Philippine Competition Commission Merger Review Guidelines
Philippine Competition Commission Merger Review Guidelines
Philippine Competition Commission Merger Review Guidelines
This document was written for informational purposes only. It is not a substitute for the
Philippine Competition Act (PCA) or its Implementing Rules and Regulations (IRR). The
Philippine Competition Commission (PCC) may revise this publication in the future. This
document should not be taken as legal advice. If you have any doubt as to how you may be
affected by the PCA, please consult with a lawyer or contact us.
Permission to reproduce
Except as otherwise specifically noted, the information in this publication may be reproduced,
in part or in whole and by any means, without charge or further permission from PCC;
provided that due diligence is exercised in ensuring the accuracy of the information
reproduced; that the PCC is properly identified as the source; and that the reproduction is not
represented as an official version of the information reproduced, nor as having been made in
affiliation with, or with the endorsement of PCC.
Contact Us
1. Introduction 1
2. Rationale for merger review 2
5. Market Definition 8
A. The Hypothetical Monopolist Test 9
B. Targeted Customers and Price Discrimination 14
C. Supply-side Substitution 15
9. Efficiencies 27
11. Remedies 30
12. Decision 31
13. Interpretation 32
1. Introduction
1.1. These Guidelines on substantive merger analysis are issued by the Philippine
Competition Commission (the “Commission”) pursuant to Section 16 of Republic
Act No. 10677, otherwise known as the Philippine Competition Act (“PCA”).
1.2. These Guidelines outline the principal analytical techniques, practices, and the
enforcement policy of the Commission with respect to mergers and acquisitions
that may have a direct, substantial and reasonably foreseeable effect on trade,
industry, or commerce in the Philippines. These are adapted from the International
Competition Network (ICN) Recommended Practices for Merger Analysis, which are
derived from the ICN Merger Guidelines Workbook and common practices across
member jurisdictions, tailored to apply to Philippine commercial and legal practices
and made consistent with the PCA, and the Implementing Rules and Regulations of
Republic Act No. 10667 (“IRR”).
1.3. The purpose of these Guidelines is to increase the transparency of the analytical
process undertaken by the Commission and thereby assist the business community
and competition law practitioners. These Guidelines may also assist the courts in
developing an appropriate framework for interpreting and applying the PCA, the
IRR and other regulations relating to mergers.
1.4. The Commission will consider each merger with due regard to the attendant
circumstances, including the information available and the time constraints, and will
apply these guidelines flexibly, or where appropriate, deviate therefrom.
1.5. The Commission may revise these Guidelines from time to time to reflect
developments and may publish new or supplemental guidance.
2.1. Most mergers do not harm competition and may in fact contribute to consumer
welfare. Many mergers enable the merged firm to reduce costs and become more
efficient, leading to lower prices, higher quality, higher quantity and diversity of
products, or increased investment in innovation.
2.2. Some mergers, however, may harm competition by creating or enhancing the
merged firm’s ability or incentives to exercise market power—either unilaterally or
through coordination with rivals—resulting in price increases above competitive
levels for a significant period of time, reductions in quality or a slowing of innovation.
2.3. Through merger control, the Commission prevents mergers that would likely
deprive customers of the benefits of competition by significantly increasing market
power of firms. When exercised by sellers, market power is the ability to profitably
raise prices above competitive levels for a significant period of time, and/or to lessen
competition on parameters other than price, such as quality, service, or innovation.
2.4. When exercised by buyers, market power is the ability to profitably reduce
the price paid to suppliers below competitive levels for a significant period of time,
which may lead to an anti-competitive reduction in supplier output.
3.3. The term “entity” is defined in Section 4(h) of the PCA as “any person, natural
or juridical, sole proprietorship, partnership, combination or association in any
form, whether incorporated or not, domestic or foreign, including those owned
or controlled by the government, engaged directly or indirectly in any economic
activity.” As such, an entity need not be a separate legal entity. For instance, an
unregistered partnership, an unincorporated joint venture, or an unincorporated
association are considered entities under the PCA.
3.4. The term “economic activity” does not only cover activities that generate profits
or dividends for shareholders; it may also include activities conducted on a not-for-
profit basis.
3.5. “Control” as used in Section 3.2 above is defined under the PCA as the ability
to substantially influence or direct the actions or decisions of an entity, whether by
contract, agency or otherwise. Control of an entity may either be legal or de facto.
3.6. Such control may be acquired by an entity acting alone or by two or more
entities acting together. The control acquired may be over one (1) or more entities
or over the whole or part of another entity or assets, including goodwill, brand, or
licenses, of such entity. Examples of acquisitions are buying a majority stake in an
entity and transfer or pooling of assets.
3.7. Control is presumed to exist when the acquisition will result in the parent of
the acquiring entity owning directly or indirectly, through its subsidiaries, more than
one half (1/2) of the voting power of the entity to be acquired, unless in exceptional
circumstances, it can clearly be demonstrated that such ownership will not constitute
control.
3.8. Where the ownership is one half (1/2) or less of the power of the entity to be
acquired, control is presumed to exist if: a. there is power over more than one half
(1/2) of the voting rights by virtue of an agreement with investors; b. there is power
to direct or govern the financial and operating policies of the entity under a statute
3.9. Acquisition of the whole or part of the assets of an entity also includes those
acquisitions which result in an entity being in a position to replace, or substantially
replace, the acquired entity in the business or in part of the relevant business, or
allow an acquirer to build up a market presence or develop market access within a
reasonably short period of time.
3.10. Assessment of whether the acquisition will bestow control to the acquiring
entity requires a case-by-case analysis of the entire relationship between the merging
parties. In making this assessment, the Commission will evaluate not only the legal
effect of any instrument, deed, assignment, or any other agreements between the
merger parties but also other relevant circumstances such as the source of financing
for the acquisition, family links and economic relationships.
3.11. For purposes of these Guidelines, mergers and acquisitions will be collectively
referred to as mergers.
4.2. The objective of the PCA is to foster and promote competition. Thus, in
reviewing mergers, the Commission will look at the effects on competition over
time in the relevant market or markets affected by the merger. A merger gives
rise to an SLC when it has a significant effect on competition, and consequently,
on the competitive pressure on firms to reduce prices, improve quality, become
more efficient or innovative. A merger that gives rise to an SLC is likely to lead to an
adverse effect on consumers.
The Commission will also take into account any substantiated efficiencies proferred
by the parties to the proposed merger, which are likely to arise from the transaction.
4.4. While a merger review typically begins with a discussion of market definition
(see Section 5 below), there are instances where the Commission’s analysis need
not start with market definition. Evidence of competitive effects can inform market
definition, just as market definition can be informative of competitive effects.
4.6. In considering the range of possible factual scenarios and competitive effects,
the Commission will turn to reasonably available and reliable evidence. The most
common sources of reasonable and reliable evidence are the merging parties,
customers, other industry participants, government offices, and industry observers.
The Commission typically obtains substantial information from the merging parties.
This information can take the form of documents, testimony, or data, and can consist
of descriptions of competitively relevant conditions or reflect actual business
conduct or decisions.
4.7. Mergers can be classified into two broad categories: horizontal mergers and
non-horizontal mergers.
4.8. While the present guidance focuses on horizontal mergers, its underlying
principles can also be applied to non-horizontal mergers. In the future, the
Commission will release guidance relevant to non-horizontal mergers.
4.9. In analyzing horizontal mergers, the Commission will generally look at the
impact of the merger on the markets in which transacting entities supply goods and
services, and other related markets, e.g. vertical and complementary.
4.10. Theories of harm provide the framework for assessing the effects of a merger
and whether or not it could lead to an SLC (see Section 7 below). They describe
possible changes in the market arising from the merger, any impact on competition
and expected harm to consumers as compared with the situation likely to arise
without the merger. For some mergers, several theories affecting the same market
may be considered. The Commission may revise the theories of harm as their
assessment progresses.
4.13. Arrangements and agreements that are entered into by the merging parties,
which restrict such parties’ freedom of action in the market, will be included in
the Commission’s merger analysis. Agreements which contain a restriction on
competition, but are not directly related and necessary to the implementation of
the merger, may be the subject of Sections 14 and 15 of the PCA.
5.2. The Commission assesses market definition within the context of the particular
facts and circumstances of the merger under review. Competitive conditions
change over time and may vary in different geographic areas. While relevant
markets identified in past investigations in the same industry or in investigations by
agencies in other jurisdictions may be informative, they may not be applicable to
the Commission’s assessment of the merger in question when, for example, market
conditions differ (or have evolved) over time or across geographic areas. The
Commission exercises particular care in defining markets where the choice among
possible market definitions may have a significant impact on market shares.
5.3. Market definition is a step in the analytical process which helps in determining
whether the merged entity possesses or will, post-merger, possess market power.
For example, in some cases, the Commission may gather more evidence regarding
likely competitive effects. In other cases, it may be clear that a merger will not
create or enhance market power in any market, or that competitive harm would be
predicted in any market. In such circumstances, the Commission may not need to
reach a firm conclusion on the scope of the relevant market.
5.4. An exercise of market power is feasible only when customers would not
sufficiently reduce their demand for the relevant product(s), or divert sufficient
demand to other products or to other locations, so as to make a price increase
(or other lessening of competition) unprofitable. Thus, market definition depends
primarily upon demand-side substitution, which focuses on the extent to which
customers would likely switch from one product to another, or from a supplier in
one geographic area to a supplier in another area, in response to changes in prices,
quality, availability, or other features.
5.8. Once a market is defined, the Commission will, where circumstances require,
consider market shares and concentration as part of the evaluation of competitive
effects. Market shares and concentration are considered in conjunction with other
reasonably available evidence. Market shares are a relevant aspect of the review
process because they can influence firms’ competitive incentives and reflect their
capabilities. For example, as an initial indicator, when the combined post-merger
market share of the merged entity is high, competition concerns may arise because
a firm may be more reluctant to impose price reductions or pass on cost savings.
Conversely, when market shares are low it may be possible to dismiss any concerns
or the need for further review.
5.9. Some mergers may have potential effects in more than one relevant product
market or geographic market, and may require an independent competitive
assessment of each market in which a potential competitive concern arises. The
Commission will examine all the relevant markets that may be potentially impacted
by a merger to determine whether significant harm to competition is likely to occur in
any of them. In addition, supply considerations also play a key role in understanding
the competitive constraints on the merging firms.
5.11. In most cases, the Commission uses the prevailing prices of the products
of the merging firms and possible substitutes as a starting point for application
of the SSNIP test. Where pre-merger circumstances strongly suggest coordinated
interaction or other evidence strongly indicates that current prices are above
competitive levels, the Commission may consider using a price more reflective of
the competitive price.
5.12. What constitutes a “small but significant and non-transitory increase in price”
will depend on the nature of the industry, but a common benchmark is a price
increase of between 5% and 10% lasting for the foreseeable future (e.g., one to
three years depending on market conditions and the type of market).
5.13. The Commission generally applies the “smallest market principle” to identify
a relevant product and geographic market that is no bigger than necessary to
satisfy the SSNIP test. At times, however, it may be appropriate to define broader
markets. In some cases, applying the smallest market principle may fail to detect
a horizontal overlap of concern between the merging parties. In other cases,
where the competitive effects analysis is the same for a broader market, it may be
unnecessary to define the smallest market. Similarly, it may be appropriate as a
matter of convenience to aggregate markets where the competitive effects analysis
is the same across a group of products or geographic areas, each of which could be
defined as a separate relevant market.
C. Supply-side Substitution
5.18. The Commission may consider the potential for supply-side substitution,
and whether to include as participants in the relevant market not only all firms that
currently produce or sell in the relevant market, but also firms that, in response to
a SSNIP in the relevant market, would likely produce or sell in the relevant market
within a short time frame without incurring significant sunk costs.
Sunk Costs: The term “sunk costs” means the acquisition costs of tangible
and intangible assets necessary to manufacture and sell the relevant product
or provide the relevant service that cannot be recovered through the
redeployment of these assets for other uses. Entry of a new firm is not likely if
the anticipated reward were not commensurate with the risk from being unable
to recover sunk costs.
5.19. The relevant question for analysis is not whether a firm has the capability to
produce or sell the relevant product, but whether it would likely make such sales
profitably in response to a SSNIP. If a firm has existing assets that could be shifted
or extended quickly into production or sale of the relevant product in the relevant
geographic market, it does not necessarily mean that (a) the firm would have the
incentive to produce or sell the relevant product, (b) the firm would entirely switch
or extend its production or sales of the relevant product, or (c) all firms producing
the other product would do so.
6.2. Mergers that require more attention are those that significantly increase market
concentration. The change in concentration caused by a merger is a useful, although
imperfect, indicator of the loss of direct competition between the parties and of the
potential for competitive harm.
6.3. In interpreting market shares and concentration, the Commission may consider,
among others, extent of product differentiation, how widely the market is drawn,
movements in market shares over time, the level of variable profit margins, and
market structure. The Commission may also use other indicators to determine the
firms’ competitive significance, for instance, when market shares do not provide a
realistic indication of the merging firms’ market power.
6.4. Market share and concentration estimates used for merger analysis are
deemed to reflect the best available indication of the firms’ future competitive
significance. Measurements may be based on units or monetary values, volume of
sales, production, supply and number of customers, as may be appropriate.
6.7. The Herfindahl-Hirshman Index (HHI), among other tools for measuring market
concentration, helps interpret market share data. The HHI is calculated by summing
the squares of the market shares of all the firms active in the market. When using
HHIs, the Commission considers both the post-merger level of the HHI and the
increase in the HHI resulting from the merger. The increase in the HHI is equal to
twice the product of the market shares of the merging firms.
6.10. These indications, however, are not meant to be a conclusive screen to separate
competitively benign mergers from anti-competitive ones. Rather, they provide
one way of identifying mergers unlikely to raise competitive concerns and those
that which require further examination of other competitive factors that confirm,
reinforce, or counteract the potentially harmful effects of increased concentration.
The higher the post-merger HHI and the increase in the HHI, the greater are the
potential competitive concerns.
7.2. While changes in market share or market concentration are useful indicators
of potential competitive concerns, competitive effects analysis involves a
comprehensive assessment of market conditions, and provides a more reliable
means to assess potential harm to competition than changes in market share or
market concentration alone.
7.4. There are two conceptually distinct means by which a horizontal merger might
result in substantial lessening of competition: unilateral effects and coordinated
effects. It is possible that a merger may raise both types of concern.
A. Unilateral Effects
7.5. In analyzing the potential of a horizontal merger to result in anti-competitive
unilateral effects, the Commission assesses whether the merger is likely to harm
competition significantly by creating or enhancing the merged firm’s ability or
incentives to exercise market power independently.
7.6. Horizontal mergers eliminate any competitive constraint that the merging
parties previously exerted upon each another. In most mergers, this has no significant
adverse effect on competition because there are other sufficient competitive
constraints on the merged entity. In some mergers, however, the elimination of
competition between the merging parties in itself may create or enhance the ability
of the merged firm independently to exercise market power, depending on market
conditions, including the lack or ineffectiveness of other competitive constraints.
7.7. Mergers may increase the likelihood of the exercise of unilateral market power
in a variety of settings. Common theories and models include, but are not limited to:
7.8. Competitive effects analysis depends heavily on the specific facts of each merger.
As such, the Commission will refine its theories or models of likely competitive harm
based on available qualitative and quantitative evidence.
B. Coordinated Effects
7.10. In analyzing the potential for coordinated effects, the Commission assesses
whether the merger increases the likelihood that firms in the market will successfully
coordinate their behavior or strengthen existing coordination in a manner that
harms competition.
7.13. Coordinated behavior may be tacit or explicit. For example, firms may
coordinate their behavior on prices in order to keep them above the competitive
level, or firms may coordinate to limit production or the amount of new capacity
brought to the market. Firms may also coordinate by dividing the market, for instance
by geographic area or other customer characteristics, or by allocating contracts in
bidding markets. Other forms of coordinated behavior that are likely to result in an
SLC will also be examined by the Commission.
7.17. To deter deviations from the terms of coordination, firms must have the ability
to punish deviations in a manner that will ensure that coordinating firms find it more
profitable to adhere to the terms of coordination than to deviate, given the cost of
reprisal. Punishment may take various forms, including temporary abandonment of
the terms of coordination by other firms in the market. In assessing whether there
will be a sufficiently credible and severe punishment when a deviation by one of the
firms is detected, the Commission looks at relevant factors that include, but are not
limited to:
7.18. Other factors, such as the presence of the same firms in several markets
(sometimes called “multi-market contacts”), may also be of relevance in determining
the likelihood of sufficiently credible and severe punishment.
8.2. Entry, or the threat of entry from potential competitors or from customers turning
to in-house supply, can be an important competitive constraint on the conduct of
the merged firm. If the merged firm is subject to significant competitive constraints
from the threat of market entry (e.g., if barriers to entry are low and entry is likely
to be profitable at premerger prices), the merger is unlikely to have meaningful
anticompetitive effects.
8.3. The ability of rival firms to expand capacity in a timely manner, or use existing
spare capacity or switch capacity from one use to another, can constitute an important
competitive constraint on the merged firm’s conduct. Many of the factors that are
used to assess entry are relevant to the analysis of expansion, including competitor
expansion plans, barriers to expansion, and the profitability of expansion.
8.4. In assessing whether entry and/or expansion would effectively constrain the
merged entity, the Commission considers whether entry and/or expansion would
be: (a) likely; (b) timely; and, (c) sufficient in nature, scale and scope.
8.5. For entry and/or expansion to be likely, it should be profitable for competitors of
the merged entity to expand output and/or for potential entrants to enter the market
in response to an attempt by the merged entity to profit from the potential reduction
in competition brought about by the merger (e.g., a post-merger price increase).
8.6. In assessing the likelihood of entry, the Commission considers the history of
entry into and/or exit from the relevant market using available evidence, including
information on firms that have recently entered or exited the market, information
about past and expected market growth, evidence of planned entry and/or
expansion, direct observation of the costs, risks and benefits associated with entry
and information from firms identified as potential entrants. Further, the Commission
considers the existence and significance of barriers to entry and expansion to the
relevant market. Relevant factors include, but are not limited to:
a) Economies of scope and/or scale, the availability of a scarce
resource that is an essential input, technical capability or
intellectual property rights;
b) The reputation of incumbent firms, incumbent firms’
investment in excessive capacity, or the duration, termination
and renewal provisions in existing contracts;
c) Government regulations that might, for example, limit the
number of market participants or impose substantial regulatory
approval costs;
8.8. For entry and/or expansion to be sufficient, the Commission considers whether
entry and/or expansion would be:
a) Sufficient in scale to compete effectively with the merged entity;
9.3. Efficiencies that increase competition in the market may also be considered.
9.4. Efficiencies are difficult to verify, and many projected efficiencies may never
be realized. Thus, as noted in PCA Chapter IV, Section 22, and IRR Rule 4, Section
11, a party seeking to rely on an efficiencies justification must demonstrate that if
the proposed merger or acquisition were implemented, significant efficiency gains
would be realized.
9.5. The burden is on the merging firms to substantiate efficiency claims so that
the Commission can verify by reasonable means the likelihood and magnitude of
each asserted efficiency and how and when each would be achieved, among other
things.
9.6. In order to be taken into account by the Commission, the efficiencies must
be demonstrable, with detailed and verifiable evidence of anticipated price
reductions or other benefits. Moreover, the efficiency gains must be merger specific
and consumers will not be worse off as a result of the merger. For that purpose,
efficiencies should be substantial and timely, and should, in principle, benefit
consumers in those relevant markets where it is otherwise likely that competition
concerns would occur.
9.7. Merger specific efficiencies are those likely to be accomplished with the
proposed merger and unlikely to be accomplished in the absence of either the
proposed merger or another means having comparable anti-competitive effects.
9.8. The greater the potential adverse competitive effect of a merger, the greater
must be the demonstrated efficiencies, and the more they must be passed through
to customers.
10.2. A merger is not likely to create or enhance market power if one of the merging
parties is likely to fail and its assets are likely to exit the market in the imminent
future. In this case, the counterfactual (the competitive situation absent the merger)
may be adjusted to reflect such likelihood.
10.3. The basis for concluding that a merger with a failing firm does not harm
competition is that the competition provided by a failing firm would be lost even
without the merger and, consequently, the competitive situation post-merger may
be no worse than the counterfactual (i.e. no merger but failing firm exists the market).
In other words, the Commission may conclude, based on the failing firm doctrine,
that the merger has no causal connection with worsened competitive conditions in
the future.
10.4. The burden of proof of exit lies on the merging parties, who also hold
the relevant evidence. In the absence of sufficient evidential support for exit, the
Commission cannot make use of the failing firm analysis.
10.5. Many firms, despite temporary difficulties, are able to survive and continue
competing. The fact that a firm has not been profitable does not necessarily mean
that it is a “failing firm.” For instance, a firm with a substantial debt may be able to
emerge from its financial trouble as an effective competitor through a new business
strategy or new management because it possesses valuable assets.
10.6. The material tests for showing that one of the merging parties is failing are
that (a) the firm is unable to meet its financial obligations in the imminent future; (b)
there would be no serious prospect of reorganizing the business; (c) there would be
no credible less anti-competitive alternative outcome than the merger in question;
and, (d) the firm and its assets would exit the market in the imminent future absent
the merger.
10.7. Merging firms should provide as evidence profit and loss and cash flow
information, recent balance sheets and analysis of the most recent statutory accounts,
the timing and nature of the firm’s financial obligations, the relationship between the
company’s costs and its revenues, the likely ability of the firm to obtain new revenues
or new customers, and the current and future availability of key inputs. Prospective
financial information and forecast information for the current year should also be
provided.
10.9. The Commission shall likewise consider whether the failure of the firm and
the liquidation of its assets could be a less anti-competitive alternative to the merger
since the remaining firms in the market would compete for the failing firm’s market
share and assets that otherwise would have been transferred wholesale to a single
purchaser.
11.2. In this regard, there are two types of remedies that the Commission may
consider: structural remedies and behavioral remedies.
a. Structural remedies are measures that directly alter market structure and
address issues that give rise to competition problems. Basic forms of
this type are divestitures (forced sale of business units or assets, either
in full or partial), licensing (compulsory licensing of legal rights, usually
intellectual property rights), rescission (undoing a completed transaction)
and dissolution (ending a legal entity).
12.3. The Commission’s decision on the merger may not be challenged under the
Act, unless it was obtained on the basis of fraud or false material information.