Governor Powell's Housing Speech

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

For release on delivery

10:00 a.m. EDT


July 6, 2017

The Case for Housing Finance Reform

Remarks by

Jerome H. Powell

Member

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

at

the American Enterprise Institute


Washington, DC

July 6, 2017
Good morning. Thank you to the American Enterprise Institute and Steve Oliner for

inviting me here to speak. My topic today is the urgent need for fundamental reform of our

system of housing finance--the great unfinished business of post-financial crisis reform. 1

The Federal Reserve is not charged with designing or evaluating proposals for housing

finance reform. But we are responsible for regulating and supervising banking institutions to

ensure their safety and soundness, and more broadly for the stability of the financial system. A

robust, well-capitalized, well-regulated housing finance system is vital to achieving those goals,

and to the long-run health of our economy. We need a system that provides mortgage credit in

good times and bad to a broad range of creditworthy borrowers.

While reforms have addressed some of the problems of the pre-crisis system, there is

broad agreement that the job is far from done. The status quo may feel comfortable today, but it
Isn't this really the result of
is also unsustainable. Today, the federal governments role in housing finance is even greater Fed disincentives for banks to
hold mortgages and the fact
that Project Restart was
abandoned, the SEC didn't go
than it was before the crisis. The overwhelming majority of new mortgages are issued with far enough with Reg ABS, the
FED and UST left the PLS
repair to the sell-side and the
government backing in a highly concentrated securitization market. That leaves us with both those firms didn't to anything
because they don't want to
lose the economic arbitrages
potential taxpayer liability and systemic risk. It is important to learn the right lessons from the they get with 300 different PLS
PSPA and Rep & Warrant
contracts?

failure of the old system. We can also apply lessons from post-crisis banking reform. Above all,

we need to move to a system that attracts ample amounts of private capital to stand between

housing sector credit risk and taxpayers. We should also use market forces to increase

competition and help to drive innovation.

1
The views I express here are my own and not necessarily those of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
-2-

The global financial crisis ended in 2009, and the economy has just completed its eighth

consecutive year of expansion. We are near full employment. The housing market is generally

strong, although it is still recovering in some regions. To preserve these gains, we must ensure

the stability of our financial system. With that goal in mind, we are near completion of a

comprehensive program to raise prudential standards for our most systemically important banks.
Please detail, specifically, the list
But fundamental housing finance reform--including reform to address the ultimate status of of items not addressed by HERA
that need to be addressed? I am
not asking about the failure of
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, two systemically important government sponsored enterprises DeMarco to fully implement the
statute (including risk based
capital requirements), rather
what authorities FHFA is missing.
(GSEs)--remains on the to do list. As memories of the crisis fade, the next few years may

present our last best chance to finish these critical reforms. Failure to do so would risk repeating

the mistakes of the past.

The Pre-Crisis System

Congress created Fannie Mae in 1938 and Freddie Mac in 1970. For many years, these

institutions prudently pursued their core mission of enhancing the availability of credit for

housing. Beginning in the early 1980s, Fannie and Freddie helped to facilitate the development

of the securitization market for home mortgages. They purchased and bundled mortgage loans,

and sold the resulting mortgage-backed securities (MBS) to investors. Fannie and Freddie also

guaranteed payment of principal and interest on the MBS. With this guarantee in place, MBS

investors took the risk of changing interest rates, and the GSEs took the risk of default on the
This is historically
underlying mortgages. Thanks to the growth in securitization, these two GSEs have dominated inaccurate, in the peak of
the early 2000's the
GSEs market share fell to
U.S. housing finance since the late 1980s. 34%

And the system broke down


The pre-crisis system did its job for many years. By promoting standardization, with the GSE lobbied legislation
in 1992 which created a weak
regulator, subjected it to
structuring securities to meet a broad range of investor risk appetites, and issuing guaranteed appropriations, implemented
weak capital standards, split the
oersight between HUD
(mission) and OFHEO (safety &
soundness) and allowed the
GSEs to become pro-cyclical
through the abuse of their
retained portfolios.
-3-

MBS, Fannie and Freddie brought greater liquidity to mortgage markets and made mortgages

more affordable. But the system ultimately failed due to fundamental flaws in its structure. In

the early days of securitization, the chance that either GSE would ever fail to honor its guarantee

seemed remote. But the question always loomed in the background: Who would bear the credit

risk if a GSE became insolvent and could not perform? Would Congress really allow the GSE to

fail to honor its obligations, given the devastating impact that would have on mortgage funding

and the housing market? The law stated explicitly that the government did not stand behind the

GSEs or their MBS, as Fannie and Freddie frequently pointed out in order to avoid tougher

regulation. Nonetheless, investors understandably came to believe that the two GSEs were too-

big-to-fail, and priced in an implicit federal government guarantee behind GSE obligations. In

the end the investors were right, of course. The implicit government guarantee also meant that

investors--including banks, the GSEs themselves, and investors around the world--did not do

careful due diligence on the underlying mortgage pools. Thus, securitization also enabled

declining lending standards. This was not only a problem of the GSEs--private label

securitizations also helped to enable lower underwriting standards.

Over time, the systems bad incentives caused the two GSEs to change their behavior and

take on ever greater risks. The GSEs became powerful advocates for their own bottom lines,

providing substantial financial support for political candidates who supported the GSE agenda.

Legislative reforms in the 1990s and the public/private structure led managements to expand the

GSEs balance sheets to enormous size, underpinned by wafer-thin slivers of capital, driving

high shareholder returns and very high compensation for management. These factors and others

eventually led to extremely lax lending conditions. The early 2000s became the era of Alt-A,
-4-

low doc, and no doc loans. 2 These practices contributed to the catastrophic failure of the housing

finance system. Almost nine years ago, in September 2008, Fannie and Freddie were put into

temporary conservatorship and received injections of taxpayer funds totaling $187.5 billion. And what was the
government's return on those
investments versus the
investments in the banks?
In the end, the system privatized the gains and socialized the losses.

The buildup of risks is clear in hindsight. But many officials and commentators raised

concerns long before the collapse. 3 The long-standing internal structural weaknesses of the old

system ultimately led to disastrous consequences for homeowners, taxpayers, the financial

system, and the economy.

Reforms to Date

Before considering the path forward, it is important to acknowledge that todays housing

sector is healthier and in some respects safer than it was in 2005. Although there are significant

regional differences, national data show that housing prices have fully recovered from their gut-

wrenching 35 percent drop during the crisis. Mortgage default rates have returned to pre-crisis

levels. Mortgage credit is available and affordable for strong borrowers.

2
See, for example, Markus K. Brunnermeier, Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007-2008, The
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23, No. 1 (Winter 2009), pp. 77-100; Major Coleman IV, Michael LaCour-
Little, and Kerry D. Vandell, Subprime Lending and the Housing Bubble: Tail Wags Dog? Journal of Housing
Economics, Vol.17, Issue 4 (December 2008) pp. 272-290; Shiller, Robert J. (2012) The Subprime Solution: How
Todays Global Financial Crisis Happened, and What to Do about It, Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University
Press; E. Pinto (2015), Three Studies of Subprime and Alt-A loans in the U.S. Mortgage Market, American
Enterprise Institute (January 2015), www.aei.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/09/Pinto-Government-Housing-Policies-
in-the-Lead-up-to-the-Financial-Crisis-3-Studies-1.6.15.pdf.
3
See, for example, Alan Greenspan, "Government-Sponsored Enterprises," remarks delivered at the Conference on
Housing, Mortgage Finance, and the Macroeconomy, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, May 19 2005,
www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2005/default.htm; and Randal Quarles Remarks Before the Women in
Housing and Finance, June 13, 2006.
-5-

There has also been meaningful progress in reforming the old system. In 2008, Congress

enacted the Housing and Economic Recovery Act, which, among other things, created the

Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA), modeled on and with similar powers to the Federal

Deposit Insurance Corporation. Under the FHFAs oversight, the two GSEs retained portfolios

have declined to about half of their pre-crisis size, and are expected to continue on a downward

path. The FHFA and the GSEs have also been working to develop a market for the GSEs to lay

off their credit risk. These innovative transactions have raised about $50 billion in private capital

that now stands between taxpayers and mortgage credit risk in the GSEs portfolios. In addition,

the creation of a Common Securitization Platform should strengthen the GSEs securitization

infrastructure and facilitate further reforms with an eye toward enhancing competition.

New regulations have also been put in place since the crisis with the goal of encouraging

sound underwriting of mortgage loans. Today, lenders must make a good faith effort to

determine that the borrower has the ability to repay the mortgage. Moreover, if the lender

provides a qualified mortgage contract to the borrower, then the lender needs to meet certain

other requirements. 4 For example, some contract features such as an interest-only period or

negative amortization, where the loan balance increases even though the borrower is making

payments, are taboo. Upfront points and fees are limited too.

4
More specifics on the features required for qualified mortgage contracts are available at
www.consumerfinance.gov/askcfpb/1789/what-qualified-mortgage.html.
-6-

Todays Challenges

These reforms represent movement in the right direction, but leave us well short of where

we need to be. Despite the GSEs significant role in this key market, there is no clarity about

their future. When they were put into conservatorship, Treasury Secretary Paulson noted that

policymakers must view this next period as a time out where we have stabilized the GSEs

while we decide their future role and structure. 5 Almost nine years into this time out, the federal

governments domination of the housing sector has grown and is actually greater than it was

before the crisis. Fannie, Freddie, the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) and U.S.

Department of Veterans Affairs have a combined market share of about 80 percent of the

purchase mortgage market, with the remaining 20 percent held by private financial institutions.

After reaching nearly 30 percent of the market before the crisis, private-label securitization has

dwindled to almost nothing today.

The two GSEs remain in government conservatorship, with associated contingent

liabilities to US taxpayers. 6 Fannie and Freddie have remitted just over $270 billion of profits to

the Treasury, more than paying back the governments initial investment. However, under

current terms of the contracts that govern their access to Treasury funds, their capital will decline

to $0 by January 1, 2018. Today, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have more than $5 trillion of

MBS and corporate debt outstanding, which is widely held and receives various forms of special

5
Statement by Secretary Henry M. Paulson, Jr. on Treasury and Federal Housing Finance Agency Action to Protect
Financial Markets and Taxpayers, September 7, 2008, www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-
releases/Pages/hp1129.aspx.
6
The size of these contingent liabilities is potentially quite large. FHFAs stress test results published in August
2016 found that under its severely adverse scenario the two GSEs could need to draw up to $125.8 billion from the
U.S. Treasury. See www.fhfa.gov/AboutUs/Reports/ReportDocuments/2016_DFAST_Severely-Adverse-
Scenario.pdf.
-7-

regulatory treatment. And because of their scale, these enterprises continue to serve as important

standard-setters and significant counterparties to other firms.

While mortgage credit is widely available to most traditional mortgage borrowers, those

with lower credit scores face significantly higher standards and lower credit availability than

before the crisis. We can all agree that we do not want to go back to the poor underwriting

standards used by originators prior to the crisis. But it may also be that the current system is too

rigid, and that a lack of innovation and product choice has limited mortgage credit availability to

some creditworthy households. According to a survey by the American Banker, in 2016 only

nine percent of mortgage originations failed to meet the qualified mortgage contract criteria,

down from 16 percent in 2013. 7 The same survey reported that almost one-third of U.S. banks

make only qualified mortgage loans, despite the fact that FHA- and GSE-eligible mortgages are

exempt from the qualified mortgage requirements until January 2021 or until housing finance

reform is enacted, whichever date comes first.

Applying the Lessons of Banking Reform to Housing Finance

The post-crisis reform program for our largest banks presents an appropriate standard Really? The Federal
Reserve has completely
avoided implementation of
Title I of Dodd Frank, the
against which the housing finance giants should be judged. After eight years of reform, our key preemptive safety
feature to end the
interconnectedness,
largest banking institutions are now far stronger and safer. Common equity capital held by the concentration and
complexity of the SIFI
banks and, instead, relies
on the flawed cleanup
eight U.S. global systemically important banks has more than doubled to $825 billion from about mechanism of Orderly
Liquidation Authority of the
FDIC.
$300 billion before the crisis. After the crisis revealed significant underlying liquidity

vulnerabilities, these institutions now hold $2.3 trillion in high-quality liquid assets, or 25

7
American Bankers Association, 24th Annual ABA Residential Real Estate Survey Report, (March 2017),
www.aba.com/Press/Documents/2017ABARealEstateLendingSurveyReport.pdf.
-8-

percent of their total assets. Under rigorous annual stress tests, they must demonstrate a high

level of understanding of their risks and the ability to manage them, and must survive severely

adverse economic scenarios with high levels of post-stress capital. And they must file regular

resolution plans that have made them significantly more resolvable should they fail. These

measures were implemented to reduce the risk that a future crisis will result in taxpayer support,

and to help ensure that the financial system could continue to function even in the event that one

of these banks were to default.

It is ironic that the housing finance system should escape fundamental reform efforts.

The housing bubble of the early 2000s was, after all, an essential proximate cause of the crisis.

Housing is the single largest asset class in our financial system, with total outstanding residential

real estate owned by households of $24 trillion and roughly $10 trillion in single-family

mortgage debt. 8 While post-crisis regulation has addressed mortgage lending from a consumer

protection standpoint, the important risks to taxpayers and the broader economy and financial

system have not been robustly addressed.

The most obvious and direct step forward would be to require ample amounts of private

capital to support housing finance activities, as we do in the banking system. We should also

strive for a system that can continue to function even in the event of a default of any firm. No

single housing finance institution should be too big to fail.

This is a straw man


Greater amounts of private capital could come through a variety of sources, including argument. How would
multiple firms be more able
to attract capital? How
through the entry of multiple private guarantors who would insure a portion of the credit risk, would they have the
economic or demographic
efficiencies of scale? Have
the PMIs attracted
adequate private capital?

8
Based on information contained in the Financial Accounts of the United States available at
www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/releases/mortoutstand/current.htm.
-9-

through risk-sharing agreements, or through expanded use of credit-risk transfers. Although

private capital must surely be part of the reform effort, there may be limits to the amount of risk

that we can credibly expect the private sector to insure. It is extremely difficult to appropriately

price the insurance of catastrophic risk--the risk of a severe, widespread housing crisis. Both the

private-sector insurance industry and government have struggled with this, particularly with how

to smooth the consistent collection of premiums with the irregular payout of potentially

enormous losses that may be needed only once or twice in a century. Furthermore, losses can be

correlated across asset classes and geographies in these catastrophic events, rendering risk-

diversification strategies ineffective. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have successfully transferred

some credit risk to the private sector, but have thus far avoided selling off much of this

catastrophic credit risk, arguing that doing so is not economical. 9


It IS uneconomi. If you disagree
show otherwise.

Principles for Reform

After promising legislative initiatives have moved forward but fallen short of enactment,

the air is again thick with housing finance reform proposals. As I mentioned at the outset,

housing finance reform has important implications for the Federal Reserves oversight of

financial institutions, and for the U.S. economy and its financial stability. While I would not

presume to judge these reform proposals, I will offer some principles for reform. These

9
See Overview of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Credit Risk Transfer Transactions, FHFA (August 2015). The
overview differentiates between expected loss (credit losses that would be projected to occur even under a stable
baseline), unexpected loss (losses that might occur under a stressful but plausible event such as recession) and
catastrophic loss (losses beyond those of an unexpected loss and that are deemed highly unlikely to occur). The
overview notes that catastrophic risk events are deemed so unlikely, meaning they present so little risk, that the
Enterprises have found it to be too costly (not economical) to transfer much of this risk to the private sector,
https://www.fhfa.gov/aboutus/reports/reportdocuments/crt-overview-8-21-2015.pdf.
- 10 -

principles are based on the lessons learned from the old systems collapse, and from the

experience of post-crisis bank reform.

First, we ought to do whatever we can to make the possibility of future housing bailouts

as remote as possible. Housing can be a volatile sector, and housing is often found at the heart of

financial crises. 10 Our housing finance institutions were not--and are not--structured with that in

mind. Extreme fluctuations in credit availability for housing hurt vulnerable households, reduce

affordability and availability, and, as we have seen, can threaten financial stability. As with

banks, the goal should be to ensure that our housing finance system can continue to function
The GSEs do not
even in the face of significant house price declines and severe economic conditions. Changing originate or allocate
capital for borrowers.
Banks can originate and
the system to attract large amounts of private capital would be a major step toward that goal. hold, or originate and
securitize, loans - not
the GSEs. Any
weaknesses in the
The question of the governments role in the new system is a challenging one for alocation of capital is the
result of the banks being
unwilling to, or
disincentivized, from
Congress. Many of the well-known reform proposals include some role for government. Some making, holding or
securitizing loans
privately.
argue that government cannot avoid bearing the deep-in-the-tail risk of a catastrophic housing

crisis. A number of proposals incorporate a government guarantee to cover this risk, to take

effect after a significant stack of private capital is wiped out.

That brings me to my second principle: If Congress chooses to go in this direction, any This is a wrongheaded
approach that will
provide dramatic RWA
capital relief to banks,
such guarantee should be explicit and transparent, and should apply to securities, not to allow them to hold more
mortgage assets
determined to be HLQA
Level 1, and again add
unwise liquidity to the
housing market while
increasing the taxpayers
ultimate risk.

10
See for example Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff, The Aftermath of Financial Crises, American
Economic Review, vol. 99 (May 2009) pp. 466-72; scar Jord, Moritz Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor, The Great
Mortgaging: Housing Finance, Crises, and Business Cycles, NBER Working Paper No. 20501 (September 2014),
www.nber.org/papers/w20501; and the International Monetary Fund, Housing Finance and Financial Stability
Back to Basics? Global Financial Stability Report (April 2011),
www.imf.org/en/Publications/GFSR/Issues/2016/12/31/~/media/Websites/IMF/imported-flagship-
issues/external/pubs/ft/GFSR/2011/01/pdf/_chap3pdf.ashx.
- 11 -

There is ZERO reason to


institutions. Reform should not leave us with any institutions that are so important as to be create an explicit government
guarantee. Proper minimum
and risk weighted capital
candidates for too-big-to-fail. standards behind the GSEs
would be sufficient to protect
against all but a 100-year flood
and that could be further
Third, we should promote greater competition in this market. The economics of strengthened by requiring the
GSEs to purchase private
catastrophic insurance from the
private sector to replace the
securitization do not require a duopoly. Yet there is no way for private firms to acquire a GSE
The secondary market is government's lines of credit or
distinct from the primary explicit guarantee.
market and must remain
so. How many electric
utilities operate in a
charter and enter the industry. This is akin to having only two banks with federal deposit
region and why are those
monopolies? Scale!
Duopoly's compete on insurance, which would make competition by other banks very difficult. Greater competition
price, that was the problem
of the GSEs from 1992-2006.
Instead they should bewould help to reduce the systemic importance of the GSEs, and spur more innovation. Greater
duopsonys and compete
on service and products.

competition also requires a level playing field, allowing secondary market access to a wide-range This is the failure of
the Federal Reserve.
Look at the
concentration of
of lenders and thereby giving homebuyers a choice among many potential mortgage lenders and lending by the top 5
originators. The top 20
control 80% of the
products. entire origination
market. That has zero
to do with the GSEs.

Fourth, it is worth considering simple approaches that restructure and repurpose parts of

the existing architecture of our housing finance system. We know that housing reform is

difficult; completely redrawing the system may not be necessary and could complicate the search

for a solution. Using the existing architecture would allow for a continued smooth, gradual

transition.

Fifth and last, we need to identify and build upon areas of bipartisan agreement. In my

view, at this late stage we should not be holding out for the perfect answer. We should be

looking for the best feasible plan to escape the unacceptable status quo.

Conclusion

I see two reasons why this is a good time to address the housing finance systems

shortcomings. First, the economy and the housing sector are healthy. It would be far more

disruptive to implement fundamental structural changes during difficult economic times.


- 12 -

Second, memories of the crisis are fading. If Congress does not enact reforms over the next few

years, we are at risk of settling for the status quo--a government-dominated mortgage market

with insufficient private capital to protect taxpayers, and insufficient competition to drive

innovation. There is a serious risk, if not a likelihood, that this state of affairs may persist

indefinitely, leaving our housing finance system in a semi-permanent limbo. Fortunately, we are

blessed with a growing menu of reform options available for public vetting. And there appear to

be areas of broad agreement among them. One of those plans, or a combination of different

features of various plans, might well suffice to move us to a better system. Housing finance

reform will protect taxpayers from another bailout, be good for households and the economy, and

go some distance toward mitigating the systemic risk that the GSEs still pose.

You might also like