Introduction To Financial Mathematics: Zhenjie Ren October 8, 2017
Introduction To Financial Mathematics: Zhenjie Ren October 8, 2017
Introduction To Financial Mathematics: Zhenjie Ren October 8, 2017
Zhenjie Ren1
October 8, 2017
1
Universite Paris-Dauphine, PSL Research University, CNRS, UMR [7534], Cere-
made, 75016 Paris, France, [email protected].
2
Chapter 1
Basic Notions
3
4 CHAPTER 1. BASIC NOTIONS
Remark 0.3 Strictly speaking, we did not show in the previous proof that K =
S0 erT is a non-arbitrage price (we only excluded all other possiblities). For the
sake of the simplicity of the course, we keep this incomplete proof.
Chapter 2
1 Types of rates
In this course, we mainly talk about two types of rates:
Treasury Rates Treasury rates are the interest rates applicable to bor-
rowing by a government in its own currency. We usually assume that there
is no chance that a government will default on an obligation denominated
in its own currency, because it can always meet the obligation by printing
money. That is why the Treasury rates are considered as risk-free rates.
LIBOR Rates (London Interbank Offer Rates) The rates are deter-
mined in trading between banks and change as economic conditions change.
LIBOR rates are generally higher than the corresponding Treasury rates,
because there is always a chance that a bank could default. However,
when evaluating derivatives transactions, banks and other large financial
institutions tend to use LIBOR rates as the risk-free rates, because they
invest surplus funds in the LIBOR rates market and borrow to meet their
short-term funding requirement in this market.
2 Different Compoundings
When referring to an interest rate, one need to specify how the rate is com-
pounded (e.g. the rate is with annual compounding, semiannual compounding,
or continuous compounding, etc.).
For example, suppose that an amount A is invested for n years at an interest
rate of R with annual compounding. Then the terminal value of the investment
is
A(1 + R)n .
If the same rate is compounded m times per year, the terminal value of the
5
6 CHAPTER 2. INTEREST RATES MARKET
investment is R mn
A 1+ .
m
If the rate is with continuous compounding, then the terminal value of the
investment is R mn
lim A 1 + = AeRn .
m m
In this course, interest rates will be measured with continuous compounding
except where otherwise stated, because it is generally more computing-friendly.
R(0, n).
Using the zero rates as the discounting rates we can calculate the current value
of a cash flow.
Most bonds provides coupons (of value C) periodically. The owner also
receives the principal or (face value F ) of the bond at maturity. Suppose a
5. ACCRUED INTERESTS AND QUOTATIONS 7
bond lasts for n years and bears annual coupon C. Given the zero rates, we can
theoretically calculate the price of the bond at the initial time:
n
X
P0 = CeR(0,i)i + F eR(0,n)n .
i=1
The yield (y) on a coupon-bearing bond is the constant discount rate that
equates the cash flows on the bond to its market value. Still take the previous
bond as an example. The corresponding yield y must satisfy
n
X
P0 = Ceyi + F eyn =: g(y). (4.1)
i=1
Unlike the yield, the par yield can generally be computed explicitly. Here, (4.2)
leads to
C
1 eyn F = 0.
ey 1
The only solution to the equation above is y = ln 1 + CF , so is the par yield
on this bond.
Actual/actual
30/360 (i.e. 30 days for each month, and 360 days for a year)
8 CHAPTER 2. INTEREST RATES MARKET
Actual/360
Actual/actual is used for U.S. Treasury bonds, 30/360 is used for U.S. corporate
and municipal bonds, and actual/360 is used for U.S. Treasury bills and other
money market instruments.
Choosing the right day count convention, we may calculate the accrued
interest (A):
Number of days since the last coupon date
A=C .
Number of days between the two coupon dates
It is noteworthy that the price quoted (clean price) for a bond is often not
the same as the cash price (dirty price) you would pay if you purchased it. In
fact, we have
Dirty Price = Clean Price + Accrued Interest.
The theoretical price mentioned in the previous section is logically the cash price
(dirty price).
7 Forward Rates
The forward rates are the rates of interest implied by current zero rates for
periods of time in the future. It will be in partiuclar useful for the pricing of
the forward rate agreements (FRA) in the next section. Suppose we have
L as the principal and consider the time period [t, T ]. Then the cash flow of a
saving with the forward rate is:
lending L amount of money at time t
obtaining LeRf (T t) at time T .
Assume the investors can borrow/lend money at the zero rate R(0, t) for the
period [0, t] and at R(0, T ) for the period [0, T ]. Then the forward rate will be
locked as
R(0, T ) T R(0, t) t
Rf = .
T t
8. FORWARD RATE AGREEMENTS 9
One can deduce this result by the mentioned cash flow through no-arbitrage
argument.
where RF is the forward rate compounded once at T , and thus different from
Rf in the previous section. More precisely, we have
eRf (T t) 1
RF = .
T t
Exercise: What is the yield of the underlying cash flow of the FRA ?
There is an alternative characterization of FRAs. Review the cash flow of
the FRA. In fact, one may borrow L amount of money at time t with the rate
R (compounded only at T ). As a result, the investor does not need to pay L at
time t, instead she need to pay L(1 + R(T t)). Therefore, the new cash flow
is:
Time t: 0
Time T : L(RK R)(T t)
Remark 8.1 At time 0, the rate R is unknown (as a random variable), and it
is only determined at time t. In many cases, R is closely related to the zero rate
R(0, t), and they are only different in the respect of compoundings, i.e.
eR(t,T )(T t) 1
R= .
T t
The new cash flow shows that an FRA is equivalent to an agreement where
interest at a fixed rate RK is exchanged for interest at the market rate R. This
interpretation will be useful when we consider interest rate swaps in the next
chapter.
10 CHAPTER 2. INTEREST RATES MARKET
9 Duration
In Section 4, we introduced yield of a bond. Indeed, yield can be defined to any
cash flow in the same way, that is, the price P and the yield y of a cash flow
must satisfy:
n
X
P = ci eyti
i=1
The duration D is a measurement for how long on average the holder of the
corresponding asset has to wait before receiving the payments. It is defined as
Pn yti n
i=1 ti ci e
X ci eyti
D := = ti ,
P i=1
P
ci eyti
that is, D is the average of {ti }1in with the weight P on ti for each
1 i n.
It is easy to note that
P
= P D. (9.1)
y
Therefore, the duration is clearly a measurement of sensitivity of asset prices to
the change of yields.
The proceeding analysis is based on the assumption that the yield y is ex-
pressed with continuous compounding. Slightly different to the current case, if
y is expressed with the compounding frequency of m times per year, the cash
price of the cash flow will (approximately) be
n
X y mti
P = ci 1 + .
i=1
m
and (9.1) still holds true. Note that as y is a small number and thus
y mti
1+ eyti ,
m
we have approximately
D
D =
1 + y/m
10. CONVEXITY 11
10 Convexity
From (9.1) we learn that the duration can provide the first order approxima-
tion to the asset price, if a slight change on the yield y happens. In some
circumstances, we urge a higher order approximation. That leads to the notion
convexity, C:
n
X ci eyti
1 2P
C := = t2i .
P y 2 i=1
P
M P 0 M P 0 D0 y.
Together with the original portfolio that the investor holds, the change of the
total wealth will be
P M P 0 P Dy + M P 0 D0 y.
Therefore, if M = PP0 DD
0 , then the change of wealth will be almost 0, that is, the
investor successfully avoid most of the risk (brought by the original portfolio),
by shorting PP0 D
D
0 bonds.
12 CHAPTER 2. INTEREST RATES MARKET
Chapter 3
Swap
where L is the amount of principal, ti are the payment dates (of fixed-rate
interests) and t = ti+1 ti .
Next we study the cash flow of the floating-rate payments. Let {sj }1jm
be the payment dates. Denote by R(sj , sj+1 ) the zero rate on the time period
[sj , sj+1 ]. Then the interest of the floating rate on date sj+1 will be
Ij+1 = L(eR(sj ,sj+1 )s 1).
In order to study the discounted value of the cash flow, we recall the pricing of
the FRA contracts. Take an FRA considering the time period [sj , sj+1 ] and of
RK = 0. We know from Remark 8.1 that the cash flow of the FRA is one single
payment equal to Ij+1 (one can calculate it using the formulas in Section 8
Chapter 2) on the date sj+1 , and thus the cash price of the FRA on time 0 is
V0j+1 = L eR(0,sj+1 )sj+1 eR(0,sj )sj .
Therefore, the value of the cash flow of the floating-rate interests is equal to
m
X
V0f loat = (V0j ) = L 1 eR(0,T )T .
j=1
13
14 CHAPTER 3. SWAP
Finally, the cash price of the swap from which the holder receives the fixed-rate
interests and pays the floating-rate ones is equal to
n
X
P0swap = V0f ix V0f loat = LrteR(0,ti )ti + LeR(0,T )T L. (1.1)
i=1
In practice, the financial institutes, for example the banks, play the intermediate
roles between the companies. See examples in Section 7.1 in [1].
15
16 CHAPTER 4. DISCRETE TIME MODELS
Bibliography
[1] J. Hull, Options, Futures, and Other Dervatives, fifth edition, Pearson Edu-
cation, 2003.
17