Marsden 1995 PDF
Marsden 1995 PDF
Marsden 1995 PDF
David Marsden *
Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics, Discussion
Paper No. 240, May 1995
Abstract
The rules and institutions of collective bargaining are widely held to have an
adverse effect on employment and thus on unemployment. These views are
analysed, and it is argued that many industrial relations institutions provide
a much greater degree of flexibility for firms than is often realised. It is often
forgotten that collective agreements involve the agreement of employers who
are thus able to influence the rules that are fixed. Nevertheless, there are many
areas where collective rules conflict with the needs for firms to raise
productivity and to adapt to market changes.
The paper then examines a number of the sources of flexibility in such areas
as low inflation bargaining structures, industry agreements, workplace
cooperation, and mechanisms for youth inclusion. It also reviews some of the
developments in the area of flexibility agreements, and recent reforms of
collective bargaining systems in a number of OECD countries, all features
likely to increase the ability of firms to adjust in these countries.
David Marsden *
Table of contents
Page
1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
2. Bargained pay and work rules and unemployment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
3. Sources of flexibility in industrial relations systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
4. Recent changes favouring more flexibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
5. Policies to increase adaptability. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
End notes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
David Marsden
1. Introduction
This chapter deals with those practices which are associated with collective
bargaining and other forms of collective employee representation, such as
works councils which, strictly speaking, usually 'co-decide' and participate
with management rather than bargain. 'Joint regulation' embraces both
collective bargaining and worker participation, and cover both the regulation
of pay and benefits, and industrial government 2 , that is, the joint management
of employment relations within the enterprise. Although negotiated and legal
rules differ in many respects, for the purposes of this chapter, they will often
be treated as analogous unless the difference has some direct impact on
employment outcomes.
Because union strength has declined during the last decade in many countries,
and there is growing evidence that many practices associated with joint
regulation might be introduced even in a non-union environment, a second
chapter is devoted to the impact of employee management practices on
unemployment. This focuses on policies management has been adopting
unilaterally rather than through joint channels.
important role in adapting substantive rules, such as those on pay, to the local
circumstances of each firm. The impact of procedural rules is not easily
analysed within the standard competitive model of labour markets because
their main function is that of reducing transaction costs. Thus, whereas many
of the substantive rules associated with collective bargaining are deemed to
cause lower levels of employment and enterprise efficiency, the procedural
rules, and the institutions regulating them, on both the employer and
employee side, may improve cooperation, and thus indirectly, help jobs.
There are strong theoretical reasons for expecting that when collective
bargaining raises the cost of employment above the competitive level, it will
have an adverse effect upon the distribution of employment and
unemployment. 3 First, because the demand for labour depends upon that for
the goods and services it produces, bargaining up the pay of a particular
category of workers above the competitive level is likely to cause employers
to hire less of it. The reaction may not be immediate because it takes time to
reorganise production and to invest in alternative methods, but in the long
run, a higher price will lead to less of that category being hired.
a) Union/non-union differentials.
effect in the non-covered section may depress pay levels to the point at which
some workers withdraw from the labour force, and employment falls; some
may search for longer in the hope of a better paying job, thus causing
unemployment to rise; or if the wage cannot fall to the market clearing level,
perhaps because of a minimum wage rule, then unemployment will also rise.
Source: Blanchflower and Freeman (1992) Tabs.3 and 4.; density and coverage: OECD
Employment Outlook 1994, p. 173.
Note: density and coverage rates adjusted for % of workers excluded from collective
bargaining (eg. managerial employees in some countries).
However, such national averages are not a reliable guide to bargaining effects
because labour demand elasticities vary among occupations, and because
different kinds of institutional arrangements enable bargaining to be more or
less effective. Information on the latter depends very much upon the existence
of suitable surveys of institutional arrangements, such as the UK Workplace
Industrial Relations Surveys (WIRS). Using the 1980 and 1984 WIRS, Stewart
(1987) and (1991) found that, in 1980, the presence of a closed shop enhanced
semi-skilled workers' earnings, with a differential of about 5% if there was a
post-entry closed shop, and about 10% if a pre-entry one. 6 The effect was
slightly smaller for skilled workers, and it appeared to increase slightly
between 1980 and 1984. Later work by Metcalf and Stewart (1991), using WIRS
1984 data, found that in plants without a close shop, union recognition had
only a statistically significant impact on pay compared with non-union plants
if membership density was above 95%. Then the differential rose to 7-10%.
Similarly, the presence of a post-entry closed shop had little effect on pay
unless membership density was above 95%. In contrast, the presence of pre-
entry closed shop led to a 17-19% differential over workers in non-union
plants.
significant product market power, and non-existent where there was none.
Unlike the type of bargaining which has been common in the US and the UK,
which is largely focused on the enterprise level, and which has attracted most
theoretical and econometric work, the commonest form in most European
Union countries is that of industry or sectoral agreements which provide a
framework for subsequent negotiations at plant and enterprise level. These
tend to produce higher rates of coverage by agreements than in either the US
or Britain and so pose a rather different problem (Table 2). The first relates to
pay, and the second to the uniformity they may impose across an industry.
The effects of such agreements on wage dispersions have not been widely
studied, but some fragmentary evidence suggests their potential effects. In
Sweden, Hibbs (1990) showed the LO union's solidarity wage policy between
1970 and 1980 was one of the chief factors responsible for reducing the
dispersion of wages among contract groups, and among blue collar workers.
However, the Swedish centralised bargaining system was not typical of
continental European models in that it fixed the size of the kitty to distributed
at lower levels, and often prescribed how it should be distributed between
different categories. It did not set minimum wages along the lines of the
-8-
In the absence of analyses of the effects of bargained minima one might look
at studies of the effects of minimum wages on pay. The French minimum
wage (SMIC) is in many ways analogous to an industry minimum in terms of
its functioning, as was the British sectoral minimum wage system under the
wages councils (abolished in 1993). For France, Bazen and Martin (1991) found
that a 1% increase in the real SMIC would raise real youth earnings by 0.4%.
Since young workers are closest to the minimum, this would suggest
compression of the dispersion. In the UK, Kaufman (1988) found that the
minimum had no effect on average male wages in the sector, and could
therefore have only had a very small effect on dispersions of their earnings),
but for women, a 1% rise would increase their earnings by 0.07% to 0.15%,
combining, according to the authors, a reduction in the dispersion and a
'ripple' effect on higher paid women in the sectors. None of this evidence
provides a direct test of how far industry agreements compress the lower end
of the wage dispersion, but the results are suggestive.
The other aspect of industry agreements is that they usually consist of two
elements: how jobs should be classified, and what rates of pay should attach
to individual categories. The two are logically related as one cannot fix rates
of pay without defining the units to which they are attached. These constrain
employers as concerns both work organisation, as the classification system
imposes a degree of uniformity across firms, and rates of pay. Such uniformity
can be ill-suited both to firms using atypical technologies or organisation
patterns. IBM's withdrawal from the German metal industry bargaining
machinery on the ground that much of its activity had shifted from
manufacturing to computer services provides an illustration of these
problems. 8
During the 1960s and 1970s, unions in many countries followed policies that
favoured the pay of low paid workers, including young workers and the
unskilled. The reduction of wage dispersions and skill differentials in many
countries in Table 3 affected young and unskilled workers.
-9-
Key: + indicates increase; - decrease; = not much change; +/- changes in different
directions depending on categories; double sign major changes; n.a not available. Where
the turning points in trends are known to deviate markedly from the turn of the decade,
they are indicated.
Sources: Marsden (1990) except: a) OECD Employment Outlook 1993, and Katz et al. 1993.
There were many reasons for this such as national incomes policies the unions
supported which favoured larger increases for the low paid, a desire to ensure
new entrants joined their respective unions. During the 1960s, this may also
have been driven by market forces as tight labour markets ensured employers
competed hard to recruit young workers. Nevertheless, with the break in
conditions, in some countries youth pay continued on its upward trend, and
in others, a ratchet effect meant that it did not fall back to earlier levels. For
the UK, evidence of a switch from excess demand to excess supply in youth
labour markets at the end of the 1960s was provided by Merilees and Wilson
(1979), and Wells (1983) showed that youth rates of pay did not respond for
several years after the switch. In several other European Union countries,
notably, France and Italy, collective agreements did not distinguish between
youth and adult rates, a practice which did not appear to harm youth entry
in the 1950s and 1960s, but which appears to have damaged their access to
jobs from the 1970s (Marsden and Ryan 1986 and 1991).
Raising youth and unskilled relative pay, and sustaining enhanced levels once
the market has turned is likely to be particularly risky for these categories.
Layard (1982) and Wells (1983) found that demand was more sensitive to
relative wages for young workers than for adults, especially male adults.
Layard (1982) for manufacturing blue collar workers 1948-77 obtained demand
-10-
elasticity estimates of -1.3 and -0.3 respectively for young males and females,
with -1.6 and -0.4 for adult females and males. For the US, work by Freeman
and Anderson obtained similar sized demand elasticities for young, and adult
males, and for adult women. Hamermesh's (1986) review including other
countries supported their results, with somewhat higher estimates for the US.
By skill, Nissim (1984) estimated higher demand elasticities for unskilled than
for skilled labour for UK engineering, ranging from -1.1 for skilled, to -2.3 for
unskilled workers. 9 Hamermesh (1986) reported that whereas skilled labour
generally emerged as a complement to capital, unskilled labour was a
substitute. This, combined with a greater likely substitutability between youths
and unskilled adults, would make unskilled employment particularly
vulnerable to increases in their relative pay that were not demand-related.
One important reason for the prevalence of such rules is that they are easy to
monitor and to enforce. If a collective agreement were to allow management
to vary the rate of pay in line with its valuation of a worker's productivity, the
union, and its members, would have no easy way of gauging whether the
employer was respecting the agreement or not. Since employers are better
informed about current and likely future sales, there is an information
asymmetry which gives them a strong bargaining advantage over individual
workers.
Another important reason for such rules is that in large firms, the
administrative cost of establishing individually variable pay is high. Therefore,
unless the variability of work demands within a particular job category is
great, which it often was not under tightly supervised and tayloristic patterns
of work organisation, pay differentiation is unlikely to be economic.
Such rules may limit job openings for less efficient workers as employers are
likely to filter them out in the recruitment process. If rate for the job rules are
motivated primarily by union policy or by employers' administrative
-11-
One area where rate for the job rules have proved particularly damaging is in
that of youth employment. By insisting on all workers being paid the same
rate for the job, young workers, whose productivity is lower than that of
adults have been penalised in several European countries. Garonna and Ryan
(1986) identified two policies: one of regulated inclusion, under which a
special status is created for young workers so that they may be hired at a
special trainee or youth rate of pay; and one exclusion, under which no such
discounts apply. The conditions for regulated inclusion are discussed in a later
section (§3.5), but exclusion generally arises because adult workers fear
substitution by cheap young workers unless there is some way of regulating
their use by employers. They attribute the small size of youth differentials in
Italy and France, as compared with Britain and Germany, to this effect, and
hence the lower levels of youth employment there compared with countries
where regulated inclusion is practised.
The theory of 'efficiency wages' has gone furthest in attempting to explain the
reason employers might seek pay differentiation within job categories, and in
particular why they might pay individuals above the competitive market rate
for their particular skills. This becomes particularly important where jobs
demand a high degree of employee discretion so that the quality of work
cannot be easily monitored. As a result, employers depend upon how
conscientiously workers do their jobs. It is argued that they can ensure higher
quality work either by increasing the cost of dismissal to the workers, or by
inducing better motivation. According to the first, employers pay above the
competitive market clearing rate in order to strengthen the sanction of
dismissal. According to the second, by paying more, they induce a feeling of
reciprocity among the workers so they feel obliged to work better (see Akerlof
and Yellen, 1986).
There have been a number of attempts to apply the theory to wage data (eg.
Dell'Aringa and Lucifora 1990, Lang and Leonard, 1987) but they provide at
-12-
best indirect tests of the potential impact of rate for the job rules, so it is
difficult to gain any idea of their possible magnitude.
A major difficulty with the theory, and thus with the feasibility of alternatives
to rate for the job rules, except for higher management, is that it is very
difficult to measure employee output to the satisfaction of both management
and employees. Bishop (1987) cites evidence that the correlation between the
ratings of the same employees by different supervisors is quite low. Hence,
employee confidence in the fairness of evaluations is likely to be low, and the
potential for causing demotivating jealousies among staff is high. Thus
employers may be deterred by the risk that the extra productivity gained by
motivating high performers may be less than that lost because of conflicts over
evaluations. Therefore, for most employees, the arguments about the efficiency
loss due to rate for the job rules are finely balanced.
Pay differentials for skill and responsibility are widely held to play an
essential part in the functioning of an effective labour market. It is worth
distinguishing job movements between firms from those within the same
internal labour market. Among the former, it seems that once workers have
entered an occupation, it seems that wages play only a small role in
reallocating labour among firms and between industries (OECD 1965, Mackay
et al. 1971). Although workers with occupational skills are somewhat more
likely to change firms than those with enterprise specific ones, many
employers seek to retain their more skilled labour whatever the type of market
to which it is integrated. In contrast, the position is different for new entrants.
In contrast, studies of new entrants suggest that supply is sensitive to relative
starting wages, especially among young males (eg. Zabalza et al. (1979) UK
teachers, and Freeman (1971) US college trained engineers). Thus, union
policies compressing differentials for skill and responsibility are most likely
to affect mobility among the latter category.
How important such questions are may depend in part on the type of
-13-
Precise estimates of the costs of laying workers off are difficult to ascertain
because regulations vary in their nature from country to country, and because
they may be enforced with varying degrees of severity. Indeed, where lay-offs
depend upon agreeing appropriate measures with worker representatives, as
is the case in Germany and France, the cost will vary according to the degree
of cooperativeness forthcoming from workforce representatives.
Although agreed provisions on lay-offs may reflect the trade-offs between the
objectives of employers and employee representatives, not all parties are
equally represented. Typically, large firms and their employees are more
influential respectively in employer and worker organisations. Large firms
may find it easier to anticipate potential redundancies and to manage
providing employees with advance notice, and because they are engaged in
a wider range of activities, may find it easier to redeploy staff to other
activities, than would small firms. Among employees, more senior, skilled,
male workers are frequently better represented in works councils and unions
than are young unskilled workers, women, and ethnic minorities (Fürstenberg
1969).
has been suggested by Atkinson and Meager (1986). However, the radicalism
of their predictions, and the extent to which firms were consciously using this
model in the UK has been contested strongly by Pollert (1988) and Hakim
(1990) using labour force survey and WIRS follow-up data. 10 Nevertheless, the
three sets of findings would be consistent with some employers responding
in a piecemeal fashion to the increased cost of laying off certain categories of
workers. In addition, because employment security provisions in the UK are
felt to be among the least stringent in Europe (see below), such tendencies
may be less developed there than elsewhere. In Spain and France employers
have made widespread use of measures to facilitate hiring on short-term
contracts. 11 Often these are followed by hiring on a standard employment
contract so they have served as part of the induction and screening process.
Since one of the greatest costs in recruitment is that of selecting the wrong
person, the advantages of induction contracts to employers should not be
underestimated. Special employment contracts for young workers have been
widely used indicating their popularity among employers. Especially in
countries where standard rates of pay apply to workers of all ages, such
measures enable young workers to be hired at more economic rates without
threatening the integrity of collective agreements and employers' salary
systems.
Although these are opinions, and the firms were not asked to specify for
which categories of labour these remarks applied, they are given some
-16-
Thus, one has to consider agreed practices which inhibit the efficient use of
labour and organisational change because of their likely indirect effects upon
employment and unemployment in the longer term. Labour utilisation in the
firm can be considered under two main headings: (i) constraints arising from
rules or commitments to using labour in a particular way which lead to
under-utilisation of current workforce skills; and (ii) limitations on firms'
ability to modernise their human resource management practices.
In a famous study of productivity and unions in the late 1940s, Zweig (1951)
warned that it was relatively easy for economists to define 'restrictive labour
practices' in terms of lost productivity or increased production cost. However,
at the end of his detailed field study of such practices in five major sectors of
British industry, he concluded that there was little unanimity among managers
in different firms as to whether they were harmful or simply, often, the price
to be paid for doing other things effectively. For example, the craft skill
demarcations which confine the execution of certain tasks to those who have
completed the appropriate apprenticeship was often seen as a natural
consequence of the way vocational training was organised.
-17-
There have been many famous cases of monopolistic labour practices which
have restricted production, and these have attracted much publicity in certain
industries, such as the media. But to rely on such cases runs the risk of
reasoning from anecdotes. An alternative approach is to look at the sorts of
issues that have arisen in flexibility discussions and negotiations between
unions and employers in a number of countries. The efforts employers have
been prepared to put into such deals is an indication of the gains they expect.
Seniority rules
Seniority rules became a major obstacle to redeployment for two reasons. First,
new production methods broke the continuity of job progression from one job
to another. Training as well as experience became necessary. Secondly,
seniority rules imply the prior existence of a group or category of workers
who can be ranked by seniority, what was commonly called a 'seniority
district'. Movement of workers from one district to another would normally
disrupt the working of seniority. If it were transferable, then the seniority
-18-
ranking in the host district is disrupted, if were not, then workers have no
incentive to accept redeployment. Katz (1985) follows the introduction of more
flexible arrangements in the US automobile industry and the removal of many
seniority rules, as a part of the recovery programme of the major firms in that
sector. Kochan, Katz and McKersie (1986) provide similar evidence for a wider
range of sectors stressing the transformation of US industrial relations in the
process, with a shift in the focus of union action from job control and seniority
to acceptance of joint labour-management and 'quality of working life'
programmes. Kochan, Katz and Gobeille (1983) provide some evidence that
union involvement in QWL programmes across a sample of GM plants had
a favourable impact on productivity, at the very least, because it appears to
have enabled management to carry out some of the organisational changes it
was seeking. McKersie (1990) has argued that many firms have moved away
from seniority towards new concepts of employment security based on more
flexible deployment of labour, and broader job grading systems (discussed
below: §4.4).
The other feature of seniority rules, brought out by the studies of Gouldner
(1954) and Crozier (1964), is that they reduce management's control over job
allocations, and so reduce the rewards at the disposal of line management in
order to gain workforce cooperation.
As with the seniority rules of the US, skill demarcation rules do not
necessarily cause loss of productivity. Apart from the risk to capital equipment
and to safety when work is undertaken by inappropriately trained workers,
under the persistent conditions of skill shortage that have characterised UK
labour markets, strict demarcations could ensure better skill utilisation (Prais,
1981). Nevertheless, during the 1980s, the removal of a number of particular
kinds of job demarcation attracted employers. First, the economic crisis faced
by a number of major firms gave management the opportunity to gain
acceptance for changes which had been delayed during the 1970s. Secondly,
as in the United States, manufacturing management faced the same need to
adopt more flexible production systems and to raise quality, both of which
transformed previously acceptable working practices into obstacles to
efficiency. New technology blurred the boundaries between established
electrical, mechanical, and hydraulic skills such that rigid skill demarcations
led to poor utilisation. Similarly, as competitors made more use of preventive
maintenance, teams of skilled maintenance workers able to work flexibly
proved more economical than previous practices. Recent work by Richardson
and Rubin (1993) on the work practice concessions made in the working time
negotiations in the British engineering industry suggests that this kind of
change has continued, enabling further productivity improvement in the firms
concerned.
Job grading systems have been another major area of change of working
practices pressed by employers during the 1980s in order to facilitate easier
deployment of labour. This was an important part of the workplace level
changes in both the United States (eg. Katz 1985, Osterman 1988), and also in
the UK (Marsden and Thompson 1990). It has also figured widely in
workplace changes in France (Eyraud et al 1989), and in Germany (Schudlich
1991).
Although apparently very technical, job classifications lie at the heart of the
employment relation, and in many countries (with Japan as a notable
exception), they provide the vital link in the 'wage-work bargain' by enabling
-20-
Similar changes have also been sought by French employers, moving away
from job classification systems based on work posts, which made transfer from
one post to another, and adaptation to new skills often very difficult. They
have sought to move to more flexible systems based on job evaluation (critères
classants), although often the influence of the old system has remained strong
(Lanfranchi 1988, Eyraud et al. 1990).
A fixed length for the working day can lead to underutilisation and raise costs
in two ways: customer demands do not always arrive predictably, and some
jobs may require specific blocks of time so that they can only be fitted into a
fixed working day if they are started early on (eg. train drivers' journeys).
Overtime working provides some flexibility, albeit at a cost, but in some
countries, there are legal or agreed restrictions on the amount of overtime that
can be worked in a given period (eg. in France, the law allows no more than
an average of 46 hours worked per week over a twelve week period Lyon-
Caen and Pélissier, 1988).
-21-
Employers in both France and Germany have been concerned to get the law
and collective agreements to concentrate on fixing limits to working time over
longer periods than one week. Annual working time, for example, would give
employers the chance to increase weekly hours during peak periods, and then
to offset these by shorter hours in off-peak periods. This would also avoid the
cost of paying for overtime hours. They have also been interested in altering
shift-working patterns and to increase the use of weekend working in order
to extend the time during which capital equipment can be run, or particular
services provided.
Legal regulation of working time, for example, setting limits on weekly hours
and overtime, can be unduly rigid because of the need to impose a general
rule which cannot be easily adapted to take account of local or changing
circumstances. The general rule may be made more flexible by allowing
exemptions, for example, to allow for certain services where there a long
periods of inactivity during the day, and to adapt conditions to different
categories of workers. It is also often possible to obtain approval from a labour
inspector for exceptional treatment. However, such adaptation multiplies the
number of exceptions and increases the burden on the enforcement agency,
and on firms which may not be aware of the law's complexities. For this, and
other reasons, successive French governments have sought to increase the role
of collective agreements on the ground that they are more capable to adapting
to the needs of particular industries while at the same time providing an
acceptable level of protection to employees. The negotiations have, however,
been fraught with difficulty, not least because the unions are often too weak
to provide effective control over enterprise negotiations, and so have been
reluctant to lose the protection of the law. Nevertheless, during the 1980s, and
particularly after the Auroux laws, a large number of agreements were
reached at both industry and enterprise level, many of which dealt with
aspects of the organisation of working time (Ministère du Travail 1989). The
employers appear to have used negotiations on the reduction of working time
in order to gain concessions for more flexible patterns of utilisation (Boulin
and Taddéi, 1989).
In Germany, although the impulse for negotiation on working time has come
from the unions' campaign for reduced weekly working hours, the employers
have used the negotiations to press for their own changes such that shorter
working time for each worker comes at the price of more flexible working
time arrangements (Bosch1990).
One such survey from the mid-1980s (Elbaum 1987) showed that French and
Belgian firms were much more likely to see insufficient flexibility in hiring and
lay-offs as a reason for not increasing employment as compared with Britain.
In contrast, British firms were more likely to see rationalisation and new
technology as a reason. Use of temporary workers, and inflexible working time
arrangements were also of more concern to Belgian and French, than to British
firms. 14
Clearly, such processes can only take effect if employers have the ability to
pay which depends partly on monetary policy, and partly on other income
recipients, and income for other purposes being squeezed. Tightening
monetary policy will restrain inflation by curbing demand, and thus
employment, but it may not always be the employment of those with most
bargaining power.
-24-
Against this rather negative balance sheet, a number of more positive features
of collective bargaining must be set before any final conclusions may be
drawn for policy. Many of these features are often neglected in the discussion
of institutional influences on unemployment. They suggest both a number of
positive benefits from working through collective bargaining and other forms
of employee representation, and by examining some of the less visible forms
of flexibility contained within collective institutions and how they have been
adapted in recent years, it is possible to identify some areas of reform which
could help combat some of their unemployment effects.
employers and unions at both sectoral and national level both preceded
legislation in this area, and provided a model for the type of provisions to be
included. A clue as to the underlying logic of such agreements. Far from
conceding simply to worker demands for greater employment security, as
might be the case in pay deals, the agreements were mainly concerned with
promoting organisational change and rationalising production, both of which
would have serious employment consequences. In the steel industry, which
pioneered such agreements in France, and in other mass production industries,
a great many workers had skills that were not easily transferable, and would
be rendered obsolete by the changes. The same applied to middle management
employees whose skills lay primarily in their previous work experience and
their detailed knowledge of their particular organisation and its work norms.
With the potential loss of jobs and skill obsolescence, workers' morale could
easily collapse, and with it, the ability of the firms to implement their change
programmes. Management had also to ensure that once the first wave of
changes was complete, the employees remaining would work effectively and
willingly.
It might be objected that such arguments are valid for voluntary but not for
legally based employment security rules. It is possible that legislation sets
more costly provisions than would agreements. Nevertheless, in many
countries, employment law has been used to set minimum conditions
sufficiently low to enable worker representatives and employers to agree
locally the arrangements which suit their needs best. The law has often been
modeled on existing agreements, particularly as concerns consultation
procedures.
It was argued earlier that certain kinds of pay bargaining structure were likely
to harm employment levels because governments would need to restrain their
inflationary tendencies by running the economy below capacity (§2.5). One
solution to the problems of competitive pay bargaining, and to the reluctance
of bargaining groups to make economically necessary concession under
fragmented bargaining has been to propose greater coordination by means of
centralised bargaining.
-26-
Blyth (1979), intuitively, and Calmfors and Driffil (1988), more formally, have
argued that centralised bargaining systems should be less prone to inflation
than more fragmented ones. The Calmfors and Driffil argument rests on the
interaction of two opposing processes. As bargaining units increase in size
from the plant or enterprise to the central level, their bargaining power
increases. However, as the coverage of collective agreements increases, so it
becomes harder to escape the negative consequences of individual settlements,
and easier to benefit from any sacrifices they might make in the general
interest (Olson 1971). The latter force serves to moderate unions' use of
bargaining power, and enables bargainers to take a longer term and more
moderate view. Bargainers who take a moderate line are also less prone to see
their position being undermined by rival groups taking a much more militant
one.
There is some evidence supporting this view. Between the 1970s and 1980s,
countries with centralised bargaining systems, and those with highly
decentralised ones tended to score better both on inflation and employment
(Paloheimo 1990). However, the indicators of bargaining structure used are
rather subjective and the results rather prone to changes in the rankings of
countries by degree of centralisation (eg. Soskice 1990). Moreover, the degree
of influence that central organisations within any given country can, or seek
to, exert over bargaining outcomes at lower levels varies over time, as does
the degree to which strong union organisations use their power aggressively
or cooperatively.
Germany
More recently, Meyer's (1991 a and b) survey of 103 small and medium-sized
firms in Niedersachsen and Baden-Würtemberg found an average mark-up
over the industry minima of 14% among firms paying above the industry
minimum. In his survey, 80% of the firms applied a wage agreement. Of these,
15% paid only the rates set in the industry agreement. The others, on average,
paid 14% above the industry rate. The main variables associated with this
being: presence of a works council; number of vacancies; level of training; and
(inversely) the percentage of women. Among these small and medium sized
firms, there appeared to be little difference in mark-up by size.
These two surveys suggest that economic pressures at the enterprise, notably,
recruitment and skill levels, do indeed affect the size of the wage gap, and are
evidence of some capacity of pay levels set at the industry level to adapt to
local pressures.
Italy.
In Italy, the scope for enterprise bargaining and pay supplements unilaterally
decided by the employer have varied over time, but were greatly squeezed by
the indexation system in force from 1977. In 1976, according to
Federmeccanica data, the wage gap between gross earnings and the minima
set in national industry agreements in the metal industry was 28%, this being
the result of local bargaining and employer supplements. It remained steady
until after the reforms of 1984 and 1984, climbing to 43% in 1990 (Asap 1993,
Appendice Statistica). Data for Assolombarda give similar, but slightly lower
estimates of the wage gap for metal industry employers in the Milan area: up
from 26% in 1983 to 37% in 1991.
The scope for enterprise bargaining and employer supplements was squeezed
by the combination of flat rate indexation and unanticipated inflation in the
late 1970s and early 1980s (de Luca 1987), and was only stabilised by the
agreements of 1983 and 1984 reducing the degree of indexation. The
Assolombarda data show the main change to be the decline in the share of
pay determined by indexation, down from 44% in 1983 to 39% in 1991 (Asap
1993, Appendice Statistica III).
The same sources show a steady increase in the wage gap for the Milan metal
industry in 1991, from 15% for unskilled to 23% for the highest skilled, and
from 14% for junior clerks to 93% for the highest level of managers still
covered by collective agreements (Asap 1993).
-29-
One can only surmise the scope for adaptation by individual firms as data are
not shown at this level. However, de Luca (1987) records quite large
differences between industrial sectors. For 1984, about 25% in textiles and
clothing, about 45% in chemicals and pharmaceuticals, and about 30% in the
metal industry. In addition, the Assolombarda data show that, in 1991,
individual premia added 18% to industry minima: ranging from 2% for blue
collar workers and 17% for white collars, to about 40% for managers covered
by collective agreements. This suggests that employers have a significant
margin with which to respond to labour market and motivational needs.
France.
In France, the gap between industry rates and enterprise pay levels is often
considerable, and has increased in recent years. Eyraud, et al. (1989: p.159 ff.)
found that average basic pay 17 in their sample of plants was considerably
above the industry agreement minima. In the metal industry firms, lower paid
manuals were paid 20-60% above above the industry minima, about 20% when
blue collar workers were in the majority, and up to 60% when white collars
were in the majority. Higher paid white collar workers were also well above
the industry minima for their grades. So, establishment level factors provide
a considerable mark-up, and also alter the structure of pay, particularly for the
larger firms and market leaders which made up the bulk of their sample.
Interestingly, the wage gap was not uniformly greater for more highly
classified workers in the plants studied, suggesting a margin for adapting
wage differentials within the enterprise. The authors concluded that the main
importance of industry agreements was as a benchmark for annual pay
increases, and a guide for wage structures.
In France, industry agreements also leave individual firms with a good deal
of freedom to develop their own policies on other remuneration issues such
as fringe benefits. A study by the CERC (1987) identified four distinct types
of policy which appeared to be pursued whatever the industry agreement
concerned.
The authors concluded that the diversity of firms' practices within sectors
highlighted the relatively weak influence of sectoral agreements on firms'
practice in France.
-31-
Sweden.
Sweden has had a different model whereby central bargaining did not specify
minimum rates of pay for industry and local levels, as in France, Germany,
and Italy, but rather set the aggregate increase in the wage bill for each
industrial contract area. This 'wage pot' or 'kitty' could be distributed as local
bargainers decided, and its size was usually determined in relation to the
growth of the total wage bill (Hibbs 1990). At various times, the central
agreement also determined set norms for its distribution, for example, that the
lower paid should get special increases. When in force, the solidarity wage
policy imposed an equalising effect by specifying how the 'wage pot' or 'kitty'
was to be distributed at lower levels. 18 Apart from that period, the model
provided a good deal of room for adaptation to local conditions, and has
indeed been introduced as a part of the government's strategy to decentralise
pay determination in the public sector (Schager,1993).
Because of the need for trade union cohesion (§3.6), it seems unlikely that
these margins of flexibility in industry agreements avoids problems for
marginal and temporarily weak firms. Two problems will need to be discussed
later: whether there are ways of making industry agreements more responsive
to the needs of firms going through a temporary crisis, and whether they can
be linked with certain active labour market policies.
Japan
The Japanese case offers an interesting variant in which pay bargaining takes
place at the enterprise level between management and enterprise unions.
However, the enterprise unions are grouped into industry federations which
play a critical role in coordinating bargaining strategies among their members.
In addition, the national union and employers' confederation coordinate the
activities of their constituents at the national level. To assist coordination, and
to avoid problems of some groups holding out until after the others have
settled in the hope of gaining a better increase, with all the problems this
entails for obtaining a first settlement, bargaining is concentrated in a short
period in the 'spring offensive' (Dore 1987).
Additional scope for individual firms to adjust their own pay increases is
provided by the annual bonus which can represent the equivalent of several
months base salary (Nohara 1992). This is decided at company level once its
financial results are known, and may also be the subject of bargaining, but
-32-
outside the spring offensive. According to Hashimoto and Raisian (1988) the
average bonus for manufacturing varies roughly in similar proportion to
production (a 10% change in production producing an 11% change in the
bonus) thus affording some variability in employers' labour costs. In 1978,
average bonus stood at roughly 20% of total benefits. Although that would
give an average margin of variation of only ±2% of benefit costs, it may
provide more scope for variation among firms.
Management has some alternative channels for employee voice at its disposal,
for example, surveys of employee opinions, and encouraging first line
management to be more active in discovering the causes of employee
discontent. Although these can provide valuable information, they are not
independent of management. Hence, employees may still fear victimisation,
particularly if first line management is also responsible for performance
appraisal and merit awards.
-33-
If such rules are part of the normal give and take between management and
-34-
One important reason is that workers (or management) come to fear that the
other party is seeking covertly to alter the terms of the agreement in their
favour. If workers were confident that management would faithfully report the
changing value of their output and pay them accordingly, there might be less
need to insist on easily monitored 'rate for the job' rules. Equally, if they were
confident that the employer would seek to minimise redundancies, and not
use lay-offs to get rid of those who have presented grievances, they might
insist less on strong seniority rules in lay-offs and in bidding for internal
vacancies. Similarly, restrictive job demarcation rules which go beyond the
needs of technical competence provide skilled workers with a buffer against
employment insecurity.
This is not to deny that monopolistic motives may also be present, but these
are often limited by the need for the support of other groups of workers.
Brown (1973) stressed that shop stewards' ability to defend work customs that
were advantageous to one group depended upon their ability to convince
other work groups that they were acceptable. His study cited cases in which
shop stewards supported management against the claims of some groups,
albeit based on custom, that threatened the good faith of their relationship
with management and their ability to sustain the support of other groups.
D'Iribarne (1988) similarly stresses that the stability of customary relations of
non-interference in each others' work ('honour') he found in French firms
depended also upon willingness to moderate claims that threatened other
groups. 19 There is less likely to be sympathy and support from other groups
for one which defends a customary rule for monopolistic goals than for one
which does so to defend its livelihood.
One reason why such rules appear to be less restrictive in German and
Japanese firms is that employment relations function at a higher level of trust
between workers and their employers, at least for their core workforces. With
a high degree of employment security, provided in the German case by widely
recognised skills and fairly long job tenures, and in the Japanese one by the
implicit understanding of company-based employment and basic income
security, many of the defensive measures discussed earlier become
unnecessary. Added to that, the methods of workforce representation, based
on works councils in Germany and strong enterprise unions in most large
Japanese firms, remove the need for workers to organise their own job level
defensive practices. In both countries also 'rate for the job' rules play a smaller
role, job rotation playing an important part in training, and in Japan, the link
between seniority and pay and the bonus system outweigh the influence of
current job on pay (Nohara 1992).
-35-
'Cooperative exchange'
Most of the strategies for cooperation which deal with the parties concerned
in isolation prove to be unstable, including those based on 'reputation' and the
use of 'tit-for-tat' strategies. Cooperative behaviour early on could, for
example, be designed to trick the other party. In 'tit-for-tat' strategies, in which
one party keeps withdrawal of cooperation in reserve in order to punish the
other party should it not cooperate, the final round of the game is always
problematic. As a result, cooperation in every round is problematic. 20
-36-
The main lesson of the 'prisoner's dilemma' model is that it is each party's
expectations as to the other's behaviour which are critical. Even if one wishes
to cooperate, but one is worse off if cooperation is not reciprocated and one
suspects that the other will not, then it is tempting to refuse cooperation.
Given the dependence of cooperation on expectations, then each party
fulfilling its commitments becomes very important. Not to do so could be a
signal that one's intentions have changed, and that in the future cooperation
will not be forthcoming. In practice, worker representatives and employers
know that economic life is full of uncertainty, and that not all commitments,
however well intended, can be met. The problem lies in distinguishing
genuine cases of force majeure in which good faith has been kept from those
in which faith has been broken. The latter would signal changed behaviour
and therefore alter the expectations of the other party.
Such would seem to be one of the important functions of the large amounts
of information exchanged between German and Japanese employers and their
respective worker representatives both at the industry and at enterprise levels.
It would also be one of the reasons why German and Japanese unions have
not had to rely upon the forms of 'job control' unionism found commonly in
the US and the UK, and why field research has found so little evidence of the
workshop level restrictive labour practices discussed earlier in this paper.
These observations show that the frameworks for cooperative exchange and
collective voice are necessary but not sufficient conditions for cooperative
relations. The contrast with the German case is revealing. There, pressures for
greater powers for shop stewards, and for direct union-enterprise bargaining
were strongly resisted by employers who maintained and encouraged the
existing system of works councils. This suggests that employers have a key
role in the development of cooperative relations. Although they may be
supported by an institutional framework which protects against non-
cooperative action, the parties have to build their cooperative practice
themselves. Employers and worker representatives demonstrate to each other
their commitment to cooperation by the amount they are prepared to invest
in it, and this encourages further cooperation. In the German case, during the
1970s, management refused to negotiate with shop stewards, which would
have undermined their relationship with the works councils, and the unions
and works councils generally kept stewards in a subordinate role.
In contrast, in Britain, Italy and Sweden, many of the additional powers came
from legislative intervention or were gained against employer opposition. It
was therefore difficult for employers to present their action within the new
institutions as the first step in a process of cooperation and so begin to win the
trust of workers and their representatives. As a result, many of the new
powers were used as a platform for additional gains at the expense of
employers rather than as the beginning of a new era of cooperation, as many
of the architects of the reforms had hoped.
levels of youth pay relative to adults. Yet, in some countries, unions and
employers are able to agree low youth rates of relative pay whereas in others
they are not. Contrasting six European Union countries, Garonna and Ryan
(1990) identify two distinct modes of youth employment: exclusion, and
regulated inclusion. Given the persistently high levels of young people's
unemployment in Europe, the reasons for this merit analysis.
Marsden and Ryan (1986 and 1990) argue that the problem lies in the
acceptability or otherwise of special low rates of youth, and particularly
trainee, pay relative to adult skilled workers. Young and adult workers always
have potentially opposed interests because the latter, if engaged on low rates
of pay, become potential substitutes. Ideally, their lower productivity and need
for training and experience should be compensated by correspondingly lower
rates of pay. However, there is always a potential problem that employers will
take advantage of the lower pay, but fail to deliver on the training so that
young workers become a source of cheap, substitute, labour. 22 Apprenticeship
regulations provide one means by which the status of young trainees can be
clearly identified, and the monitoring of training received becomes easier for
adult workers and their representatives. Under such circumstances, skilled
adult workers are more likely to agree to special apprentice pay rates, and
other kinds of wage for age system.
Both this and the previous example suggest that the impact of collective
bargaining institutions upon employment depends less upon their existence
or otherwise, but on what kinds of policy they pursue. Adversarial relations
may be compatible with good overall economic performance under
decentralised bargaining, and with relatively simple production processes
which are less subject to the dysfunctions of tight management control.
There are two main areas in which workplace cooperation may require
substantive rules: a degree of employment security may be necessary to ensure
cooperation in job flexibility; and the various institutions of workplace
-39-
cooperation, and cooperative working itself, may call for smaller occupational
pay differentials than would be the case under competitive markets.
Where firms use specialist coordinators, there are strong arguments for
concentrating rewards on those in these key positions (eg. Alchian and
Demsetz 1972). Substandard performance in these roles is likely to damage the
whole organisation. In contrast, in an organisation with more widely diffused
responsibility, such roles are less critical, and so require less rewards.
Policies to reduce wage inequalities have been common when unions have
been closely involved in general fights against some national emergency, such
as the control of inflation, and when they have sought to develop
'encompassing' structures which embrace a large percentage of their potential
membership. 23 Examples of such policies can be found in those of the British
and Italian unions supporting their countries' incomes policies of the latter half
of the 1970s, and in the long term policies of the unions in Germany, Sweden,
and a number of the other countries with 'neo-corporatist' bargaining systems.
The problem therefore is how to ensure that the coalition holds together. The
only bonds would seem to be either long-term self-interest, which may seem
very abstract when compared with the immediate and concrete gains from
breaking away, or some moral goal. Hence the importance for encompassing
unions to have wider goals such as solidarity, greater equality, or social
justice. These provide a moral justification for the self-restraint by stronger
-41-
groups. It is notable that both the British and Italian unions justified their
wage equalisation policies in the fight against inflation by the idea that those
on higher pay had to help the lower paid who suffered disproportionately
from price rises. It is also notable that the Swedish unions promoted greater
wage equality as one of the goals of central bargaining (Hibbs 1990) and that
the German unions, although not stressing equality to the same extent, have
long stressed the importance of skill and its associated rewards, as something
which can be achieved by all workers, rather than individual performance.
The processes discussed so far have already generated some response from
firms, employers' and workers' organisations, and these may provide clues as
to policies whose extension might be encouraged in other firms, industries, or
countries.
The hardship agreements are concluded between individual firms and their
works councils, and have so far involved such concessions as delayed
implementation of the industry pay agreement and possible payment of lump
sum compensation to the employees at the end of the period. By December
1993, fifteen such agreements had been reported in the metal industry in
Saxony (EIRR 12.1994).
It remains to be seen whether the new opt out clauses will be effective, either
in giving enough flexibility to enable some firms to survive or in halting the
erosion of membership of the employers' organisations and of that of the
coverage of industry agreements.
-43-
Industry bargaining in Italy has undergone two major reforms during the past
ten years: the first reducing the coverage of the indexation provisions of the
Scala Mobile in 1983 and 1984, and the second, involving the final abolition of
indexation and the agreement, in July 1993, to establish a new system of
articulated bargaining.
The impact of the first change has been to increase the scope for adjusting pay
at the enterprise level, and to enable employers to reverse the compression of
pay differentials that occurred as a result of flat-rate indexation. The wage
gap, discussed earlier, increased as a result of these reforms, and occupational
wage differentials were markedly increased (Ministero del Lavoro 1987, ch 4).
The agreement reached in July 1993 sought a new constitution for collective
bargaining with national level discussions on incomes policy, sectoral
agreements setting pay for two years and other issues for four, supported by
a system of enterprise or territorial agreements of four year duration. The aim
of the sectoral agreement is to set pay within a forum which enables
coordination with macroeconomic performance, while leaving room at the
enterprise level for pay to reflect changes in productivity, quality, and other
elements of company performance. The system should be articulated in the
sense that the higher levels set a framework for negotiation at the lower levels.
In particular, company level negotiations should be bound by what has been
agreed at the sectoral level. At the enterprise level, a form of works council
should be established with two thirds of its members directly elected by
employees, and one third by union members (Protocollo, 1993, EIRR 236, 9.93).
Enterprise level representation was agreed in December 1993 (EIRR 241, 2,
1994) and the first sectoral agreement, in the chemical concluded in the
chemical industry, was concluded in March 1994. Shortly after its formation,
the first government of the new, reformed, electoral system reaffirmed its
support for the new industrial relations in system.
The new system has been developed from an analysis of the ills of the former
system. Apart from reducing wage differentials, the former indexation system
had also greatly limited the scope for collective bargaining at both sectoral and
company level. New initiatives at the sectoral level and change at company
level could only be 'funded' by adding to the inflation payments. By
substituting national level discussions for indexation, it becomes possible for
industry-level negotiators to make allowances for likely pay supplements
negotiated at enterprise level, and so keep the overall total increase in line
with macroeconomic objectives. Reforming work place representation with a
mixture of individual and union-based representation is intended to overcome
the declining support for the previous workplace system, and thus to increase
the effectiveness of workplace employee negotiators.
-44-
Green and Macdonald (1991) cite survey evidence from the 1991 AWIRS27
supporting the view that the award system had removed responsibility for
confronting certain issues from workplace level unions and management.
Particularly in large workplaces, many managers reported employee related
factors as barriers to change, and among those cited, the most important were
unions, lack of resources, and government regulations.
Thus, the shift towards enterprise bargaining fostered by the 1991 National
Wage Case represents an attempt to give enterprise level bargainers greater
scope over pay in order to agree new working practices and new
-46-
One of the effects of union and government action on pay that is likely to
reduce employment reviewed earlier was the reduction of wage differentials,
particularly as concerned lower paid and less skilled workers. During the
1970s, in many OECD countries, wage differentials were compressed, often
under the influence of such policies. This movement could be seen in most
dimensions of wage structures: dispersions, as well as differentials in earnings
by skill, industry, and by gender (Table 3).
Italy: reassertion of the 'right to manage' in large enterprises from the late
1970s (Becchi and Negrelli, 1986); government led negotiation of partial
de-indexation in 1983/84 (dell'Aringa and Lucifora 1990), and its
abolition in 1992;
Sweden: the breakdown of central pay negotiations from 1983 when the
-47-
Survey evidence from France, Italy and the UK, indicates that its use is now
quite widespread, but that it accounts for a greater share of total earnings
among managerial than among other staff. For other staff, its use has
increased, especially among white collar staff, but the percentage of total pay
resulting from it has remained limited.
Similar movements have been under way in Britain and Italy with
increased use of discretionary bonuses and merit pay systems (Della Rocca
1989, Negrelli (1991).
How far the spread of merit pay has contributed to greater pay responsiveness
to markets is not clear. It may simply give management more autonomy over
pay for the purposes of local enterprise management. It may establish a closer
link between individual pay and individual performance, but there are
considerable difficulties for management to measure the performance of
individual employees accurately (see §2.2 above). It may also enable
management to allocate more pay to highly skilled or able employees who
might otherwise leave. One indicator of change is the growth of earnings
dispersions within occupations which might signal the decline of rate-for-the-
job systems. Data available for France, Sweden and the UK show an increase
in intra-occupational dispersions during the 1980s. In France, the movement
began from the mid-1980s (CERC, 1989: 38). In Sweden the movement began
in the early 1980s, and in the UK, from the late 1970s (Marsden 1989).
A number of case studies in the United States reveal a significant role for such
-49-
This dichotomy has been refined for intellectual debate, but in practice, in
several countries there is evidence that unions, workplace representatives, and
local management have been able to reach working compromises. The reason
is probably the same as that behind the flexibility concessions agreed in Britain
and the United States: neither workers nor management have many illusions
about the survival of non-competitive firms. In practice, lean production has
been widely adopted in Japanese firms that were unionised, and from there
spread to North American and European producers. In Italy, the survey
reported by Negrelli (1991) showed individual negotiation over aspects of
labour deployment and flexibility developing within a framework of collective
rules for employee representation and adjustment of the production process.
In another survey, or northern Italian firms, Regalia and Ronchi (1989) found
that practices such as quality circles and management-employee
communication programmes were positively correlated with local union
presence, although there had been some conflict over introduction of quality
circles. They also reported that they had been widely used for purposes of
work reorganisation and increased flexibility. In Germany, in the automobile
industry, lean production, team working, and new skill concepts have been
dealt with by enterprise management and the works councils, and the metal
workers' union, IG Metall, has been active in promoting its own concepts of
-50-
team working. The main conflict has not been so much over the use of new
working methods as over the powers of works councils to oversee such
processes as staff appraisal, and whether the emphasis of merit pay should be
upon skill, which can be externally measured, or management assessment of
an employee's performance (Huber and Lang, 1993).
Such examples can be multiplied (see for example reports on individual firms
in EIRR), but they show only that in many firms, management and employee
representatives have been able to introduce new concepts of employee
management and work organisation by adapting rather than abolishing pre-
existing forms of employee representation. There is no necessary contradiction
between them, although it would not have been possible to introduce these
changes in the face of militant or ideological worker opposition.
At the microeconomic level, the main analytical conclusions to this paper may
be summarised by looking at the effects of collective employee representation
on three broad groups of workers. For the less skilled, lower paid groups,
raising their rates of pay by collective action, in the absence of suitable
training policies, is likely to cause greater unemployment. For the highly
skilled and educated, reducing pay differentials may reduce incentives to
train, and, perhaps more important, to take the risks associated with exercising
initiative and responsibility. For the middle groups, those with blue and white
collar technical and intermediate professional skills the outcome is less clear.
For such workers, both employer and employee often have considerable sunk
costs in the employment relationship: detailed knowledge of the employer's
business, skills learned on the job, and so on, such that both parties incur
considerable costs if the relationship ends. For this group, motivation, and the
quality of the exchange between employer and employee is the vital ingredient
to good economic performance.
may militate against both wage flexibility and high managerial incentives.
Flexible working and information sharing needed for high productivity and
quality among the intermediate group requires an environment of cooperative
exchange.
Cooperative working may require greater equality of rewards than the right
to manage, more market-oriented, model. First, it has been argued (§3.4 above)
that cooperation needs a stable framework, and that when this is provided by
the parties involved, it relies upon coalitions of interests within encompassing
groups. Because the existence of such groups usually entails a loss of
individual bargaining power by the strongest groups, some wider moral or
ideological purpose is needed to motivate them. In the post-war years, this has
mostly been provided by solidarity and egalitarian sentiments. Secondly,
cooperative working in the workplace, where people work flexibly within
teams implies a less sharp division between tasks of coordination and
organisation and those of execution. Where there is a strong polarisation it
makes sense to concentrate rewards on those in the coordinating role because
their performance is critical. Without such polarisation, cooperation depends
more on sharing information and responsibility so the need for exceptional
rewards is weaker. Indeed, it might even harm cooperation.
potency of the competition between rival groups excluded from the peak level
negotiations in Sweden between LO and SAF, and their unwillingness to be
bound by agreements which represented the needs of the industrial sector
illustrate the problems arising in the first case (Kjellberg 1992). The pressures
for bargaining decentralisation highlighted by Katz (1993) and Windolf (1989)
arising from the need for enterprise level flexibility underline this.
Industry bargaining generally sets minimum rates of pay for whole industries
in a particular region, and usually play an important role in determining
annual pay increases. Although the industry bargaining systems discussed in
this paper leave considerable room for adjustment at the enterprise level, there
being a wide and varying range of wage gaps, this does not always meet the
needs of firms that enter into severe employment crises. This is particularly
a problem for small and medium-sized firms which, although efficiently run,
may still face extreme difficulties as a result of the loss of a major order, or an
exchange rate shift suddenly wiping out a once profitable market. In such
cases, industry minima may be too restrictive, and there is a strong case for
the development of 'hardship clauses' to enable the firm to weather the storm.
Although it is still early to evaluate the outcome of the German experience,
first reports suggest that the guarantees built into the 'hardship clauses' have
given flexibility while maintaining the overall integrity of industry agreements
which provide a critical element in overall bargaining coordination there.
The other major role that can be played by industry agreements is to provide
a framework for negotiations at enterprise and plant level to enable existing
work rules to be adapted to the new patterns of management and production
organisation. The importance of trust was stressed earlier for there to be
cooperative exchange in the workplace. The introduction of organisational
change can be extremely important to enable firms to respond to the increased
competition flowing from the removal of tariff and other trade barriers. Yet
a workforce on the defensive could prove a serious obstacle to the efficient
working of such practices. If management's goal in reorganising is to innovate
and raise efficiency, and not to destroy existing forms of employee
representation, then it will be important to be able to signal these intentions.
An agreed framework at the industry level, and agreed means of supporting
existing representation could provide a strong signal of commitment to
working within agreed procedures.
This does not have to be tied to pay flexibility, but there are a number of areas
in which some of the recent developments in pay could help promote
cooperation. It was argued earlier that at least one of the reasons for the
widespread acceptance of 'rate for job' pay rules was that in an environment
of mutual suspicion, the application of such rules could be easily monitored.
Similar factors have laid behind the difficulty of using both merit pay and
profit sharing. In a study of the UK tax office merit pay scheme, Marsden and
Richardson (1994) found that one of the most important factors which turned
general support among the employees for the principle of relating pay to
performance was distrust of the way management was applying it. In the case
of profit related pay, the French government found that the only criterion that
was acceptable to the unions was that of declared profits because only this
could be effectively monitored (Camerlynck and Lyon-Caen 1982).
Many production systems have evolved beyond the point at which workers
produced a highly standard output with little scope for quality. This change
has undermined many of the traditional individual output-based incentives,
a point recognised in the debates on payment systems in all the major EU
countries (eg. Schudlich 1991, Della Rocca 1990). Equally, relating pay to
average experience, as is done by length of service payments is unpopular in
many administrative-type jobs because of the automaticity of the pay whatever
the quality of effort. 29 Indeed, both kinds of system are forms of rate for the
job: output based incentives being based often on a form of piece price; and
length of service increments corresponding to steps towards the rate for the
experienced worker at the top of the scale.
cause of its failure lay in its perceived unfairness (Marsden and Richardson
1994), and notably in the suspicion that management had placed a ceiling on
good evaluations for cost reasons irrespective of how good individual
performance was.
This points to an important feature of 'merit pay' systems, that they are part
of a wider wage-effort bargain, and so cannot easily be insulated from pay
bargaining. In addition, markets reward individual merit only in so far as it
meets customer demands ( a question of outputs) whereas individual workers
tend to judge their work from the quality of the inputs. The difficulty of
measuring performance to the satisfaction of all parties, and the problem of
establishing the amounts of money to be used for merit awards indicate the
need for joint regulation.
Profit sharing schemes also break away from rate for the job rules, and
introduce a modest element of variability into pay in response to the firm's
performance. Recent work reviewed by Blinder (1990) and by FitzRoy (1992)
indicates that it can indeed improve performance. A frequent theoretical
objection is that the impact of any one individual's effort on profits is too
small to be noticed, and that there will be tendency towards free riding as
those who put in minimum effort will get the same as those who work much
harder. This would indeed be a problem if the employment relation were
short-term, but because it is still usually long-term (with median job durations
of ten or more years), there is ample scope for peer group pressure to limit
'free riding'. Thus, profit sharing can turn to advantage the very continuity of
employment relations that makes norms of fairness so powerful.
However, 'rate for the job' rules are a product of low trust relations between
employers and employees. They have been a powerful principle in collective
bargaining because they are easy for workers and their representatives to
monitor. Merit pay, profit sharing, and productivity change depend upon a
much greater amount of trustworthy information being available from the
employer. For that reason, the information needs to be subject to joint control.
Two final policy areas include training and increasing product market
competition. Training emerges in two important contexts: the problems of the
unskilled unemployed, and that of labour market bottlenecks. Policies to foster
cooperation among the middle section of the workforce, it was suggested, tend
to favour smaller occupational wage differentials and greater equality of
rewards, but these are harmful for the jobs of the unskilled. Providing greater
opportunities for improving one's own skill levels, and for replacing obsolete
skills could ease the policy dilemma in this area.
market policies.
-58-
End notes.
. For an extremely clear statement of this argument see the survey of Japan
1
and industry.
. These results are broadly consistent with those for the US reported by
5
Freeman and Medoff 1984, and Lewis 1986, and for the UK by Gregory and
Thompson (1981), Blanchflower and Oswald (1988), and Metcalf (1990).
6
In a post entry closed shop workers are expected to join the union after the
.
employer has hired them. In the pre-entry closed shop, workers have to be
members of the appropriate union before they can be hired. The pre-entry
kind was made illegal in 1990.
7
The coefficient on membership density was 0.07, and on the presence of an
.
service bonuses.
18
1964 saw the first 'low wage pot': a common flat rate increase for every
.
worker; wage drift amounts; cost of living adjustments, flat rate; and low
wage adjustment amounts (Hibbs 1990 p.62 ff.).
. At a more general level, this argument finds some support also in game
19
theory. Maynard-Smith (1982) shows that the expectation that one will escalate
any conflict that threatens one's own territory (because that it something one
cannot afford to lose) produces a stable pattern of behaviour whereas the
conventional choice between aggressive ('hawk') and non-aggressive ('dove')
strategies does not.
20
This is the 'reverse induction' argument. The 'tit-for-tat' strategy implies one
.
should start by cooperating in the first round, and only refuse cooperation in
the round following one in which the other party failed to cooperate. Thus not
cooperating is used as a retrospective punishment. However, this sanction
-60-
does not work for cooperation in the last round of a finite game, so both
parties fear the other will not cooperate. Since mutual non-cooperation means
that both parties lose the gains from cooperation, the threat of punishment for
non-cooperation also loses its effect. Therefore cooperation is also problematic
in the penultimate round, and so on, back to the first round (Dasgupta 1988).
21
The failure of the Donovan reforms to produce the gains in productivity and
.
. In 1991, the metal industry employers and union had agreed a staged
24
by the agreement until its expiry. Only after then would they cease to be
bound by it.
27
. Australian Workplace Industrial Relations Survey.
28
Bilan de la négociation collective en 1988, Ministère des Affaires Sociales et
.
de l'Emploi, Paris.
-61-
29
.The Efficiency Unit (Next Steps) reported that 70% of civil servants
approved of the idea of rewarding good performance with better pay, and a
recent survey of Inland Revenue staff found that 57% thought that
performance pay was good in principle (Marsden and Richardson 1991).
References.
Addison J.T, and Barnett A.H. (1982) The impact of unions on productivity.
British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol XX, No. 2, July 1982, pp.145-162.
Akerlof G, and Yellen J. (eds.) (1986) Efficiency wage models of the labor
market. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Bazen S, and Martin J. (1991) The impact of the minimum wage on earnings
and employment in France. OECD Economic Studies, No. 16, Spring, pp. 199-
221.
Belman D. (1992) Unions, the quality of labor relations, and firm performance.
In Mishel L, and Voos P. eds. pp. 41-107.
62
Blanchflower D, and Freeman R. (1992) Unionism in the US and other
advanced OECD countries, in Bognanno M, and Kleiner M. Labor market
institutions and the future role of unions. Blackwell, Cambridge Mass.
Bosch G, and Sengenberger W. (1989) Employment policy, the state and the
unions in the Federal Republic of Germany, in Rosenberg ed. The state and
the labor market, Plenum, New York.
63
Carniti P. (1988) I salari in Italia negli anni ottanta: Rapporto dell
Commissione Carniti. Marsilio Editori, Venezia.
CERC (1989) Les Français et leurs revenus au tournant des années 1980,
Documents du CERC no. 94, 3rd quarter, Documentation Française, Paris.
Coase R. H. (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica, November, pp. 386-405.
64
Angeli, Milano
Ferner A, and Hyman R. eds. (1992) Industrial relations in the new Europe.
Blackwell, Oxford.
Fox A. (1974) Beyond contract: work, power and trust relations. Faber,
London.
Freeman R.B, and Medoff J.L. (1984) What do unions do? Basic Books, New
York.
65
Unions and economic crisis: Britain, West Germany, and Sweden. George
Allen and Unwin, London.
Hamermesh D. (1986) The demand for labour in the long run. In Ashenfleter
O, and Layard P. R. G. eds. Handbook of labour economics. North Holland.
66
Katz H, Kochan T, Gobeille K.R. (1983) Industrial relations performance,
economic performance, and QWL programs: an interplant analysis. Industrial
and Labor Relations Review, Vol 37, No. 1, Oct. 1983, pp.. 3-17
Kjellberg A. (1992) Sweden: can the model survive? In Ferner A, and Hyman
R. eds. pp. 88-142.
Koike K, and Inoki T. eds. (1990) Skill formation in Japan and Southeast Asia.
University of Tokyo Press, Tokyo.
67
change. Open University Press, Milton Keynes.
Maguire M. ed. (1993) Pay flexibility in the public sector. OECD, Paris.
Marsden D. W. ed. (1992) Pay and employment in the new Europe. Edward
Elgar, Cheltenham.
Metcalf D. (1989) Water notes dry up: the impact of the Donovan reform
proposals and Thatcherism at work on labour productivity in British
manufacturing industry. British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 27 no. 1,
68
March, pp 1-32.
Metcalf D, and Stewart M. (1991) Closed shops and relative pay: institutional
arrangements or high density? Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,
52:2, pp. 503-516.
Ministero del Lavoro (1987) Rapporto '87. Ministero del Lavoro e della
Previdenza Sociale, Roma.
69
Torino.
Niland J. ed. (1986) Wage fixation in Australia. Allen and Unwin, Sydney.
Olson M. (1971) The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of
groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge Mass.
Pollert A. (1988) The 'flexible firm': fixation or fact? Work, Employment and
Society, vol.2, no. 3, pp. 281-316, September.
70
Sainsaulieu R. (1965) Pouvoir et stratégie des groupes ouvriers dans l'atelier,
Sociologie du Travail, 65, pp.162-171.
Schager N-H. (1993) An overview and evalation of flexible pay policies in the
Swedish public sector. In Maguire ed.
Silvestre J.J. ed. (1992) Les systèmes de rémunération dans le secteur public:
une comparaison France, Grande-Bretagne, Italie. ILO, Geneva.
Stewart M. (1990) Union wage differentials, product market influences and the
division of rents. Economic Journal, 100: 403, December, pp. 1122-1137.
Stiglitz (1984) Theories of wage rigidity, paper presented to the Centre for
Labour Economics, London School of Economics, April.
71