Productivity Improvements in Education: A Replay: by Dr. Maria Darra
Productivity Improvements in Education: A Replay: by Dr. Maria Darra
Productivity Improvements in Education: A Replay: by Dr. Maria Darra
Abstract
*Dr Maria Darra, Ph.D University of Piraeus, Department of Business Administration, E-mail:
[email protected]
102 European Research Studies, Volume IX, Issue (3-4) 2006
1. Introduction
efficiency measure used depends upon the objective set by the administration.
Efficiency ratios such as enrolment per section or contact hours per faculty member
are reasonable and useful. An objective of improving students’ progress toward a
degree would require measures such as a withdrawal rate and average course load
taken. Examples of cost-efficiency measures include instructional costs per student,
library expenditures per student, and administrative costs per student.
Measuring effectiveness can be difficult, though not impossible. Several
ideas have been suggested in the literature. One way to measure effectiveness is to
assess community or client conditions and benchmark them to community standards
or those standards of other institutions of higher learning. An example could be the
number of graduates who find a job within three months of graduation. Another
option is to measure accomplishments, such as the number of graduates or the
percentage of students taking a class that requires relatively advanced work, such as
technical research paper. The number of graduates going on to receive advanced
degrees is an alternative measure. Finally, client satisfaction is a third avenue to
measure effectiveness. Clients can include alumni or businesses that frequently hire a
university’s graduates.
3. Productivity Improvement
Often the pressure to provide more services can lead to neglect of employee
development, degradation in the morals of employees and breakdown in
communication within the organization. Productivity improvement requires focus on
people and product requirements. The manager’s role in the improvement process is
to provide the right level of encouragement, training, guidance, support and help as
required. Employees also have very important roles to play in ensuring that there is a
mutual trust and confidence required to deliver the final output successfully.
Everyone within an organization has both internal and external customers. The
notion that educational service quality is only important to the final customer outside
the organization should be discouraged. Increasing productivity at the individual level
ensures that excellent services are delivered to the ultimate customer.
b. Goal clarification
Productivity Improvements in Education: A Replαy 105
This approach focuses on identifying specific goals and objectives that will
improve productivity, implementing these objectives and providing on- going
assessment of the strengths and weaknesses of an organization.
c. Incentive systems
This approach focuses on thorough analysis of each task and elements at the
operational unit level. The purpose of the task analysis is to eliminate barriers and
bottlenecks that affect productivity.
a. Controls
b. Coordination
c. Cooperation
d. Contribution of analysis
e. Communication
f. Cost avoidance
This model subdivides inputs, conversion technology and outputs into useful
subclasses. The rational for selecting inputs and outputs as variables to be subdivided
into classes, is that these are the basic components of a productivity index.
Organizational productivity is used to measure a family of productivity measures. It is
likely that organizational productivity measures will result in different families of
measures depending upon the level within the organization that is being measured.
Sociotechnical systems have been proposed as a method of viewing
organizations (Davis and Taylor, 1972). There are a multitude of psychological –
sociological instruments to measure behavior and individual beliefs concerning the
social aspects of productivity (Adam et. all. 1981)
being more direct in their influence on productivity. The model divides all factors into
two groups. The first is the technological development and the second the employee’s
motivation. Motivation is a function of ability and employees’ job performance.
Ability is composed of skill and knowledge whereas job performance is influenced by
individuals’ needs and the physical and social conditions at the workplace.
Sutermeister’s model provides an excellent overview of the many factors involved in
productivity improvement.
This model incorporates the major factors, both organizational and extra
organizational that have a direct casual effect on the productivity of the individual
employee. Major factors in this model of productivity are represented by rectangles.
Circles are used to denote factors that act as filters or butters within the influential
relationship between two major factors. Productivity in this model is a function of
three primary factors. First the capacity at the task, second the individual effort
brought by the worker to the task and third the interference that cannot be controlled
by any individual. These three factors are combined through some form of work
measurements to yield productivity data for the individual in some specified time
period.
b. Instructional variables
6. Home environment;
7. Classroom or school environment;
8. Peer group environment outside the school;
9. Mass media environment, especially amount of leisure-time television viewing.
The first five aspects of student aptitude and instruction are prominent in the
educational models of Benjamin Bloom, Jerome Bruner, John Carroll, Robert Glaser,
and others (see Walberg, 1986, and Chapter 4 for a comparative analysis). Each
aspect appears necessary for learning in school because the student can learn very
little. Large amounts of instruction and high degrees of ability, for example, could
count for little if students are unmotivated or if instruction is unsuitable. Each of the
first five factors appears necessary but insufficient for effective learning. High-quality
instruction can be understood as providing information cues, correctives, and positive
reinforcement or encouragement that insures the fruitfulness of engaged time. Careful
diagnosis and tutoring can help make instruction suitable for students. Inspired
teaching can help students to persevere. Quality of instruction, then, may be
considered an efficient enhancement of study time.
The four remaining factors in Walberg’s model are environmental variables.
Three of these environmental factors as the psychological climate of the classroom
group enduring affection and academic stimulation from adults at home and an out-of-
school peer group with its learning interests, goals, and activities influence learning in
two ways. Students learn from peers directly. These factors indirectly benefit learning
by raising student ability, motivation, and responsiveness to instruction.
Classroom morale is measured by obtaining student ratings of their
perceptions of the classroom group. Good morale means that the class members like
one another, they have a clear idea of the classroom goals, and the lessons are
matched to their abilities and interests. In general, morale is the degree to which
students are concentrating on learning rather diverting their energies because of
unconstructive social climates. Peer groups outside school and stimulating home
environments can help by expanding learning time and enhancing its efficiency.
Students can both learn in these environments becoming able to learn in formal
schooling.
The last factor, mass media, particularly television, can displace homework,
leisure reading, and other academically stimulating activities. It may dull the student’s
keenness for academic work.
In addition to encouraging and supervising homework and reducing television
viewing, parents can improve academic conditions at home. What might be called
“the alterable curriculum at home” is much more predictive of academic learning than
is family (Walberg, 1984). This curriculum includes informed parent–child
conversations about school and everyday events; encouragement and discussion of
leisure reading; monitoring, discussion, and guidance of television viewing and peer
activities; deferral of immediate gratification to accomplish long-term goals;
expressions of affection and interest in the child’s academic and other progress as a
person.
Cooperative efforts by parents and educators to modify alterable
academically stimulating conditions at home had beneficial effects on learning
(Walberg, 1984).
Productivity Improvements in Education: A Replαy 109
Sticht and James (1984) have pointed out that children first develop
vocabulary and comprehension skills by listening, particularly to their parents before
they begin school. As they gain experience with written language between the first
and seventh grades, their reading ability gradually rises to the level of their listening
ability. Highly skilled listeners in kindergarten make faster reading progress in the
later grades, which leads to a growing ability gap between initially skilled and
unskilled readers.
The educational productivity model of Walberg does not contain interaction
terms and, instead, it is assumed that the factors interact by substituting for one
another with diminishing returns. This can be contrasted with the way that researchers
typically conceive of interactions (e.g., aptitude-treatment interactions) in terms of
different types of students achieving differentially under alternative instructional
methods.
Other social factors not included in the productivity model influence learning
in school but are less directly linked to academic learning. For example, class size,
financial expenditures per student and private governance (independent or sectarian in
contrast to public control of schools) correlate only weakly with learning, especially if
the initial abilities of students are considered. Thus, improvements in the more direct
and more alterable factors contained in the model in Exhibit A hold the best hope for
increasing educational productivity (Walberg & Shanahan, 1983).
Carroll (1963) argues that the basic component of a model of learning is time.
The degree of learning is a function of the engaged time divided by time needed.
Engaged time is equal to the smallest of three quantities. Opportunity or time allowed
for learning, perseverance or the amount of time a learner is willing to engage actively
in learning and aptitude or the amount of time needed to learn, increased or decreased
by whatever amount of time is necessary as the result of the quality of instruction and
the ability of the pupil to understand instructions. This last quantity (aptitude or time
needed) is also the denominator in Carroll’s equation:
Neither Carroll nor Bloom and their successors pay much attention to learning
processes. Indeed, Glaser (1980) pointed out that aptitude, learning, and instruction
traditionally have been kept at a distance from each other. To minimize this distance,
Glaser envisaged various macro- and micro-theories of teaching and instruction.
Macro-theory concerns the large practical variables dealt with in schools. As it is
stated in page 324 of his work “…such as the allocation and efficient use of time, the
structure of the curriculum, the nature of feedback and reinforcement to the student,
the pattern of teacher student interaction, the relationship between what IS taught and
what is assessed, the degree of classroom flexibility required for adapting to learner
background and the details of curriculum materials. Such variables need to be part of
a theory of instruction (and), as this theory develops; it will be under girded by the
more macro-studies of human intelligences, problem solving, and learning”.
Glaser is representative of many recent psychologists/educators who have
outlined models of learning primarily related to learning processes (Case, 1978;
Greeno, 1980; Scandura, 1977; Sternberg, 1977). These models provide concentration
on the procedures for effective learning and emphasis on the importance of feedback
between learning processes and achievement outcomes. The models do not provide a
focus on the role of the teacher, school, or curriculum in terms other than how these
factors impede or aid the processes of learning. Glaser (1976, 1977, 1980 and 1982)
identified four essential components for producing student learning.
a. Analysis of competent performance which includes identification of the
information structures required for performance, as well as a description of the
cognitive strategies that apply to the learning task.
b. The description of the learner’s initial state which is similar to Bloom’s cognitive
entry behaviours.
c. The transformation process between the initial state and a state of competence; this
is the unique contribution of Glaser-type models.
Productivity Improvements in Education: A Replαy 111
In the USA unlike most sectors of its economy that steadily increase their
productivity over time, schools become less rather than more efficient, a serious
matter given the size of the education sector and the central and increasing importance
of learning in the American economy and society. School productivity or the relation
of achievement to costs was 65% higher in 1970–71 than in 1998–99 (Hoxby, 2001).
processing capacity among several functions of noticing, storing, and indexing on the
input side, and retrieving, reorganizing, and controlling his effectors [actions] on the
output side” (Simon, 1981, p. 167).
Language mastery, the fundamental and pervasive skill necessary for
achievement in school, is determined more by experience than by psychometric
intelligence. Decisive is the amount and intensity of the experience rather than age or
psychometric intelligence (Walberg, Hase, & Rasher, 1978).
To foster learning, that it can best provide logical, readily understood
explanations suitable to learners as well as the time, opportunity and incentives for
them to learn. These simple, commonsense principles set the stage for understanding
research on the psychological causes within and outside school that foster
achievement.
Practice makes perfect, says an old adage. An analysis of time effects on
learning suggests the obvious: 88% of 376 study estimates revealed the positive
effects of various aspects of study time such as preschool participation, school
attendance, amount of attention to lessons, amount of homework, and length of the
school year (Walberg, 1998b). The positive effect of time is perhaps most consistent
of all causes of learning.
This taxonomy of nine factors in three sets derives from an early synthesis
of 2,575 study comparisons (Walberg, 1984) suggesting that these factors are the
chief psychological causes of academic achievement. Subsequent syntheses have
shown results consistent with the original findings. Each of the first five factors—
prior achievement, development, motivation, and the quantity and quality of
instruction—seems necessary for learning in school. Without at least a small amount
of each factor, the student may learn little. Large amounts of instruction and high
degrees of ability for example, may count for little if students are unmotivated or
instruction is unsuitable. Each of the first five factors appears necessary but
insufficient by itself for effective learning.
6.2 Motivation
principals should accept the diversity of human attitudes, feelings and motives and
professionalism while working with each teacher to personalize his/her needs.
Moreover, as commercial concerns broadened, Lawrence (1975) believed that
individual interests should be adapted to increase motivation, morale, and
productivity, thereby reducing employee turnover and alienation within the
organization.
While motivation varies between individuals, the administrator in the current
educational climate must understand the beliefs, desires, and values of his or her
employees and how these attributes will affect job performance. The ability to
understand motivated behavior of employees is only the initial stage. Limited
unmotivated behavior is the desired outcome for administrators and managers alike.
Much motivated research has concluded that a strong organization and
positive work environment will encourage, and even promote greater motivation and
productivity. Administrators who offer professional employees the possibility of
doing new and original tasks in an effort to motivate them to set high standards of
performance often exceed organizational standards.
Motivation itself is closely associated with how much students can learn.
Multivariate analysis of surveys and control-group studies of reinforcement
corroborate its causal influence. This effect sharply contradicts the prevalent idea in
education that learning must be intrinsically motivated for its own sake.
b. Home Environment
The effect of the home environment can be taken very seriously for several reasons.
Control-group studies corroborate many correlational findings. The home effect is far
larger than apparent socioeconomic effects. Something can be done about home
environments. School–parent programs can help parents academically stimulate their
children by reading to them, taking them to libraries, guiding and discussing leisure
television viewing, cooperating with home visitors and teachers and similar practices.
c. Grouping
d. Student Incentives
complex. The difficulty with output indicators is the selection of which indicator is
the best measure of a schools performance. Schools priorities are shaped through a
political process and the multifaceted school programs reflect the outcome at such a
process. Schools exist for all the above purposes with others that have not been listed.
The roots of school improvement can be seen historically as having two-distinct
threads of research: the first, spanning many years, is concerned with educational
innovation; while the second is more recent and involves the study of effective
schools.
Loucks- Horsley and Hergert (1985) in a very useful Action Guide to school
Improvement state some of their beliefs which appear to contradict the conventional
wisdom about improving schools.
Considerable work has been undertaken on the study of educational innovation, and
this is admirably summarised by Michael Fullam in his book, “The meaning of
Educational Change (1982)”.
knowledge yet and therefore they face serious obstacles to doing so, but that it is too
soon to give up on the attempt.
Monk uses the production function as the basic element for studying
productivity in schools. He defines a production function as a model which links
conceptually and mathematically outcomes, inputs, and the processes that transform
the latter into the former in schools. He notes that production functions are important
for improving both technical and allocate efficiencies. However, despite their
potential benefits, Monk recognizes the major obstacles that face the creation of
production functions for education. Outcomes, inputs and processes are not easily
understood.
Monk is aware of the difficulties in dealing with both micro and macro
analyses. He concludes that there is no any other better approach. As he points out in
page 327: "... it is not always the case that micro-level data are better than macro-level
data. The proper level of analysis depends largely on the nature of the phenomenon
being studied. Some phenomena are district rather than school or classroom
phenomena and have effects that are felt throughout entire school districts".
The inputs of the school itself are relatively easy to recognize--buildings, teachers,
textbooks, and the like-- although Monk notes difficulties here, too, in knowing which
inputs do reach students, and in what form.
What does it mean to say that a resource flows to a student? A teacher might
spend time providing tutorial instruction for a single student. But the student may or
may not be attentive to the instruction being provided. The student may "... decline the
assistance, either overtly or covertly. In such a case, did the resource flow, as he
points out in page 328.
Time is another significant problem for studying educational productivity. It
seems reasonable to believe that students will learn at different rates. Yet this
seemingly innocuous conclusion creates enormous difficulties for analysis, since it
means that different resources at different times and in different arrangements may be
necessary for different students. Indeed, there could be a unique production function
for each child or even several functions for each child under different circumstances
as it is stated in page 344 in Monk’s book.
Analysts also agree that learning is influenced significantly by factors outside
the school. A vast array of home and background variables, Monk indicates, have
been used at various times as part of the specification of the inputs of schooling, not
always accompanied by a strong theoretical rationale for their importance. Even when
identified, these input variables are difficult to measure. Monk cites intelligence as a
particularly important and difficult to resolve instance.
Finally, as if these problems were not enough, Monk mentions various
technical problems for studying productivity in education. These include the limited
variation among schools in many of their attributes, the possibility that both input and
outcome variables are collinear, and the likelihood that inputs and outcomes influence
each other. Finally, there is the real possibility that certain aspects of education are
"anarchistic," by which Monk means that actors are not goal-oriented, so that even if
the best way of doing things was known, people would not pay attention to it as it
stated in page 339.
Monk raises the possibility that there is no production function for education.
In page 342 of his book, he states that no "systematic process governs the
transformation of inputs into outcomes" (p. 342). Many of the same themes are
reprised in Monk's (1992) article. He begins by pointing out the current policy
towards what he calls "outcomes as standards". He notes that there is a paradox
116 European Research Studies, Volume IX, Issue (3-4) 2006
weld a piece of metal to be the roof of a car the part that one had in hand would
announce its unwillingness to play the assigned role and its desire instead to be part of
an art gallery instead of being part of a car, or to become a piece of cloth instead of a
piece of metal.
The idea of the student as worker seems more promising than that of the
student as material to be worked on, since it acknowledges that learning is something
that students do. In economic processes workers are doing something to some material
or for someone else. Although students often do think of schooling in this sense, as
doing something for their teachers or their parents, the concept of education is
centrally concerned about what happens to learners, not what happens to others
around them. If students are the workers, then they are working on themselves rather
than on external materials.
Every teacher knows it. Every teacher realizes that what happens in a class is
fundamentally dependent on who the students are, how they make sense of the world
and what they want or do not want to do. Students are constantly making decisions
about the amount of effort, attention and interest they will put into their school work.
They decide to come to school or not, to pay attention in class or not, to take the
material seriously or not, to focus on grades or not (Doyle, 1986). These decisions are
not entirely independent of what schools and teachers do. Neither are they determined
by what happens in schools. We may arrange schooling on the basis of relatively
standard treatment of all while every educator recognizes that the best laid plans may
come to nothing in the face of students with different agendas.
If what students do and think is central to education, then it must also be
central to the way schooling is organized. Yet that is far from being the case. Most of
the policy attention about schools focuses on such matters as curriculum, teachers,
school organization, or governance. Policies in these areas are presumed, almost
unthinkingly to yield changes in what students do, think, or learn.
Consider various sides of the debate over restructuring schooling. One
approach has been what Fullan (1991) calls the "intensification" approach -- stricter
curriculum requirements, closer supervision of teachers and students, external
examinations, and so on. Here the assumption is that teachers and administrators will
be tougher on students, and that students will respond to the changes by intensifying
their own efforts at school. The strategy could be phrased as one of "making them
learn whether they want to or not". Presumably we would already have taken steps to
make sure all students learned what we wanted them to. As soon as we see students as
both workers and product, clearly a strategy of intensification will not be successful,
since it does not take into account the power and the range of students' ideas and the
motivations.
The main alternative policy currently being proposed is the
"professionalization" approach in which more authority is given to teachers to take the
steps they see as most desirable. In some versions authority is moved to school
communities which include teachers, parents, and sometimes students (Zeichner,
1992). But if we think of students as the central element, then this strategy seems
unlikely to succeed. It assumes that teachers know what to do to create more learning,
and that they will do so by giving them the authority. Neither assumption seems
credible. It is reasonable to think that most teachers have a real concern about students
and their welfare. It is not reasonable to think that all teachers have a tremendous
store of knowledge about how to educate that they are waiting to unleash with
dramatic effect as soon as they are freed from the shackles of bureaucratic restrictions.
118 European Research Studies, Volume IX, Issue (3-4) 2006
Although the basic options for change are evident, there is increasing
evidence that schools are remarkably resistant to change. One explanation for this
resistance is the absence of adequate incentives. Pincus in his work (19…) “Incentives
for Education in the Public Schools”, offers six contrasts between schools and
organization functioning in a competitive sphere. He notes that schools should be
expected to:
a. Be more likely than the competitive firm to adopt cost-raising innovations since
there is no marketplace to test the value of the innovation (e.g. smaller class size) in
relation to its cost.
b. Be less likely than the competitive firm to adopt cost-reducing innovations unless
the funds so saved become available for other purposes within the district.
c. Be less likely than the competitive firm to adopt innovations that significantly
change the resource mix (e.g. a higher ratio of teacher aides to teachers, sharply
increased use of capital-intensive technologies) because any consequent productivity
increases are not necessarily matched by greater profits to the district and because
replacement of labor by capital may threaten the guild structure of the schools.
d. Be more likely than the competitive firm to adopt new instructional processes or
new wrinkles in administrative management that do not significantly change
institutional structure.
e. Be less likely than the competitive firm to adopt innovations that change
accustomed authority roles and established ways of doing business because changes in
these relations represent the heaviest kind of real cost bureaucracies.
f. Be equally unwilling as competitive firms to face large-scale encroachments on
protected markets (voucher systems, metropolitan are wide open enrollment),
although for somewhat different reasons.
Type of Outcome
Cognitive Affective
Knowledge Self-concept
General Intelligence Interests
Psychological
Type of Data
Level of educational
attainment Choice of major career
Vocational
achievements: Avocations
Behavioral
Level of responsibility Mental health
income, Citizenship
Awards of special
recognition Interpersonal relations
or classes ebb and flow over time there is little change in the number of faculty in
each department. A failure to match teaching capacity with student demand is
completely opposite the private sector, where changes in business conditions directly
influence staffing levels.
Several policies can increase the flexibility of faculty. But, arguably, the
greatest obstacle to increased flexibility of faculty is tenure. An economic argument
for tenure is that it saves initial expense on the part of the university. The saving arises
because faculty with tenure, or those hired with the possibility of tenure, will work at
a lower salary in return for the guarantee of lifetime employment. However, while
there may be initial cost savings from tenure, the resulting inflexibility imposed by
tenure has greater costs in terms of both dollars and student quality. Tenure prevents
significant staffing changes in response to changes in student demands, and also may
prevent lower quality faculty from being replaced by higher quality faculty.
Administrators and management professionals have suggested strategies that can
increase faculty flexibility in the presence of tenure, although each of these strategies
is not without problems. Some of these strategies may be met with opposition from
faculty or even legal challenges. One strategy is to impose tenure quotas on the
number or percentage of the faculty who may hold tenure at any one time.
e. The use of citation analysis to assess scholarly productivity
The current state of the art in the analysis of scholarly productivity, citation
analysis, unfortunately provides a good illustration of this latter phenomenon. The
conceptual difficulties besetting those who use this methodology are suggested by
their entering focus as well as by their technique. John Smart provides an adequate
working definition of this approach: “Citation analysis is a special form of
bibliographic research used to assess the quality or importance of scientific
contributions. This methodology is based on reference citations found in scientific
publications and assumes that citation frequency data can be used to assess the
significance of scientific contributions of individual scientists, academic departments,
and scholarly journals.”
8. References