Chapter8 PDF
Chapter8 PDF
Chapter8 PDF
Costs Functions
The economic cost of an input is the minimum payment
required to keep the input in its present employment. It is the
payment the input would receive in its best alternative
employment. This cost concept is closely related to the
opportunity cost concept (not talking about accounting costs).
We usually assume that inputs are hired in perfectly competitive
markets. The firm can get all the input it wants without
affecting prices. The supply curve for an input is horizontal at
the prevailing price.
w
L
Total Cost, Revenue, and Profit
• Total cost = C = wL + vK (with only 2
inputs, capital and labor)
• TR = pq (with only 1 output)
• Then, economic profit is:
pq wL vK pf (K, L) wL vK
• Thus, economic profit is simply a function
of K and L, given that all prices (p, w, and
v) and technology are fixed.
Cost Minimizing Input Choices (for
given q)
• Assume for now that output has been
determined to be q0 and the firm wishes to
minimize its cost. That is, the firm must
choose a specific point on the q0 isoquant.
K
q0
L
• Cost will be minimized by choosing the point
where RTSLK (-slope of isoquant) equals the ratio
of input prices (w/v). This happens when the rate
of substitution in production equals the rate of
substitution in the market.
Min: C = wL + vK is the increase in C
st: q0 = f(K, L) or q0 – f(K, L) = 0 when q0 increases by
= wL + vK + (q0 –f(K, L)) one unit. is marginal
cost, MC.
f
w 0
L L The SOC require diminishing
f RTSLK or q=f(K, L) strictly quasi-
FOC v 0
K K concave or K = f(L,q0) strictly
convex.
q 0 f (K , L) 0
w f L MPL dK
Then RTS L , K
v f K MPK dL
The isocost line shows
K* q0 combinations of K and L
C1 C2 C that can be purchased with
0 3
C w
K L isocost line.
v v
The solution can be a corner point, but not usually unless the inputs
are close substitutes (close to linear isoquants). Assuming perfect
substitutes and RTSLK > w/v, which input would not be used? (K!)
Dual: Output maximization subject to a cost
constraint:
Max: q=f(K, L)
s.t.: C1 = wL + vK or C1 – wL – vK = 0
= f(K, L) + D(C1 – wL – vK)
D represents the marginal product of one additional
dollar of expenditure on inputs. It equals 1/.
Solving the FOC yields K* and L* as did the primal.
C1
K Output Maximum
K* qo
q-1
0 L
L*
Can we derive a demand curve for L
by changing price (w) and looking at
the resulting change in L*?
• The answer is “yes”, but the logic is somewhat different from
the consumer’s demand for a good. As w changes and L*
changes, the output level changes, which will change the market
for q, which will change p (price of q). We cannot investigate
the demand for an input without also considering the interaction
of supply and demand for the output. The demand for the
input is derived from the output market. Along the demand
curve for L, v and p are held constant.
• Therefore, the analogy between consumer and firm optimization
is not exact. (Isoquants are not directly interpretable as revenue
whereas indifference curves represent utility.)
py ΔU for consumer
w q for firm p in market for q.
Demand for L is a derived demand
from the market for q.
• Expansion Path – As the firm expands q, the
cost minimization points trace out the
expansion path. The Expansion Path shows how optimal
input usage changes as output expands with
K C4 v, w, and technology constant (isocost lines
C3
C2 are parallel because v and w are constant).
C1
q2
q3
q4
If the production function is homothetic, the
Expansion Path will be linear. The shape of
the isoquants determines the shape of the
q1 L Expansion Path. The Expansion Path shows
0
points of equal RTSLK on the isoquants
because the isocost lines are parallel.
$ C $
AC = MC
q q
However, typical (in theory) cost curves are
sloped as follows: C' 0
C is cubic C
C '' 0 and then 0
C is concave; C convex
$ Inflection
point AC = the slope of a cord from
the origin to any point on C.
A If w and v double, this isocost line changes from C1 to
2C1 = C2, but L*, K* and q* do not change. 2w w RTS
LK
C1/w = 2C1/2w =C2/2w is the intercept. 2v v
L
Changes in a Single Input Price
(relative prices of K and L change).
• The slope of the isocost line will change, resulting in changes in
the optimal input combination and changes in the expansion path.
Input Substitution (q constant)– Deals with how the optimal combination of
K and L (or K/L) changes as w/v changes with q constant.
Total Effect and its Direction (q changes)– An increase in v or w will
increase C. AC will also rise. MC will rise if the input is not inferior.
From Footnote 9 on page 228 and Footnote 7 on page 226:
MC ( q) 2 2 ( v) k MC k MC
; , so if k is inferior, 0,
v v qv vq q q v q v
Lagrangian function from the cost minimization problem subject to an output constraint.
K
w %Δ K
L
An alternative elasticity of substitution is s v L.
w K %Δ w
with q, v, and w constant (Partial Elasticity of Substitution). v L v
s is positive in a two-input world, but can be negative if three or more inputs.
This elasticity is similar to the elasticity of substitution () developed earlier
from the production function if we remember that at the optimal combination
of K and L w dK
RTSLK . K/L RTS
LK
v dL RTS K/L
LK
close substitutes. q0 in w/v – not close
q0 substitutes.
L
L
For many inputs
xi w
w
j
This formula gives a partial
x
s ij
j i
approach for use where many
w j xi inputs are involved.
wi xj
quantity along the line K
C0
K1 A = K1, SC is minimized
SC0
q3
but C is not minimized.
q2
q1 For C minimization, we
q0 would need to use less K
and more L for points on
L K = K1 to the left of L1
L0 L1 L2
and more K and less L
SC0 > C0 SC1 = C1 SC2 > C2
for points on K = K1 to
the right of L1.
The concepts and
Per Unit Costs relationships between
SC SC and SAC and
SAC
q SMC are the same as
described earlier for
SC SVC C, AC, and MC.
SMC
q q Only variable costs
affect MC.
If SFC = α and SVC = q2, then SC = α + q2, SAC
= α/q + q, and
SC SVC
SMC 2β q
q q
SAC can be separated into
SVC
$ fixed and variable parts. SAVC βq
SMC q
SFC α
SAC SAFC
SAVC q q
SC α
SAFC (Same
vertical distance) SAC βq
q q
SAFC
0 q SAC SAFC SAVC
•SAFC is a rectangular hyperbola that is asymptotic to 0.
Thus, as q increases, SAVC approaches SAC, ie., SAVC is
asymptotic to SAC.
•SMC passes through minimum SAVC and SAC.
•The cost curves (total and variable) reflect the shapes of
corresponding physical product curves (production function,
etc.).
Switching to the Long Run
By changing the fixed factor (K) we can draw a large number
SC1
of SC curves. SC2 SC0 is drawn for K = K0
SC0
C SC1 is drawn for K = K1
$
SC2 is drawn for K = K2
Optimal q and For a constant returns to scale
C for K = K1 production function, C would
Optimal q and C for K = K0 be a ray from the origin.
q0 q1 q2
q
•At the q that corresponds to optimal L for the fixed level of K, the SC curve will
be tangent to C curve. At all other points, the particular SC is above C, reflecting
the fact that SC represents costs higher than would be necessary if K were variable.
•The long run C is the “envelope” of the SC curves when K is allowed to vary.
•Every point on C is taken from a SC at its optimal combination of K and L.
Average and marginal curves - For every level of K
(fixed) there exists different SAC and SMC.
SAC0 SMC0 SMC2
SAC0 MC
$ SMC1
SAC1
SAC2
AC
SAC0'
A
Level of K indicates
the size of “plant”.
K2 > K1 > K0' >K0