Who Learns What From Whom: A Review of The Policy Transfer Literature
Who Learns What From Whom: A Review of The Policy Transfer Literature
Who Learns What From Whom: A Review of The Policy Transfer Literature
DAVID
DOLOWITZ MARSH
AND DAVID
Department of Political Science and International Studies,
University of Birmingham
’
K. Rose. Lesson-drawing in Public Polic!.: a Guide 10 Lmwning a c r o s Time and Space (New
Jersey. Chatham House. 1993).
‘
J. Walker. The diffusion of innovations among the American states’. The American Polilical
Scicwcc Revielt., 3 3 (1969). 880-99.
( Political Studieb Associaison. 1996
Review Section 345
advanced the weaknesses of the approach emerged; so that by the 1980s a major
critical review argued: ‘(the) major problem of this research tradition is that it
reveals nothing about the content of new policies. Its fascination is with process
not s~bstance’.~ It was as a result of this perceived need to answer questions
ignored by diffusion studies that comparative policy analysts began discussing
lesson drawing and policy transfer.
Initially transfer studies primarily focused upon voluntary transfer, seeing the
process as one in which policies implemented elsewhere were examined by
rational political actors for their potential utilization within another political
system. More recently the literature has begun to address questions concerning
coercive transfer.
Policy EntrepreneurslExperts
As Rose points out, policy entrepreneurs are not only important to lesson
drawing because of their advocacy of lessons, but also because: ‘their concern
with a special subject . . . leads them to build up a nationwide or international
network of contacts that are a source of ideas for new programs’.’’
The role of such policy entrepreneurs in the international spread of an idea is
clearly illustrated in Rowat’s study of Ombudsmen. He argues:
There is no doubt that some of the ombudsmen themselves have been very
influential in bringing about the further spread of the institution,
particularly Professor Hurwitz of Denmark . . . and Sir Guy Powles of
New Zealand.”
J. Clark, ‘Policy diffusion and program scope’, Publius, 15 (1985) 61-70, p. 65.
See A. Heidenheimer, H. Heclo and C. Adams, Comparative Public Policy (New York, St.
Martins Press, 1990); D. Robertson and J. Waltman, ‘The politics of policy borrowing’, paper
presented to the APSA Annual Meeting, Chicago, 3-6 September (1992).
’ H. Heclo, Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden (New Haven CT, Yale University Press,
1974).
See E. Haas, ‘Why collaborate? Issue-linkage and international regimes’, World Politics, 32
(1980). 357-405, p. 357; H. Wolman, ‘Understanding cross-national policy transfers: the case of
Britain and the US’, Governance, 5 (1992) 27-45, p. 31.
See Rose, Lesson-drawing in Public Policy, p. 56. For further examples see: D. McAdam and
D. Rucht, ‘Cross-national diffusion of movement ideas’, Annals of the American Academy of
Polirical and Social Science, 528 (1993), 56-74, or G. Hoberg, ‘Sleeping with an elephant: the
American influence on Canadian environmental regulation’, Journal of Public Policy, 11 (1991),
107-32.
‘O Rose, Lesson-drawing in Public Policy, p. 56.
I I D. Rowat, The Ombudsman Plan: Essays on World-wide Spread of an Idea (London,
McClelland and Stewart, 1973), pp. 357-76, p. 119.
C Political Studies Association, 1996
346 Re vie Sect ion
In this way experts from inside and outside government interact to spread
ideas in what Haas terms epistemic communities.’*
Supra-national Organizations
As Rose argues:
Intergovernmental and international organizations encourage exchanges of
ideas between countries . . . The European Community and OECD
encourage exchanges among advanced industrial nations . . . and the
World Bank and the United Nations agencies focus on programs of
concern to developing countries.’3
Rose goes on to emphasize that the European Community: ‘promotes com-
parison . . . so that member states can become aware of what their competitors
are doing and decide which elements of foreign programs they may wish to copy
or adapt.14 Similarly, Bennett found that international organizations were
important actors transferring data protection p01icies.I~ One problem with
these studies is they pay too little attention to the fact that international
organizations are also involved in coercive transfer, an issue we shall return to
later.
’’ P. Haas, ‘Do regimes matter? Epistemic communities and mediterranean pollution control’,
Internalional Orgunisarions, 143 (1989), 233-403.
’’ Rose, Lesson-drubring in Public Policy. p. 105. See also Robertson and Waltman, ‘The politics
of policy borrowing’, esp. p. 7.
l 4 Rose, Lesson-druning in Public Policy. p. 105.
’’ C. Bennett, ‘Different processes, one result: the convergence of data protection policy in
Europe and the United States’, Governance. 1 (1988) 425-41, especially p. 431.
l 6 Robertson. ’Political conflict and lesson drawing‘. p. 55.
” Rose, Lesson-druw’ing in Public Policj,. p. 10.
( Political Studies Association. 1996
Review Section 347
C. W. Anderson ’The logic of public problems’ in D. Ashford (ed.), Comparing Public Policies
(Beverly Hills, Sage, 1978). pp. 19-38.
l9 N. Polsby, Political Innovations in America, p. 161.
2o Heclo, Modern Social Politics.
*’
C . Bennett, ‘How states utilize foreign evidence’, Journal of Public Policy, 11 (1991), 31-54,
p. 38.
22 Henig et al., ‘The politics of privatization: a comparative perspective’.
23 Haas, ’Do regimes matter?’, pp. 377-403.
‘Cj Political Studies Association, 1996
348 Review Section
'4 G . Majone, 'Cross-national sources of regulatory policy making in Europe and the United
Styes', Journal of Public Policx. 11 (1991), 79 106, pp. 85-6.
-'For recent examples see: J. Lloyd. 'IMF gives go-ahead for $1.5bn loan to Russia', The
Financial Times. 23 March (1993) or 'Algeria devalues in deal with IMF', The Financial Times,
1 1 April (1994).
''M. Shapiro. 'The European Court of Justice'. Euro-polirics (Washington DC, Brookings
Institute, 1992).
''Heidenheimer et al.. Comparative Public Polio', p. 3 1 1.
''Hoberg. 'Sleeping with an elephant'.
''Haas. 'Why collaborate? Issue-linkage and international regimes'.
1 Polilioal Studies Association. 1996
Review Section 349
What is Transferred?
As is clear from this review to date, it is wrong to think of policy transfer merely
in terms of the successful transfer of policy. Bennett’s review focuses largely
upon the transfer of policy goals, content and instrument^.^^ In our view this
focus is still too narrow. In fact, we identify seven objects of transfer: policy
30 Majone, ‘Cross-national sources of regulatory policy making’, p. 98. See also C. Bennett, ‘The
formation of a Canadian privacy policy: the art and craft of lesson-drawing’, Canadian Public
Administration, 33 (1990), 551-70, p. 563.
3’ C. Bennett, Regulating Privacy (Ithaca NY, Cornell University Press, 1993), p. 118-23, 150-1.
32 M. Moran, The Politics of the Financial Services Revolution: the U S A , U K and Japan (Basing-
stoke, Macmillan, 1991).
33 W. Coleman, ‘Policy convergence in banking: a comparative study’, Political Srudies, XLII
(1994), 274-92.
34 Hoberg, ‘Sleeping with an elephant’, p. 109.
35 Bennett, ‘How states utilize foreign evidence’, p. 43.
36 Hoberg, ‘Sleeping with an elephant’, p. 114.
3’ Bennett, Regulating Privacy.
38 Bennett, ‘How states utilize foreign evidence’.
[C, Political Studies Association. 1996
3 50 Reviebt. Section
and Skocpol found social democratic policy ideas were re-articulated from past
attempts to implement Keynesian type programme^.^^
Searching for lessons within a political system‘s past has the advantage of
saving time and resources. However, searching the past involves subjective
evaluation; while history is constant it is open to many interpretations and
current situation’s may not be truly analogous to past ones. Indeed, when
drawing lessons actors might not truly understand the past or its relation to the
present. At the same time, given that most policy develops over time, deciding
from which period to draw lessons can critically affect the lesson drawn.
Finally, as Rose points out, time is not a constant when actors are engaging in
policy transfer: ‘obstacles to lesson-drawing are not permanent; in the course of
time many obstacles become variable^'.^^
When searching within a nation, actors may start with their own organization
because different branches and divisions provide opportunities for transferring
administrative techniques and procedures. As Rose emphasizes: ‘the first lace
for an organisation to look is to its own standard operating procedure .5 r 7
Actors can also draw lessons from other political systems within their own
country if its constitutional structures create a series of similar sub-national
units of government within a relatively harmonious political culture. As an
example, the United States 1988 Family Support Act, was developed based
upon the experiences of state welfare programmes during the 1980~.~’
Although constraints exist, it is common for governments and agents to
transfer policies from one nation to another. So, for example, in the welfare
area international policy transfer has played a crucial role in the spread of poor
laws and unemployment legislation since the nineteenth century. Not only were
British poor houses adopted in the United States during the nineteenth century,
but, as Heclo shows: ‘experience in Denmark and New Zealand were important
in Britain . . . however, it was experience in Germany that stirred greatest
international interest’.6’
Some countries and regional governments commonly export policies to other
nations and regions. While examining policy transfer between the United States
and Canada, Robertson and Waltman found that particular American States
and Canadian Provinces acted as policy leaders: ‘(their) innovations are
disproportionately copied by neighbouring jurisdictions’.62 Heclo shows that
Germany played a similar role in the transfer of unemployment insurance to
Sweden and Britain during the early twentieth century.63 Similarly, Bennett
found that the 1973 Swedish Data Act acted as an exemplar to other nations
instituting data protection laws.64
’’ M. Weir and T. Skocpol, ‘State structures and the possibilities for “Keynesian” responses to
the Great Depression in Sweden, Britain, and the United States’ in P. Evans, D. Ruescheneyer and
T. Skocpol (eds), Bringing the Stares Back In (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1985),
pp. 107-63.
58 Rose, Lesson-drawing in Public Policy, p. 18.
s9 Rose, ‘What is lesson drawing?, p. 13.
6o For more information on this case contact David Dolowitz.
6’ Heclo, Modern Sociul Politics, p. 310.
Robertson and Waltman, ‘The politics of policy borrowing’, p. 8.
63 Heclo, Modern Social Po/itics.
Bennett, Regulating Privacy. This case also demonstrates that some policies, as well as nations
and regions, are used as exemplars.
C, Political Studies Association, 1996
Review Section 353
The basic assumption involved in drawing lessons from other nations is that:
‘similarities are greater within a given program across national boundaries than
among different programs within a ~ountry’.~’ When drawing lessons across
nations, geographic propinquity does not equate with policy transfer because
ideological and resource similarities are necessary preconditions to adapt
lessons from one country to another and neighbouring countries do not always
meet these preconditions. We return to this question below.
6 5 R. Rose, ‘Comparative policy analysis: the program approach‘ in M. Dogan (ed.), Comparing
Pluralisz Democracies (Boulder CO, Westview, 1988), pp. 219-41, pp. 227-8.
66 Rose, Lesson-drawing in Public Policy, pp. 132-4.
67 Rose, Lesson-drawing in Public Policy, p. 78.
Heclo, Modern Social Politics.
69 Robertson and Waltman ‘The politics of policy borrowing’.
‘Q Political Studies Association, 1996
354 Review Section
As Wolman shows, the institutional and structural constraints faced by
agents transferring policies are crucial. So, Wolman demonstrates how the
United States’ federal structure acted as a constraint on the transfer of policies
from the unitary British system, while the British system facilitated the Govern-
ment’s ability to transfer policies from the United States.70
Policy transfer is also dependent upon the transferring political system
possessing the political, bureaucratic and economic resources to implement the
policy. Robertson suggests that both transfer, and the success of transfer, is
more likely if the policy is consistent with the dominant political ideology in the
‘host’ c o ~ n t r y . ~Certainly,
’ ideological similarities between countries can be a
key factor when actors look for lessons.’* Examining the transfer of environ-
mental policies between the United States and Canada, Hoberg found that one
reason for the Canadian adoption of American environmental standards was
the ‘value consensus’ which existed between the two nations.73 Similarly,
Kelman explained the convergence of safety and health regulations in Sweden
and the United States as a product of the ideological consensus between
government officials.74
Rose emphasizes that the bureaucratic size and efficiency may influence
transfer.75 Similarly, even desirable programmes will not be transferred if
implementation is beyond a nation’s technological abilities. For example,
developed nation’s emission standards generally require the installation of high
technology monitoring equipment and filters which are beyond the techno-
logical and monetary resources of most Second and Third World countries.
Even developed countries might decide not to transfer policies because of the
technological complexities involved. On several occasions Canada explicitly
rejected particular American environmental protection policies because the
technology used to implement them was too expensive and r e ~ t r i c t i v e . ~ ~
Implementation costs money so economic resources are another critical
constraint for agents engaged in policy transfer. In this way, Bennett demon-
strated the importance economic constraints played in the transfer of data
protection principles during the 1 9 7 0 ~ ’ ~
’* D. Marsh, ‘The convergence between theories of the state’ in D. Marsh and G. Stoker (eds),
Theories and Methods in Polirical Science (Basingstoke, Macmillan, 1995).
l9 Rose, Lesson-drawing in Public Policy, p. 123.
0Political Studies Association, 1996
356 Review Section
institutions play in shaping policy. Institutions structure the actions and values
of actors working within them: ‘political institutions determine, order [and]
modify individual motives . . . in terms of institutional interests’.*OAdditionally,
as March and Olsen point out: ‘expectations, preferences, experiences and
interpretations of other actions are constructed within political institutions’.’’
More specifically, they also influence which actors search for lessons and where:
‘political behaviour [is] embodied in institutional structures of rules, norms,
expectations, and traditions that [limit] free play of individual will and
.I.March and J. P. Olsen, Rediscovering Instirurions (New York NY, Free, 1989), p. 3.
March and Olsen, Rediscovering Institutions, p. 39.
’’ March and Olsen, Rediscovering Institutions, p. 5 .
83 D. Marsh, ‘The politics of private investment’ in A. Blais (ed.), Industrial Policy (Toronto,
University of Toronto Press, 1985). pp. 83-1 17.
84 Rose, Lesson-drawing in Public Poliq, p. 33.
Conclusion
Policy transfer refers to the process by which actors borrow policies developed
in one setting to develop programmes and policies within another. It is an
important area to study because transfer is a common phenomena. We have
suggested a series of questions which can be used both to organize our current
knowledge of the process and to guide future work. However, it is crucial that
the concept is developed beyond the pluralist perspective which has almost
exclusively underpinned research in this area. We have suggested a number of
alternative frameworks within which the process of policy transfer can be
understood and explained. However, further consideration of these broader
questions is essential if the literature is to progress beyond description.
85 See: M. Cohen, J. March and J. P. Olsen ‘A garbage can model of organizational choice’,
Administrative Science Quarterly, 17 (1 972), 1-25; Kingdon, Agendas, Alternatives, and Public
Policies (USA, Harper Collins, 1984).
86 See: G. Stoker and K. Mosberger, ‘The dynamics of cross-national policy borrowing’, paper
presentd at the Urban Affairs Association Conference, 2-5 March (1994), New Orleans; J. L.
Waltman and D. T. Studlar, Political Economy: Public Policies in The United States and Britain
(Jackson MS, Jackson University Press, 1987); Robertson and Waltman, ‘The politics of policy
borrowing’.
87 Rose, Lesson-drawing in Public Policy, p. 59
88 Anderson, ‘The logic of public problems’.
89 Wolrnan, ‘Cross-national comparisons of urban economic programs’.
Q Political Studies Association, 1996