Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensions Walter
Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensions Walter
Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensions Walter
The problems in this chapter focus on competitive supply behavior in both the short and long
runs. For short-run analysis, students are usually asked to construct the industry supply curve (by
summing firms’ marginal cost curves) and then to describe the resulting market equilibrium.
The long-run problems (10.5– 10.8), on the other hand, make extensive use of the equilibrium
condition P = MC = AC to derive results. In most cases, students are asked to graph their
solutions because, I believe, such graphs provide considerable intuition about what is going on.
Comments on Problems
10.1 This problem asks students to constructs a marginal cost function from a cubic cost
function and then use this to derive a supply curve and a supply-demand equilibrium.
The math is rather easy so this is a good starting problem.
10.2 A problem that illustrates “interaction effects.” As industry output expands, the wage for
diamond cutters rises, thereby raising costs for all firms.
10.3 This is a simple, though at times tedious, problem that shows that any one firm’s output
decision has very little effect on market price. That is shown to be especially true when
other firms exhibit an elastic supply response in reaction to any price changes induced by
any one firm altering its output. That is, any one firm’s effect on price is moderated by
the induced effect on other firms.
10.4 This is a tax-incidence problem. It shows that the less elastic the supply curve, the
greater the share of tax paid this is paid by firms (for a given demand curve). Issues of
tax incidence are discussed in much greater detail in Chapter 11.
10.5 This is a simple problem that uses only long-run analysis. Once students recognize that
the equilibrium price will always be $3.00 per bushel and the typical firm always
produces 1,000 bushels, the calculations are trivial.
10.6 A problem that is similar to 10.5, but now introduces the short-run supply curve to
examine differences in supply response over the short and long runs.
10.7 This problem introduces the concept of increasing input costs into long-sun analysis by
assuming that entrepreneurial wages are bid up as the industry expands. Solving part (b)
can be a bit tricky; perhaps an educated guess is the best way to proceed.
10.8 This exercise looks at an increase in cost that also shifts the low point of the typical
firm’s AC curve. Here the increase in cost reduces optimal firm size and has the
44
Chapter 10/The Partial Equilibrium Competitive Model 45
seemingly odd effect of a cost increase leading to a fall in quantity demanded but an
increase in the number of firms.
Solutions
1 3
C(q) q .2q 4q 10 MC(q) .01q2 .4q 4
2
10.1
300
5 P 50, P 25 Q 3000
10.2 C = q2 + wq MC 2q w
a. w = 10 C = q2 + 10q
MC = 2q + 10 = P q 0.5P 5
1000
Industry Q q 500P 5000
1
P = 20, Q = 5000 Supply is more steeply sloped in this case where expanded output
bids up wages.
P = 21, Q = 5250
46 Solutions Manual
10.3 a. Very short run, QS = (100)(1000) = 100,000. Since there can be no supply response,
this Q must be sold for whatever the market will bear:
160,000 – 10,000P = 100,000. P* = 6
b. For any one firm, quantity supplied by other firms is fixed at 99,900.
Demand curve facing firm is q = 160,000 – 10,000P – 99,900 = 60,100 – 10,000P.
c. If quantity supplied by the firm is zero,
qS = 0 = qD = 60,100 – 10,000P. P* = 6.01
If quantity supplied by the firm is 200,
qS = 200 = qD = 60,100 – 10,000P P* = 5.99
6
d. eQ,P = – 10, 000 ? 6
100, 000
6
For single firm: eq,P = – 10, 000 ? 00.
100
Demand facing the single firm is “close to” infinitely elastic. Now redo these parts
with short-run supply of qi = – 200 + 50P
a. QS = 1000qi = – 200,000 + 50,000P
Set supply = demand: Resulting equilibrium price is P* = 6
b. For any one firm, find net demand by subtracting supply by other 999 firms.
qD = 160,000 – 10,000P – (– 199,800 + 49,950P) = 359,800 – 59,950P
359,800
c. If q S 0, P 6.002 .
*
59, 950
359, 600
If q S 200, P 5.998 .
*
59, 950
d. Elasticity of the industry demand curve remains the same. Demand curve facing the
firm is even more elastic than in the fixed supply case:
6
e q p 59, 950 3597.
100
10.4 a. QD = 100 – 2P QS = 20 + 6P
At equilibrium, QD = QS.
100 – 2P = 20 + 6P P* = $10, Q* = 80
b. Demanders and suppliers are now faced with different prices PS = PD – 4. Each will
make decisions on quantity based on the price that it is faced with:
QD = 100 – 2PD QS = 20 + 6PS = 20 + 6(PD – 4).
Chapter 10/The Partial Equilibrium Competitive Model 47
b. QS = QD = 3,200,000 – 200,000P
In the short run, QS = 2,000,000, so 2,000,000 = 3,200,000 – 200,000P
1,200,000 = 200,000P P = $6/bushel
q(P AC) 1000(6 3) 3000
c. P = $3/bushel in the long run.
QS = QD = 3,200,000 – 200,000(3) = 2,600,000 bushels
2, 600, 000 bushels
There will be = 2, 600 farms.
1000 bushels/farm
d.
48 Solutions Manual
4n
In long run equilibrium: AC = MC so q 10 .5q 10
q
4n
.5q q 8n
q
Total output is given in terms of the number of firms by Q nq n 8n . Now in
n = 50 (= # of entrepreneurs)
Qn 1000
q = Q/n = 20
P = q – 10 = 10
Chapter 10/The Partial Equilibrium Competitive Model 49
w = 4n = 200.
b. Algebra as before, (n 50) 2928 , therefore n = 72
Qn 1728
q = Q/n = 24
P = q – 10 = 14
w = 4n = 288
c.
This curve is upward sloping because as new firms enter the industry the cost curves
shift up: AC 0.5q 10 (4n q) as n increases, AC increases.
b. Constant costs industry means that as new firms enter this low point of average, total
cost remains unchanged, resulting in a horizontal supply curve at P = $10 (when
q = 10, AC = $10). Thus, long-run equilibrium P = $10 and Q = 30,000. There will
30, 000
be = 3,000 firms.
10
100
8q – 10 = 4q – 10 + , q2 = 25, q = 5.
q
Long-run equilibrium price = low point of AC, = 30.
Thus, Q = – 1,000(30) + 40,000 = 10,000.
10, 000
There will be = 2,000 firms.
5
The problems in this chapter are intended to illustrate the types of calculations made using
simple competitive models for applied welfare analysis. Usually the problems start from a
supply-demand framework much like that used for the problems in Chapter 10. Students are
then asked to evaluate the effects of changing equilibria on the welfare of market participants.
Notice that, throughout the problems, consumer surplus is measured as the area below the
Marshallian (uncompensated) demand curve.
Comments on Problems
11.1 Illustrates some simple consumer and producer surplus calculations. Results of this
problem are used later to examine price controls (Problem 11.4) and tax incidence
(Problem 11.5).
11.2 This problem illustrates the computations of short-run produce surplus in a simple linear
case.
11.3 An increasing cost example that illustrates long-run producer surplus. Notice that both
producer surplus and rent calculations must be made incrementally so that total values
will add-up properly.
11.4 A continuation of Problem 11.1 that examines the welfare consequences of price controls.
11.5 Another continuation of Problem 11.1 that examines tax incidence with a variety of
different demand and supply curves. The solutions also provide an elasticity
interpretation of this problem.
11.6 A continuation of Problem 11.2 that looks at the effects of taxation on short-run producer
surplus.
11.7 A continuation of Problem 11.3 that examines tax incidence, long-run producer surplus,
and changes in input rents.
11.8 Provides some simple computations of the deadweight losses involved with tariffs.
11.9 A continuation of Problem 11.8 that examines marginal excess burden. Notice that the
increase in the tariff rate actually reduces tariff revenue in this problem.
11.10 A graphical analysis for the case of a country that faces a positively sloped supply curve
for imports.
51
Solutions
11.1 a. Set QD = QS 1000 – 5P = 4P -80 P* = 120, Q* = 400.
For consumers, Pmax = 200 For producers, Pmin = 20
11.5 a. Because the gap between PD and PS is 45 at Q = 300 in Problem 11.1, that is the post
tax equilibrium. Total taxes = 13,500.
b. Consumers pay (140 – 120)(300) = 6,000 (46%)
Producers pay (120 – 95)(300) = 7,500 (54%)
c. Excess burden = Deadweight Loss = 2250 from 11.1 part b.
d. QD = 2250 – 15 PD = 4PS – 80 = 4(PD – 45) – 80
19PD = 2460 PD = 129.47 PS = 84.47
Q = 258 tax = 11,610
Consumers pay 258(129.47 – 120) = 2,443 (21%)
Producers pay 258(120 – 84.47) = 9,167 (79%)
53
e. QD = 1000 – 5PD = 10(PD – 45) – 800
2250 = 15PD PD = 150 PS = 105
Q = 250 Total tax = 11,250
Consumers pay 250(150 – 120) = 7500 (67%)
Producers pay 250(120 – 105) = 3750 (33%)
f. Elasticities in the three cases are
Part a eD = – 5(140/300) = – 2.3 eS = 4(95/300) = 1.3
Part d eD = – 15(129/258) = – 7.5 eS = 4(84/300) = 1.12
Part e eD = – 5(150/250) = – 3.0 eS = 10(105/250) = 4.20
Although these elasticity estimates are only approximates, the calculations clearly
show that the relative sizes of the elasticities determine the tax burden.
54
Chapter 11/Applying the Competitive Model 55
55
11.10 a. In the graph D is the demand for importable goods, SD is the domestic supply curve
and SD+F is the supply curve for domestic and foreign goods. Domestic Equilibrium
is at E1 , free trade equilibrium is at E2. Imports are given byQ2 Q3 .
b. A tariff shifts SD+F to S'D+F = Equilibrium is at E3. Imports fall and quantity
supplied domestically increases.
c., d. Losses of consumer surplus can be illustrated in much the same way as in the
infinitely elastic supply case. Gains of domestic producer surplus can also be shown
in a way similar to that used previously. In this case, however, some portion of tariff
revenue is paid by the foreign producers since the price rise from P2 to P3 is less than
the amount of the tariff (given by the vertical distance between S'D+F and SD+F).
These tariffs may partly affect the deadweight losses of domestic consumer surplus.
56