Running Government Like A Business Implications For Public Administration Theory and Practice
Running Government Like A Business Implications For Public Administration Theory and Practice
Running Government Like A Business Implications For Public Administration Theory and Practice
RUNNING GOVERNMENT
LIKE A BUSINESS
Implications for Public Administration
Theory and Practice
RICHARD C. BOX
University of Nebraska–Omaha
The public sector faces increasing demands to run government like a business, importing private-
sector concepts such as entrepreneurism, privatization, treating the citizen like a “customer,” and
management techniques derived from the production process. The idea that government should
mimic the market is not new in American public administration, but the current situation is particu-
larly intense. The new public management seeks to emphasize efficient, instrumental implementa-
tion of policies, removing substantive policy questions from the administrative realm. This revival of
the politics-administration dichotomy threatens core public-sector values of citizen self-
governance and the administrator as servant of the public interest. The article examines the political
culture that encourages expansion of market-like practices in the American public sector, explores
the issues of the purpose and scope of government and the role of the public-service practitioner, and
offers a framework for the study and practice of public administration based on citizenship and pub-
lic service.
AUTHOR’S NOTE: The author wishes to thank the reviewers for their very thoughtful and useful
comments.
AMERICAN REVIEW OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION, Vol. 29 No. 1, March 1999 19-43
© 1999 Sage Publications, Inc.
19
20 ARPA / March 1999
the public sector. Rather, the article suggests constructive ways that public-
service practitioners and academicians can approach these issues in their work,
seeking to preserve and enhance the essence of public service within the market
context.
Expansion of market concepts in the public sector is taking place at the end of
the 20th century thrust to build administrative systems that address the problems
of a growing urban-industrial nation. That thrust produced a public sector that
appears today to be large, cumbersome, wasteful, and beyond citizen control
(King & Stivers, 1998b, p. 11), isolated from and out of touch with the rest of
society (Peters & Pierre, 1998, pp. 228-229). Large government requires that a
few elected people represent the wishes of the masses, and representative
democracy has grown so remote from the everyday lives of people that it no
longer bears a clear relationship to common experience (Hummel & Stivers,
1998). Many citizens are so alienated from the concept of self-governance that
they think of government as something separate, not a reflection of their own
will, though some others would like to participate directly in re-creating the
machinery of government to allow for genuine self-governance. As a potential
remedy, many politicians and citizens believe that government should be run
more like businesses, becoming trim and lean, exhibiting competitive behav-
iors, and giving greater attention to the needs of “customers.”
Evidence of the expansion of market concepts in the public sector may be
found in the literature and practice of public administration in an emphasis on a
constellation of cost-cutting and production management concepts taken from
the private sector, currently drawn together as new public management. These
concepts include, among others, privatization, downsizing, rightsizing, entre-
preneurism, reinvention, enterprise operations, quality management, and cus-
tomer service. New public management seeks to separate politics (in the sense
of decision making by the people or their representatives) from administration,
allowing (or making) managers to manage according to cost-benefit economic
rationality, largely free from “day-to-day democratic oversight” (Cohn, 1997).
Such a separation resembles the old politics-administration dichotomy and Her-
bert Simon’s (1945/1997) description of administrative decisions that are
largely “factual.” In this reformed management setting, the public-private dis-
tinction is “essentially obsolete,” and management is generic across sectors
(Peters & Pierre, 1998, p. 229).
This desire to separate the activities of politics (deciding about public poli-
cies) and administration (implementing them) is part of a redefinition of the
function of government based on “a new elite consensus on the role of the state
22 ARPA / March 1999
We have known for some time that the modern market economy would have
serious impacts on society and in particular on democracy. In 1906, Max Weber
asserted that
The dominant issue is whether the people of the United States are to control our
government, federal, state, and municipal, and to use it in behalf of the peace and
welfare of society or whether control is to go on passing into the hands of small
powerful economic groups who use all the machinery of administration and legis-
lation to serve their own ends. (in Campbell, 1996, pp. 178-179)
Ramos (1981/1984) took for granted the “intrusion of the market system upon
human existence,” with its accompanying emphasis on instrumental rationality
that advances the goals of the market, rather than substantive rationality that
offers the individual an opportunity to achieve “truly self-gratifying interper-
sonal relationships” through reason, the activity of the human psyche (p. 23).
Scott and Hart (1979) documented the transition from a society based on the
value of the individual in the preindustrial era to one of organizational values in
the 20th century. Now, in an age in which we are replaceable parts of large sys-
tems, we think with nostalgic fondness of a time when each person was an inte-
gral part of a local community. We spend part of our leisure time watching mov-
ies or television shows that glorify the heroic loner, but most of us in real life
fulfill our destiny as small productive parts of larger systems.
In the United States, the nation’s founders created a governmental structure
that allowed limited popular participation in national political life while empha-
sizing order and stability. In so doing, they established a semidemocratic form in
which “the ‘people’ was no longer being defined, like the Athenian demos, as an
active citizen community but as a disaggregated collection of private individu-
als whose public aspect was represented by a distant central state” (Wood,
1996, p. 219). The focus was on individual rights and protection from the power
of government, as contrasted with the classical republican ideal of citizen self-
governance.
With the rise of capitalism in the 19th century, it became possible to combine
democracy and capitalism by clearly separating the economic and political
spheres. Thus, citizens maintained their formal public-sector liberal equality in
relation to rights, voting, and the law, whereas private-sector inequalities of
wealth and power generated by capitalism were largely off-limits to collective,
Box / RUNNING GOVERNMENT LIKE A BUSINESS 25
public action. These were the conditions of creation of modern liberal democ-
racy (Adams, Bowerman, Dolbeare, & Stivers, 1990; Wood, 1996, p. 234), a
“Lockean accommodation” that “reconciled representative government with
capitalism by disenfranchising the group most likely to contest the hegemony of
wealth—the working class itself” (Bowles & Gintis, 1986, p. 42). It is
semidemocratic in that the mass of people participate in a limited and marginal
way in collective decision making. In the balance between the public and eco-
nomic spheres, the public sector is allowed to trim off the rough edges of eco-
nomic excess in relation to treatment of workers, consumers, and the physical
environment, in exchange for keeping public-sector interference with the ine-
qualities of the economic sector to a minimum. Thus, as the market has “insinu-
ated itself into the domains of sentiment, life-style and psyche,” it has “bound
the state with subtle threads of economic dependency” (Bowles & Gintis, 1986,
p. 34).
There do not at present seem to be any viable alternatives to this semidemo-
cratic capitalist model (Dryzek, 1996). On a global level, there were competing
models for much of the 20th century, but now those models have largely van-
ished. There are a few socialist enclaves remaining, and a number of relatively
undeveloped countries with authoritarian regimes, now being pressured by the
public and private institutions of developed nations to change their economic
systems to conform with the semidemocratic capitalist model. Over time, it may
be discovered that this model is not optimal for all nations, that it works best for
mature, stable societies with institutions that can support it. It may not work well
for a range of nations with cultural and political histories very different from
those of developed Western societies, nations in which the semidemocratic capi-
talist model can lead to hardship and social unrest (Kaplan, 1997).
Today, even the possibility of alternative systems seems to be disappearing,
and the market metaphor is dominant. We are apparently in the midst of post-
modern conditions characterized by thick interpretations of reality at the micro,
local level where people can interact directly and form coherent mutual interpreta-
tions of values and identity, and thin reality at the macro level of broad classes of
people, regions, and nations. This results in a profusion of difference, an “asser-
tion of the random nonpattern and the unassimilable anomaly” (Fox & Miller,
1995, p. 45) that shifts and changes constantly. In such an environment, post-
modernists believe it is difficult if not impossible to identify grand themes of
common belief or interest across large groups of people or geographic areas.
In the midst of this apparent fragmentation of meaning, the daily mechanics
and values of the market permeate social, political, and economic life. Families
are pressed by economic circumstances to alter their expectations about work,
retirement, child rearing, and care of the elderly. Workers are forced to abandon
the certainties of lifetime employment, instead constantly keeping an eye on the
job market and the best opportunities to increase earning power. Private, public,
and nonprofit organizations must constantly adapt to their rapidly changing
environments. In the public sphere, it becomes harder and harder to generate
26 ARPA / March 1999
the public sphere. By focusing on the individual as the unit of analysis, assuming
that individuals seek to maximize their personal preferences in the “political
market” as they do in the private sector, and treating the behavior of citizens,
elected officials, political appointees, and public professionals as examples of
self-seeking regard for their own interests, the public choice scholars discovered
a public world very different from that of public administration scholars (John-
son, 1991). Where traditional theorists found people searching for a better soci-
ety and the public interest, economic theorists found the public sector operating
like an alternative form of market. In this view, traditional bureaucratic, hierar-
chical government is not a means to social betterment, but a mechanism that dis-
torts private economic behavior, reduces individual freedom, and makes the
economy less efficient. The way to reduce these negative effects, according to
economists, is to decentralize government, make it smaller, and introduce
market-like concepts such as fees and user charges, vouchers, and systems to moni-
tor employee performance, such as merit pay plans (Jennings, 1991, pp. 115-116;
Ostrom, 1973/1991).
At the conceptual level of the size and scope of government, the economic
view is that, when it will be to their benefit, individuals, groups, politicians, and
bureaucrats seek to maximize their gains in the public market by competing with
others for the benefits offered by collective action (Downs, 1957; Niskanen,
1971; Olson, 1965). Corporations seek to make it harder for potential competi-
tors to enter the market, associations seek tax breaks others cannot have, politi-
cians fight for the power and money of office, and public-sector bureaucrats
want their agencies to grow so that their status and freedom to act are increased.
Governmental action coerces individuals in society into behaving in a manner
consistent with majority will, whether or not they agree with it, and those who
stand to benefit the most from governmental action will spend the time and
resources to influence public policy decisions. A basic assumption of econom-
ics is that free and uncoerced individual choice should be maximized and that,
where a clear need for collective action in the public interest is lacking, citizens
should be allowed to act alone or in voluntary cooperation without governmen-
tal coercion (Schmidtz, 1991, chap. 7). But government grows larger and more
powerful as people use it to gain advantage over one another. This rent-seeking
behavior joins the economic inefficiency of government-as-monopoly-
provider-of-services as an argument for smaller and more limited government.
At the conceptual level of public agencies and employees, economic rational-
ity has had a significant impact on scholarly thinking about behavior in organi-
zations. Niskanen’s argument that public bureaucrats will seek to increase the
size of their agency’s budgets (1971; or as modified in 1991, the size of the dis-
cretionary budget) was an effort to reconceptualize the behavior of public
employees, moving away from models of control by legislatures or a sense of
duty to the public interest, to a model of the public professional as a self-
interested maximizer of competitive position in the bureaucratic world.
Niskanen’s ultimate purpose was to shift attention from the attributes of
28 ARPA / March 1999
It was in the 1980s, amid the antigovernment ideology of the Reagan admini-
stration and a wave of public sentiment for shrinking the public sector, that
market-like concepts broke through the weak wall of separation between the val-
ues of the market and the values of public management. Trickle-down, supply-
side economics and public choice economics pointed the way to prosperity
through smaller government, and it was thought that bureaucratic waste could be
eliminated through contracting out and becoming entrepreneurial, and soon the
entire public sector would, supposedly, be as efficient as the private sector was
assumed to be. The negative aspects of treating public purposes as if they were
private became apparent through events such as the savings-and-loan crisis at
the national level and reevaluation of the tenets of “reinvention” at the local level
(Gurwitt, 1994), but the transformational impact of this period cannot be denied.
This is reflected in the writing of a deputy project director for the Clinton admin-
istration’s new-public-management-inspired National Performance Review.
Although noting that “there is no single intellectual source for the reinventing
government movement,” he says that it “evolved during the past 10 to 15
years . . . based, in part, on the pioneering intellectual work of public choice
theoreticians such as Mancur Olson, E.S. Savas, Gordon Tullock, and William
Niskanen” (Kamensky, 1996, pp. 248).
As Weintraub (1997) has pointed out, there are several meanings of the dis-
tinction between public and private, including the following: the liberal-
economistic model, based on neoclassical economics, which regards the public-
private distinction the same as that between state administration and the market
economy; the civic perspective, which views the public realm as separate from
both the market and the administrative state; and other perspectives, including
feminism, that examine distinctions between public and private as involving the
spheres of sociability and family and household (pp. 16-17). Here, we take a
viewpoint looking outward from inside the administrative state to examine
penetration of the market metaphor into public administration, so we are con-
cerned with the liberal-economistic model that is “dominant in most ‘public pol-
icy’ analysis” (p. 16).
Given the development of the political environment described above, it is not
surprising that Americans have always been searching for an acceptable balance
between what is private and what is public. In the early to mid-19th century,
there were debates over the national government’s role in banking and funding
internal improvements such as telegraph transmission and canals for water
transportation. For the most part, the trend was toward resisting expansion of the
national role amid prevailing public opinion hostile to action by the national
30 ARPA / March 1999
government (White, 1954, pp. 437-481). Efforts to expand the role of govern-
ment were more successful in the late 19th century and into the 20th century, as
the regulatory and welfare state was built in response to the changing character
of national economic life. Then, beginning with the Reagan administration in
the 1980s, the growth of the national government was again brought into ques-
tion. At the local level, the scope of governmental activity grew steadily, accel-
erating after World War II as the population expanded and suburbia was built.
Along with questioning the size and scope of government in the 1980s, there
was a revival of interest in localism and limited government. If it seems to the
individual that the national or state government is too distant, too big, and so
dominated by entrenched interest groups that he or she cannot have much effect
on public policy, it is natural to turn attention toward a locus of action small
enough to offer the possibility of quick and satisfying results. As president, Ron-
ald Reagan encouraged this sentiment as he sought to dismantle the welfare state
and return its functions to states, localities, and private and nonprofit sector
organizations. The communitarian movement emphasized nongovernmental
action and citizen duties as well as rights. These ideas were given additional
thrust by the withdrawal of the national government from many domestic initia-
tives and the phenomenon of tight resources at all levels of government.
In the midst of the 1980s milieu of negativity toward government, with its
bureaucrat bashing and belief that government is the problem rather than the
solution, economic thinking about the role of government in society blossomed
and became part of the ordinary vocabulary of normative debate. By the 1990s,
the idea that government needed to be smaller and more efficient had become
accepted as common wisdom (though the reality was different at the state and
local levels, as government continued to expand; see Walters, 1998). Of those
people who spend time thinking about the size and scope of government and its
role in society, many have come to hold the view that government at all levels is
too big and it would be wise to spin off functions from the national government
to the states and localities, or from government to the private and nonprofit
sectors.
The economist’s conceptual scheme for determining what is public and what
is private has become standard fare for students of public affairs and underlies much
of the public discourse about the role of government (Mikesell, 1995, pp. 1-6).
Thus, we distinguish between public goods, such as national defense, and pri-
vate goods, such as household appliances or a hamburger. Public goods would
not ordinarily be offered by the private sector acting on the incentive of making a
profit because people cannot be excluded from using it and so have no incentive
to pay for it (the market failure to provide a good). If it is provided at all, it is
available to everyone, and one person’s use of a public good does not exhaust its
usefulness to others (because I experience the benefits of being defended from
foreign aggression does not mean that you cannot experience them, too).
Because people could experience the benefits of public goods without paying
Box / RUNNING GOVERNMENT LIKE A BUSINESS 31
for them (the free rider problem), government coercively forces members of the
public to pay taxes or face financial penalties or imprisonment.
In the real world, things are not so simple, so there are modifications and
exceptions to the concept of pure public goods and pure private goods. Toll
goods are services that many people use but from which people may be excluded
(such as swimming pools open for public use or expressways that charge fees),
and common-pool resources are goods that can be exhausted as many people use
them but for which exclusion is difficult (notably natural resources such as fish-
eries). The distinctions between types of goods are often fuzzy, and public-
sector decision makers use criteria of public demand and political action to
choose which services to offer rather than ideal conceptualizations of types of
goods. Thus, government becomes involved in providing a variety of services
that might appear to belong in the private or nonprofit sector. In addition, gov-
ernment regulates the activities of private actors as they work with toll,
common-pool, or private goods, attempting to control negative effects (exter-
nalities) of private economic activity on people or the environment.
To add to the complexity, a distinction is made between the provision of pub-
lic services and their production. Provision is the fundamental question of
whether or not government will cause a service, or good, to be offered. It is a pol-
icy question to be decided by the people or their representatives. If the answer is
negative (“No, we don’t want to provide garbage pickup service”), then either
private or nonprofit organizations will provide the service or no one will. If,
using the example of garbage pickup, no one provides the service (a market fail-
ure), there will likely be a discussion of the public health implications and a
revisiting of the negative provision decision. Production is a separate issue. If
the provision decision is positive, then the question remains how to actually
deliver the service, how to produce it. Osborne and Gaebler argued in their book
Reinventing Government (1993) that government often does a better job of gov-
ernance, or steering (making policy decisions) than of delivering services, or
rowing (see chap. 1). Osborne and Gaebler included in the steering-rowing dis-
tinction governmental decision making about contracting out services and a
governmental role in serving as catalyst for private and nonprofit initiatives such
as downtown renewal or building sports facilities.
In an appendix to their book, Osborne and Gaebler built on the work of Savas
(1987) to offer decision-making criteria for choosing public, private, or non-
profit action, such as stability, regulation, and enforcement of equity (public-
sector strong points), expertise and willingness to take risks (private-sector
attributes), and compassion and promotion of community (nonprofit-sector
attributes). Vincent Ostrom (1973/1991; 1977; 1991/1994) has written exten-
sively about institutional structures, intergovernmental arrangements, and
building institutional capacity that helps people to govern themselves. Using a
combination of public choice theory and a historical analysis of American
32 ARPA / March 1999
Lyons & Lowery, 1989; Phares, 1989; Ross & Levine, 1996, chap. 11; Stillman,
1991, pp. 176-185; Waldo, 1981, p. 97).
like a business as economic concepts permeate the thinking of policy makers and
implementers. Although administrators are pushed to use entrepreneurial and
scientific techniques to please the “customer’s” assumed desire for businesslike
government, they paradoxically become less accountable to the public, whose
members lose some control over administration. For example, administrators
may use expenditure-control budgets, which allow flexibility to spend as the
professional sees fit, and to save money to carry over for discretionary spending
later to avoid direct budgetary control by politicians. The assumptions are that
this flexibility will make for more nimble response to changing conditions, give
managers an incentive to be frugal, and remove political motivations from what
ought to be expert decisions. Using Bellone and Goerl’s reasoning, the good
public administrator will, in exercising this greater degree of discretionary
space, take into account the wishes of citizens in making choices. This logic
reopens the question of representative democracy and agency; that is, do public
administrators answer to the public, or to their elected representatives (Box,
1998; Fox & Miller, 1995; Kelly, 1998)?
The argument against such flexibility in budgeting is that clear and detailed
line-item budgets were created to avoid problems of financial abuse and to
ensure that money is spent as citizens or their elected representatives decide it
should be spent. Saving up money means that it has not been spent as intended by
representatives but instead will be spent as nonelected administrators
decide—thus, a question of accountability. Supposedly scientific techniques
administered by experts, such as cost-benefit analysis, reengineering, and qual-
ity control, may lead to more precise and economically efficient service deliv-
ery, but they may also crowd out competing citizen preferences for public policy
and service delivery, preferences that can be shown by experts to be inefficient
or impractical. This sort of result is often seen in disputes over such relatively
minor issues as whether to preserve a historic building or remove esthetically
pleasing landscaped medians in major streets to make traffic flow smoothly.
In these and similar instances, there is a conflict between the idea of public
management as efficient, businesslike, and scientific, and public management
as responsive to these and to other public values as well. Jennings (1991) offered
three approaches to public administration that capture the essence of this con-
flict. The bureaucratic approach “takes efficiency and equal treatment of citi-
zens as its primary values,” the pluralism approach “emphasizes responsiveness
to multiple interests,” and the market approach “takes efficiency as its prime
value,” differing from the bureaucratic approach in emphasizing diversity of
product and maximum consumer choice (p. 122). It may be argued that public
administration theorists have in the past tended to prefer one of the first two
approaches. Those who favor greater status and discretion for public administra-
tors lean toward the bureaucratic approach, and those who favor greater citizen
discourse and self-governance lean toward the pluralist approach. But today,
most agree that some measure of market-like matching of public services to con-
sumer preferences, along with efficient and technically competent management,
Box / RUNNING GOVERNMENT LIKE A BUSINESS 35
is inevitable if not desirable. The question is how much, in what ways, and
whether there are aspects of public service that should not be governed or man-
aged from a market perspective.
The problem in seeking a reasonable balance between approaches in the face
of demands to run government like a business is that operating with private-
sector entrepreneurial techniques in the public sphere can subvert values of
openness, fairness, and public propriety. In such cases, the public-service practi-
tioner may take on the appearance of an independent actor separated from the
public, concerned less about the public interest (however defined) and more
about making money and maximizing individual power and freedom to act with-
out review. This decreased accountability carries the possibility of unexpected
program outcomes, uneven treatment of citizens, and behaviors that have not
generally been thought of as consistent with public service. Again, using the
example of city utilities in a community in which the author lived, this time in
relation to the question of openness, the utilities department attempted to deny
public access to many of its documents on the premise that it must operate
secretly to level the playing field with its private-sector counterparts. In relation
to fairness and a sense of public propriety, the local publicly owned hospital in
the same community is semiautonomous, competes aggressively and success-
fully for market share with the other hospital in town, advertises its high-tech
services widely, makes a sizable surplus, and pays its top executive approxi-
mately $300,000 per year, including bonuses based on how much the hospital
makes. To some people these may not seem like appropriate behaviors for the
public sector.
Movement toward a market model thus may result in loss of citizen self-
determination in the creation of public policy and the operation of public organi-
zations. Today, most people recognize that a general return to the participatory
democracy of an earlier time and simpler society is impossible. However, in this
post-progressive era, many are working to rebuild citizen capacity for self-
governance through discourse and active citizenship (Barber, 1984; Box, 1998;
Eberly, 1994; King & Stivers, 1998a). Not everyone will take part in such
efforts, but, as Fox and Miller (1995) put it, having “some-talk” is better than
having “few-talk” (pp. 129-159). The goal is to move beyond the typical model
of citizen participation that is “not designed primarily for citizens but for agen-
cies” (Timney, 1998, p. 98), in which administrators use citizen involvement
processes for “informing, consultation, and placation” (Timney, 1998, p. 97)
rather than enabling people to govern themselves.
Market-driven new managerialism can run counter to self-governance, as it is
structured around the idea of happy consumers rather than involved citizens.
This is a problem because government is not a business from which customers
can voluntarily decide whether to purchase a product. It is, rather, a collective
effort that includes every person within a defined geographic area (city, county,
district, state, nation), and membership is involuntary unless a resident moves
out of the jurisdiction. Mandatory membership carries with it a sense of the right
36 ARPA / March 1999
James March (1992) argued that in the past few decades economic theorists
have softened the pure application of their ideas to the public sector, moving
from methodological individualism to recognition of the fabric of institutional
and structural relationships that make up a community. They now take into
account, along with their original assumptions, “a rich, behavioral interpreta-
tion attentive to limited rationality, conflict, ambiguity, history, institutions, and
multiple equilibria” (p. 228). He also noted that this softer, more subtle applica-
tion of economic concepts has not yet penetrated into the world of applied theory
because “the news of the transformation of rational theory spreads rather slowly
from the inner temples of microeconomics to the rationalizing missionaries in
the rest of an economizing society and social science” (p. 229). As this news
spreads, the current reforms will fade and reformers will move on to new ideas,
but like earlier reforms, they are likely to leave a legacy. The legacy of economis-
tic theory in the public sector may include greater attention to “performance-
motivated administration” and the integration of economic concepts into the tra-
ditional intellectual matrix of public service (Lynn, 1998, p. 232).
Turning toward application of these ideas to the size and scope of govern-
ment, the historical American attitude toward the public sector has been that it
should not compete with the private sector but should provide services that the
private sector will not. However, with time, the clarity of the public-private dis-
tinction has faded as people ask government to do more and citizens grow accus-
tomed to things as they are. In the past two decades, this combination of a prefer-
ence for limited governmental scope with incremental accumulation of services
in violation of that preference has been complicated by expansion of economics-
based theory and practice. The public-choice side of the running government
like a business metaphor suggests shrinking government by contracting out
services or returning them to the private sector on the premise that the private
sector is more efficient (in the case of contracting) or the assertion that the public
sector should simply be smaller (in the case of true privatization). Meanwhile,
the entrepreneurial side of the metaphor suggests that government may retain its
traditional services and operate them like a business, plus operating services
ordinarily thought of as private in order to make money. One way government
officials are able to accommodate these diverse demands without making gov-
ernment smaller is to make it appear to be morphing into a publicly owned busi-
ness by charging user fees, contracting parts of its services, or adopting the lan-
guage and practice of the private sector by, for example, calling certain services
companies or businesses and using a variety of private-sector internal manage-
ment techniques.
In the area of application of market concepts to the conduct of public service,
the potential impacts are significant. The prevailing American attitude about the
nature of public service has been to expect market-like efficiency and business-
like operation but in combination with public service values such as account-
ability, fair and equal treatment, democratic self-governance, social justice, pro-
tection of the physical environment, and others. Schachter (1997) pointed out
38 ARPA / March 1999
Services the public sector should provide. In every community, region, state,
and at the national level, there are at a given time services that a majority of citi-
zens believe should be provided by the public. This belief may not be based on
extensive knowledge and could change if people were to have more information
(this is the problem of improving the quality of public judgment; see
Yankelovich, 1991), but it is possible to identify attitudes about what services
should be public. There are likely a range of reasons that people would give for
wanting to have certain services provided by the public sector rather than by the
private sector or not at all, but there may be a primary characteristic of public
services that most Americans would agree forms a sound decision rule for deter-
mining what is public and what is private.
We may hypothesize that, asked to consider a particular service that they
think should be publicly provided, people would generally agree that they want
certainty that the public has the ability to maintain or change the service in keep-
ing with what the majority thinks to be in the public interest (however defined; in
this case, it can be assumed to be the long-term interests of the greatest number,
when the public is provided adequate information to make a determination). The
standard example of national defense is one on which strong majority agreement
Box / RUNNING GOVERNMENT LIKE A BUSINESS 39
can be found and other examples would draw varying responses according to
place, time, and the sampled population.
The decision rule of ability to maintain or change a service in accord with a
majority view of the public interest is different from the market-driven service
rule that uses individual preferences as the basis for governmental response. It
focuses not only on efficiency or businesslike operation but also on citizen
beliefs about the public interest, the good community, whatever it is that citizens
think is best for themselves and others, acting collectively. How to inform and
involve citizens in making such decisions may be unclear, but it is clear that this
is a decision milieu driven by different values than those of the market. It is also a
process that includes collective public deliberation and assistance from public-
service professionals.
Services the public sector should produce. Within the category of services
that people believe should be provided by the public, there are services involv-
ing discretion and accountability such that the public is uncomfortable with an
arm’s length contractual relationship and the possibility of the profit motive
rather than public interest determining outcomes. Examples could include
police patrol and crime investigation, protective services for children, land-use
regulation, and some human resources functions.
These services can be contrasted with a range of things that do not involve the
same level of discretion and accountability and are good candidates to be con-
tracted out or fully privatized for reasons of cost efficiency, purchase of special-
ized expertise that would cost too much to maintain on staff, or greater flexibil-
ity in staffing levels. Examples could include operating a police impoundment
facility for seized vehicles, conducting psychological evaluations of defendants
awaiting trial, and constructing valid test instruments for jobs that draw large
numbers of applicants.
The role of the practitioner. It might be assumed, in the manner of the old
politics-administration dichotomy or the current policy-management split of
the market metaphor, that public-service practitioners should not play an active
part in shaping issues, debates, and decisions on the questions of what is public
or private or whether public policy and services should be approached using the
market or the citizenship models. However, there is little doubt today that practi-
tioners are an important part of policy formulation and implementation, provid-
ing information needed by citizens and elected officials to frame policy deci-
sions and generating proposals that often form the basis for public action.
Thus, practitioners fill multiple roles in addition to the traditional bureau-
cratic role, serving as expert advisers and as facilitators of citizen discourse. The
open question is how this is to be done in a society that expects nonelected public
servants to maintain a position clearly subordinate to elected officials and citi-
zens. This question involves issues of legitimacy and leadership. Is it possible to
be an important actor in the creation and implementation of public policy with-
out straying outside the legislative mandate or becoming dominating, self-
serving, and causing restriction of public access and freedom to act?
Public practitioners are, because of proximity and knowledge, deeply
involved in the broad issue of the extent to which the market metaphor should
guide public governance. They exercise influence in discussions about what
services should be public, how they should be operated, and whether the public
practitioner serves customers or citizens. Though there will always be concern
about the legitimacy of this role, many practitioners are in a position to shape the
public sector by offering their knowledge to peers, citizens, and elected repre-
sentatives trying to meet the challenge of governing in an economics-driven
political culture. In doing so, they can serve the interests of public service and
democratic will formation by keeping in mind the shifting and dynamic nature
of the relationship of the market to the public sector and the importance of their
actions in shaping the future.
REFERENCES
Adams, G. B., Bowerman, P. V., Dolbeare, K. M., & Stivers, C. (1990). Joining purpose to practice: A
democratic identity for the public service. In H.D. Kass & B.L. Catron (Eds.), Images and identities
in public administration (pp. 219-240). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Box / RUNNING GOVERNMENT LIKE A BUSINESS 41
Anderson, T. T., & Crawford, R. G. (1998). Unsettling the metaphysics of neo-classical micro-economic
and management thinking. International Journal of Public Administration, 21, 645-690.
Arnold, P. E. (1995). Reform’s changing role. Public Administration Review, 55, 407-417.
Barber, B. R. (1984). Strong democracy: Participatory politics for a new age. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Barber, B. R. (1998). A place for us: How to make society civil and democracy strong. New York: Farrar,
Straus, and Giroux.
Barrett, K., & Greene, R. (1998, March). Customer disorientation. Governing, 11, 62.
Bellah, R. N., Madsen, R., Sullivan, W. M., Swidler, A., & Tipton, S. M. (1985). Habits of the heart:
Individualism and commitment in American life. New York: Harper & Row.
Bellone, C. J., & Goerl, G. F. (1993). In defense of civic-regarding entrepreneurship or helping wolves to
promote good citizenship. Public Administration Review, 53, 396-398.
Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (1986). Democracy and capitalism: Property, community, and the contradic-
tions of modern social thought. New York: Basic Books.
Box, R. C. (1998). Citizen governance: Leading American communities into the 21st century. Thousand
Oaks, CA: Sage.
Campbell, J. (1996). Understanding John Dewey: Nature and cooperative intelligence. Chicago: Open
Court Publishing.
Cheung, A.B.L. (1997). The rise of privatization policies: Similar faces, diverse motives. International
Journal of Public Administration, 20, 2213-2245.
Cohn, D. (1997). Creating crises and avoiding blame: The politics of public service reform and the
new public management in Great Britain and the United States. Administration and Society, 29,
584-616.
Cope, G. H. (1997). Bureaucratic reform and issues of political responsiveness. Journal of Public
Administration Research and Theory, 7, 461-471.
Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.
Dryzek, J. S. (1996). Democracy in capitalist times: Ideals, limits, and struggles. Oxford, UK: Oxford
University Press.
Eberly, D. E. (1994). Building a community of citizens: Civil society in the 21st century. New York: Uni-
versity Press of America.
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review,
14, 57-74.
Fox, C. J., & Miller, H. T. (1995). Postmodern public administration: Toward discourse. Thousand
Oaks, CA: Sage.
Gerth, H. H., & Mills, C.W. (1958). From Max Weber: Essays in sociology. New York: Oxford Univer-
sity Press.
Giddens, A. (1984). The constitution of society: Outline of the theory of structuration. Berkeley: Univer-
sity of California Press.
Golembiewski, R. T. (1977). A critique of “democratic administration” and its supporting ideation.
American Political Science Review, 71, 1488-1507.
Hood, C. (1996). Beyond “progressivism”: A new “global paradigm” in public management? Interna-
tional Journal of Public Administration, 19, 151-177.
Hummel, R., & Stivers, C. (1998). Government isn’t us: The possibility of democratic knowledge in rep-
resentative government. In C. K. King & C. Stivers (Eds.), Government is us: Public administration
in an anti-government era (pp. 28-48). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Jennings, E. T., Jr. (1991). Public choice and the privatization of government: Implications for public
administration. In J. S. Ott, A .C. Hyde, & J. M. Shafritz (Eds.), Public management: The essential
readings (pp. 113-129). Chicago: Nelson-Hall.
Johnson, D. B. (1991). Public choice: An introduction to the new political economy. Mountain View,
CA: Mayfield.
Kamensky, J. M. (1996). Role of the “reinventing government” movement in federal management
reform. Public Administration Review, 56, 247-255.
42 ARPA / March 1999
Kaplan, R. D. (1997, December). Was democracy just a moment? Atlantic Monthly, 280, 55-80.
Kass, H. D., & Catron, B. L. (1990). Images and identities in public administration. Newbury Park, CA:
Sage.
Kelly, R. M. (1998). An inclusive democratic polity, representative bureaucracies, and the new public
management. Public Administration Review, 58, 201-208.
Kettl, D. F. (1997). The global revolution in public management: Driving themes, missing links. Journal
of Policy Analysis and Management, 16, 446-462.
King, C. S., & Stivers, C. (1998a). Government is us: Public administration in an anti-government era.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
King, C. S., & Stivers, C. (1998b). Introduction: The anti-government era. In C. S. King & C. Stivers
(Eds.), Government is us: Public administration in an anti-government era (pp. 3-18). Thousand
Oaks, CA: Sage.
Lan, Z., & Rosenbloom, D. H. (1992). Public administration in transition? Public Administration
Review, 52, 535-537.
Lasch, C. (1996). The revolt of the elites and the betrayal of democracy. New York: Norton.
Lynn, L. E., Jr. (1998). The new public management: How to transform a theme into a legacy. Public
Administration Review, 58, 231-237.
Lyons, W. E., & Lowery, D. (1989). Governmental fragmentation versus consolidation: Five public-
choice myths about how to create informed, involved, and happy citizens. Public Administration
Review, 49, 533-543,
March, J. G. (1992). The war is over, the victors have lost. Journal of Public Administration Research
and Theory, 2, 225-231.
McSwite, O. C. (1997). Legitimacy in public administration: A discourse analysis. Thousand Oaks, CA:
Sage.
Mikesell, J. A. (1995). Fiscal administration: Analysis and applications for the public sector (4th ed.).
Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.
Moe, T. M. (1984). The new economics of organization. American Journal of Political Science, 28, 739-
777.
Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine Atherton.
Niskanen, W. A. (1991). A reflection on bureaucracy and representative government. In A. Blais &
S. Dion (Eds.), The budget-maximizing bureaucrat: Appraisals and evidence (pp. 13-31). Pitts-
burgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Osborne, D., & Gaebler, T. (1993). Reinventing government: How the entrepreneurial spirit is trans-
forming the public sector. New York: Penguin.
Ostrom, V. (1977). Some problems in doing political theory: A response to Golembiewski’s “critique.”
American Political Science Review, 71, 1508-1525.
Ostrom, V. (1991). The intellectual crisis in American public administration. Tuscaloosa: University of
Alabama Press. (Original work published 1973)
Ostrom, V. (1994). The meaning of American federalism: Constituting a self-governing society. San
Francisco: ICS. (Original work published 1991)
Peters, B. G., & Pierre, J. (1998). Governance without government? Rethinking public administration.
Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 8, 223-243.
Phares, D. (1989). Bigger is better, or is it smaller? Urban Affairs Quarterly, 25, 5-17.
Public Administration Review. (1993). Forum on public administration and the Constitution. Public
Administration Review, 53, 237-267.
Ramos, A. G. (1984). The new science of organizations: A reconceptualization of the wealth of nations.
Toronto, Canada: University of Toronto Press. (Original work published 1981)
Ross, B. H., & Levine, M. A. (1996). Urban politics: Power in metropolitan America (5th ed.). Itasca,
IL: F. E. Peacock.
Savas, E. S. (1987). Privatization: The key to better government. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House.
Box / RUNNING GOVERNMENT LIKE A BUSINESS 43
Schachter, H. L. (1997). Reinventing government or reinventing ourselves: The role of citizen owners in
making a better government. Albany: State University of New York Press.
Schmidtz, D. (1991). The limits of government: An essay on the public goods argument. Boulder, CO:
Westview.
Scott, W. G., & Hart, D. K. (1979). Organizational America. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Simon, H. A. (1997). Administrative behavior: A study of decision-making processes in administrative
organizations (4th ed.). New York: Free Press. (Original work published 1945)
Skowronek, S. (1982). Building a new American state: The expansion of national administrative
capacities, 1877-1920. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Stillman, R. J. II (1991). Preface to public administration: A search for themes and direction. New York:
St. Martin’s.
Terry, L. D. (1993). Why we should abandon the misconceived quest to reconcile public entrepreneur-
ship with democracy. Public Administration Review, 53, 393-395.
Terry, L. D. (1998). Administrative leadership, neo-managerialism, and the public management move-
ment. Public Administration Review, 58, 194-200.
Timney, M. M. (1998). Overcoming administrative barriers to citizen participation: Citizens as partners,
not adversaries. In C. S. King & C. Stivers (Eds.), Government is us: Public administration in an
anti-government era (pp. 88-101). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Waldo, D. (1981). The enterprise of public administration: A summary view. Novato, CA: Chandler &
Sharp.
Walters, J. (1998, February). Did somebody say downsizing? Governing, 11, 17-20.
Waterman, R. W., & Meier, K. J. (1998). Principal-agent models: An expansion? Journal of Public
Administration Research and Theory, 8, 173-202.
Weintraub, J. (1997). Public/private: The limitations of a grand dichotomy. Responsive Community, 7,
13-24.
White, L. D. (1954). The Jacksonians: A study in administrative history, 1829-1861. New York:
Macmillan.
Wood, E. M. (1996). Democracy against capitalism: Renewing historical materialism. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Yankelovich, D. (1991). Coming to public judgment: Making democracy work in a complex world. Syra-
cuse, NY: Syracuse University Press.