expected to Hit Small Banks’ Business with North Korea.” The
New York Times, June 3, 2016. http://www.nytimes.com/2016/06/04/world/asia/us-sanctions-
expected-to-hit-small-banks-business-with-north-
korea.html?action=click&pgtype=Homepage&module=well-region&region=bottom-
well&WT.nav=bottom-well&hpw&rref=world&_r=0; European Council. “North Korea: EU
Adopts New Restrictions on Trade, Financial Services, Investment and Transport.” May 27,
2016. http://www.consilium.europa.eu/en/press/press-releases/2016/05/27-dprk-new-
restrictions/; “Russian Central Bank Halts Dealings with N. Korea.” The Chosun Ilbo, July 9,
2016. http://english.chosun.com/site/data/html_dir/2016/05/23/2016052301327.html.
22
July 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
23
Wertz, Daniel and Ali Vaez. “Sanctions and Nonproliferation in North Korea and Iran: A
Comparative Analysis.” FAS Issue Brief, June 2012.
12

The sanctions skeptics point to their own set of cases: U.S. sanctions against Cuba, Sudan, and
China over human rights; UN sanctions against the Taliban in 2001 and 2010; sanctions against
Rhodesia, which caused white Rhodesians to rally behind their government; among others.24
Some analysts have suggested that recent sanctions against Syria and Russia have also been
unsuccessful, but it would appear too early to make an assessment.25

Given the significant variation across countries, sanctions regimes, and other factors, it is
difficult to make generalizations about the effectiveness of sanctions using case studies alone.
To overcome this problem, some scholars have turned to medium- and large-n studies. The view
from this ‘wide angle’ approach to the study of sanctions is not generally encouraging. As one
study concluded, “economic sanctions have little independent usefulness for pursuit of
noneconomic goals.”26 Even where sanctions appear to have been effective, skeptics have
argued that those successes are mostly attributable to other factors (e.g., the threat of military
force). In one study, a researcher identified only five clear cases out of 115 attempts in which
sanctions alone were successful.27 In recent years, the emergence of new, targeted sanctions has
gained momentum, but there is “no systematic evidence that smart sanctions will yield better
policy results.”28

The dispute over the efficacy of sanctions remains unresolved. Indeed, this seemingly simple
question may in fact be so broad and complex that clear, straightforward answers will remain
elusive. Regardless, the existing literature on sanctions does offer lessons. First, sanctions are
more likely to be successful when their goals are limited and clearly defined.29 Second, they are

http://www.ncnk.org/resources/publications/Comparative_Iran_North_Korea_Sanctions.pdf/?sea
rchterm=sanctions.
24
Cortright, David and George A. Lopez. The Sanctions Decade: Assessing UN Strategies in the
1990s. Lynne Rienner Pub. 2000.
25
Ashford, Emma. “Not So-Smart Sanctions: The Failure of Western Restrictions Against
Russia.” Foreign Affairs 95 no. 1. (January/February 2016).
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/russian-federation/2015-12-14/not-so-smart-sanctions.
For a more positive view of the effect of sanctions on Russia and Syria, see Rosenberg,
Elizabeth, Zachary K. Goldman, Daniel Drezner, Julia Solomon-Strauss. “The New Tools of
Economic Warfare: Effects and Effectiveness of Contemporary U.S. Financial Sanctions.”
Center for a New American Security, April 15, 2016, pp. 23-25. http://www.cnas.org/new-tools-
of-economic-warfare#.V2Nezlc3Fzcv
26
Pape, Robert A. “Why economic sanctions do not work.”
27
Ibid.
28
Drezner, Daniel W. “Sanctions sometimes smart: targeted sanctions in theory and
practice.” International Studies Review 13, no. 1 (2011): 96-108. More recently, Rosenberg et al
found that contemporary financial sanctions do not have a strong impact on traditional economic
measure like GDP growth but do affect other economic activity such as private investment. It is
worth repeating that the real measure of sanctions effectiveness is not the ability to impose costs
but rather the capacity to alter state behavior. Rosenberg, et al. “The New Tools of Economic
Warfare: Effects and Effectiveness of Contemporary U.S. Financial Sanctions,” 15.
29
Eckert, Sue and Thomas Biersteker. The Impacts And Effectiveness Of UN Nonproliferation
Sanctions: A Provisional Report on the Targeted Sanctions on Iran and North Korea.
13

more likely to be effective when the targets are friendly or democratic countries.30 Third, when a
political consensus and commitment is achieved, multilateral sanctions are generally more
powerful than purely national sanctions.31

Research on North Korea Sanctions


The academic literature on sanctions suggests that policymakers should temper their
expectations. Sanctions have been effective in some cases, and they have not been effective in
many others. Certain characteristics of the sanctions regime or the target state may make
sanctions more or less efficacious. As regards North Korea, in particular, the research provides
cause for caution. North Korea has some attributes that make it more susceptible to sanctions
(e.g., dependence on China), as well as others that make it less so (e.g., lack of exposure to
international financial institutions). Given the opaque nature of the DPRK, scholars face an
especially demanding challenge when trying to assess the impact of sanctions. Despite the
obstacles, a number of analysts have examined the effects of sanctions on the Hermit Kingdom.32

The research literature on North Korea sanctions roughly falls into three schools of thought
regarding their effectiveness in halting North Korea’s weapons of mass destruction (WMD)
programs, though most assessments are skeptical about the influence of sanctions on North
Korea.33

The first school posits that despite the conventional wisdom that North Korea is the world’s most
heavily sanctioned country, there is a great deal of room for expanding sanctions. Stanton and
Lee are strong proponents of this viewpoint.34 A second school argues that sanctions on North

30
Hufbauer et al. Economic Sanctions Reconsidered, 3rd Edition, 2009.
31
Martin, Lisa L. Coercive cooperation: Explaining multilateral economic sanctions. Princeton
University Press, 1993. Other researchers have found that as a sanctions regime expands in size,
so does defection. Early, Bryan and Robert Spice. “Economic Sanctions, International
Institutions, and Sanctions Busters: When Does Institutionalized Cooperation Help Sanctioning
Efforts?” Foreign Policy Analysis (2014), 0, 1-22.
32
National and international sanctions are not the only instruments that are employed to deny the
DPRK access to weapons-related goods. There is an extensive system of national laws that are
intended to deny the export or impede the import of sensitive technologies. In addition, there are
national policy initiatives aimed at blocking the financing, transport, and other aspects of WMD
procurement. There are also multilateral regimes whose purpose is to prevent the transfer of
nuclear and missile technology, including the Nuclear Suppliers Group, the Missile Control
Technology Regime, the Proliferation Security Initiative, and International Atomic Energy
Agency (IAEA) safeguards, among others.
33
Drezner, Daniel W. “Sanctions Sometimes Smart: Targeted Sanctions in Theory and Practice.”
International Studies Review 13, no. 1 (March 2011): 96-108; Rosenberg et al. “The New Tools
of Economic Warfare: Effects and Effectiveness of Contemporary U.S. Financial Sanctions,” 58;
Kang, David. “An Interview with David Kang: The New Sanctions Regime against North Korea
and Its Implications for U.S. Policy.” Interviewed by Claire Chaeryung Lee. Policy Q & A.
National Bureau of Asian Research, March 17, 2016.
34
Lee, Sung-Yoon and Joshua Stanton, “Make Pyongyang Pay – Stop North Korea by hitting it
where it hurts: its wallet,” Foreign Policy, February 10, 2016; Stanton, Joshua. “North Korea:
14

Korea have been largely ineffective due to the lack of sanctions implementation. Despite being
obligated to implement UNSCR sanctions, the track record shows that many UN members have
not done so. Without follow through, most analysts expect that North Korea-focused sanctions
will continue to be ineffective.35 A third school focuses on the larger macroeconomic trends and
the trading relationship between North Korea and China. Noland and Haggard show that trade
with China provides a coping mechanism for the North Korean regime.36 Highly skeptical of
Chinese implementation of DPRK-focused sanctions to begin with, Noland and Haggard note
that the growing opportunities for North Korean entities to draw on credit from Chinese partners
insulates North Korean state trading companies from the reach of sanctions. Early’s Busted
Sanctions focuses on the role of private Chinese companies that have been effective “third-party
spoilers” in procuring illicit components.37

Many of the concerns raised by each of these schools are echoed in the findings of the UN Panel
of Experts. The Panel, whose charge is to monitor and report on international sanctions against
the North, provides perhaps the most authoritative source on the implementation and
effectiveness of DPRK sanctions. Established by the UN Security Council in 2009, the Panel
has periodically reported to the Security Council with analysis and recommendations. Its
February, 2016 report identifies a number of problem areas in the current sanctions regime. The
shortcomings include a lack of reporting by member states (both “a low rate of reporting” and
“the poor quality and lack of detail” in reports that are filed), the absence of regular inspection
and seizure, and the need for domestic implementing legislation. More generally, the Panel finds
a “lack of capacity and political will” to aggressively pursue the sanctions. The result, says the
Panel, is that “sanctions have not prevented the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea from
gradually improving and expanding its nuclear and ballistic missile capabilities.” 38

This conclusion should not come as a surprise. In addition to the collective action problems
inherent in a sanctions regime, the limited capacities of some states, and differing political
interests among the relevant parties, there are basic structural issues that make enforcement
difficult.

The Myth of Maxed-Out Sanctions.” Fletcher Security Review 2, No. 1 (21 January 2015).
http://www.fletchersecurity.org/#!stanton/c1vgi
35
U.S. Government Accountability Office. “United States Has Increased Flexibility to Impose
Sanctions, but United Nations Is Impeded by a Lack of Member State Reports.” Washington,
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, May 2015. http://gao.gov/assets/680/670170.pdf; Eckert,
Susan. “United Nations Sanctions on DPRK: Implementation Evasion, and Opportunities to
Strengthen.” Providence: Watson Institute for International and Public Affairs. June 15, 2015, 1-
16.
36
Haggard, Stephan and Marcus Noland. “Engaging North Korea: the efficacy of sanctions and
inducements,” in Etel Solingen, ed., Sanctions, Statecraft, and Nuclear Proliferation
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2012), 241-243.
37
Early, Bryan. Busted Sanctions: Explaining Why Economic Sanctions Fail (Stanford, CA:
Stanford University Press, February 2015).
38
Report of the Panel of Experts established pursuant to resolution 1874 (2009). February 24,
2016; 10, 11, 65. http://www.un.org/ga/search/view_doc.asp?symbol=S/2016/157.
15

The first is simple geography. The DPRK sits astride China, the second largest economy in the
world and until recently, a country enjoying double-digit rates of economic growth. The simple
fact that the North shares a permeable 875-mile border with an economic powerhouse makes the
task of isolating North Korea more difficult.39

A second unalterable reality is economic, namely that North Korea is pursing its weapons
programs at a moment in history that is characterized by the rise of globalization, international
and intra-regional trade, and decentralized and distributed manufacturing. These trends have had
transformative effects on the economies of Asia, but it is an ecosystem that has created new
opportunities for North Korea to pursue the procurement of weapons-related technologies.

Third, given the volume of international trade, especially in East Asia, there are limits to what
can be physically inspected. It is simply not reasonable to expect that customs officials can
physically inspect even a fraction of what passes through ports and other transit points.40

In sum, most assessments of sanctions on North Korea conclude that Pyongyang has been able to
evade international constraints and continue its pursuit of banned weapons systems.41 Moreover,
the January, 2016 nuclear test and the subsequent February satellite launch suggest that the
North’s capabilities are advancing, even if slowly.42 What is particularly striking about North
Korea’s improving capabilities is that it they have continued, or perhaps even accelerated, in the
face of Washington’s’ increasing application of sanctions. As the U.S. has stepped up its
pressure, the DPRK has responded, adapted, and become even more skilled at evading
sanctions.43

39
Albert, Eleanor, and Beinz Xu. “The China-North Korea Relationship.” CFR Backgrounder,
February 8, 2016. http://www.cfr.org/china/china-north-korea-relationship/p11097.
40
Bliss, Jeff. “U.S. Backs off All-Cargo Scanning Goal with Inspections at 4%.” Bloomberg,
August 13, 2012. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2012-08-13/u-s-backs-off-all-cargo-
scanning-goal-with-inspections-at-4-; McNeill, Jena Baker, and Jessica Zuckerman. “The Cargo-
Screening Clog: Why the Maritime Mandate Needs to Be Re-examined.” The Heritage
Foundation Backgrounder #2357. January 13, 2010.
http://www.heritage.org/research/reports/2010/01/the-cargoscreening-clog-why-the-maritime-
mandate-needs-to-be-reexamined.
41
See for example, Rosenberg et al. “The New Tools of Economic Warfare: Effects and
Effectiveness of Contemporary U.S. Financial Sanctions,” 58.
42
The January nuclear test, while unlikely to have been a test of a hydrogen bomb as the DPRK
claimed, was nonetheless a successful, if small, nuclear test that may have used a fission-fusion
design. And the results from the satellite launch suggest modest improvement in North Korea’s
long-range rocket technology: it can carry a heavier payload farther into the Earth’s atmosphere.
Other reports regarding warhead miniaturization, tests for a submarine launched ballistic missile
program, test of an engine for an ICBM, a successful test of an intermediate range rocket, and
progress with solid-fueled rockets—while not fully assessed—suggest potential areas of DPRK
progress.
43
As Bryan Early points out, “North Korea was subject to U.S. sanctions for decades even
before the international sanctioning effort started. They learned a lot and had a long-established
procurement network in place to build upon when the sanctions against the regime were
16

What’s Missing? Alternative Perspectives on North Korea Sanctions


Previous research on North Korea sanctions has provided a useful picture of the political,
institutional, and other barriers that undermine sanctions. Its conclusions are consistent with the
historical track record, which points to North Korea’s increasing nuclear and missile capabilities
even in the face of increasing sanctions.

Still, there are aspects of North Korea sanctions that have received less attention and that could
strengthen our understanding of the problem and what to do about it. This study focuses on two
such areas.

The first is looking at the phenomenon of DPRK sanctions from a North Korean perspective.
Much of the research on DPRK sanctions is directed at countries other than North Korea, i.e., the
countries imposing (or not imposing) sanctions. Instead, one can focus on how North Korea has
responded with tactics to evade sanctions. Sanctions can be thought of as a multi-move, iterative
game of action and adaptation.44 Any given set of sanctions may be less important than the
adaptation that is adopted by the targeted country and the ability of the sanctioning parties to
respond to that adaptation. In short, this study looks at evasion by the sanctioned rather than
implementation by the sanctioners.

Second, one can go beyond the initial question of whether sanctions are effective or ineffective
and instead consider a broader range of possible outcomes. In principle, sanctions, like any
policy instrument, could at any given point make things better, have no impact, or make matters
worse. In a sanctions context, that translates into 1) reducing the North’s ability to procure
weapons technology, 2) having no impact on the North’s procurement capacity, or 3)
unintentionally advancing the North’s weapons programs.

How this Study was Conducted


To understand the evolving North Korean response to national and international sanctions, this
research project interviewed North Korean defectors with operational knowledge of the DPRK’s
commercial and procurement practices. Among the more than 30,000 North Korean defectors
now residing in South Korea, there is a small group of former North Korean state trading
company managers. These operators conducted procurement and sales activities directly for the
North Korean regime.

strengthened. No other country in the world has had more experience in developing strategies
for circumventing sanctions than North Korea.” This would seem to be particularly relevant
(and reason for reflection) given the new emphasis on financial sanctions and the DPRK’s early
experience involving Banco Delta Asia. As Joshua Stanton notes, “Banco Delta Asia and the
relaxation of pressure in 2007 ended up being a terrific training exercise for Bureau 39. They
have burrowed down. So while they continue to use banks that run NK transactions through
correspondent accounts in the U.S., they are effectively concealing the beneficial owners of
many of those accounts.” Early, Bryan. Communication with the authors, July 2016. Stanton,
Joshua. Communication with the authors, July 2016. On Banco Delta Asia, see footnote 51.
44
For an example of a formal game theoretic model, see Morgan, Clifton T. and Bapat, Navin
“Imposing Sanctions: States, Firms, and Economic Coercion.” International Studies Review
(2003) 5(4), 65–79.
17

For this study, more than 40 interviews with a dozen STC managers were conducted. All who
were interviewed had worked for North Korean companies sometime within the last three years
of the interviews (2010-2012). Interviewees were asked about how STCs function. How were
contracts negotiated? How was insurance obtained? How does a DPRK trading company
partner with a private Chinese company, and what are the responsibilities of the Chinese
partners? What methods are employed for payment and delivery?

Given the limited pool of defectors with experience in North Korean trading companies, the
research design used here is less a survey than it is a business case study—an attempt to a)
document the pathways, partners and practices the DPRK uses for procurement, and b) chart the
ways in which the DPRK regime’s behavior has evolved (and remained the same) over time.

A second set of interviews was directed at policymakers and commercial firms in the region,
including China, South Korea, Hong Kong, and Singapore. The goal of the interviews was to
learn about North Korean processes and practices, but also to better define the governmental and
commercial contexts in which sanctions and illicit procurement operate.

These interviews have greatly enhanced our knowledge of how North Korea, Inc. operates, but it
is important to underscore the limits and uncertainties in this initial research. First, while the
interview data represents the largest, non-classified pool of interviews on North Korean STC
managers, the number of officials interviewed is necessarily small. STC managers make up a
tiny fraction of the total pool of defectors. It also represents a snapshot in time—how STC
managers in a particular cohort behaved. It is hoped that additional research in this area will
reach more North Korean defectors and generate a time series that allows scholars to observe the
evolution of STC behavior. This will be critical insofar as one of the core findings of this study
is that sanctions should be thought of as an iterative game in which the target country will
innovate and adjust in response to actions taken by sanctioning governments.

Finally, this initial interview series cannot answer every question the researchers would have
liked to address. There are limits on the number and depth of the subjects one can explore, and
in conducting the research, one learns new information and understandings that can only be used
in subsequent interview series. So, for example, while the interviews undergirding this study
cover procurement activities that include both licit and illicit commerce, we cannot with
precision distinguish between illicit goods that were on control lists versus catchall lists versus
other dual use technologies and materials. We can say with confidence, however, that even this
modest effort has generated new insights and new ways of thinking about the challenge of the
DPRK’s illicit procurement.
18

II. North Korea, Inc.: The Evolution of North Korea’s State Trading Companies

The North Korean regime procures a wide variety of goods and services from international
markets. Some of this procurement, including everyday items used by the general population, is
legal. Other procurement is illegal, because it contravenes UN, U.S., or other sanctions. Illegal
procurement involves either proscribed goods and services (e.g., nuclear and missile related
technologies) or designated individuals and entities that have been banned from participating in
international commerce.

The people who procure goods and services, legally and illegally, on behalf of the North Korean
regime, mainly work for North Korean STCs. It is their job to find sellers and partners and to
arrange for the delivery of procured items to the DPRK. STCs are at the heart of North Korea’s
efforts to circumvent international sanctions. Consequently, this study focuses primarily on their
activities.

This section examines how North Korean STCs have operated over time. It first looks at STC
practices prior to 2000 and then STC behavior after 2000. It concludes with an assessment of
how Pyongyang’s practices have evolved: what has changed and what has remained the same
over time.

The Origins of STCs in the 1980s


The North Korean regime launched the present day form of STCs in the early 1980s. Newly
created STCs were employed as a mechanism for raising funds for the 13th World Festival of
Youth and Students. South Korea was slated to host the 1988 Summer Olympics, and
Pyongyang hoped to avoid being overshadowed by its neighbor and rival to the south. North
Korea convened over 22,000 people from 177 countries for the 13th World Festival of Youth and
Students, which was held in Pyongyang in 1989. The games caused the DPRK to incur a
massive debt, but the development of the STC concept had shown promise and would become a
model for subsequent iterations in the late 1990s.45 A key architect of what became the current
STC structure was reportedly Jang Song-taek, the uncle of North Korean leader Kim Jong-un.46

After the Fall of the Soviet Union


During the Cold War, the DPRK depended on state-to-state trade with its Communist allies in
Moscow and Eastern Europe, as well as with countries in the Middle East. North Korean
officials would procure goods from mostly state entities and transport the items on North Korean
freighters or Soviet-era transport planes chartered in Ukraine or the Russian Far East. Illicit
goods were relabeled on the shipping manifest, and the North would oversee their clandestine
shipment to the DPRK. North Korean procurement was less sophisticated then. Acquisitions

45
For a collection of archival documents illustrating North Korean prestige concerns stemming
from the 1988 Seoul Olympics, see Wilson Center Digital Archive, “1988 Seoul Olympic
Games,” http://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/collection/70/1988-seoul-olympic-games/; Park,
John. “North Korea, Inc.,” U.S. Institute of Peace Working Paper, April 2009, 6-7.
46
July 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
19

were limited by physical constraints, but defectors report that these evasion techniques were
reliable and effective.47

With the collapse of the Soviet Union and political transitions in Eastern Europe, Pyongyang had
to look elsewhere for trading partners.48 With the STC architecture already in place from the 13th
World Festival of Youth and Students, North Korea began to establish a more robust system of
STCs. The STCs’ focus was increasingly on China, and in particular, on the border between to
the two neighbors. STCs looking for either legal or illicit goods sought parts and materials from
cross-border trade with private Chinese companies—companies often run by Chinese nationals
of Korean ethnicity. Agents working for the North’s STCs would make frequent but brief trips
to China to arrange the transactions.

One of the fundamental but more ignored aspects of the DPRK’s procurement system is that it is
not a fully dedicated proliferation network. Instead, pieces of Pyongyang’s procurement network
combine licit and illicit procurement. It expanded its commercial activities in a manner that
allows it to move banned components and materials within this larger flow of legitimate
business.

The DPRK paid for its purchases with revenues from various illegal enterprises, including sales
of recreational drugs, counterfeit pharmaceutical drugs, cigarettes, counterfeit bills, and arms
(e.g., ballistic missiles). The DPRK also used monies earned by North Korean laborers working
abroad as well as trade in commodities such as fish and coal.49

47
Park, John. “The Key to the North Korean Targeted Sanctions Puzzle,” The Washington
Quarterly 3, no. 37 (November 1, 2014): 199-214; July 2014 research interviews with defectors
in Seoul.
48
While the focus of this study is rightly China, several countries and their nationals have played
critical roles in North Korean weapons programs, including Russians (missile program) and
Pakistanis (nuclear program.) For example on Russia, see “Former Soviet Researches Aid N.
Korea’s Missile Development.” KBS World Radio, June 28, 2016.
http://world.kbs.co.kr/english/news/news_Po_detail.htm?lang=e&id=Po&No=120002&current_
page.
49
Greitens, Sheena Chestnut. “Illicit: North Korea’s Evolving Operations to Earn Hard
Currency.” Washington, DC: Committee for Human Rights in North Korea, 2014.
https://www.hrnk.org/uploads/pdfs/SCG-FINAL-FINAL.pdf; Noland, Marcus. “How North
Korea Funds its Regime.” Testimony before the Subcommittee on Federal Financial
Management, Government Information, and International Security Committee on Homeland
Security and Governmental Affairs, United States Senate, April 25, 2006.
https://piie.com/commentary/testimonies/how-north-korea-funds-its-regime.
20

North Korean Procurement Practices After 2000


After 2000, North Korea, Inc. began a new phase, one that resulted in a deeper penetration of
both China and regional economic hubs.50 This period is defined by three major events: the
sanctioning of Banco Delta Asia (BDA) in Macau, the visit to North Korea by China’s Premier
Wen Jiabao in 2009, the death of Kim Jong-il in 2011 and subsequent succession of Kim Jong-
un. The first event demonstrated to the DPRK that it needed to develop new, less vulnerable
forms of finance. The second had the effect of opening the door to new Chinese partners,
including local Chinese banks. The third event is more difficult to assess, but Kim Jong-un’s
accession has been accompanied by an emphasis on both economic growth and illicit military
technologies, making STCs all the more important.

In the mid-2000s, the U.S. Treasury Department designated North Korean accounts in BDA as
money-laundering concerns. This, in turn, led the Macanese monetary authority to freeze these
accounts.51 For almost a year, North Korea was unable to access its funds, which totaled
approximately US$24 million. Washington and Pyongyang reached a political agreement to
resume the stalemated Six-Party Talks in return for unfreezing these accounts, but even with an
agreement in hand, the U.S. had difficulty arranging the release of the frozen funds to North
Korea. Eventually it facilitated a wire transfer of the balances from Macau to a private bank in
Moscow via the U.S. Federal Reserve System. The North Koreans promptly withdrew the funds
from this Russian bank.

The BDA episode demonstrated to the North Koreans that their illegal activities were vulnerable
to U.S. sanctions against international banks, especially those using dollars. The DPRK would
have to find new partners and new instruments of finance that would allow them to operate
outside the reach of the U.S. Treasury Department. Serendipitously, for the DPRK, Premier
Wen’s subsequent visit to North Korea precipitated a chain of events that provided Pyongyang
with access to the partners and instruments it sought via the Chinese market.

In October 2009, Wen led a senior Communist Party of China (CPC) delegation to Pyongyang.
While ostensibly celebrating the sixtieth anniversary of the establishment of Sino-DPRK
diplomatic relations, the premier brought an entourage including the chief planners and
implementers of Chinese internal economic development. Wen signed bilateral agreements with
the Workers’ Party of Korea (WPK) in the areas of economic development, education, and
tourism.52 Initially dismissed by analysts as propaganda, these agreements effectively facilitated
the creation of the bilateral mechanism through which North Korean STCs were able to expand

50
This study demarcates DPRK procurement before and after 2000, because the 2000s represent
the period where the DPRK begins to deploy STCs more proactively in China. The second half
of the 1990s was defined by the famine and efforts at stabilization. Beginning in the 2000s,
North Korea starts to more affirmatively pursue foreign commerce as well as the procurement of
nuclear and missile related items.
51
July 2015 research interviews with private sector firms in Hong Kong.
52
Park, John. “Assessing the Role of Security Assurances in Dealing with North Korea,” Chap. 9
in Security Assurances and Nuclear Nonproliferation (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press,
August 2012).
21

their export of coal to China and enhance their procurement capabilities within the Chinese
national economy.53

Moreover, the agreements signaled to private Chinese firms that it was permissible to do
business with DPRK entities. In particular, it made it possible for the North to find Chinese
firms that could help with the procurement of dual use and other high value items.

The timing of Wen’s October visit was critical, as it came after the DPRK’s second nuclear test
in May of 2009. Following the test, both the U.S. and the United Nations imposed new sanctions
on the North, including financial sanctions. This combination of new sanctions and new
opportunities to contract with private Chinese partners had powerful interactive effects.

Chart 1. North Korea Trade, 2001-201454

Finally, no account of this time period would be complete without reference to Kim Jong-un’s
rise to power. It is still early in the young Kim’s tenure to assess the full ramifications of this
political transition, but already there have been changes, most notably the new byungjin policy,
which seeks to simultaneously increase North Korea’s nuclear weapons arsenal and develop its

53
August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
54
Annual reports on North Korean economic performance released by the Bank of Korea, and
available at “DPRK Economic Statistics.” NK Econ Watch. http://www.nkeconwatch.com/north-
korea-statistical-sources/. This chart reports on all DPRK except for that between North Korea
and South Korea, which is reported separately. Data for China-DPRK trade from the Korea
Trade-Investment Promotion Agency, Korea International Trade Association, and the ROK
Ministry of Unification document the same pattern. For a useful source of public data on the
DPRK economy, see: Melvin, Curtis. Ed., North Korea Economy Watch,
http://www.nkeconwatch.com
22

national economy.55 Certainly, for North Korean STC managers pursing illicit weapons
technology, the message is full speed ahead.56

North Korea’s Adaptations


The combination of greater access to the Chinese market, new sanctions, and later, an increased
demand for economic growth and illicit technologies under Kim Jong-un precipitated a dramatic
shift in DPRK procurement. In particular, five changes to the STC system are noteworthy.

1) Employment of more capable Chinese middlemen


With improved bilateral economic relations following Wen’s visit, the DPRK regime expanded
its use of private Chinese middlemen. It also contracted with more capable private firms than it
had in the past. New sanctions raised the risk of doing business with North Korea, as the U.S.
and others had hoped, but Pyongyang responded by paying higher fees to compensate for the
increased risk. Higher fees, in turn, drew larger and more sophisticated Chinese partners.

Essentially, Pyongyang is able to rent the procurement capabilities of Chinese firms. New,
larger, and more sophisticated brokers provided Pyongyang with a number of additional
capabilities. These included:

Enhanced access to local Chinese suppliers and foreign firms located in China
North Korean STCs operating in China often use third parties to obtain goods that they otherwise
could not acquire. The STCs, acting in their own name or through a shell company, contracted
with private firms in China. The Chinese brokers, in turn, signed contracts with Chinese
suppliers. The suppliers assume they are doing business with a Chinese firm, not a North Korean
one. Once the brokers acquired the targeted goods from the unsuspecting supplier, they were
transferred to the intended endpoint, the DPRK.

A similar arrangement is used to place orders with Western companies that have established their
own production platforms in China. Tapping into this segment of the Chinese economy has
proven to be particularly valuable for Pyongyang. Foreign firms in China constitute a gateway to
the international market but with significantly lower exposure to risk, compared with directly
trying to procure goods from Western companies in their home markets.57

More precise procurement


Buying the services of larger more sophisticated Chinese partners allowed the DPRK to expand
the number and kinds of firms it could target for procurement. It enabled North Korea to search
for specialty, hard-to-find goods that its less capable partners (e.g., along the border) cannot
acquire. In short, Pyongyang achieved greater precision in its procurement.

55
Snyder, Scott A. “The Motivations Behind North Korea’s Pursuit of Simultaneous Economic
and Nuclear Development,” CFR, November 20, 2013, http://blogs.cfr.org/asia/2013/11/20/the-
motivations-behind-north-koreas-pursuit-of-simultaneous-economic-and-nuclear-development/
56
August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
57
Chinese middlemen would also place orders to foreign firms’ subsidiaries in other parts of
Asia, such as Japan. August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
23

Box 2. DPRK Adaptations

1) Employment of more capable Chinese middlemen


Enhanced access to Chinese suppliers and foreign firms located in China
More precise procurement
Outsourcing of logistics
Bulk payments and broker financing

2) Embeddedness in China
Building procurement relationships and developing tacit knowledge
Chinese banks and on-shore accounts

3) Use of Hong Kong


4) Use of commercial hubs in Southeast Asia

5) Increased use of embassies and diplomatic personnel for procurement

Specialized products range from dual-use industrial equipment manufactured on a foreign


company’s China-based assembly line to luxury items imported directly from their country of
origin into China. The combination of 1) readily accessible specialized products and 2)
specialized services for hire has substantially bolstered the DPRK’s procurement capabilities.58

Outsourcing of logistics
For an extra fee, Chinese middlemen often manage procurement logistics for their North Korean
clients, including receipt from a supplier and shipment to the DPRK. This makes for a smoother
procurement pathway and also diminishes the risk associated with illicit acquisition.59 Gone are
the days of having to rely exclusively on North Korean ships secretly ferrying parts from a port
in the Middle East. Chinese partners instead hide North Korea’s relatively small consignments
amid the massive volume of regular commercial activity within China’s domestic market. Once
in this flow, defectors noted that the consignment would essentially be “hiding in the open.”

The DPRK’s Chinese partners target sea and land routes that are congested, and where rates of
inspection are low. Although an option, commercial aviation is rarely used largely due to its
high cost. The main advantage of using air is expedited delivery and the infrequent inspection
of checked packages at airports. In Beijing Capital International Airport, it is common to see
large packages wrapped in cardboard but rarely inspected by airline representatives before they
are moved along and stored in the airplane’s cargo compartment. From there, it would be a

58
July 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
59
Aaron Arnold suggests that a comparison might be made to “the evolution of narco-trafficking
post-Medellin cartels. In order to minimize risk, the Columbian cartels outsourced logistics to
Mexican drug trafficking orgs, like the Zetas and Sinaloa cartels.” Arnold, Aaron.
Communication with the authors, July 2016.
24

direct flight to Pyongyang Sunan International Airport. The same is true for direct flights
originating from Shanghai Pudong International Airport.60

For an additional fee, a Chinese broker will not only arrange for the acquisition and transport of
illicit goods but will also cover up the illicit transfer. One defector explained how this operated
in the case of advanced medical imaging equipment exported by a Japan-based manufacturer.
The Chinese broker not only arranged for the export of the item but also engaged in an elaborate
deception to hide the identity of the end user (North Korea). When the Japanese supplier sought
to confirm the export’s end use, the broker arranged for hospital representatives to create a false
“transfer trail,” so that the inspector from the Japanese manufacturer was endlessly visiting
Chinese hospitals in search of the equipment. By the time the company inspector returned to the
Chinese hospital listed in the original purchase documents, the medical diagnostic equipment had
long since been shipped to North Korea.61

Bulk payments and broker financing


Doing business with larger PRC firms permits the DPRK to rely on bulk payments and broker
financing. This reduces the need for STC cash up front, and reduces the risk associated with
illicit transactions. The DPRK can now structure contracts that allow North Korean
representatives to pay for the bulk of the transaction—approximately 80-90%—upon final
delivery to North Korea. In the interim, the PRC firm directly pays for the procured item. This
new practice also has the effect of weeding out smaller and less capable Chinese middlemen.62

Defectors stress the importance of this arrangement for STC managers. In the eyes of the North
Korean leadership, an STC manager is responsible for a missing delivery. A failed deal is
detrimental to a manager’s career.

2) Embeddedness in China
With new opportunities in China, more North Korean STCs began to relocate their operations to
the mainland. The move to embed inside the Chinese market signified a shift from what had
previously been primarily trans-border procurement facilitated by brief business trips. As a
consequence, the STCs are able to 1) build deep relationships and develop tacit knowledge, and
2) take advantage of the Chinese banking system.

60
August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul. STC managers report that civil
aviation flights are particularly well suited to the transport of physically small but critical goods
such as electronic components. They suggest that, contrary to expectations, air transport is
relatively easy—a claim that appears to be borne out by the near absence of reported
interdictions involving Chinese civil air transport.
61
July 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
62
Lesser middlemen would lack the capital to self-fund the purchase of a shipment. That type of
market actor would likely lead a hand-to-mouth existence, where almost all of the revenue it
earned on a deal would immediately go to settling expenses. The margins would be so small that
this type of broker would be focused on daily survival and thus represent a more risky partner.
July 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
25

Building procurement relationships and developing tacit knowledge


Rather than making quick trips or a short-term posting abroad, STC managers now reside in
Chinese commercial hubs with their families.63 Their children attend local international schools.
On the mainland, North Korean managers are viewed and treated much like other foreign
businessmen making deals.

This new arrangement—i.e., normalcy—enables these managers to sink roots in local


communities and gain access to local resources. The tacit knowledge (i.e., informal knowledge
generated from direct experience) and relationship building acquired by working in China
enables North Korean managers to more effectively navigate the Chinese economy and the world
of private Chinese middlemen. North Korean STCs have even bought into Chinese firms and
then with ownership rights, used the Chinese firms to carry out wire transfers and conduct other
activities outside the sanctions regime.64

Chinese banks and on-shore accounts


Moving more of its procurement network to the mainland also allows the DPRK to take
advantage of the Chinese banking system. Pyongyang set up on-shore accounts in China with
the funds generated from North Korea’s coal sales to Chinese customers. DPRK officials then
drew on these accounts for funds to purchase technology, luxury goods, and other banned items.
Having access to a Chinese bank account allowed DPRK managers to transfer money within the
Chinese banking system, using private Chinese middlemen. When a private Chinese middleman
wired funds on behalf of its North Korean STC client, the documentation recorded it as a
Chinese company making the transfer. As a result, it was difficult for the Chinese government to
detect illicit activity.65

Having access to Chinese bank accounts also helped the DPRK avoid using U.S. dollars.
International wire transfers in dollars typically pass through American banks, where illicit
transactions can be detected and funds seized. North Korean STCs benefited enormously from
Chinese bank accounts that permitted them to avoid these risks. Defectors pointed out that these
onshore accounts constituted the foundation upon which the North Korean regime had been
carefully building a foothold inside of China’s domestic market.66 This trend continues today.
Indeed, the use of onshore banking accounts set up by Chinese brokers may very well be the
main counter-measure North Korean STC managers employ against the new banking and
financial sanctions.

3) Use of Hong Kong


As a Special Administrative Region of China, Hong Kong operates as an open commercial and
financial hub. The existence of deep, well-developed, financial markets in Hong Kong help
North Korean STCs monetize their business risks. By paying higher fees to reflect higher risk in
a post-nuclear test, post-financial sanctions environment, North Korean STCs have been able to

63
Defectors who experienced this expat lifestyle explained how they sent their children to local
international schools. July 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
64
August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
65
July 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
66
August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
26

take advantage of Hong Kong’s central role in trade and finance, including the privileged
relationship Hong Kong-based entities enjoy with their mainland counterparts. The North
expanded STC branches in Hong Kong, which made it even easier to use Chinese middlemen on
the mainland to execute deals and transport procured goods.

4) Use of commercial hubs in Southeast Asia


North Korean STCs frequently use their bases of operations in mainland China and Hong Kong
to develop relationships with individuals and firms in Southeast Asian commercial hubs and to
establish bank accounts throughout the region.

STCs often reach out to “Hwa-gyos,” the Korean term for ethnically Han Chinese North Korean
citizens or their descendants who live abroad. By leveraging North Korean cultural ties, the
DPRK can take advantage of the fact that many Hwa-gyos are wealthy businessmen. Thus, a
combination of cultural affinity and monetized risk is often sufficient to persuade these unique
businessmen to provide loans or front-end financing for North Korean STCs.67

North Korea’s bank accounts in Southeast Asia are useful for money laundering and local
procurement. An STC manager provides cash to a Chinese middleman who, in turn, wires the
sum from point A in northern China to point B in southern China. From there, the broker
arranges for the funds to be wired to a financial institution in a Southeast Asian country. Once in
country, the funds can be used for a host of purposes, from paying a local firm to ship a
consignment to processing payment for a transit fee.68

A court case in Singapore in August 2015 documents how North Korean STCs pay local firms to
conduct activities designed to evade sanctions—particularly with respect to arranging wire
transfers for payments to foreign counterparties.69

5) Increased use of embassies and diplomatic personnel for procurement


North Korea abuses its diplomatic privileges to support its procurement efforts abroad. North
Korea has traditional diplomatic relations with most countries, particularly in Asia. It has
embassies and diplomatic representation in these countries, where it is accorded normal consular
privileges. These privileges include the use of diplomatic “pouches” which can travel through
countries and across borders without the risk of search. Diplomatic couriers carrying these
pouches enjoy immunity from arrest.70 The DPRK has taken advantage of this system and used

67
Park, John. “The Key to the North Korean Targeted Sanctions Puzzle.”
68
July 2015 research interviews with private sector firms in Singapore.
69
An August 2015 court case in Singapore illustrates how this sort of arrangement can work: on
July 8, 2013, Chinpo Shipping Company of Singapore reportedly transferred US$72,000 to
Panama shipping agent C B Fenton and Co. for a vessel transporting weapons from Cuba to
North Korea. The prosecution alleged that Chinpo agreed to make the payment on behalf of
North Korean entity Ocean Maritime Management for Chong Chon Gang, one of its vessels, to
travel through the Panama Canal. Singapore Public Prosecutor v. Chinpo Shipping Company
(Private) Limited, 2016. Case No. DSC 900002-03 of 2014.
70
Over time the concept of a diplomatic “pouch” has evolved to include larger cartons, even
shipping containers.
27

diplomatic personnel both as agents engaged in illicit procurement and as couriers who transport
unreported cash and other illicit items. If caught, they can be expelled, however.

The improper use of embassies was cited in 2013 in UNSCR 2094, and reaffirmed in UNSCR
2270 (2016), which expressed “continued concern that the DPRK is abusing the privileges and
immunities accorded under the Vienna Conventions on Diplomatic and Consular Relations.”71

The use of embassies and diplomatic personnel provide the DPRK with several advantages from
a procurement perspective. Defectors note that the North Korean regime co-locates shell
companies with its overseas embassies in countries that are particularly active commercially.
This permits managers to operate their firms with a lower level of scrutiny from local law
enforcement.72

In addition, credentialing an STC official as a diplomat enables that individual to reside in the
designated country for a longer period. This arrangement provides an opportunity for an STC
manager to further develop working relationships with middlemen and build up commercial
expertise related to the local market. As a recent defector pointed out, “in the end, all
procurement is local.”73

The Evolving DPRK Revenue Stream


Just as the North’s procurement modalities have evolved over time, so has the mix of revenue
sources that it uses to finance purchases of licit and illicit items. Money made from the sale of
illegal drugs, cigarettes, pharmaceuticals, weapons systems and counterfeit bills have declined in
relative terms over time.74 A variety of factors explain this outcome with particular causes
depending on the type of trade involved. In some cases, sanctions have created new barriers; in
others, the market for those items has changed as additional suppliers have entered the global
marketplace. In some cases, the emerging competitors have been non-state actors such as
criminal enterprises (e.g., counterfeiting rings in Thailand).75

As these illicit sources of revenue have declined, the DPRK’s export of coal and human labor
has increased. At its peak in the early 2010s, some 90% of the North’s exports were sold to
China. For years, China famously bought up commodities to feed its growing economy. In
2015, North Korea was China’s third largest provider of coal behind Australia and Indonesia.76

71
UN Security Council Resolutions 2094 and 2270 are available at:
http://www.securitycouncilreport.org/un-documents/dprk-north-korea/.
72
August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
73
August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
74
There is some evidence that North Korean counterfeiting may be making a come back. See
footnote 118.
75
Greitens, Sheena Chestnut. “Illicit: North Korea’s Evolving Operations to Earn Hard
Currency;” Noland, Marcus. “How North Korea Funds its Regime.”
76
July 2015 research interviews with South Korean government officials in Seoul.
28

During the second half of the 2000s, the DPRK regime earned record sums as the international
commodity price of coal almost tripled compared to the first half of the 2000s.77 But during the
1st quarter of 2015, South Korean diplomats posted in China reported a decline in North Korea’s
coal sales and revenue with China. The first factor accounting for the decline in the coal trade
was the PRC government’s newly instituted environmental standards. DPRK coal was sent back
by China because of its high sulfur content. Second, a decline in the economic value of the trade
reflected a drop in the international price of coal. The monetary value of the North’s coal
exports declined, as prices for commodities declined. The drop in commodity prices represented
the biggest shock yet to North Korea’s once highly lucrative coal trade.78

North Korea has also raised revenue by sending laborers to work abroad, especially in Chinese
factories, and Russia’s timber and construction industries.79 Coordinating closely with Chinese
partners, select North Korean STCs have been steadily expanding the number of North Korean
workers in China. The vast majority of the wages they earn from their Chinese employers are
sent back to the North Korean leadership’s affiliated organizations in bulk cash shipments that
are physically transported back to Pyongyang. This scheme enables the regime to evade
financial sanctions. Defectors report that the North Korean workers only receive about 10
percent of their wages.80

Jang Song-taek and North Korea’s Commercial Relations with China


Stepping back, one cannot describe the North’s commercial relationship with China without
reference to Jang Song-taek, Kim Jong-un’s uncle by marriage. Following the death of Kim
Jong-il until his surprise execution in December 2013, Jang was arguably the most senior and
powerful official in Pyongyang other than Kim Jong-un. Jang was the DPRK official with the
closest ties to Beijing, having personally met with Premier Wen, President Hu Jintao, and an
array of senior Chinese officials. In particular, Jang oversaw economic cooperation with the
PRC and used that position to build a large patronage network whose main purpose was trade
and procurement.

77
August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
78
July 2015 research interviews with South Korean government think tank analysts in Seoul;
Solomons, Ilan. “New Sanctions Could Cripple Reclusive North Korea’s Mining Sector.” Mining
Weekly, May 27, 2016. http://www.miningweekly.com/article/new-sanctions-could-cripple-
reclusive-north-koreas-mining-sector-2016-05-27/rep_id:3650. In the early 2010s, Pyongyang’s
total quantity of coal exports rebounded and actually increased, but the increased volume did not
make up for the declining price.
79
Snyder, Scott A. “North Korea’s Latest Export: Labor.” Forbes, May 22, 2015.
http://www.forbes.com/sites/scottasnyder/2015/05/22/north-koreas-latest-export-
labor/#7ef0e18d4e33.
80
July 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
29

At the time of his death, analysts tried to make sense of the dramatic turn of events. Some
wondered whether the execution signaled a potential change in relations with China, and in
particular, a turn away from economic cooperation and development with Beijing.81

In the end, Jang’s execution did not portend a shift in economic relations with China. While
some of the senior members of Jang’s network were recalled or some punished, it did not result
in a wholesale closing or restructuring of Jang’s institutional apparatus. Some of his top officials
were retained as well as the larger infrastructure. Kim apparently preferred to take control of
Jang’s network rather than rooting it out. Many officials remained in China to do Pyongyang’s
bidding. Indeed, in some cases, the post-Jang regime generated new opportunities for those
working in the North’s STCs, as it afforded the chance to change jobs and join a different trading
company.82

The Evolution of DPRK Trading Practices over Time


As one charts North Korean procurement from the 1990s into the 2000s, following the 2009
DPRK-PRC economic agreements, and then again after the rise and fall of Jang Song-taek, there
are both continuities and changes. Among the consistent features of North Korean trade and
procurement are the use of shell companies, the use of embassies, the export of laborers, and the
centrality of the Chinese market—both as a source of revenue and a vehicle for procurement.

The evolution in DPRK trade and procurement can be seen in Pyongyang’s choice of partners,
pathways, and practices.

At one level, the centrality of China as North Korea’s main trading partner remains constant.
Within China, however, the past decade has witnessed significant changes in the North’s
selection of commercial partners. Over time, Pyongyang has increasingly turned to private
Chinese firms rather than party bureaucrats and state-owned entities, and more crucially, to
private Chinese middlemen. Rather than providing goods themselves, these middlemen facilitate
the procurement of materials and technology by acting as agents for the North, thus masking
Pyongyang’s role. In addition, the character of the brokers has evolved, as Pyongyang has
attracted larger, wealthier, and more sophisticated Chinese partners.

The North’s ability to attract more capable Chinese firms has allowed it to adopt new practices.
It has been able to target the procurement of whole systems rather than parts and to more
effectively procure goods from foreign firms operating in China. The use of more sophisticated
Chinese partners has also allowed changes in the contracts and financial structure of procurement
deals, for example, by having Chinese firms cover the upfront costs of procurement in many
instances.

Finally, the procurement pathways have changed. Over time, the DPRK has moved from a
reliance on local, cross-border procurement towards operations deep inside the mainland. North

81
Kuhn, Anthony. “An Execution In North Korea Has A Chilling Effect In China.” NPR,
January 10, 2014. http://www.npr.org/sections/parallels/2014/01/10/261412968/an-execution-in-
north-korea-has-a-chilling-effect-in-china
82
August 2014 research interviews with defectors in Seoul.
30

Korean STCs have become embedded in China, where they are part of the normal Chinese
business environment. This shift to on-site procurement has been supplemented by efforts to
expand regional procurement nodes, in Hong Kong and throughout Southeast Asia. The use of
DPRK couriers and diplomats for illicit commercial purposes illustrates the North’s efforts to
diversify its procurement pathways.

III. The Unintended Consequences of Sanctions on North Korea

Conceptualizing Unintended Consequences


Debates over sanctions in general, and over North Korea sanctions in particular, tend to focus on
whether sanctions are effective or ineffective. Less discussed are the potential unintended
consequences of sanctions. In principle, these unintended consequences might affect 1) North
Korea, 2) the governments that impose sanctions on North Korea, and 3) third parties.

It is important to distinguish the popular notion of unintended consequences from the way the
term is used here. In common parlance, unintended consequences are almost always associated
with negative outcomes. In the typical narrative, a government enacts a policy with good
intentions, but in practice, other inadvertent effects overwhelm the good outcomes leaving the
situation worse than before the policy was adopted. In contemporary policy debates, reference to
unintended consequences can be a “gotcha moment,” where the identification of an unintended
consequence is commonly used to delegitimize a policy.

The concept of unintended consequences presented here is more descriptive and neutral than
normative or evaluative. Most, if not all, policy actions generate unintended consequences.
Moreover, unintended consequences include a range of potential outcomes. These vary across
two dimensions: from positive to negative and from significant to insignificant. And regardless
of whether a given unintended consequence is positive or negative, significant or insignificant,
unintended consequences can change over time. Thus, unintended consequences are seen here as
dynamic: an effect that is negative in one phase of policy implementation could turn out to be
positive at a subsequent point or vice versa.

Table 1. Types of Unintended Consequences

Positive Negative
Significant Maximize Minimize
Insignificant Monitor Monitor

Medicines provide a useful analogy here. A drug taken to combat a bacterial infection might
also improve the complexion of one’s skin—a positive but not particularly consequential
unintended effect. Other medications can heighten the risk of stroke: a negative and more
consequential event. Some medications are effective when first taken but wane in efficacy over
time, even as the negative side effects increase over the same period. More broadly, an antibiotic
might cure an infection for an individual patient, but the widespread use of this effective
treatment might, in time, produce resistant strains of bacteria that have the effect of leaving a
population more vulnerable to disease.
31

In general, one should expect and plan for unintended consequences. Moreover, this planning
process should anticipate the likelihood that unintended consequences evolve, especially under
conditions where a policy takes the form of an iterative game of actions and reactions over an
extended time horizon.

The Unintended Consequences of Sanctions on North Korea


Sanctions on North Korea are precisely the kind of policy arena where one might expect an
evolving set of unintended consequences: sanctions on the DPRK have been imposed for
decades. As previously noted, they have resulted in counter-moves by Pyongyang, and in some
cases, responses to those counter-moves by the international community. These iterative actions
and reactions over an extended period of time have contributed to the evolution of the North
Korean sanctions regime, North Korea’s responses to it, and the unintended consequences that
follow.

The task here is to identify these possible unintended consequences—positive and negative,
significant and insignificant—and to specify how they may have changed over time.

Negative Unintended Consequences of Sanctions on North Korea

1) Strengthens North Korean capabilities (“sanctions conundrum”)


A key, counter-intuitive finding of this study is that sanctions on the DPRK had the net effect of
strengthening Pyongyang’s procurement capabilities, what might be called the “sanctions
conundrum.” U.S. and international sanctions did have the intended effect of increasing the risk
of doing business with North Korea, Inc., but Pyongyang responded by monetizing the risk and
offering to pay higher commission fees to middlemen. These higher fees, in turn, drew larger
and more sophisticated private Chinese brokers. With more capable partners, the North’s
procurement progressed from predominantly border trade in parts to the acquisition of systems
and a network of Chinese facilitators that stretched from the mainland to Hong Kong and to
commercial hubs throughout Southeast Asia.

Having identified the “sanctions conundrum,” it is worth stepping back and putting it in a
theoretical context. First, it is unlikely that the relationship among risk, higher fees, and rates of
participation by Chinese brokers is continuous and absolute. Presumably, there are extremely
high levels of risk that even very high fees cannot overcome. Imagine, for example, that Chinese
middlemen faced the death penalty for working with North Korean clients, and that the brokers
believe that the risk of getting caught is substantial.83 At the other end of the curve, small
increases in fees for small increases in risk might not provide sufficient incentives to attract the
larger, more capable Chinese firms. The charts below illustrate these basic concepts. Chart A
represents a simple, continuous model. Chart B posits a more realistic, but unconfirmed model.

83
Bryan Early points out that Malaysia did institute the death penalty for violations of strategic
trade laws. To be clear, our reference is intended as an illustration, not a policy
recommendation. Early, Bryan. Communication with the authors, July 2016.
32

Chart 2. Continuous Relationship Among Chart 3. Notional Estimated Relationship Among


Cost, Risk, and Broker Participation Cost, Risk, and Broker Participation

The research presented in this study—using interviews with North Korean defectors—offers a
snapshot of this phenomenon, that is, it tells us what STC managers saw at a particular moment
in time. Ideally, one would want to have data from a series of interviews over time. A time
series would enable analysts to estimate where current sanctions are on the risk/fees/brokers
curve. If, for example, policymakers were confident that the DPRK could no longer compensate
for sanctions by monetizing the risk (the right hand side of the curve), it would suggest one set of
options. If it appeared that the DPRK could still overcome sanctions by paying higher fees, and
that as a consequence they could actually augment their procurement capabilities, it would
suggest caution and a different set of policy instruments.

In the absence of additional data, this analysis will assume that the “sanctions conundrum” is still
in play, namely that it has not yet reached a point where increased fees do not attract Chinese
partners.

While theoretical, this discussion is likely to be relevant in the very near term. As a result of
recent UN, U.S., Russian, and European efforts to close North Korean correspondent banking
accounts, it would seem likely that the DPRK would respond by increasing its use of brokers to
an even greater level. For example, Chinese and other middlemen could be asked to establish
new bank accounts or use their existing ones to facilitate DPRK procurement activity without
North Korean fingerprints.

It remains to be seen whether this effect persists at higher levels of sanctions and over time, but a
sanctions regime that actually improved the North’s procurement capabilities is perhaps the
quintessential unintended consequence.

2) Incentivizes collaboration with illicit networks and states of concern


The old adage suggests that my enemy’s enemy is my friend. In the case of North Korea, a
sanctions regime could, in theory, incentivize Pyongyang to collaborate with other entities that
participate in illicit trade or are themselves the target of sanctions. The former might include
33

criminal and other non-state actors. In the latter category would be other sanctioned states such
as Syria, Iran, Myanmar, Russia, and the like.84

There is some evidence of North Korean cooperation with other sanctioned states. The North
surreptitiously began construction of a nuclear reactor in Syria (later bombed by Israel). In
addition, there were allegations of cooperation between Myanmar and the DPRK, though its
extent remains unclear. And it may be that this cooperation ended following Myanmar’s
agreement with the United States and the international community to begin a transition to
democracy.85 In the 1990s in particular, North Korea reportedly sold small arms and missiles to
customers in the Middle East. Technology sharing between the North and Iran is well
documented in the area of missiles, though allegations of cooperation on nuclear technology
have never been substantiated. The missile exchanges occurred largely in the past, and the
recent Iran nuclear agreement may render such activity less likely in the future.86

There is evidence of North Korean collaboration with criminal and other entities, particularly in
the area of drug trafficking.87 Anecdotal evidence points to collaboration with Russian criminal
organizations, for example.

Of course, the North may have had other motivations for its cooperation with sanctioned entities
even absent sanctions. And in any case, it appears that the effects of such cooperation have not
substantially altered the capabilities of any of the partners involved. It may be that even
countries like the DPRK are reluctant to cooperate with organizations that are seen as
untrustworthy or unaccountable.

84
U.S. sanctions have been lifted on Myanmar. U.S. and international sanctions have been
partially lifted on Iran. Before these changes there was speculation about North Korean
collaboration with both states. See Boye, Catherine, Melissa Hanham and Robert Shaw. “North
Korea and Myanmar: A Match for Nuclear Proliferation?” Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists.
September 27, 2010. http://thebulletin.org/north-korea-and-myanmar-match-nuclear-
proliferation; and Taylor, Guy. “U.S. Urged to Block any North Korean Support for Iranian
Nukes.” Washington Times. January 28, 2016.
http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2016/jan/28/n-korea-iran-nuclear-ties-probably-deep-
report/?page=all.
85
Albright, David, Paul Brannan, Robert Kelley, and Andrea Scheel Stricker, “Burma: a Nuclear
Wannabe, Suspicious Links to North Korea and High-Tech Procurements to Enigmatic
Facilities,” ISIS, January 28, 2010, http://isis-online.org/uploads/isis-
reports/documents/BurmaReport_28January2010.pdf.
86
It is worth noting that despite numerous opportunities to do so, “the Director of National
Intelligence has never claimed Iranian-DPRK nuclear coordination even as the DNI has pointed
to missile cooperation between the two countries and testified as to Syrian-DPRK nuclear
cooperation.” See Walsh, James. “The Iran-North Korea Strategic Alliance.” Testimony before
the House Committee on Foreign Affairs, July 28, 2015.
http://web.mit.edu/ssp/people/walsh/Walsh%20HFAC%20Testimony%207-28-2015.pdf.
87
Arnold Aaron. Communication with the authors, June 2016; Greitens, Sheena Chestnut.
“Illicit: North Korea’s Evolving Operations to Earn Hard Currency.”
34

3) Hinders positive forms of engagement


Throughout the Cold War competition between the United States and the Soviet Union, there
were a small number of nuclear and other experts from both countries that met in order to keep
lines of communication open, and according to some observers, to help the Soviets understand
the full ramifications of what it meant to be a nuclear weapons state. Paul Doty and his
colleagues at Harvard and MIT were deeply involved in such efforts, as was Pugwash and other
groups. Looking back, many observers believe that these exchanges had a positive impact on the
course of the Cold War, making it less dangerous than it otherwise would have been.88

As regards North Korea, private individuals—academics, retired officials, and others—have


visited North Korea over the years for talks with DPRK officials. These exchanges in North
Korea as well as other meetings in “neutral” countries have provided a vehicle for
communication in the absence of formal diplomatic relations. On occasion, these visits have
yielded information that was communicated to the U.S. government that directly affected U.S.
policymaking.89

So far, U.S. and international sanctions have not prevented these kinds of interactions, but new
rounds of restrictions may have the inadvertent effect of discouraging, constraining, or even
preventing those exchanges.90 It is difficult to measure the impact of positive engagement
beyond individual cases and the testimony of U.S. policymakers who have pointed to the value
of having alternative sources of information on North Korean intentions. One can imagine that
this is a circumstance in which the value of positive engagement is generally modest—until a
particular moment arrives when it suddenly becomes critical. If that is the case, and sanctions
inadvertently inhibit those information flows, then policy makers may 1) miss opportunities to
advance their policy goals with the DPRK and 2) miss opportunities to prevent a crisis or some
other negative outcome.

4) Imposes costs on the North Korean civilian population


Sanctions can hurt vulnerable civilian populations.91 In recent years, the U.S. has emphasized
targeted sanctions, ones that seek to avoid imposing significant costs on average citizens. The

88
Homans, Charles. “Track II Diplomacy: A Short History.” Foreign Policy, June 20, 2011.
http://foreignpolicy.com/2011/06/20/track-ii-diplomacy-a-short-history/; “Pugwash Conferences
on Science and World Affairs - History.”
http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/peace/laureates/1995/pugwash-history.html; Martin,
Douglas. “Paul Doty, Biochemist and Arms Control Advocate, Dies at 91.” The New York Times,
December 6, 2011. http://www.nytimes.com/2011/12/07/science/paul-doty-biochemist-and-
arms-control-advocate-dies-at-91.html.
89
U.S. officials have confirmed that information reported from these interactions has generated
new and important data that reached the highest levels of the U.S. government.
90
South Korea, whose national laws regulate interactions between North and South Koreans,
may be seeking to reduce these exchanges. “S. Koreans Fined for Unauthorized Contact with N.
Koreans.” The Korea Herald, June 13, 2016.
http://www.koreaherald.com/view.php?ud=20160613000567.
91
Pape, Robert A. “Why economic sanctions do not work;” Pape, Robert A. “Why economic
sanctions still do not work.” International Security 23, no. 1 (1998): 66-77.
35

interest in targeted sanctions reflects a new American sensitivity to the humanitarian costs of
sanctions. This is, in part, a consequence of U.S. sanctions against Iraq in the 1990s, which were
widely seen as having had a devastating impact on Iraqi civilians. 92

Still, even targeted sanctions have had adverse economic and societal.93 Sanctions on Iran, for
example, typically had “carve outs” that exempted food, medicines, and other humanitarian
goods. Despite these exceptions, U.S. sanctions on Iran appeared to have had a negative impact
on the delivery of humanitarian goods, as risk-averse banks and related entities avoided any
involvement with Iran, even in the face of clear statements by the U.S. Treasury Department that
such trade was permitted.94 (This problem of “de-risking is discussed below in the context of
“compliance culture.”)

To date, humanitarian organizations working in the DPRK have not reported that past U.S. and
international sanctions have substantively interfered in the delivery of humanitarian aid. That
may be changing, however. There are some indications that the international push for sanctions
may have negative effects on non-governmental organizations (NGOs) operating in the North.
As some countries have moved to impose their own national sanctions on the DPRK, they have
not consistently provided exemptions for humanitarian aid. It appears that South Korean
restrictions, for example, have slowed or even prevented humanitarian assistance.95 Officials
concerned about humanitarian aid have also cited recent problems with the UN World Food
Program’s ability to provide assistance to the DPRK.96 All this comes at a time when the Kim
government has ominously warned of an “arduous” march ahead and imposed two consecutive
loyalty campaigns intended to extract even more resources from the North Korean population.

http://www.jstor.org.libproxy.mit.edu/stable/4329469.
92
Baram, Amatzia. “The Effect of Iraqi Sanctions: Statistical Pitfalls and
Responsibility.” Middle East Journal 54, no. 2 (2000): 194-223; Hoskins, Eric. “Humanitarian
Impacts of Sanctions and War in Iraq,” in Political Gain and Civilian Pain: Humanitarian
Impacts of Economic Sanctions, edited by Thomas Weiss, David Cortright, George Lopez, and
Larry Minear, 112. New York: Rowman & Littlefield, 1997.
93
Rosenberg et al. “The New Tools of Economic Warfare: Effects and Effectiveness of
Contemporary U.S. Financial Sanctions,” 20.
94
Setayesh, Sogol, and Tim K. Mackey. “Addressing the impact of economic sanctions on
Iranian drug shortages in the joint comprehensive plan of action: promoting access to medicines
and health diplomacy.” Global Health 12 No. 31 (June 8, 2016).
http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC4897941/; Namazi, Siamak. “Sanctions and
Medical Supply Shortages in Iran.” Viewpoints. Washington: Wilson Center Middle East
Program, February 2013.
https://www.wilsoncenter.org/sites/default/files/sanctions_medical_supply_shortages_in_iran.pd
f.
95
Padden, Brian. “How Will Sanctions Affect North Koreans?” Voice of America, April 11,
2016. http://learningenglish.voanews.com/a/how-will-sanctions-on-north-korea-affect-its-
people/3277042.html
96
For example, see Kim, Hyunjin. “Cash-strapped World Food Program Cuts Aid to N. Korea.”
Voice of America. October 01, 2015. http://www.voanews.com/content/cash-strapped-world-
food-program-cuts-aid-north-korea/2987790.html
36

Going forward, it will be particularly important to monitor the impact of sanctions on


humanitarian relief. This is true for two reasons. First, there have been suggestions that the
North may be facing a significant food security issue in the coming months. North Korean
officials suggested in June of 2015 that they were facing the worst drought in a century, though
NGO personnel on the ground have yet to report strong evidence of this. More recent
assessments by the UN suggest, however, that the food security issues are real.97 Second, the
current economic slowdown in China may negatively affect economic conditions in the DPRK,
putting the general population at greater risk. In a “military first” society, workers and peasants
will be last in line if foods, medicines, and other humanitarian goods become scarce. Some
combination of draught, economic slowdown, and sanctions might trigger a new humanitarian
crisis in the Hermit Kingdom.98

5) Increases risk of triggering North Korean collapse


One assumption underlying U.S. policy towards North Korea in the 1990s was the belief that a
DPRK economic collapse was in the offing. With an economy that lacked a countrywide
transportation network and suffered a chronically insecure food supply, it was an understandable
assumption. The North Korean famine did take a terrible toll, and Pyongyang’s once totalitarian
control over every aspect of North Korean life frayed. The reality, however, is that there are two
North Koreas—the 99% and the 1%. While the former continues to struggle, the latter has
thrived in the past decade.

A sanctions-induced collapse of the DPRK is, on its face, unlikely.99 North Korea’s government
has proven, despite predictions to the contrary, to be highly resilient. It has survived the loss of
the Soviet Union and other patrons, the famine of the 1990s, two familial transfers of power,
decades of sanctions, several failed attempts at economic reform, and international isolation.
The notion that some future round of sanctions might tip the balance seems implausible.

97
“North Korea Says it Faces Worst Drought in a Century.” BBC News. June 17, 2015.
http://www.bbc.com/news/world-asia-33160768; UN Food and Agriculture Organization. “The
Democratic People’s Republic of Korea Outlook for Food Supply and Demand in 2015/16
(November/October).” April 27, 2016. http://www.fao.org/3/a-i5572e.pdf. For an alterative
view, see Ireson, Randall. “Why Headlines about DPRK Agricultural Production Miss the
Point.” 38 North, May 6, 2016. http://38north.org/2016/05/ireson050616/.
98
Padden, Brian. “North Korea Sanctions Pose Human Rights Dilemma.” Voice of America,
April 8, 2016. http://www.voanews.com/content/north-korea-sanctions-pose-human-rights-
dilemma/3275962.html.
99
For a different view, see Olson, Wyatt. “Retired USFK Head: North Korea Collapse May
Happen Sooner.” Stars and Stripes, May 25, 2016. http://www.stripes.com/news/retired-usfk-
head-north-korea-collapse-may-happen-sooner-1.411276. Some analysts point to a growing
number of defections as a possible indicator of problems within North Korea. “Number of N.
Korean Defectors Rises Again this Year.” Yonhap News Agency, June 5, 2016.
http://english.yonhapnews.co.kr/news/2016/06/05/0200000000AEN20160605000600315.html;
Jun, Ji-hye. “Defections Point to Instability in North Korea.” The Korea Times, May 25, 2016.
http://www.koreatimes.co.kr/www/news/nation/2016/05/116_205448.html.
37

Moreover, at least one important actor—China—has a core interest in preventing such an


outcome.100

Still, policymakers and scholars are not very good at predicting or anticipating state collapse.
From the Soviet Union to the Arab Spring, state failure has been easier to explain after the fact
than to forecast. This likely reflects a number of factors, including the relative opacity of
troubled states and a lack of information about various interaction effects between events.
Different factors, each of which may be individually small may combine in unpredictable ways
to set off a downward spiral.

It is worth noting in this regard that sanctions against North Korea have increasingly targeted the
North’s commodities industry, with the February, 2016 UN Security Council (UNSC)
resolutions seeking to stop Pyongyang’s coal and iron ore exports—or at least those whose
revenues are used for weapons programs. These sanctions have broad exemptions, but it is
precisely these kinds of sanctions, ones aimed at the North’s core sources of state revenue, which
could induce the broadest and most unexpected effects.

In sum, the risk of inadvertently inducing a DPRK collapse would seem to be small, but that risk
could grow or be larger than we imagine, and the consequences could be catastrophic. It also
seems unlikely that the U.S. and the international community know enough about the internal
workings of the North to be able to calibrate the effects of the pressure they impose on the
regime.

6) Increases risk of sanctions overreach that could backfire


With the effective application of targeted sanctions against Iran, there have been growing calls,
primarily from Congress, for the greater use of sanctions. In response to these calls, Treasury
Secretary Jack Lew felt compelled to respond publicly. Lew declared that while sanctions can be
potent “… they are not the answer to every threat we face.”101

An overuse of sanctions could lead friendly countries to defect from a sanctions regime. It could
also incentivize governments to build alternatives to the dollar and the American banking
system, and encourage sanctioned countries to form a cooperative bloc.102

100
Chinese President Xi Jinping said as much during an April 28, 2016 speech in which he said
“we will absolutely not permit war or chaos on the peninsula.” See Martina, Michael. “China
Won’t Allow Chaos or War on Korean Peninsula: Xi.” The Fiscal Times. April 28, 2016.
http://www.thefiscaltimes.com/latestnews/2016/04/27/China-wont-allow-chaos-or-war-Korean-
peninsula-Xi.
101
Lew, Jack. Remarks of Secretary Lew on the Evolution of Sanctions and Lessons for the
Future at the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. March 30, 2016.
https://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/jl0398.aspx.
102
For a more expansive version of this argument that suggests that U.S. financial sanctions
could create incentives to revise the structure of the global financial system to undermine U.S.
financial power, see Arnold, Aaron. “The True Cost of Financial Sanctions.” Survival 58 no. 3
(May 2016): 77-100. See also Rosenberg et al. “The New Tools of Economic Warfare: Effects
and Effectiveness of Contemporary U.S. Financial Sanctions,” 13, 38-39. Others would argue
38

Lew cautioned, “To preserve the effectiveness of sanctions over the long term, we must use them
wisely. We must clearly articulate our goals, and we must provide relief when those goals are
met.”103

Sanctions against North Korea are unlikely to tip the balance and lead to a backlash or other
responses that undermine the long-term utility of U.S. sanctions. North Korea is not a
particularly popular country in the international system, and its economic footprint is small. One
can imagine, however, a scenario in which unintended consequences combine, where a
humanitarian disaster or collapse in North Korea creates greater animosity towards U.S.-led
sanctions and a financial system dominated by the dollar.

Positive Unintended Consequences

1) Generates a market for compliance


Markets get created in many ways, and one way is that policymaking produces the need for a
good. The U.S. sanctions on North Korea are first and foremost focused on North Korea, but
their implementation requires that private firms follow certain rules or face the risk of
punishment. This, in turn, establishes a market for “compliance.” Firms that want to avoid
punishment will respond by establishing compliance departments, hiring in-house staff, seeking
outside legal counsel, and other steps to buy the safety and stability provided by “compliance.”
This is especially true for larger banking and other financial services firms participating in
international commerce.104

A number of policy concerns have driven the development of an international compliance


architecture. Concerns about the drug trade, terrorism, money laundering, and other illicit
activities carried out by criminal organizations, political non-state actors, and nation states have
led the United States and other governments to establish rules and transparency measures to
combat these activities.

that trade with the DPRK, or even Iran, is such a small fraction of total international commerce
that it would be insufficient to motivate such a large change in international banking practices.
103
Lew, Jack. Remarks of Secretary Lew on the Evolution of Sanctions and Lessons for the
Future at the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.
104
Regarding corporate compliance incentives generated by sanctions, see Anderson, Alexandra
L. “Good Grief! Iran Sanctions and the Expansion of American Corporate Liability for Non-U.S.
Subsidiary Violations Under the Iran Threat Reduction and Syria Human Rights Act of 2012.”
Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business 34, (October 1, 2013): 125. For the
challenges of sanctions compliance that illustrates the desirability of developing a market for
compliance-related services, see Rathbone, Meredith. “Sanctions, Sanctions Everywhere:
Forging a Path Through Complex Transnational Sanctions Laws.” Georgetown Journal of
International Law 44, (January 1, 2013): 1055. Jacqueline Shire suggests that compliance
culture in private firms outside the financial sector has also grown, particularly in the area of
export controls, but that it still lags financial firms. The difference may be the absence of a
regulatory body and enforcement mechanisms found in the financial area. Shire, Jacqueline.
Communication with the authors, July 2016.
39

Sanctions on North Korea have also contributed to this process, particularly in Asia. The
continuing cycle of nuclear and missile tests followed by new sanctions has raised the profile of
North Korea and, in turn, the question of corporate compliance. The emergence of a
“compliance culture” is suggested by a number of developments.

One indicator is the emergence of a robust labor market for experienced compliance officers.
Individuals who have worked on compliance with governments (e.g., OFAC) or the UN are in
high demand in the corporate sector. In addition, a cottage industry of compliance-related
businesses appears to be developing, one that includes new professional associations and
publications, headhunters poaching talent from governments and competitors, and the presence
of American law firms in Seoul and other regional commercial hubs providing compliance-
related legal counsel.105

A second indicator is the manner in which compliance is becoming institutionalized within firms.
More CEOs are requiring frequent and direct briefings and reports on compliance, and senior
compliance officers are located at regional branches as well as corporate headquarters. These
moves are driven, in part, by the high profile fines and other punishments that the Treasury
Department has levied against firms that were found to have illicitly processed wire transfers or
payments for sanctions-designated foreign companies. Firms worry not only about fines or
losing access to the U.S. market but also about the reputational damage that prosecution would
bring.106

The unintended consequence of spurring the development of a corporate compliance culture


could prove to be a very powerful and positive unintended consequence. Increased compliance
in Asian banking and finance would strengthen the effect of future North Korea sanctions but
perhaps more importantly, could affect broader financial practices in Asia, the center of gravity
for the twenty-first century global economy.

On the other side of the ledger is the danger of de-risking. Under that scenario, a desire for
compliance leads banks, insurance companies, and other firms to avoid risk by simply ending all
commercial and financial interactions with North Korea. That over-reaction would increase the
dangers of a humanitarian crisis.107

105
See, for example, the Association of Trade Compliance Professionals,
www.complianceprofessionals.org. Across industries, chief compliance officers at publicly
traded firms earned an average base salary of $200,000 per year. Jaeger, Jaclyn. “How Does
Your Chief Compliance Officer Salary Measure Up?” Compliance Week 12, no. 142 (November
2015): 10.
106
July 2015 research interviews with private sector firms in Hong Kong and Singapore.
107
Rosenberg et al. “The New Tools of Economic Warfare: Effects and Effectiveness of
Contemporary U.S. Financial Sanctions,” 34-37; “2014 Year-End Review of U.S. BSA/AML
and Sanctions Developments and Their Importance to Financial Institutions.” Sullivan and
Cromwell LLP, January 2015. https://sullcrom.com/2014-year-end-review-of-us-bsa-aml-and-
sanctions-developments-and-their-importance-to-financial-institutions
40

2) Promotes North Korean elite engagement with the outside world


Traditionally, the DPRK has put a premium on the control of its domestic population and has
tried to limit its citizens’ exposure to the outside world. It restricts visits by outsiders as well as
travel by North Koreans to other countries. It seems acutely sensitive about South Korean
broadcasts from towers along the DMZ and message-filled balloons launched by South Korean
NGOs. It employs a closed intranet that prevents domestic access to international websites. The
regime’s core ideology, Juche, is one that devalues anything and everyone outside the North.

Absent international sanctions, in a world where Pyongyang could obtain all it wanted, it would
likely do so with the least amount of outside contact possible. It is in the political interest of the
North Korean leadership to keep the Hermit Kingdom a hermit kingdom.

Interestingly, sanctions have forced the DPRK to become more cosmopolitan, if only to be able
to find international suppliers for materials and technologies it cannot produce on its own or
obtain through simple cross-border trade with China. As Pyongyang’s procurement shifted from
cross-border to embeddedness on the mainland and expanded their activities in Hong Kong,
Southeast Asia, and beyond, more North Koreans officials have been living abroad for extended
periods of time. This trend has persisted despite the execution of Jang Song-taek.

Many analysts assume that it is better for citizens from closed, authoritarian countries to see the
outside world rather than to be cut off from it. Some contend that North Koreans abroad will see
with their own eyes that their system is failing.

In sum, sanctions have forced the North to let more of its citizens get a peek at the outside world.
It is difficult to know whether that dynamic matters, and whether it has happened in sufficient
numbers to be consequential, but it is more likely a positive effect than a negative one.

Unintended Consequences Whose Effect Could be Either Negative or Positive

1) Introduces North Korean elites to markets


As the DPRK sends more people abroad to engage in procurement, more North Koreans learn
how international markets work—how to set up contracts, acquire financing, obtain insurance,
establish logistics, and other tasks. Some of these markets are legitimate. Others are black, gray,
or underground, but they are markets nonetheless. And as North Korean STCs have hired larger
and more sophisticated Chinese brokers, they have doubtless learned new skills. One effect of
this process is that an increasing number of North Korean managers are forming their own
businesses on the side.

It is difficult to say whether this phenomenon will be positive or negative. On the one hand, it
could be said that the more North Koreans learn how to function in markets, the better. It would
be consistent with the Chinese model of economic liberalization and political evolution. Its
decision to pursue economic liberalization in the 1970s has been accompanied by an evolving
economy and less harsh domestic politics. The Chinese model is one of the few scenarios for the
future of North Korea that does not end in revolution, war, or collapse.
41

On the other hand, as more and more North Koreans acquire market skills, sensibilities, and
sophistication, it may be easier for Pyongyang to skirt sanctions and improve its ability to
acquire illicit weapons technologies. Put another way, as the North increases the capacities of its
human capital, those new capabilities can be deployed in the service of both welcome and
unwelcome objectives.

2) Fosters corruption
The study of sanctions has long suggested that sanctions breed corruption.108 Sanctions busting
is often an illegal act that requires bribes, deception, and other unsavory practices. It is probably
safe to assume that sanctions have, at least on the margins, further contributed to corrupt
practices by DPRK officials. It is less clear whether the North would be less corrupt in the
absence of sanctions. Corruption is an issue in many of the countries in the region, and there are
other features of the North’s political system that encourage corruption.109

Perhaps more important for this inquiry is the question of whether greater corruption in the North
is a good thing or a bad thing. Corruption might have the effect of reducing the efficiency of the
North’s procurement network, thus undercutting some of the gains it has made with its
increasing sophistication and capability. Widespread corruption might also contribute to popular
dissatisfaction with the government and thus hasten a political transition. Whether that is to be
welcomed or not depends on the nature of the “transition.” A Soviet style soft landing would be
welcomed; a failed nuclear weapons state with internal strife and an increased risk of conflict on
the peninsula would not.

Assessing the Unintended Consequences of North Korea Sanctions


Not surprisingly, the use of sanctions against the DPRK has had varied inadvertent effects.
Many of the potential unintended consequences considered here either have not manifest
themselves or have had only minor effects so far, e.g., incentivizing cooperation with other
sanctioned entities or increasing corruption.

108
See Andreas, Peter. “Criminalizing Consequences of Sanctions: Embargo Busting and Its
Legacy.” International Studies Quarterly 49, no. 2 (June 1, 2005): 335–60;
Rosenberg, et al. “The New Tools of Economic Warfare: Effects and Effectiveness of
Contemporary U.S. Financial Sanctions,” 19.
109
Park, Young-Ja. “Informal Political System in North Korea: Systematic Corruption of Power-
Wealth Symbiosis.” International Journal of Korean Unification Studies 24, no. 1 (June 2015):
123; Habib, Benjamin. “North Korea’s parallel economies: Systemic disaggregation following
the Soviet collapse.” Communist And Post-Communist Studies 44, (January 1, 2011): 149-159.
42

Table 2. Unintended Consequence of Sanctions on North Korea

Negative Unintended Consequences


1) Strengthens North Korean capabilities
2) Incentivizes collaboration with illicit networks and states of concern
3) Hinders positive forms of engagement
4) Imposes costs on the North Korean civilian population
5) Increases risk of triggering North Korean collapse
6) Increases risk of sanctions overreach that could backfire

Positive Unintended Consequences


1) Generates a market for compliance
2) Promotes North Korean elite engagement with the outside world

Potentially Negative or Positive Unintended Consequences


1) Introduces North Korean elites to markets
2) Fosters corruption

In this regard, it is worth remembering that this process is likely to be dynamic. It may evolve
over time such that an unintended consequence that is significant today could be less so in the
future or consequences that seem modest in likelihood or impact loom larger down the road. For
example, the ways in which sanctions actually improve the North’s procurement capabilities
could decline over time, while the risk of a sanctions-induced collapse might increase, especially
if there is a significant downturn in the Chinese economy.

In addition, nothing said in this report, including the findings regarding the “sanctions
conundrum” or other negative unintended consequences should be taken to suggest that sanctions
cannot be effective or should be avoided. Indeed, the recommendations offered in this report for
improving sanctions underline the proposition that sanctions have an important, if limited, role to
play in constraining and reversing the North’s nuclear and missile programs. Our findings
emphasize that all policy actions generate unintended consequences, and even when the effects
are negative, policymakers may nevertheless conclude that, on balance, the benefits justify the
costs. In short, this research is not an argument that sanctions are ineffective or to be avoided.
Rather, it points to the reality of unintended effects and the need for policy actors to recognize
them and respond accordingly.

Turning the Tables: The Unintended Consequences of Sanctions Evasion for North Korea
This research has been primarily concerned with North Korean innovations in the face of
sanctions and the unintended consequences of sanctions imposed on the DPRK. It is worth
remembering, however, that if all policy actions carry unintended consequences, then the
counter-measures developed by the DPRK to evade sanctions—embeddedness in China, use of
private Chinese companies, etc.—will generate unintended consequences of their own for
Pyongyang. The logic further suggests that some of these will be positive and some will be
negative, i.e., create new vulnerabilities. Put another way, North Korea’s actions to counter
sanctions may create new opportunities for governments to undermine North Korea, Inc. and its
43

WMD procurement.110 The fact that more North Korean procurement is taking place outside of
the DPRK and that the North has parked large sums of money in Chinese banks means that
North Korean procurement is more vulnerable, at least compared to the old system where STC
managers resided in the North and Pyongyang was able to exercise tighter control.

Recent high profile defections make that point, but of even more interest are the actions
Pyongyang has taken along its border.111 As STC commerce has increased and broadened, so
too has the participation of private North Korean actors in market activities along the Chinese
border. The regime has probably tolerated these business ventures, because this unregulated
commercial activity generates income for North Korean citizens, much like grey markets inside
the DPRK. Pyongyang, however, has cracked down on these activities by withholding visas for
North Koreans looking to visit China on business.112 Though it is impossible to know, it may be
that the reason for curtailing the activities of private traders is to reduce competition and increase
revenues for the state-owned trading companies also operating at the border. (The DPRK also
appears to be allowing new competition between STCs for the similar types of trade.113) If true,
it suggests both that the STC system had the unintended consequence of spurring market activity
by North Korean citizens and that this, in turn, had the effect of undercutting STCs at a time of
potential austerity. At this moment, it is difficult to assess the political or economic side effects
such actions may cause, but they illustrate the fundamental point that North Korean sanctions
evasion will generate its own unintended consequences, and that policy makers would be well
advised to monitor these dynamics and the opportunities they might provide to disrupt DPRK
procurement.

IV. Policy Recommendations

Goals and Objectives


Before enumerating various recommendations, it is important to first be clear about goals,
objectives, and the logic of the policy options being offered. This would seem obvious, and yet
much of the conversation about sanctions on North Korea, and more centrally, much of the
proposed legislation and executive action in this arena, appears confused on this score.
Sanctions can have many different and mutually exclusive goals. It is critical to separate out

110
We are indebted to the Asan Institute, which hosted a briefing on this research, and at which,
scholars offered hypotheses about how the DPRK’s evolving procurement practices could have
broader implications for the North’s future.
111
The defections have, in turn, forced Pyongyang to take new measures, which themselves may
have unforeseen consequences. Kim, Joohno. “Stung by Defections, North Korea Steps up
Indoctrination of Workers in China.” Radio Free Asia, July 1, 2016.
http://www.rfa.org/english/news/korea/korea-ideology-07012016124911.html.
112
Moon, Sunghui. “Suspension of Travel Visas to China Creates Hassles for North Koreans.”
Radio Free Asia, June 16, 2016. http://www.rfa.org/english/news/korea/suspension-of-travel-
visas-to-china-06162016154059.html.
113
“N. Korean Traders Going All Out to Receive Permits: Report.” The Korea Herald, June 20,
2016. http://www.koreaherald.com/view.php?ud=20160620000679.
44

these competing goals, not only because they may be at odds with each other, but also because
they entail wildly different probabilities of success, time horizons, and costs.

Some policymakers would be willing to eschew regime change, if Pyongyang’s missile and
nuclear programs could be frozen and rolled back. Others find that unacceptable and will settle
for nothing less than an end of the Kim regime.

Table 3. Possible Goals for Sanctions Against North Korea

Concept Description
1) Denial E.g., cutting access to WMD or other technology
2) Coercion E.g., to force North Korea to the bargaining table
3) Bargaining E.g., having something to trade for concessions114
4) Punishment E.g., for human rights violations
5) Inducing regime collapse E.g., regime change

A lack of clarity and consensus about goals is evident both in Congress and the executive branch.
On Capitol Hill, there is no shortage of legislative proposals that mix opposing goals. That is not
surprising given the nature of the legislative process and the need to attract support from
members with differing views, but one observes these conflicts within the executive branch as
well, where some officials focus on halting North Korea’s nuclear program even as others
threaten actions that would harm the North Korean people and not just the Kim leadership.115

The recommendations offered in this report focus on denial, that is, reducing and eventually
halting the DPRK’s acquisition of WMD-related materials and technology. This goal has a more
immediate timeline and a narrower focus. It also avoids some of the larger risks and potentially
negative unintended consequences of a regime change policy aimed at a nuclear weapons state.

Given a goal of reducing and even halting progress in North Korea’s nuclear and missile
programs, there are a number of objectives a government can pursue—objectives informed by
the DPRK’s recent behavior. Over the last several years, Pyongyang’s procurement has evolved
in a particular direction. North Korea has expanded the scope of its procurement efforts: moving
from the border and embedding inside China as well as using commercial hubs in Southeast
Asia. Its procurement officials are working abroad and taking up residence for a longer tenure.
It has hired more sophisticated and capable foreign partners, some of whom are ethnic Koreans.

114
Sanctions for bargaining could also include incentivizing the DPRK to cooperate with
international bodies like the IAEA.
115
In particular, talk in the media about cutting off remittances would seem to be an action that
could have an adverse impact on the civilian, non-elite population, even assuming the
government skims a sizeable share of those monies. Mohammed, Arshad and David
Brunnstrom. “US Says North Korean Remittances at Risk if it Conducts Nuclear Test.” Reuters,
April 20, 2016. http://in.reuters.com/article/northkorea-nuclear-usa-idINKCN0XG2CI.
45

It would seem to follow, therefore, that the objectives of a robust denial policy would be to
reduce the scope of North Korea, Inc.’s operations (i.e., fewer operations in fewer places), cut
the number of procurement officials working in foreign countries, decrease the tenure of DPRK
procurement officials (i.e., higher turnover), and discourage or disrupt Pyongyang’s use of
Chinese and other middlemen.

In different ways, the recommendations offered here attempt to advance these objectives. Some
of the suggestions manage to avoid the “sanctions conundrum,” for example, by disrupting North
Korea, Inc. directly. Others do not, and thus will require focused attention to insure that they do
not inadvertently increase North Korean capabilities. Many of the most important
recommendations are directed at new ways of thinking, modeling, and testing prospective policy
remedies.

It should be noted that any interested government, not just the United States, could adopt many
of these recommendations. In our discussions with policymakers in the region, it became
apparent that some recommendations might be better suited to South Korea, Japan, China or
other states. Moreover, many of the recommendations are likely to be more effective if
implemented by more than one country.

Table 4. Policy Recommendations

Engage China
1) Encourage China to use its domestic laws to counter North Korea, Inc.
2) Encourage China to send strong signals to its private industry

Build Capacity
3) Improve the capacity of national governments
4) Build the capacity of U.S. government to respond to the misuse of DPRK embassies
5) Augment the capacity of the UN Panel of Experts on North Korea

Encourage a Culture of Compliance in Private Firms


6) Prioritize the prosecution of high profile cases of sanctions violations
7) Experiment with the use of incentives

Disrupt North Korea, Inc.’s Operations


8) Reduce the scope, size, and tenure of STC managers in China and the region

Information Collection and Analysis: Methods and Models


9) Analyze DPRK procurement as a business case study
Run game simulations with procurement managers from Asia
Test potential sanction concepts with defector community
10) Employ new models for analysis
View as commercial ecosystem
Consider the mix of legitimate commerce and illicit trade
Compare with others that engage in comparable practices
Define blueprint of North Korean transaction
Track North Korea, Inc.’s behavior to see if it tells us anything more generally
11) Adopt an evidence-based and outcomes-focused approach to evaluation
46

None of the ideas discussed here promises a cure for the problem of North Korea’s weapons
programs, but taken as a whole they may advance the U.S. and international community’s ability
to slow the North’s technological advancements. They may also generate positive unintended
consequences, insofar as many of the steps would contribute to an architecture that can also be
used to counter transnational criminal groups, violent extremist organizations, and other threats.
And from a nonproliferation perspective, it makes sense to strengthen international institutions, if
not because of North Korea today, then to deter a potential, future proliferator tomorrow.

Engage China
China is far and away the most important player in North Korean trade and procurement. It is
not the only actor, as the DPRK has expanded its commercial and financial activities in
Southeast Asia and beyond, but it is the center of gravity. No sanctions regime targeting North
Korea will be successful without robust participation by Beijing.

Persuading China to increase sanctions pressure on the North has been difficult, however, as
Beijing sees that there are risks in such a policy. Too much pressure and North Korea could
crack or lash out. Pressure could also jeopardize whatever remaining leverage China has over
the DPRK. If the leadership sitting in Pyongyang sees its neighbor to the north doing the bidding
of its enemy, it may conclude that it is on its own, that it’s the North against the world. That is a
bad outcome for China and also one that makes any negotiated settlement even more difficult to
achieve. A North Korea that can trust no other government to protect its interests will be less
likely to give up its nuclear programs, even if it is promised a sufficient return in the bargain.

The policy challenge, therefore, is finding actions that can reduce North Korea’s illicit
procurement that China can fully embrace.116

1) Encourage China to use its domestic laws to counter North Korea, Inc.
How can China degrade the North Korean regime’s illicit procurement while simultaneously
minimizing the risk of a DPRK collapse and avoid alienating its neighbor to the south? One
avenue is to use existing national laws—to which China is already committed—to target Chinese
middlemen who assist the DPRK with WMD-related procurement.

First, China could deploy its already existing anti-corruption campaign. Beijing views anti-
corruption as in its self-interest. It has already committed itself to a national campaign that goes
after both “tigers and flies.” North Korea, Inc.’s use of private Chinese brokers and banks, some
of which may bribe party officials or are closely affiliated with corrupt local officials, can be
targeted within the framework of China’s ongoing anti-corruption campaign.

For its part, the U.S. and international partners could offer to assist China in this effort.
Cooperation could include capacity building in the areas of port inspections and maritime law
enforcement activities along shipping lanes between Chinese and North Korean ports.117 Pilot

116
On alternative approaches that recognize China’s national interests, see Goldstein, Lyle J.
“Time to Think Outside the Box: A Proposal to Achieve Denuclearization by Prioritizing the
China-DPRK Relationship.” North Korean Review 12, no. 1 (Spring 2016): 82-100.
117
July 2015 research interviews with private sector firms in Singapore.
47

projects focusing on training, reporting, and inter-agency coordination could promote improved
practices and monitoring. At present, port inspections are fragmented and prone to understaffing
relative to the volume of commercial activity.

Getting China to focus attention on North Korea, Inc. would be consistent with efforts that China
initiated in 2013. There were indications at that time that the Chinese national authorities were
seeking to “sanitize” Sino-DPRK commercial activities. The clearest sign has been the Chinese
government’s issuance of a 236-page report titled “Technical Bulletin #59 on Prohibition of
Dual-use Exports to North Korea.”118

Four institutions—the Ministry of Commerce, the Ministry of Industry and Information


Technology, China Customs Bureau, and the China Atomic Energy Authority—produced this
joint document. Given the technologies related to missiles and drones listed in the report, it is
likely that the General Armaments Department of the Ministry of National Defense was also
involved.119 An update to Technical Bulletin #59 was issued in early 2016 and may portend
increased attention to the DPRK’s nuclear and missile procurement activities in China.

China should be supported and encouraged in these efforts. Anti-corruption is not explicitly
anti-North Korea: the campaign is aimed at Chinese nationals, not North Koreans. Anti-
corruption activities could have a disruptive impact on North Korean procurement without
threatening the broader North Korean economy and the millions of average North Koreans who
depend on it.

The Chinese government’s efforts to prevent drug trafficking and counterfeiting provide two
additional examples of Chinese domestic policies that might also be used to disrupt the DPRK’s
illicit commercial activities. The example of counterfeiting is particularly noteworthy given
recent reports of a North Korean agent being arrested for trying to pass off counterfeited U.S.
currency at a Chinese bank and allegations that Pyongyang is also counterfeiting Chinese
currency.120 It remains to be seen whether this is a one-off episode or instead represents a return

118
Cazavos, Roger, Peter Hayes, David von Hippel. “Technical Bulletin #59 on Prohibition of
Dual-use Exports to North Korea.” NAPSNet Special Reports. September 26, 2013,
http://nautilus.org/napsnet/napsnet-special-reports/technical-bulletin-59-on-prohibition-of-dual-
use-exports-to-north-korea/. In the wake of recent DPRK weapons tests, Beijing has issued a
follow on list of proscribed goods. See Rajagopalan, Megha. “China Says to Ban Export of
More Dual-Use Goods to North Korea.” Reuters, June 14, 2016. http://uk.reuters.com/article/uk-
china-northkorea-nuclear-idUKKCN0Z01GS.
119
Cazavos, Roger, Peter Hayes, David von Hippel. “Technical Bulletin #59 on Prohibition of
Dual-use Exports to North Korea.”
120
Ryall, Julian. “North Korea May have Resumed Counterfeiting Operation.” The Telegraph,
June 28, 2016. http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/2016/06/28/north-korea-may-have-resumed-
counterfeiting-operation/; Shim, Elizabeth. “North Korea Printing Massive Amounts of Fake
Chinese Currency, Defectors Say: The Illicit Project has Kim Jong Un’s Approval.” United
Press International, June 23, 2016. http://www.upi.com/Top_News/World-
News/2016/06/23/North-Korea-printing-massive-amounts-of-fake-Chinese-currency-defectors-
say/2891466694503/.
48

to an old tactic resurrected in the face of new international sanctions. In any case, North Korean
counterfeiting and the North Korean trade in drugs would represent a threat to Chinese national
interests and provide cause for increased Chinese law enforcement activities.

2) Encourage China to send strong signals to its private industry


Premier Wen’s visit to the DPRK in 2009 was a pivotal moment in Chinese-North Korean trade
relations. Private Chinese firms viewed the visit and attending agreements as a green light for
doing business with the DPRK. As Beijing now seeks to separate legitimate commerce with the
DPRK from illegal commerce involving banned items and organizations, a clear signal from the
top could reinforce efforts to encourage a compliance culture (see below). Such signals would
not alter the behavior of firms knowingly engaged in illicit trade, but it would encourage
companies that want to remain clean to be cautious in their dealings with certain types of
transactions.

Following the passage of UNSCR 2270, Chinese officials made surprisingly strong statements
about their intentions to enforce the new sanctions resolution. There were early signs that
suggested that China was more aggressively implementing sanctions, including raids on North
Korean officials alleged to be involved in illicit commerce as well as data indicating a sharp
decline in trade.121 There were also reports of business as usual and a general skepticism about
Chinese intentions.122 The fact that there appears to be continued confusion and a lack of
coordination between local and central authorities is not surprising, and it may take time to

121
“China Arrests Dozens of Smugglers Trading Weapons with North Korea.” Yonhap News,
June 16, 2016.
http://english.yonhapnews.co.kr/news/2016/06/16/31/0200000000AEN20160616008700315F.ht
ml; “China’s Imports of N. Korean Goods Plunge 22.3% in April.” The Korea Herald, May 24,
2016. http://www.koreaherald.com/view.php?ud=20160524000638; “Seoul Says North Korean
Exports Have Plunged After UN Sanctions.” Latin American Herald Tribune, July 1, 2016.
http://www.laht.com/article.asp?ArticleId=2415486&CategoryId=12395; Nagai, Oki. “Cross-
Border Trade Hints Sanctions on North Korea Taking a Bite.” Nikkei Asian Review, May 26,
2016. http://asia.nikkei.com/Features/Pyongyang-provocation/Cross-border-trade-hints-
sanctions-on-North-Korea-taking-a-bite; Rogin, Josh. “Satellite Imagery Suggests China is
Secretly Punishing North Korea.” The Washington Post, July 1, 2016.
https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/global-opinions/satellite-imagery-suggests-china-is-
secretly-punishing-north-korea/2016/06/30/8638d8d6-3ee8-11e6-80bc-
d06711fd2125_story.html. For an alternative view see, Boutin, Paul. “Is China Cutting Off North
Korea? New Analysis of Satellite Images Say No.” Medium, July 26,
122
“What Sanctions?” The Economist, March 12, 2016.
http://www.economist.com/news/china/21694578-border-between-china-and-north-korea-it-
business-usual-what-sanctions; Hunt, Joshua. “Decoder: North Korea’s Maritime Industry—
How UN Sanctions Targeting the Hermit Kingdom’s Shipping Business Awaken Pyongyang’s
Creative Spirit.” Foreign Policy, May/June 2016. http://foreignpolicy.com/2016/05/04/decoder-
north-koreas-maritime-industry-united-nations-sanctions-business-oil/; Lankov, Andrei. “China
and NK: Back to Square One.” The Korea Times, June 12, 2016.
http://www.koreatimes.co.kr/www/news/opinon/2016/06/304_206779.html.
49

discern the degree to which UNSCR 2270 represents a new chapter in North Korea sanctions
implementation.123

In any case, Chinese officials should be encouraged to continue to send signals to its domestic
business community that illicit commercial dealings with the DPRK are unacceptable. It can
promote this message in a number of different ways, from public statements, to the promulgation
of additional regulations (building on Technical Bulletin #59), to the prosecution of high profile
cases.

Here it will be important that Chinese officials address both the issues of severity of punishment
and likelihood of punishment. A slap on the wrist for Chinese middlemen, even if done with
frequency is unlikely to alter broker behavior. On the other hand, severe punishments that are
rarely enforced will also fail. Chinese officials will need to communicate that 1) the punishment
will be robust, 2) the probability of getting caught and facing that punishment is not trivial, and
3) that Chinese businesses can avoid punishment and still do business with the DPRK as long as
they do not support illegal procurement. This third message is equally important as it provides a
way for Chinese businesses (and the government) to avoid an all or nothing decision. Both
Beijing and its business community can maintain ties to the DPRK, which it views as in its self-
interest while reducing North Korean procurement for its WMD programs.

Build Capacity
A sanctions regime is only as good as its implementation by individual, sovereign countries—
countries that vary in their administrative capacities and interests. Three areas appear ripe for the
kinds of capacity building that would improve sanctions enforcement:

§ the ability of individual governments to track international trade and financing

§ the ability of the U.S. government to monitor and counter the DPRK’s use of its
embassies and consulates for procurement

§ the ability of the UN Panel of Experts to collect evidence and report on country
performance and DPRK practices

Unlike many areas of U.S. foreign policy, where the executive branch takes the lead, capacity
building is a policy tool that Congress can pursue. It is a natural follow-on to sanctions
legislation passed by Congress, and it falls squarely within the privileges of the power of the
purse.

123
Haggard, Stephan. “Once Again, Sanctions Enforcement.” Peterson Institute for International
Economics, July 5, 2016. https://piie.com/blogs/north-korea-witness-transformation/once-again-
sanctions-enforcement; Lee, Chaeryung Claire. “An Interview with David Kang: The New
Sanctions Regime against North Korea and its Implications for US Policy.”
http://nbr.org/downloads/pdfs/psa/kang_interview_03172016.pdf.
50

3) Improve the capacity of national governments


Even if country partners have the political will to pursue DPRK-related sanctions, they may lack
the ability: national enabling legislation, human capital, technical infrastructure, and other
elements are needed for implementation and enforcement.124

Helping governments build their capacity to collect data for sanctions enforcement is no small
undertaking, as the UN Panel of Experts reports would illustrate. Still there are priorities.
Assisting regional governments in East and Southeast Asia should be the first priority, and
particularly in the areas of shipping and finance. Japan has long promoted capacity building,
including in the area of nonproliferation and illicit procurement, but the U.S. and other partners
can do more. Support could take many forms, from assistance with the digitization of records
and electronic infrastructure, to the training of regulators, to peer-to-peer advising.

4) Build the capacity of U.S. government to respond to the misuse of DPRK embassies
The DPRK has used its foreign ministry, through embassies and consulates, to place North
Korean managers whose priority is illicit procurement. The UNSC explicitly refers to this
practice in calling on member states to act against abuses of diplomatic privilege.

While the UNSC waits for members to heed that call, there is nothing that prevents governments
from allocating additional resources to law enforcement officials or others seconded from
elsewhere in the U.S. government to work at embassies and consulates in countries where the
DPRK also has diplomatic relations to focus on North Korean procurement activities. These
officials could reach out to local companies and government officials, matching the efforts of the
North Koreans. It would be especially helpful if U.S. officials tasked with this job have Korean
language skills, as the DPRK has often turned to ethic Koreans living in other countries as
partners. Indeed, one objective of these efforts should be to conduct outreach and build positive
relations with the Korean-speaking business community in the region. These communities may
be in a good position to identify and call attention to illicit activities by North Korean managers.

5) Augment the capacity of the UN Panel of Experts on North Korea


If increasing the capacity of national governments is meant to address institutional deficits or
match the North Korean moves, then bolstering the UN Panel of Experts is about building on
strengths. The UN Panel is arguably the single best public source of information on the
enforcement of sanctions against the DPRK. It has direct, firsthand knowledge of North Korea,
Inc.’s practices and may be the only international organization whose primary focus is
Pyongyang’s procurement. Its technical orientation has enabled it to provide objective
information about North Korean procurement, and it has carried out its duties in a professional
manner, consistent with the mandate of the Security Council.

Of course, the Panel’s multi-national character means that there will be disagreements among
panel members and within the Sanctions Committee to which the Panel reports. There will also
be concerns over the sharing of sensitive information.

124
See, for example, Eckert, Susan. “United Nations Sanctions on DPRK: Implementation
Evasion, and Opportunities to Strengthen.”
51

Despite those limitations, the Panel has performed well, and the U.S. and others should advocate
within the UNSC for more resources and a broader mandate for the Panel. With additional
support, the Panel could encourage a culture of compliance among small- and medium-sized
firms that produce dual-use or proliferation-sensitive goods. It could also bolster information
sharing between the public and private sectors on topics such as proliferation-sensitive trade
finance.

Outside of the UN, individual member states, including the U.S., might consider the ways they
could assist the Panel to carry out its objectives, e.g., enhanced information sharing.

Capacity building is not a new idea, either in general or in the domain of nuclear security. As
with all capacity building, there is the need to build in sustainability. Will the technologies or
practices first learned continue after the capacity building support ends? How can one
incentivize an organization to commit over the long-term? These are central and difficult
questions. It may help, however, that sanctions implementation may—because of its proximity
to markets and market players—provide more opportunities for innovation, incentivizing, or
experimentation than most arenas of public capacity building.

Encourage a Culture of Compliance in Private Firms


The recommendations offered so far have concerned public actors: China, national governments,
and the UN Panel of Experts. A focus on North Korea, Inc. highlights the critical role played by
private actors: those that knowingly engage in illegal activity (e.g., private Chinese brokers,
some Chinese banks) and those that unwittingly contribute by selling goods or financing
transactions they wrongly believe do not involve the DPRK.

As has been discussed, this group can be incentivized to affirmatively avoid illicit trade with the
North. Indeed, the chief positive unintended consequence of sanctions on North Korea has been
to further feed the development of a compliance culture in Asia, particularly in the financial
services industry. Policymakers should seek to replicate this success with other kinds of firms,
including trading companies, manufacturers, export-import firms, and the like. Doing so will not
only help address the challenge of North Korean WMD programs but also a host of other illegal
enterprises.

The two most straightforward ways to further catalyze compliance culture are to impose costs on
violators (or establish the expectation of costs) and to offer incentives for compliance.

As the U.S., China, and the international community encourage compliance, they also need to
make clear to firms that legitimate, legal commerce with North Korea is permitted, if not
encouraged. China should welcome that approach, but other countries should as well. If
companies overcompensate and seek to “de-risk” by cutting off all commercial activity with the
DPRK, the humanitarian impact could be profound.125

125
See footnote 105.
52

6) Prioritize the prosecution of high profile cases of sanctions violations


The U.S., China, and other national authorities should prioritize the prosecution of larger firms
with reputation equities that have violated sanctions rules. Aggressively pursuing violators and
affirmatively publicizing those actions will encourage other firms to lower their risk of exposure
to transactions that may involve the DPRK regime or its Chinese proxies.

7) Experiment with the use of incentives


Governments might also experiment with incentives that reward particularly high value
behaviors. Incentives are an undervalued tool in international affairs, where the first response to
objectionable behavior tends to be punishment.126

Governments could test a number of ideas with small pilot projects, e.g., monetary rewards for
the provision of information leading to the interdiction of prohibited items bound for, or
originating in, North Korea. Unlike many areas of public policy, procurement is a highly
marketized arena, where governments might be able to take advantage of competition or small
payments to change behavior.127 It may be possible to persuade a Chinese broker to provide
information about a competitor or an STC manager, if he can make more money in the long run,
e.g., by getting rid of a rival or winning new STC contracts. More broadly, the U.S., South
Korea, China, and Japan are all far wealthier than the DPRK. This greater wealth represents a
comparative advantage over the North that sanctioning countries should exploit. In short, the
DPRK cannot win a bidding war with its wealthy opponents. Beyond that, it would be useful to
identify non-monetary incentives that the DPRK cannot match, e.g., a U.S. green card.

Disrupt North Korea, Inc.’s Operations


Our research suggests that as the international community has imposed sanctions and raised the
risk of doing business with the DPRK regime, STCs have compensated by monetizing the risk
and paying higher fees to their Chinese partners thus improving their overall procurement
capabilities—the “sanctions conundrum.” An obvious question, therefore, is how to hinder
North Korean illicit procurement in ways that cannot be monetized and countered.

126
See for example, Crumm, Eileen M. “The Value of Economic Incentives in International
Politics.” Journal of Peace Research 32 no. 3 (August 1995): 313-330; Nincic, Miroslav. The
Logic of Positive Engagement. Cornell, NY: Cornell University Press 2011.
127
For example, the U.S. government offers rewards of up to $5 million for information leading
to the arrest and conviction of major drug traffickers, and unspecified rewards for information on
transnational organized crime, including human trafficking, arms smuggling, and money
laundering. See U.S. Department of State, “Narcotics Rewards Program,”
http://www.state.gov/j/inl/narc/rewards/c27667.htm; and U.S. Department of State,
“Transnational Organized Crime Rewards Program,”
http://www.state.gov/j/inl/tocrewards/index.htm. Lessons can also be drawn from other
established mechanisms for governments to receive information on trade finance via suspicious
activity reports submitted to financial intelligence units. Shire, Jacqueline. Communication with
the authors, July 2016.
53

One possibility is to disrupt North Korea, Inc. itself. U.S. and UN policies aimed at interdiction
provide one example of disruption, but it is worth asking whether there are upstream
opportunities—before the ship has sailed—to undermine North Korean procurement.

8) Reduce the scope, size, and tenure of STC managers in China and the region
The chart below offers a thought experiment. It begins with a list of DPRK adaptations and
counter-measures and then specifies the benefits or advantages these adaptations have yielded.
The last column offers general ideas about how one might seek to reverse those benefits.

Pursuing any of these ideas will be difficult, insofar as North Korean STC managers are
operating in sovereign states, some of which may not be enthusiastic about the idea of outsiders
(e.g., the U.S.) carrying out law enforcement or intelligence operations on their soil.
Coordination and cooperation will be critical. Still, a focus on North Korea, Inc. in situ may
generate new policy instruments for retarding North Korea’s WMD programs. And already,
some governments are beginning to focus on STC managers in their countries. Vietnam, for
example, recently expelled two North Korean diplomats for prohibited activities.128

Table 5. Responding to DPRK Procurement Counter-measures

NK, Inc. Adaptation Benefit to North Korea Possible Responses to Adaptation


§ Threaten something of value to the more
Hire more capable § PRC firms hide NK sophisticated Chinese brokers that make the
PRC firms fingerprints profit margins from NK, Inc. not worth the
§ PRC firms can do logistics trouble
and financing § Conduct sting operations to increase buyer-
seller suspicion and STC manager failure
§ Increase bank transparency, scrutiny, and
Embed in China § Develop tacit knowledge standardization
§ Use Chinese banks § Reduce tenure of STC managers
§ Threaten something of value that is more
Use of Hong Kong § Credibility/sophistication of valuable than NK, Inc. business
Hong Kong firms
§ Increase U.S. law enforcement and related
Use of commercial § Less regulated, less in presence in SE Asian commercial hubs
hubs in SE Asia spotlight, less national § Capacity building for governments
capacity for sanctions § Outreach to Korean speaking business
enforcement community
§ Reduce the tenure of NK STC managers who
Use of DPRK § STC managers stay longer use diplomatic cover
embassies § Enjoys immunities, § Encourage countries to reduce the number of
privileges NK consulates and diplomats assigned to
embassies

128
“Vietnam, China Ban Blacklisted North Korean Officials.” The Chosun Ilbo, July 8, 2016.
http://english.chosun.com/site/data/html_dir/2016/06/03/2016060301468.html.
54

Information Collection and Analysis: Methods and Models


The U.S. policy response to North Korea’s weapons programs has brought together relevant
departments and agencies: State, Treasury and Defense, as well as the FBI, Directorate of
National Intelligence, the National Security Council, and others. From a U.S. government
perspective, the North’s procurement efforts are viewed as an issue of national security or
foreign policy. A full understanding of Pyongyang’s procurement requires an additional lens,
the company manager.

9) Analyze DPRK procurement as a business case study


In addition to the national security-foreign policy frame, Pyongyang’s procurement is a business
activity that calls for the analytical tools of political economists, economists, business scholars,
commercial firms, and even business consultants. And it suggests that commercial intelligence,
private or public, might be a useful information resource.

Critically, in an iterative game of action and reaction, analysts will want to look at the challenge
of procurement from a North Korean perspective. That could include standard red teaming
exercises but also business simulations with players who have direct experience conducting
commercial transactions in East and Southeast Asia.

Perhaps surprisingly, North Korean behavior should be viewed from the prism of innovation.
Whatever its rigid domestic system, North Korean STC managers have to reinvent themselves
and their organizations in the face of new obstacles (sanctions). They have moved from using
direct transactions and their own freighters for shipment to more efficient networks using brokers
based in a globalizing, Chinese national economy. As the U.S. and its allies have introduced
sanctions, the DPRK has changed, but as the DPRK has changed, others have failed to keep pace
with the North’s innovations.

10) Employ new models for analysis


Analysts might consider using alternative models that highlight different aspects of Pyongyang’s
behavior. There is a need to both step back and understand North Korean actions in a broader
context and also to be more granular in mapping the specific steps in the North’s procurement
chain.

One way to better understand North Korea, Inc. is to realize that the DPRK operates in a regional
and international commercial ecosystem. North Korean procurement is occurring in the context
of a massive economic transformation that is taking place inside of China. In pursuit of its goal
to move the majority of the Chinese population into the middle class, the senior leadership
continues to prioritize the development of the Chinese national economy.129 The scale and scope

129
Reforming its population policy may now rival GDP growth among China’s top priorities.
Arguments, however, in favor of loosening China’s traditionally strict population policies tend to
be rooted in beliefs about the relationship between modest population growth and long-term
economic health. For example, see “China said to Consider Policy Shift to put Population
Growth Before Economy.” Bloomberg. August 20, 2015.
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-08-20/xi-said-to-put-population-over-growth-in-
china-s-economic-plan-idkp0hyy.
55

of this experiment comprises a new gravitational force in the Asia-Pacific region. Viewing
North Korea sanctions solely in terms of its impact inside of the DPRK misses the bigger picture.
It is the broader ecosystem that makes the regime’s procurement more efficient and effective.130

Here again, it is important to recognize that the DPRK’s procurement system is not the typical
one used by a proliferator.131 It is not pursued as a wholly separate, dedicated proliferation
enterprise. Instead, some fraction of its WMD-related procurement makes use of the same
procurement networks that are used for the acquisition of legal goods, i.e., a procurement system
that sometimes includes both legitimate commerce and illicit trade. Indeed, all the STC
managers interviewed for this study engaged in mixed procurement. Accordingly, it will be
important to map the North Korean regime’s use of legitimate commercial pathways and their
implications for proliferation-focused procurement activities. Doing so will yield an improved
understanding of market mechanisms and practices that facilitate advancements in North Korea’s
WMD programs.

An alternative way to put the DPRK’s illicit procurement in context is to compare it to other
entities that engage in comparable practices. One would expect that the methods of A. Q. Kahn,
transnational criminal organizations, violent extremist groups (e.g., ISIL or Da’esh), and other
sanctioned states (e.g., Syria) and individuals would differ from the practices adopted by the
DPRK, but there will be areas of overlap as well. By comparing the DPRK to others, an analyst
can better understand Pyongyang’s behavior and perhaps even anticipate future North Korean
practices that are already being employed by other entities.

Analysts can also fruitfully move in the opposite direction: from the general to the particular. It
would be useful for policymakers to have an evolving blueprint of the North Korean
procurement chain, from the decision to procure an item until its successful delivery—complete
with timelines and costs. Establishing a baseline transaction map would help policymakers
devise counter-tactics and would allow analysts to chart changes in North Korean practices (and
changes in the business environment) over time.

Finally, analysts might attempt to construct their own model of procurement, complete with
indicator lists, and test whether it is predictive of North Korean behavior in any other domain.
Put another way, analysts might want to see if the North’s behavior in this one area tells us
anything more generally about the DPRK, and where it is headed.

11) Adopt an evidence-based and outcomes-focused approach to evaluation


Evaluating whether a public policy is effective, ineffective, or actually harmful is typically
difficult, especially in foreign policy with its multiple players and relatively low information.
Nevertheless, policymakers should feel obliged to do the best they can. With regard to sanctions,
the room for improvement is substantial.

130
July 2015 research interviews with private sector firms in Hong Kong.
131
For an in-depth description of a dedicated, multilateral illicit proliferation network, see
Albright, David. Peddling Peril: how the secret nuclear trade arms America’s enemies. New
York, NY: Free Press, 2010.
56

Aside from the work done by a small number of scholars, there is almost no attempt to
systematically evaluate the effectiveness of sanctions. The presumption of policymakers is
“more is better,” even if there is no evidence for such a conclusion. A related and arguably more
misleading tendency is to judge the effectiveness of sanctions by whether sanctions are adopted.
“Success” is then defined by whether there are sanctions, not on whether sanctions actually
work. This is akin to judging the efficacy of a cancer drug by charting the number of pills
prescribed.

Even on those rare occasions when the focus is on the effects of sanctions rather than sanctions
for sanctions sake, the discussion typically consists of an advocate for one side or another in
Congress, the executive branch, or the non-governmental community cherry picking a single
indicator like inflation or GDP growth in a given year as “proof.”

If the U.S. and its partners want to achieve their policy objectives and avoid costly mistakes, then
policymakers need to be serious about evaluation and adopt a more evidence-based approach.

A first step in this direction is to clarify the goals and objectives of a given sanctions policy (see
above). One cannot know if a policy is a success or a failure without identifying the goals and
objectives the policy is supposed to achieve. When policymakers mix and match different goals
without separating one from another for evaluation, it is impossible to tell whether a policy is
working.

After defining goals and objectives, the next task is to establish metrics and sources of data for
those metrics. In the real world, there are rarely metrics complete with reliable data that
perfectly measure success or failure. In many cases, evaluators are forced to rely on process
measures rather than measures of outcomes, i.e., did the government do a good job of
implementing the policy as opposed to actually achieving the desired result.

With respect to sanctions, typical process metrics include the number of shipments interdicted or
the number of individuals and entities designated. Unfortunately, these numbers do not tell one
very much about whether sanctions are effective, particularly if one does not know what the
context is. Whether interdicting 100 shipments matters will depend, in part, on whether there are
1,000 shipments or 100,000 shipments and whether the shipments tend to carry WMD-related
materials and technology rather than dry goods. Data on the number of interdictions is not
worthless—zero interdictions would probably be a strong indicator of failure, for example—but
it is a weak indicator of success. Similarly, judging sanctions by the robustness of the legal
authorities provided might represent a political win, but it provides little evidence about whether
a policy is working.

A somewhat better, though imprecise, indicator is trade flows. In discussions about the DPRK,
one sometimes hears reference to the level of Chinese-DPRK trade, a time series published by
the Korea Trade-Investment Promotion Agency, a South Korean government body. The problem
here, obviously, is that it is hard to know what these numbers mean for WMD procurement.
General trade could decline even as the DPRK’s WMD-related procurement increases. The
opposite is true as well: general trade could increase even as Pyongyang faced increasing
57

difficulties importing weapons material and technology, e.g., if China was able to successfully
“sanitize” its trade with North Korea.

As suggested earlier, this study prioritizes denial—stopping WMD procurement—rather than


punishment or regime change as the goal of sanctions on the DPRK. Given that goal, it would
make sense to employ a number of different outcome and process metrics. By way of
illustration, outcome metrics might include the ratio of successful missile tests to unsuccessful
missile tests over time (by type of missile), the length of time between missile and nuclear tests,
changes in the qualitative aspects of the tests (missile payload, use of solid fuels, changes in
design, etc.). If the policy is intended to retard or halt North Korea’s progress in its WMD
programs, then outcome metrics should address whether and how quickly these programs are
progressing and the rate of change over time.

Process metrics might include measures assessing the state of North Korea, Inc. The number of
North Korean STC managers embedded in China and the region or the average tenure of these
managers in foreign countries might offer some indication on the relative health of North Korea,
Inc. An even more direct measure might be reports by former STC managers about the relative
ease or difficulty of doing business.

None of these measures will be sufficient by themselves. The fundamental point, however, is
that policymakers need to begin the process of conducting serious evaluation and employing an
evidence-based approach. Early efforts will doubtless suffer a variety of limitations, but with
attention, they will improve over time. In the absence of a conscious decision to enhance
evaluation, they will not improve, leaving policymakers unable to discern whether their actions
are making the situation better or worse.

V. Answering the Questions, Changing the Mindset, and Addressing a Post-UNSCR 2270
World

The 3 Questions
This inquiry began with three questions, and each has been addressed.

1) Do sanctions intended to reduce or halt WMD procurement work, and if not, why not?

No, sanctions against North Korea have not “worked.” The DPRK has slowly but steadily
advanced its nuclear and missile capabilities despite increasingly strong sanctions resolutions.132

132
As Bryan Early suggests, the DPRK’s continued progress in its missile and nuclear programs
reflects a number of adaptations, not just sanctions evasion. Among these is “a ‘MacGyver’-like
approach to its nuclear and missile programs” and “finding non-listed items just under the
threshold for control/sanctions that were functionally similar.” Evasion and counter-measures
are employed against national exports controls, multi-lateral strategic trade controls, and other
instruments designed to inhibit the DPRK’s programs. Early, Bryan. Communication with the
authors, July 2016.
58

In general, sanctions are hard to do, and in the case of North Korea, it has been particularly
challenging. The DPRK is not Iran, and there are a variety of structural and political
impediments that make effective sanctions even more difficult to achieve. In addition, North
Korean procurement has evolved over time, innovating in the face of sanctions and employing
new partners, practices, and pathways.

2) What, if any, unintended consequences—positive or negative—do sanctions against North


Korea generate?

This study identifies a number of real and potential unintended consequences. On the negative
side, the most surprising and unwelcome effect is the “sanctions conundrum”: the North Koreans
simply monetized the risk caused by sanctions, paid higher fees, and thereby attracted more
capable partners. Other negative consequences may or may not be in play (e.g., collaboration
with other sanctioned parties, reduced positive engagement, sanctions overreach), but it is hard to
measure a substantial impact at this point.

Two other unintended consequences may not be likely but would be significant if they took
place: a humanitarian disaster or a hard collapse of the DPRK state—with the former more likely
than the latter. China has strong incentives to prevent both these outcomes, but all the parties
operate in a low information environment.

On the positive side, sanctions against North Korea have helped nurture a “compliance culture”
among some of the larger Chinese financial firms that want to do international business. In
addition, sanctions have forced the DPRK to locate more North Koreans abroad, where they
must engage the broader world.

Finally, there are some consequences that might be positive or negative, though neither is likely
to have an immediate or direct impact. One is that sanctions and North Korea’s decision to
embed in China means that more North Koreans are learning market skills—a potentially
double-edged sword, depending on the objectives to which these skills are employed. Another is
that sanctions are likely to foster corruption.

3) What can be done to improve the effectiveness of these and other sanctions?

This study outlines a total of eleven policy recommendations. Included are suggestions for
engaging China, building new capacities, encouraging a corporate culture of compliance,
disrupting North Korea, Inc., and rethinking the methods and models analyzing North Korean
procurement behavior.

Changing the Mindset


The recommendations on information collection and analysis posit that scholars and analysts
need to think about the challenge of DPRK procurement in new ways. But it is not only scholars
and analysts that need to rethink their approach. In the press, many policymakers’ attitude
toward sanctions appears to be, “the more, the better.” This is particularly true for members of
Congress and some executive branch officials. As one suggested, “Like a regimen of medicine,
59

the dosage can be upped when the effects fall short of what’s required.”133 It is the right
metaphor but the wrong conclusion. In the real world, upping the dosage does not guarantee
success and often leads to unwelcome consequences. It can kill the patient (a North Korean
collapse). It can also produce drug resistance—sanctions evasion innovations that undermine all
sanctions or worse, actually improve North Korean procurement (e.g., “sanctions conundrum”).
More is not better. Better is better; smarter is better. A blunt approach to sanctions is likely to
fail and risks making matters worse, not better.

In addition, sanctions need to be put in a larger policy context. While many of the
recommendations offered in this report could prove useful, the larger and unavoidable truth is
that North Korea long ago crossed the threshold of a nuclear weapons capability. While there
are debates over whether assessments have generally overestimated or underestimated DPRK
weapons capabilities, the larger truth is that in the arc of nuclear development, the DPRK is
somewhere in the messy middle. It can certainly build a simple but deadly nuclear weapon (e.g.,
using the gun-type design) and deliver it from a plane, but it is some distance from a militarily
reliable nuclear arsenal with a secure second strike. Where along that continuum North Korea
resides is a matter of debate, but small differences probably do not matter.

Put another way, the horse is already out of the barn, but it has not jumped the fence and left the
farm. We judge that some elements of North Korea’s nuclear and missile programs will continue
to depend on procurement from other countries, and that at least for the near and intermediate
term, denial of weapons-related material and technology is a worthy policy objective.

It seems unlikely at this juncture, but it is still possible that the DPRK will decide on an alternate
path and forgo or limit its nuclear weapons at some point in the future. More effective sanctions
could extend the time governments have to reach that objective, before the North reaches either a
point of no turn or crisis. Sanctions cannot, however, remove North Korea’s basic nuclear
weapons capability. Nor can sanctions alone achieve denuclearization (or any policy objective)
on its own; they must be integrated into a larger political strategy.134

In sum, policymakers have to think about sanctions in new ways, and they have to devote as
much attention to developing a practical political strategy as they do to sanctions.135

133
Mohammed, Arshad and David Brunnstrom. “US Says North Korean Remittances at Risk if it
Conducts Nuclear Test.”
134
Eckert, Sue and Thomas Biersteker. The Impacts and Effectiveness of UN Nonproliferation
Sanctions: A Provisional Report on the Targeted Sanctions on Iran and North Korea; Litwak
and Daly offer one path: Litwak, Robert, and Robert Daly. “How to Put North Korea’s Nukes on
Ice.” Los Angeles Times, May 6, 2016. http://www.latimes.com/opinion/op-ed/la-oe-littwak-
daly-north-korea-nuclear-freeze-20160506-story.html.
135
For example, see Wit, Joel S. “Trapped in No-Man’s-Land: The Future of US Policy Toward
North Korea.” North Korea’s Nuclear Futures Series. U.S.-Korea Institute at SAIS. June 2016,
1-18.
60

UNSCR 2270 and Beyond: Anticipating the Future


The new international sanctions adopted by the UN in early 2016 represent an unprecedented and
noteworthy diplomatic accomplishment. Few analysts expected language on North Korean coal,
iron ore, jet fuel, or other items critical to the DPRK’s revenue and procurement. Still, if there is
one lesson from the research presented in this report, it is that the DPRK will not simply sit idly
by; it will take counter-measures. Some of its adaptations will likely enhance its ability to
procure while others will create new vulnerabilities and thus opportunities for governments
trying to disrupt its weapons procurement. For example, as regards North Korean bank accounts,
the North will likely respond by relying even more on private Chinese middlemen to be the
financial “face” of DPRK procurement. There will be no North Korean bank accounts. They
will be Chinese bank accounts. If UNSCR 2270 is to have its intended impact, then governments
need to think as much about likely North Korean evasive maneuvers as they do about the next
sanctions resolution, and they need to think about that today.

More broadly, China and South Korea will be at the center of whatever happens with North
Korea. Changes in the Chinese economy, in the PRC-DPRK relationship, and in South Korean
policy and military doctrine can create new dangers and new opportunities. U.S. policymakers
will be obliged to factor in these changes.

Finally, if policymakers are to achieve their objectives, if they are to avoid the worst negative
unintended consequences and maximize the positive ones, then there will have to be more and
better information about North Korea, Inc. We have emphasized the limits of this initial research.
The number of interview subjects is small and covers a particular period in time. Nonetheless,
even this modest effort has generated new insights about DPRK procurement. It is a research
topic that should not be limited to American scholars. Researchers in South Korea, China, Japan
and elsewhere should be encouraged to take up this research program, and there is more work for
American scholars as well. And given the resources available in these countries, this should
represent a comparative advantage for the U.S. and its partners over the DPRK. If we fail to
press that advantage and instead rely on slogans and intuition, we may miss our last opportunity
to halt and rollback North Korea’s nuclear and missile programs.
61

Appendix I. U.S. and International Sanctions Against North Korea

U.S. and International Sanctions Against North Korea

Pre-2006 U.S. Sanctions on North Korea


The October 9, 2006 North Korean nuclear test marked the beginning of a new era in U.S. and
international sanctions towards North Korea. Long before 2006, however, the U.S. imposed
sanctions on the DPRK. The United States maintained comprehensive economic sanctions on
North Korea starting from the Korean War (1950-1953) until 1989. During this period, two
main sanctions measures were applied. First, an economic embargo on the DPRK was imposed
under the Trading with the Enemy Act (TWEA). Second, following the North Korean bombing
of a South Korean civilian airliner in 1987, the DPRK was listed as a State Sponsor of Terrorism.
These provided the basis for further restricting trade and financial transactions with North
Korea.136

From 1989 to 1995, the United States eased sanctions, initially on humanitarian grounds, and
later as a consequence of successful U.S.-North Korea negotiations that led to the 1994 Agreed
Framework. In September of 1999, North Korea adopted a moratorium on missile testing. The
Clinton Administration responded positively with a comprehensive easing of sanctions. During
the early 2000s, the Bush Administration applied sanctions related to North Korea’s WMD
proliferation activities. The DPRK ended its moratorium on missile flight tests in July of
2006.137

UN and U.S. Sanctions for Nuclear and Missile Tests


Following North Korea’s 2006 nuclear and ballistic missile tests, both the UN Security Council
(UNSC) and the U.S. Treasury Department issued additional sanctions on North Korea. The
Treasury Department drew upon the Executive Orders (E.O.) issued by the President for
authority to sanction designated North Korean individuals and entities. These were early steps
towards the development of the new, far more sophisticated U.S. sanctions machinery that has
evolved within the Treasury Department over the past 10 years.

After North Korea conducted its first nuclear test at the Punggye-ri test site on October 9, 2006,
the international community swiftly condemned the test and the UNSC imposed sanctions on

136
Park, John. “Nuclear Ambitions and Tension on the Korean Peninsula,” in Strategic Asia
2013-2014: Asia in the Second Nuclear Age, edited by Ashley J. Tellis, Abraham M. Denmark,
and Travis Tanner. Washington: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2013.
http://belfercenter.ksg.harvard.edu/files/nuclearambitionandtensiononthekoreanpeninsula.pdf.;
Lee and Choi. “U.S. Sanctions and Treasury Department Actions Against North Korea.” North
Korean Review 4, no. 1 (Spring 2008): 10.
137
McGrath, Matthew and Daniel Wertz. “North Korea’s Ballistic Missile Program.” The
National Committee on North Korea, Issue Brief, August 2015.
http://www.ncnk.org/resources/publications/Missile_Issue_Brief.pdf; Samore, Gary. “U.S.-
DPRK Missile Negotiations.” The Nonproliferation Review 9, No. 2 (Summer 2002): 16-20.
https://www.nonproliferation.org/wp-content/uploads/npr/92samore.pdf.
62

North Korea through the adoption of Resolution 1718.138 On June 26, 2008, the President issued
E.O. 13466, declaring “a national emergency to deal with the unusual and extraordinary threat to
the national security and foreign policy of the United States constituted by the existence and risk
of the proliferation of weapons-usable fissile material on the Korean Peninsula.”139 It was this
E.O. that provided the basis for the Treasury Department, through its Office of Foreign Assets
Control (OFAC), to launch its current North Korea sanctions program.140

On May 25, 2009, North Korea conducted a second nuclear test, also at the Punggye-ri test site.
The UNSC again imposed sanctions on North Korea with the adoption of Resolution 1874.141
On August 30, 2010, the President issued E.O. 13551, expanding the scope of the national
emergency declared in E.O. 13466, and “providing for the blocking of property and interests in
property of certain persons with respect to North Korea.”142

On December 12, 2012, North Korea conducted a satellite launch, which was condemned by the
international community as a long-range ballistic missile test. The Security Council passed
UNSCR 2087 which reaffirmed and expanded sanctions outlined in UNSCRs 1718 and 1874.
The Treasury Department implemented its first set of bilateral sanctions following the passage of
UNSCR 2087.143 North Korea conducted a third nuclear test on February 12, 2013, which it
claimed was a successful test of a “lighter, miniaturized atomic bomb.”144 After North Korea’s
third nuclear test, the UNSC passed Resolution 2094. Susan Rice, then U.S. ambassador to the
United Nations, argued that the new, stronger measures under this resolution would have teeth
and would significantly impede “North Korea’s ability to develop further its illicit nuclear and
ballistic missile programs, as well as its proliferation activities.”145 Drawing on previous E.O.s,
the Treasury Department issued another round of sanctions on North Korea.146

138
Park, John. “Nuclear Ambitions and Tension on the Korean Peninsula.”
139
OFAC. “Sanctions with Respect to North Korea.” Department of the Treasury.
https://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/sanctions/Programs/Pages/nkorea.aspx.
140
Ibid.
141
Park, John. “Nuclear Ambitions and Tension on the Korean Peninsula.”
142
OFAC. “Sanctions with Respect to North Korea.”
143
Press Release. “Treasury Sanctions Company and Individuals Linked to North Korean
Weapons of Mass Destruction Program.” U.S. Department of Treasury, January 24, 2013.
Treasury Sanctions Company and Individuals Linked to North Korean Weapons of Mass
Destruction Program.
144
Choe Sang-hun, “North Korea Threatens to Attack U.S. With ‘Lighter and Smaller Nukes,’”
The New York Times, March 5, 2013.
145
U.S. Mission to the United Nations, “UN Security Council Resolution 2094 on North Korea,”
Fact Sheet, March 7, 2013.
146
Park, “Nuclear Ambitions and Tension on the Korean Peninsula.”
63

Table 6. UN Security Council Resolutions on North Korea147

UNSCR Date Reason Measures Adopted Vote


825 05/11/93 DPRK says will § Calls upon DPRK to reconsider decision to withdraw from NPT 13-0148
w/draw from NPT; § Does not implement sanctions
IAEA says DPRK
noncompliant
1695 07/15/06 DPRK launches a § Prohibits transferring technologies or materials to DPRK that would aid 15-0
series of missiles missile and WMD programs
on 07/04/06 § Prohibits acquisition of missiles or associated technologies from DPRK
§ Prevents transfer of financial resources for missile or WMD programs
1718 10/14/06 North Korea § Reaffirms and expands UNSCR 1695 15-0
conducts a nuclear § Prohibits sale or transfer of certain luxury goods to DPRK
test 10/09/06 § Enforces inspection of cargo for illicit materials related to WMD
§ Bans import and export of arms and related items to and from DPRK
§ Bans travel for select individuals
§ Establishes a UNSC committee to review compliance with resolution
1874 06/12/09 DPRK conducts a § Reaffirms and expands UNSCR 1718 15-0
second nuclear test § Prohibits financial assistance to DPRK, except for humanitarian needs
on 05/25/09 § Establishes a panel of experts
2087 01/22/13 DPRK conducts a § Reaffirms and expands UNSCRs 1718, 1874 15-0
long-range rocket § Freezes assets of entities that provide financial support to DPRK
launch on 12/12/12 § Broadens travel ban to individuals associated with missiles and WMD
§ Encourages members to enhance enforcement of existing sanctions
2094 03/07/13 North Korea § Reaffirms and expands UNSCRs 1718, 1874, and 2087 15-0
conducts a third § Blocks financial transactions or the transfer of bulk cash and DPRK
nuclear test on access to international financial institutions
02/12/13 § Denies permission to aircraft wishing to take off from, land in, or
overfly territory if is suspected of transporting prohibited items
§ Extends the panel of experts
§ Strengthens authority to inspect suspicious cargo to or from DPRK
§ Requires states to deny port access to DPRK vessels refusing inspection
2270 03/02/16 North Korea § Reaffirms and expands UNSCRs 1718, 1874, 2087, and 2094 15-0
conducts a fourth § Reaffirms that members should prevent transfer to DPRK of all forms
nuclear test on of tech training, advice, services, or assistance
01/06/16 and a § Prohibits transfer of “any item,” except food or medicine, that “could
ballistic missile directly contribute” to military capabilities
launch on 02/07/16 § Requires that states engage in searches of all cargo from and to DPRK
§ Freezes assets of and imposes travel bans upon 28 persons and entities
§ Directs Panel of Experts to identify DPRK front companies
§ Requires expulsion of DPRK agents, others engaged in sanctions
evasion
§ Calls on states to prohibit leasing or chartering flagged DPRK vessels
§ Prohibits purchase of coal, iron, or iron ore from DPRK if used for
WMD or missile programs
§ Prohibits public and private financial support for DPRK illicit trade

Following North Korea’s fourth nuclear test on January 6, 2016 and the launch of a satellite on
February 7, 2016, the UNSC passed Resolution 2270 on March 2, 2016. On March 15, 2016, the

147
UN Security Council Resolutions 825, 1695, 1718, 1874, 2087, 2094, and 2270, available at
http://www.securitycouncilreport.org/un-documents/dprk-north-korea/. Park, “Nuclear Ambition
and Tension on the Korean Peninsula” pp. 170-171. “Vote” refers to votes in favor of the
resolution.
148
China and Pakistan abstained.
64

President issued E.O. 13722, which blocked the “property of the Government of North Korea
and the Workers’ Party of Korea.”149

Table 7. U.S. Executive Orders (E.O.s) on North Korea150

Executive Date/President Reason Measures Adopted


Order
13466 06/26/08 § Part of process of § Declaration of national emergency to deal with
George W. Bush removal of DPRK from DPRK proliferation threat.
TWEA designation § Extends sanctions under TWEA, which would
consistent with U.S.- have otherwise been lifted by forthcoming
DPRK negotiations.151 proclamation.
§ Delegates to the Treasury Department
responsibility for enforcing these sanctions.
13551 08/30/10 § Sinking of ROK Navy § Freezes assets of, bans trade with (‘blocks’)
Barack Obama ship Cheonan. individuals and entities involved with North
§ May 2009 nuclear test. Korea’s illicit activities.
§ Ballistic missile tests. § Prohibits donations to these individuals and
§ Violation of UNSCRs entities.
1718 and 1874. § Delegates to the Treasury Department
§ “Illicit and deceptive responsibility for enforcing these sanctions.
activities in international
markets,” e.g., money
laundering, smuggling,
counterfeiting.
13570 04/18/11 § Address possible issue § Bans imports of DPRK goods, services, and
Barak Obama with the Korea-US Free technology.
Trade Agreement.152
13687 01/02/15 § Cyber attack on Sony.153 § Blocks transfer of property and interests of the
Barak Obama DPRK that are in or come to the U.S.
§ Prohibits donations to DPRK.
§ Restricts entry into the U.S. of DPRK officials.
13722 03/02/16 § Continuing pursuit of § Freezes assets of, bans trade with (‘blocks’)
Barack Obama nuclear and ballistic property of DPRK government, WPK.
missile programs, § Forbids U.S. persons to export or re-export
evidenced by recent tests. goods, services, technology, or financing to
DPRK.
§ Delegates to the Treasury Department
responsibility for enforcing these sanctions.

149
Executive Order 13722, “Blocking Property of the Government of North Korea and the
Workers’ Party of Korea, and Prohibiting Certain Transactions With Respect to North Korea”
(Effective date - March 16, 2016).
https://www.treasury.gov/resourcecenter/sanctions/Programs/Documents/nk_eo_20160316.pdf
150
National Archives. “Executive Orders Disposition Tables Index.”
http://www.archives.gov/federal-register/executive-orders/disposition.html.
151
Arms Control Association. “Chronology of U.S.-North Korean Nuclear and Missile
Diplomacy.” March 2016. http://www.armscontrol.org/factsheets/dprkchron%20.
152
Noland, Marcus. “President Moves Preemptively on KORUS.” PIIE, April 19, 2011.
https://piie.com/blogs/north-korea-witness-transformation/president-moves-preemptively-korus
153
“Obama Extends Executive Orders Imposing Sanctions on N. Korea.” Yonhap, June 22, 2016,
http://english.yonhapnews.co.kr/national/2016/06/22/0301000000AEN20160622000400315.htm
l

You might also like