Research 2
Research 2
PROPONENTS:
MATIGA, MAEBELLE R.
CHAPTER I
INTRODUCTION
defray the necessary expenses of the government. It is a bare way of distributing the cost of
government among those who in some measure are privileged to enjoy its benefits and must
also bear its burdens. However, tax compliance among SMEs (small and medium enterprises)
Small and medium sized enterprises make up the vast majority of business entities
and contribute strongly to employment and economic growth, spanning the full breadth of
industries and sectors, and differing in their propensity to innovate and grow. At the same
time, SMEs face specific challenges in relation to their access to finance. The tax system
plays a dual role: at times, as a tool to aid in overcoming these challenges, and at others, as an
for the people to get the protection they needed from the government, taxes must be paid.
Once taxes are not paid, the government will be paralyzed due to the lack of the
Compliance with tax laws is important to keep the system working for all and to
support the programs and services that improve lives. One way to encourage compliance is to
keep the rules as clear and simple as possible. Overly complicated tax systems are associated
According to Kim (2002), as cited by Gberegbe and Umoren (2017) in their book The
Perception of Tax Fairness and Personal Income Tax Compliance of SMEs in Rivers State,
researchers have identified that tax compliance is one of the most important factor that can
affect the perception of SMEs on tax fairness. It also plays a crucial role in tax reporting
behavior.
Tax fairness describes a system of taxation that is equitable for all taxpayers. Groups
focused on tax fairness look to limit the amount of tax legislation and rules that benefit one
In as early as 1776, Adam Smith has recognized the importance of tax fairness. His
thought about fairness was that a tax payer will want to contribute to the government based
on their ability to pay or the benefits that they will get from the tax funded projects and
programs of the government (Richardson, 2005) cited in the book The Perception of Tax
Fairness and Personal Income Tax Compliance of Smes in Rivers State of Gberegbe and
Umoren (2017). This means that individuals and corporations with greater incomes pay a
Since then, fairness is recognized as one of the attributes of a good tax system in
modern taxation (Tan & Chin-Fatt, 2000). Accordingly, tax payers who are not satisfied with
the treatment from tax authorities may hold resistance view (Trivedi, Shehata & Lynn, 2003,
Murphy, 2005, Ho & Wong, 2008) and may not be willing to pay their tax (Murphy 2003).
3
The study seeks to determine the factors that affect the tax compliance and their
1.1. Age
1.2. Sex
4. Correlate the tax compliance and the perception towards tax fairness of the
This research study will be conducted in the City of Borongan, specifically in Eastern
Samar State University. The study is limited only to the owners of business enterprises such
as the store owners in ESSU’s Business Center and the private stores located alongside the
The Government. The study will provide data or information concerning on how the
problems on tax compliance could be resolved based on their insight in the present tax
system. This could also serve as a guide in improving the tax system of the country so that
the taxpayers would be obligated to comply their responsibilities in paying tax which will
The Business Owners. The study will help them understand the moral obligations
behind tax payment and encourage them to responsibly obey their tax obligations. They
would be able to contribute in nation building by simply paying their taxes on time.
The Future Researchers. The study will serve as a useful source of data or information
and reference for future research endeavors. The study will also serve as a guide to future
researchers who might be willing to study more about tax compliance and tax fairness.
Definition of Terms
Tax. An amount of money that a government requires people to pay according to their
income, the value of their property, etc., and that is used to pay for the things done by the
government.
Taxation. Defined as the power by which sovereign taxes raises revenue to defray the
Tax compliance. Taxpayers’ willingness to obey tax laws in order to obtain the
Tax Fairness. Describes a system of taxation that is equitable for all tax payers.
5
CHAPTER II
Tax Compliance
The definition of tax compliance in its most simple form is usually cast in terms of the
degree to which taxpayers comply with the tax law. However, like many such concepts, the
meaning of compliance can be seen almost as a continuum of definitions. This ranges from
the narrow law enforcement approach, through wider economic definitions and on to even
Taking the narrow end of the continuum first, one suggestion is that the degree of
noncompliance may be measured in terms of the ‘tax gap’. This represents the difference
between the actual revenue collected and the amount that would be collected if there were
100 per cent compliance. Andreoni, Erard and Feinstein (1998) include a time dimension to
compliance but are still mainly concerned with tax evasion as the central part of the tax gap
definition. As they put it: ‘A popular indication of the magnitude of evasion is the tax gap -
the difference between the federal income taxes households actually owe, and what they
report and pay voluntarily on a timely basis.’ Regarding time dimension, James (2000) states
that a tax payer might eventually pay his/her full liability but, if the payment is late, the
compliance by Brown & Mazur (2003) consists of three distinct types: payment compliance,
filing compliance and reporting compliance. However, these basic concepts of the ‘tax gap’
rather than be forced to undertake every aspect of their obligations unwillingly. The Internal
Revenue Service (IRS, 1996) has two definitions - gross tax gap and the net tax gap. The
gross tax gap is the amount of ‘true’ tax liability that is paid ‘voluntarily’ and on time and the
net tax gap is this amount less tax paid late or collected by the Internal Revenue Service
through enforcement activities. Both the gross and net tax gaps can be subdivided into the
three main components (Internal Revenue Service, 1996) - the non-filing gap, the under-
reporting gap, and the underpayment gap. The underreporting gap is in turn made up of three
A major concern with such definitions is that they might be taken to indicate a
certainty in the measurement of tax compliance that does not exist. Tax law is not always
precise. Indeed, although legal definitions are often of the tax gap form, there are sometimes
practical difficulties of interpretation. Bergman (1998) elucidate that tax compliance ‘is what
the state assumes is legally owed by taxpayers, but the state and taxpayers do not necessarily
share the same interpretation’. The extent to which taxpayers dispute the meaning of the tax
law can depend on a number of things, including their basic willingness to comply with a tax
system. The basic concept of the ‘tax gap’ of non-compliance seems to be inadequate. The
‘tax gap’ definition and measure are far too simplistic for practical policy purposes since
successful tax administration requires taxpayers to cooperate in the operation of a tax system
rather than to be forced to carry out every aspect of their tax obligations. Tax law cannot cope
with every eventuality as said by James and Wallschutzky (1995) and therefore has to be
part to play but the tax system cannot work properly without a reasonable degree of willing
7
compliance on the part of taxpayers themselves. There is the question whether ‘compliance’
refers to voluntary or compulsory behavior. If taxpayers ‘comply’ only because of dire threats
or harassment or both, this would not appear to be proper compliance even if 100 percent of
the tax were raised in line with the ‘tax gap’ concept of noncompliance.
comply willingly, without the need for enquiries, obtrusive investigations, reminders or the
therefore include the degree of compliance with tax law and administration, which can be
achieved without the actual application of enforcement activity. This ‘voluntary’ aspect
appears in the definition supplied by Andreoni et al. (1998) which recognizes a basic
difference in terms of compliance between tax paid without direct enforcement activity and
If taxes were considered to be intrusive or unfair, taxpayers might wish to reduce their
tax liability by working less. Even though this will have a cost to themselves that might be
outweighed by a feeling of revenge. It is also possible that taxes might be used as an excuse
to avoid unwanted overtime or other obligations. It is not known how powerful any spite
effects might be but it is clearly possible that, apart from the direct costs of compliance
themselves, difficulties in the willingness of taxpayers to comply might affect the revenue
potential itself. The ‘tax gap’ definition of non-compliance might then have been partly
A fuller economic definition of compliance should also take into account other
possible economic effects of the tax system and its enforcement. There has been some
economic analysis of such possibilities. An example of this by Cowell (1985) who considered
the case where a worker can choose not just between working in the legal or illegal sectors
8
but how much time to spend in work of any sort as opposed to leisure. It has also been
specifically shown that uncertainty in tax audits could affect labor supply according to
Horowitz & Horowitz (2000). It seems reasonable to conclude that tax administration could
therefore, a severe tax enforcement policy could even claim to have improved tax compliance
by the narrow ‘tax gap’ definition because it would have reduced the amount there was to
collect. Timing issues will also affect the value of the potential revenue available. A taxpayer
might eventually pay his or her full liability but if it is paid late it cannot be considered to be
full compliance or worth as much as tax liability paid on time or even before the due date. In
economic terms, money in the future is worth less than the same nominal sum of money now.
If the Government does not receive tax payments on time it either increases the amount it has
to raise elsewhere or reduces the revenue available for public expenditure. Although late
payments of tax fit many of the ‘tax gap’ measures, they do not represent full compliance. As
already indicated above, tax compliance may be seen in terms of tax avoidance and tax
evasion. The two activities are usually distinguished in terms of legality, with avoidance
referring to legal measures to reduce tax liability and evasion to illegal measures. James
(2000) describes tax avoidance as the legal manipulation of an individual’s affairs in order to
hardly be considered ‘compliance’ either. Such activities might include engaging in artificial
transactions to avoid tax, searching out every possible legitimate deduction, using delaying
tactics and appeals wherever this might reduce the flow of tax payments and so on. ‘Tax
exiles’ even seem to prefer to emigrate rather than fulfill their obligations as citizens.
9
Even if such activities are within the letter of the law, they are clearly not within the
spirit of the law. Compliance might therefore be better defined in terms of complying with
the spirit as well as the letter of the law. Many of the studies of compliance are concerned
with intentional noncompliance. There is, however, considerable scope for unintentional non-
compliance. Full compliance may require positive actions on the part of the taxpayer to
discharge his or her legal duties in full. It may be that taxpayers innocently fail to meet their
tax obligations because they fail to complete their tax returns correctly or are unaware of, or
misunderstand, various provisions of the tax system, or for similar reasons. As stated by
James et. al., (1987) and James, Sawyer & Wallschutzky (1998), attempts by different tax
authorities to improve tax administration in this respect have often found the problem of
Jackson and Milliron (1986) listed fourteen main factors that have influenced tax
compliance as discussed by various researchers. These factors are age, gender, education,
income, occupation or status, peers’ or other taxpayers’ influence, ethics, legal sanction,
complexity, relationship with taxation authority (IRS), income sources, perceived fairness of
the tax system, possibility of being audited and tax rate. Various researchers have listed
factors that influenced tax compliance such as demographic, income, compliance cost, and
tax agents (Mohani, 2003), in addition to moral or ethical factors (Singh, 2003; Kasipillai et
al., 2003).
Other researchers (Sour, 2002; Keller, 1997; Trivedi, 1997; Hamm, 1995; Chang et al.,
1987)listed enforcement element factors (such as penalty, audit, and tax rates) as having a
10
Taxpayers are greatly influenced by other taxpayers. Besides, the rate and quality of
audit will also influence tax compliance behaviours of a taxpayer (Trivedi, 1997).
Due and Friedlaender (1981) also state that a person’s preference for a tax may be
influenced if the tax- or an increase in it- is tied directly to the expenditures he strongly
favors. Generally, attitudes toward choice of taxes and tax structures are greatly influenced
by various criteria-often called principles- of taxation that have come to be widely accepted.
taxation such as cultural background of tax payers, their awareness level, fairness/equity, tax
authority, will be touched. The empirical work of various researchers and other reference
materials are scanned to have basic conceptual framework of the subject matter.
Cultural Factors
compliance. Different social norms and ethical values will create different incentives for tax
compliance.
In fact, ethical values influenced by social norms may prohibit taxpayers from
engaging in tax evasion (Blanthorne and Kaplan, 2008). The cultural framework most widely
used is that of Hofstede (1980). Based on an attitude survey of about 116,000 employees,
uncertainty avoidance and masculinity. Cultural research has found significant differences
suggested by Chan et al. (2000). In Hofstede's model, individualism and collectivism refer to
maintains among its members. A high individualism culture is signified by people focusing
on themselves rather than on the group to which they belong. Under this perspective, an
individual is seen as separable from and independent of a group affiliation. People in such
low individualism culture as Chinese citizens, they tend to be collectivists who are expected
to follow and subscribe to the values of their in-groups in order to gain peer acceptance and
social status (Hofstede, 1991). In contrast, a high individualism culture such as US citizens is
signified by people focusing on themselves rather than on the group to which they belong.
Under this perspective, they view themselves as distinct entities and place great value on
individual rights. These cultural differences may have a direct impact on ethical values and
The study conducted by Chan et al. (2000) indicates that culture of the taxpayers has
an impact on taxpayer compliance efforts. There is reason to believe that societal reasons
may account for the way taxpayers behave. While tax evasion may be considered wrong and
immoral in some societies, it may be regarded as socially tolerable in other (Schwartz and
In countries with a tradition of high compliance with tax law; few tax payers would
attempt tax evasion strategies. However, empirical evidence seems to suggest that tax payer
compliance with the law is influenced by their perception about whether or not other tax
payers are complying (Van den Doel, 1979; laver, 1981; lewis, 1982), especially when they
12
fell that the taxes they pay are intended for worthy purposes (oldman, 1965; dean, keenan and
kenney, 1980).
In Ethiopia where the system of government has evolved from feudal (where taxes
were used by individuals in government) to current one, it is obvious that negative attitude
towards tax has been developed in the society. In this sense it is difficult to conclude that
Social Factors
The issue of (non-) compliance is not only a question of state-society relationships but
also a question of relationship between citizens and/ or groups of citizens within local
communities. There is an existing social bond between the society and this bond influences
the members of the society in complying with the tax law. That is taxpayers may be
influenced by their peer groups to comply or not to comply with the tax law. Peers are usually
referred to taxpayers’ associates and include friends, relatives and colleagues (Jackson and
Sanvely (1990) said that compliance behavior and attitude towards the tax system is
affected by the behavior of an individual’s reference group such as relatives, neighbors, and
friends. Thus if a tax payer knows many people in groups important to him who evade taxes,
his commitment to comply will be weaker. On the other hand, social relationship may also
help deter individuals from engaging in evasion for fear of social sanctions imposed once
discovered and revealed publicly (Grasmick and Green, 1980; Grasmick and Scott, 1982).
The survey conducted by Mason et al. (1975) finds that people committing tax
noncompliance are more likely to discuss tax matters with their peers. The study conducted
13
by Chan et al. (2000) also reveals that taxpayers may still commit noncompliance so long as
As cited by Slemrod (2000) and Levi (1998) in (Fjeldstad and Ranker, 2003), the
dimension of trust that seem to affect compliance is trust in other citizens to pay their share of
service charges. In particular, trust in other citizens to pay their share seems to be important.
The larger the fraction of the local population that is observed not paying, the lower
perceived risk of being prosecuted. This has impacts on the individual taxpayer’s perception
Most theories of tax compliance, as well as empirical works (Smith and Kinsey, 1987) have
until recently been premised on the assumption that tax under reporting is an intentional
behavior. Behavior that is unintentional has either been ignored or set aside in a footnote or
behavior it is also attributed to lack of ability to pay, lack of awareness and weak institutional
James et al (2003) said that a number of tax authorities have been moving towards a
more sophisticated approach to tax compliance. Traditionally there seems to have been an
assumption that with a basic level of assistance for taxpayers, together with an enforcement
14
there seems to have been a shift in attitudes towards treating the taxpayer less as a passive
donor who simply has to be billed for taxes due and more as a customer sometimes requiring
revenue authorities must identify and address the risk associated with non-compliance by
revenue authorities are aware of major developments and trends in the business and
legislative enforcement, and are responsive to their implications on tax administration and
compliance.
opportunity, convenience, or even interpretation of the law (Smith and Kinsey, 1987). Legal
validity, economic and social purpose, distributive justification, and revenue yield may all be
defeated if a tax is not levied and collected well. No matter what the justifications advanced,
a tax fails to the extent that it is avoided or evaded (Shultz and Harriss, 1949).Taxation is an
inevitable phenomenon in any economy or nation as far as services and other roles are
expected from governments. Even though the history of taxation is as old as that of states or
governments, still there are gaps in every nation, particularly underdeveloped countries like
Ethiopia as far as voluntary compliance is concerned. Taxes are considered by many citizens
as necessary evils that cannot be avoided under normal conditions. Hence, the issue of
voluntary compliance is a central idea when dealing with efficiency and effectiveness of a tax
system. From the above review of literature several writers have discussed about factors that
affect voluntary compliance behavior and how it is related with various socio-cultural,
Legal enforcement (i.e. penalties and sanctions) are all exist in the tax laws of every
nation in varying degrees. But still are gaps in tax compliance regardless of these laws. This
clearly shows that tax compliance cannot be ensured only through enforcement or stick
approach. Even though the existence of enforcement and penalties cannot be undermined
when dealing with tax compliance, focusing on positive side i.e. encouraging voluntary
compliance is by far rewarding as far as long lasting and consistent advantage is concerned.
Hence, the understanding of tax compliance that is why people tend to comply and why they
tempt to evade, gives a clear road map to the solution of this very classical problem in
varying degrees. But still are gaps in tax compliance regardless of these laws.
This clearly shows that tax compliance cannot be ensured only through enforcement
or stick approach. Even though the existence of enforcement and penalties cannot be
undermined when dealing with tax compliance, focusing on positive side i.e. encouraging
voluntary compliance is by far rewarding as far as long lasting and consistent advantage is
concerned. Hence, the understanding of tax compliance that is why people tend to comply
and why they tempt to evade, gives a clear road map to the solution of this very classical
problem.
Fairness/Equity
objectives, chooses and adheres to certain principles which become its characteristics. A good
tax system, therefore, is one which is designed on the basis of an appropriate set of principles,
such as equality or fairness and certainty. Since fairness of a tax system is its corner stone a
As said by James (2000), the most obvious requirement of equity or fairness is to treat
equal people in equal circumstances in an equal way. The problem here is in deciding who is
equal to whom. Similarly, Due and Friedlaender (1981), also argue that what is fair or
distribution pattern is possible, or people may be equal income wise while they may be
unequal regarding their expenditure, wealth, total utility and so on. Such a pattern can be
specified only on the basis of a consensus of attitudes of persons in the contemporary society.
Lemessa (2005) also adds that a major responsibility is to ensure that all taxpayers dealt with
by a given official are accorded similar treatment and that all officials dealing with a given
tax payer would accord the same treatment. Suchlike, Brooks (2001) states that fairness has
always been widely regarded as the most important criteria in judging a tax system. The
problem of unfairness is that a tax system allows taxes to be shifted from dishonest to honest
tax payers. The fairness of a tax system may also be perceived in different ways by the
taxpayers and tax authorities. What is fair in the eye of the tax authorities may not have the
Bhatia (1976) also stated that the attitude of taxpayers is an important variable
determining the contents of a good tax system. It may be assumed that each taxpayer would
like to be exempted from taxpaying, while he would not mind if others bear that burden. In
any case, he would want his share to be within the general level of tax burden being borne by
Due and Friedlaender (1981) have argued that persons will oppose taxes that they feel
strike them “unfairly” and allow others to escape a “reasonable” burden, and they will favor
taxes they accept to concentrate on others, especially when “others” are non-humans such as
corporations. To sum, regardless of this inherent problem ensuring the fairness or equity of a
17
tax system is second to nothing. To put it differently, it is essential that a good tax system
No tax will work effectively, unless its administrators maintain an aggressive attitude
with respect to the correctness of the taxpayers’ actions. Some taxpayers will fail to file or
make mistakes through ignorance or neglect; others will deliberately cheat as said by Bird
and Oldman (1967). A passive attitude by the authorities towards these errors and
falsifications will soon undermine the entire structure, since the diligent and honest taxpayers
will almost in self-defense be forced to the level of the careless and dishonest. A tax
administration which seeks compliance must protect those who comply or else compliance
will not be forthcoming. Most commentators, policy makers, and tax administrators agree
that voluntary compliance would be greatly facilitated by the existence of a simplified tax
structure.
Indeed, without institutional simplification that enables tax payers to fulfill their
responsibilities more effectively, even the most elaborate service offered to tax payers by the
tax administration would be lost in a sea of confusion, waste, and widespread disrespect of
the law (Bahl, 1989; Jenkins, 1992). A simpler tax structure will make it easier for tax payers
to assess their tax liability and thus comply more fully with tax laws.
Bird and Oldman (1967) further explained that the sure sign of ineffective tax
administration is the presence of a very large delinquency in tax payments for it indicates the
lack of taxpayer respect for the tax system. The taxpayer in effect is acting on his belief that
the administrative machinery may bark, but that it has no bite. These writers argue that in
large part the solution for the large delinquency lies in providing the bite. In this sense
18
effective tax collection is a facet of the larger problem of providing adequate penalties, to
which reference will later made. In other words tax is evaded to the extent that tax authorities
are perceived as weak by taxpayers. A tax system doesn’t function in a vacuum. Its
relationship with at every turn are with the public, and since the combination of taxes reaches
nearly every individual in one way or another, the administration finds itself dealing with the
nation as a whole. Hence, inevitably its operations and effectiveness are affected by the
attitudes of the nation towards the tax system (Bird and Oldman, 1967).But while tax
administration is thus affected by these national attitudes (Bird and Oldman, 1967); it is
equally true that the attitudes can in turn be affected by tax administration.
improvement in relation with the public and in the daily contacts between tax official and
taxpayer, can operate to increase the public respect for the tax administration. Moreover, once
the tax administration has been placed on a sound basis, it is in a position to assert that
compliance must be forthcoming. Such an assertion would hardly be tolerated or even taken
seriously, as long as tax officials were themselves inefficient and corrupt. But if the
administration has brought stability and honesty to its own operations, the self-respect thus
achieved can form the foundation for its demand of respect and compliance from the tax
payer.
is equally important that tax authorities administer the law fairly. This implies both an
absence of arbitrary or corrupt behavior on the part of the officials, and “normative standards”
to ensure that the same laws are applied and administered in a standard fashion across the
board. A taxpayer (Peacock and Forte, 1981) will be more receptive to information on his
19
obligation if, in his efforts to comply, he receives a reasonable degree of service from the
revenue administration.
Poorly drafted forms, long waiting lines and even charges for acquiring them,
bureaucratic hassle in processing the case, rudeness from the officials, cumbersome appeal
procedures, and the like, can repel even the most loyal taxpayers.
On the other hand the ways in which revenue authorities interact with taxpayers and
their own employees have an impact on public perception of the tax system and the degree of
voluntary compliance. Taxpayers who are aware of their rights and expect, and in fact receive,
a fair and efficient treatment are more willing to comply. Voluntary compliance is promoted
not only by an awareness of rights and expectations of a fair and efficient treatment but also
by clear, simple and “user friendly” administrative systems and procedures. Voluntary
James (2000) argues that the norm is usually to comply rather than not to comply. As
already pointed out for a tax system to be effective the majority of the taxpayers have to
comply. It follows that there may be greater gains in assisting basically compliant taxpayers
to meet their fiscal obligations than in spending more resources in pursuing the minority of
non-compliers.
Many taxpayers might be willing to comply in full, but are unable to do so because
they are not aware of, or do not understand, their full obligations. Even if such tax payers
understand their obligations, they may not know how to meet them or may be unable to do so
for other reasons. On other side, other writers such as Smith and Kinsey (1987) argue that tax
In countries like Ethiopia where most of the business community have no access to
and Mckee, 1992; Andreoni, et al., Cowell and Gordon, 1988). Individuals may pay tax
because they value the goods provided by the government, recognizing that their payments
are necessary both to help finance the goods and services and to get others to contribute. A
tax payer therefore is seen as exchanging purchasing power in the market in return for the
government services (Levi, 1988). Positive benefits may increase the probability that tax
payers will comply voluntarily, without direct coercion. Without a material benefit,
compliance becomes less assured. Although most tax payers cannot assess the exact value of
what they receive from the government in return for taxes paid, it can be argued that they
have general impressions and attitudes concerning their own and other’ terms of trade with
satisfaction or lack of satisfaction with his terms of trade with the government. Thus, if the
system of taxes is perceived to be unjust, tax evasion may, at least partly, be considered as an
attempt by the tax payer to adjust his terms of trade with the government. Wahlund (1992)
also stated that tax compliance is related to political affiliation that is people favoring parties
with social democratic values tend to comply more than people voting for liberal parties.
Due and Friedlaender (1981), also argue that, attitudes toward the general level of
taxation and tax increases are dependent, of course, on attitudes about the desirability of
21
governmental programs and on attitudes toward the government itself . On the other hand,
(Fjeldstad, 2004) citizens’ willingness to pay taxes voluntarily rests on the local
government’s capacity to provide services and its demonstrated readiness to secure the
Taxation has to be in accordance with the notion of fairness that exists in the
justice concerns justice in legal decision-making processes, fairness of the income tax
focuses mainly on the substantive justice, which means a focus on the substantive
Radbruch, said that justice is the ultimate value. This means that tax laws should
aim to realize justice. Laws should be intended to realize justice, even if they are not
CHAPTER III
METHODOLOGY
This chapter deals with the set of methods or process that the researchers’ will be
using to obtain the needed data for the study. It contains the research design, locale of the
study, respondents of the study, sampling procedure, research instrument, measurement of the
variable, data gathering procedure, data analysis, and the statistical tool to be used.
Research Design
know the factors that affect the tax compliance of store owners. In addition to this, the study
also aims to find out the perception of store owners towards tax fairness.
As shown in Figure 1, the study will be conducted at Eastern Samar State University-
Main located at Borongan City. The study focuses only on stores in ESSU-Main Campus
specifically in the Business Center and the private stores alongside the CAS building.
There are twenty-four (24) stores in Eastern Samar State University. The owners of
these stores as taxpayers will be the respondents to the researchers’ questions about the study.
Sampling Procedure
In this study, we will be utilizing purposive sampling so that we could make use of all
the data we have gathered efficiently. The respondents we will select would be based on their
accumulated experience when it comes to paying their taxes. Hence, being capable of
Research Instrument
out to the selected business owners. The questions that could be included will tackle mainly
Measurement of Variable
The researchers of this study will be using two out of four levels of measurement to
identify the measurement of the variables. First, the nominal level as our questionnaire will
include several questions that don’t imply any ordering among the possible responses.
Second, ordinal level as our research aims to measure the respondents’ perception on tax
fairness.
The researchers will personally distribute survey questionnaires with everything the
researchers want to ask will be given out to the chosen respondents which are the business
Data Analysis
After gathering all the completed questionnaires from the respondents, total responses
28
Statistical Tool
Chi Square
This will be used to determine the differences between the actual result and
Formula:
2
(𝑜 − 𝑒)2
𝑥 =∑
𝑒
To calculate chi square, we take the square of the difference between the
observed (o) and expected (e) values and divide it by the expected value.
Please circle the number that appropriately represents your response in each of the following
questions.
A. Gender:
1. Male
2. Female
B. Age:
1. Less than 20
2. 20-29
3. 30-39
4. 40-49
5. 50-59
6. 60 and Up
C. Marital Status:
1. Single
2. Married
3. Widowed
4. Others ______
D. Level of Education:
1. Elementary
2. High School
3. College
4. Graduate
5. Others ______
E. Experience in business
1. 1-5 years
2. 6-10 years
3. 11-15 years
4. 16-20 years
TAX FAIRNESS
Please respond by putting a one check in each line across as to how you feel about income taxes and
1 2 3 4 5
3 I believe the income tax system is the fairest kind of system that
7 Some perfectly legal tax deductions are not fair because only
so it is fair that they should pay a higher rate of tax than low
income earners.
their income:
11 The share of the total income taxes paid by high income earners
12 Middle income earners don’t pay more than a fair share of the
TAX COMPLIANCE
Please respond by putting a one check in each line across as to what is your level of tax compliance.
1 2 3 4 5
Tax Return.
BIR.
References
Bozdoğanoğlu, B. (2016). Factors That Effect Taxation of Small and Medium Sized
Enterprises (SMEs).
Atawodi, O.W. and Ojeka, S.A. (2012). Factors That Affect Tax Compliance among Small
(www.doingbusiness.org/data/exploretopics/paying-taxes/why-matters).
Gberegbe, B. and O Umoren, A. (2017). The Perception of Tax Fairness and Personal Income
(https://www.investopedia.com/terms/t/tax_fairness.asp).
Alm, J., Jackson, B., Mckee, M. (1992). Deterrence and beyond toward a kinder, gentler
Andreoni, J., Erard, B., and Feinstein, J.S. (1998). Tax compliance. Journal of economic
Literature, 36 (2).
Bahl, (1989) and Jenkins (1992).Taxpayer Compliance: a conceptual frame work, Journal of
Bergman, M. (1998). Criminal law and tax compliance in Argentina: testing the limits of
Bhatia, H.L.(1976). Public Finance, 19th Ed. New Delhi, India: Vikas Publishing House pvt
Ltd.
Brown & Mazur (2003). Tax compliance And Public Opinion in Sweden: An Interpretation
Cowell. F.A. (1995). The economic analysis of tax evasion, Bulletin of economic research,
Vol.37.
Dean, p., T. Keenan and F. kenney (1980). Taxpayers’ attitudes to income tax evasion: an
Due, J.F. and Friedlaender, A.F. (1981). Government Finance: Economics of the Public
Eckstein, Otto. (1979). Public Finance 4th edition. Englewood Cliffs, USA: Prentice-Hall,
INC.
Edlund, J. (2003). Attitude towards taxation: ignorant and incoherent? Scandinavian Political
Ekstrand, L. (1980). Factors affecting compliance: focus group and survey results.
Proceedings of the 73rd annual conference on taxation. National tax association- tax institute
of America (November)
Fjeldstad, O. and ranker, L. (2003). Taxation and tax reforms in developing countries:
Grasmick, H., and Green, D.E (1980). Legal punishment, social disapproval and
Grasmick, H., and Scott.W.J. (1982). Tax evasion and mechanisms of social control.
Hamm, J.L. (1995). Income level and tax rate as determinants of tax payers’ compliance: an
Horowitz, I., and Horowitz, A. R. (2000). Tax audit uncertainty and the work-versus-leisure
Internal Revenue Service. (1996). Federal tax compliance research: individual income tax
J.L.M. Gribnau, ‘Rechtsbeginselen en evaluatie van belastingwetgeving’, in: A.C. Rijkers &
H. Vording, Vijf jaar wet IB 2001, Deventer: Kluwer 2006, p. 33: Radbruch’s view is based
J.L.M. Gribnau, Belastingen als moreel fenomeen, Den Haag: Boom fiscale uitgevers 2013,
p.40.
Jackson, B.R. and Milliron, V.C. (1986). Tax compliance research: findings, problems, and
James, S. and Nobes, C. (2000). The Economics of taxation: principles, policy and Practice
James, S., Sawyer, A., and Wallschutzky, I. (1998). The complexities of tax simplification:
progress in Australia, New Zealand and the United Kingdom. Australian tax forum Vol. 14(1).
Keller, C.E. (1997). An experimental investigation of how ethical orientations, tax rates,
penalty rates, and audit rates after tax compliance decisions. Doctoral dissertation, the
University of Tennessee.
Laver, M. (1981). The politics of private desires. New York: Penguin Books. 68
Lemessa, B. (2005). Federal Income Tax Administration in Ethiopia: the case of Employment
Levi, M. (1988). Of rule and revenue. Los Angles/London, university of California press.
Lewis, A. (1982). The psychology of taxation. New York: St. Martin’s press Misrak Tesfaye
(2008). Ethiopian Tax Accounting Theory and Practice, 1st edition, Addis Ababa.
Latin America ( papers and proceedings of a conference held in Buenos Aires, Argentina,
October, 1961)
Richupan, S. (1987). Determinants of income tax evasion. Role of tax rate: shape of tax
Sanvely, K. (1990). Governmental policies to reduce tax evasion: coerced behavior versus
Seldon, A. (1979). Tax evasion: the economic, legal and moral inter relationships between
Shultz and Harriss. (1949). American Public Finance 4th edition. New York, USA: Prentice
Hall, INC.
Smith, K.W. and Kinsey, K. A. (1987). Understanding taxpaying behavior: a conceptual
frame work with implications for research. Law and Society Review, Vol.21 (4).
Sour, D.L. (2002). An analysis of tax compliance for the Mexican case: Experimental
Trivedi, V.U. (1997). An experimental analysis of the impact of imperfect audits on future
Van den doel, H (1979). Democracy and welfare economics. Cambridge: Cambridge
university press.
Wahlund, R. (1992). Tax changes and economic behavior: the case of tax evasion. Journal of
Warneryd, K.E. and B. Walerud (1982). Taxes and economic behavior: some interview data