The CDS-Bond Basis: Jennie Bai Pierre Collin-Dufresne

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 43

The CDS-Bond Basis

Jennie Bai Pierre Collin-Dufresne


September 2018

We investigate the cross-sectional variation in the CDS-bond basis, which measures the
difference between credit default swap (CDS) spread and cash-bond implied credit spread. We
test several explanations for the violation of the arbitrage relation between cash bond and CDS
contract, which states that the basis should be zero in normal conditions. The evidence is
consistent with ‘limits to arbitrage’ theories in that deviations are larger for bonds with higher
frictions as measured by trading liquidity, funding cost, counterparty risk, and collateral quality.
Surprisingly however, we find that the basis is more negative when the bond lending fee is
higher, suggesting that arbitrageurs are unwilling to engage in a negative basis trade when
short interest on the bond is high.

JEL Classification: G12.

Keywords: limit of arbitrage; basis, credit default swap, counterparty risk, liquidity

We thank the editor (Bing Han), one anonymous referee, and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, the European Finance Association 2011, the American Finance Association Annual Conference
2013, Rutgers University, Baruch College, the 6th MTS conference on Financial markets at London School of
Economics, Cheung-Kong Graduate School of Business as well as Francis Longstaff (AFA discussant),
Christopher Polk (EFA discussant), Kent Daniel, Robert Goldstein, John Kiff, Long Chen, Liuren Wu for useful
comments. Bai is from Department of Finance, McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University, 3700 O
Street, Washington, DC 20057, USA, e-mail: [email protected]. Collin-Dufresne is from Department of
Finance, cole Polytechnique Federale de Lausanne, Quartier UNIL-Dorigny, Extranef 209 CH-1015 Lausanne,
Switzerland, e-mail: [email protected].

1. Introduction
Financial markets experienced tremendous disruptions during the 2007-2009 financial crisis.
Credit spreads across all asset classes and rating categories widened to unprecedented levels.1

1
For example, investment-grade corporate credit spreads as measured by the CDX.IG index rose from 50 basis
points (bps) in early 2007 to more than 250 bps at the end of 2008. Even at the safest end of the spectrum the
widening was dramatic. AAA-rated synthetic debt products, that would have been deemed virtually risk-free
before the crisis, saw their spreads widen dramatically: CDX.IG super senior tranche widened from 5 bps to
100 bps, CMBX AAA “super duper" widened from 2 bps to 700 bps, ABS-HEL AAA tranche price rose from 0 to

This article has been accepted for publication and undergone full peer review but has not been through
the copyediting, typesetting, pagination and proofreading process, which may lead to differences
between this version and the Version of Record. Please cite this article as doi: 10.1111/fima.12252.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Perhaps even more surprising, many relations that were considered to be text-book arbitrage before
the crisis were severely violated. For example, in currency markets, violations of covered interest
rate parity occurred for currency pairs involving the US dollar (Coffey, Hrung, and Sarkar, 2009). In
interest rate markets, the swap spread that measures the difference between Treasury bond yields
and Libor swap rates turned negative. In interbank markets, basis swaps that exchange different
tenor Libor rates (e.g., 3-month for 6-month) deviated from zero. In inflation markets, break-even
inflation rates turned negative implying an arbitrage with inflation swaps (Fleckenstein, Longstaff,
and Lustig, 2014). In credit markets, the CDS-bond basis that measures the difference between
credit default swap (CDS) spreads and cash-bond implied credit spreads turned negative.

These anomalies suggest that such relations are not, in fact, arbitrage opportunities in the
traditional textbook sense. Indeed, the arbitrage profits may be difficult to realize in practice. Many
of these relations involve a fully funded (e.g., cash) instrument and one or more unfunded derivative
positions. Thus, counterparty risk of the derivative issuer may have rendered the ‘arbitrage’ risky.
Furthermore, funding cost differentials between the cash instrument and derivative positions may
have made the arbitrage costly to implement for an investor requiring funding. In the latter case, the
arbitrage violations persist because of ‘limits to arbitrage’ such as the inability of arbitrageurs to
raise capital quickly and/or their unwillingness to take large positions in these ‘arbitrage’ trades
because of mark-to-market risk. These apparent arbitrage violations thus provide an interesting
opportunity to test several of the ‘limits to arbitrage’ theories (as surveyed, for example, by Gromb
and Vayanos, 2010).

In this paper, we focus on the CDS-bond basis, which measures the difference between the CDS
spread of a specific company and the credit spread paid on a bond of the same company. Figure 1
plots the time series of the CDS-bond basis for investment-grade (IG) and high yield (HY) bonds. The
plots show that the average basis for IG firms, which hovers usually around 17 basis points (bps)
before the crisis, fell to 243 bps, and the average basis for HY firms dropped from 12 bps to 560
bps. Also, the bases for both IG and HY firms remain negative even after the financial crisis. At first
sight, a large negative basis smacks of arbitrage since it suggests that an investor can purchase the
bond, fund it at Libor, and insure the default risk on the bond by buying protection via the CDS
contract. The resulting trade is ‘virtually’ risk-free and yet, as the plots show, it generates between
243 bps and 560 bps in arbitrage return per annum.

20% upfront plus 500 bps running. These numbers illustrate that it became much more expensive to insure
AAA-rated debt across various markets (corporate, residential and commercial real estate).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Studying the CDS-bond basis during the crisis is interesting for several reasons. First, early
studies of this basis found that the arbitrage relation between CDS and cash-bond spreads holds
fairly well during the pre-crisis period (Hull, Predescu, and White, 2004, Blanco, Brennan, and Marsh,
2005, Longstaff, Mithal, and Neis, 2005). In fact, if anything, these studies typically conclude that the
basis should be slightly positive. Indeed, the arbitrage is, in general, not perfect (Duffie, 1999), and
there are a few technical reasons (such as the difficulty in short-selling bonds and the
cheapest-to-deliver option) that tend to push the basis into the positive domain (Blanco, Brennan,
and Marsh, 2005). However, during the crisis the bases were tremendously negative, which suggests
the need for alternative explanations.

Second, there is a large cross-sectional variation in the observed bases across individual firms.
This cross-sectional variation makes the basis arbitrage an interesting laboratory to test various
‘limits to arbitrage’ theories. It is the focus of our paper.

There are several reasons why one might expect the basis to become negative during the
financial crisis of 2007 2009. Anecdotes for the negative basis claim that several major financial
institutions, pressed to free up their balance sheet and to improve their cash balance, reduced their
leverage by selling off bonds. The argument is that deleveraging exerted downward pressure on
bond prices and thus upward pressure on credit spreads relative to CDS spreads that represent the
‘fair’ value of the default risk insurance. This however cannot be the whole story since in a perfect
frictionless market, investors would simply borrow cash to buy the bonds, buy protection and
finance the position until maturity or default. For deleveraging to have a persistent impact on the
basis, there must be some ‘limits to arbitrage’ (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997). In particular, if risk capital
is limited then the mark-to-market basis trade becomes risky and investors will tend to buy the
bonds-basis packages that are (ex-ante) most attractive from a risk-return tradeoff.

In this paper we analyze the risk-return tradeoff in a basis trade for an investor with limited
capital. We find that the investor is exposed to (i) increased collateral values of the underlying
bonds, (ii) increased illiquidity of bond trading, (iii) counterparty risk in buying CDS contracts, and (iv)
increased funding constraint faced by investors who want to explore the arbitrage. For a given level
of the basis, we expect investors with limited arbitrage capital to prefer those trades with better
collateral, higher trading liquidity, less counterparty risk, and lower exposures to funding costs. Put
differently, if arbitrageurs have limited capital, then in equilibrium we expect to see a larger basis
(which can be thought of as an expected return) for firms with worse collateral quality, lower trading
liquidity, more counterparty risk, and higher funding liquidity risk. To disentangle which explanation
is most relevant in explaining the deviations in the CDS-bond basis, we construct measures of

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


collateral quality, bond liquidity risk, counterparty risk, and funding liquidity risk for each firm, and
explore whether they can explain the cross-section of the bases first for the individual bond bases
and second for a set of 24 portfolios sorted on rating and size.

We find that all our ‘limits to arbitrage’ measures matter and together they ‘explain’ about 80%
of the cross-sectional variation in the bases of 24 size and rating sorted portfolios and about 40% of
the cross-sectional variation of individual firm bases. During the crisis, where the basis became
significantly negative, all measures of collateral quality, bond illiquidity, counterparty risk and
funding liquidity risk are statistically significantly correlated with the basis and with the expected
sign, suggesting that the basis was more negative for a bond more costly to engage in the arbitrage
trade. We find one exception, namely that the bond lending fee is associated negatively with the
negative bond basis. This is surprising since a high lending fee is typically associated with high
collateral value and thus should make the arbitrage trade easier to implement (since the negative
basis arbitrage involves buying the bond, the lending fee could be earned by the arbitrageur). In
contrast, and as expected, bond lending fee is associated positively with the basis when the bond
basis is positive (a high lending fee indicates the bond is costly to short rendering the positive basis
arbitrage trade more costly). We speculate that arbitrageurs refrain from engaging in a negative
basis trade with a high-fee bond, because the high lending fee proxies the high short interest on the
bond (Bai, 2018; Reed, 2013) and the high demand in the short-selling arbitrage signals that bond
prices may further drop and thus the basis might further widen. So arbitrageurs might be avoiding
the ‘catching-a-falling-knife’ trade. In fact, we find that for firms with a negative basis, the basis
tends to be more negative if the underlying bond has worse rating, higher CDS, and smaller size. All
of these characteristics typically correlate negatively with collateral quality. So for firms with a
negative basis, the lending fee seems to capture different information than collateral quality.

In sum, our cross-sectional results strongly support the hypothesis that limits to arbitrage
prevented arbitrageurs from closing the basis gap.

The negative basis has attracted considerable attention in the practitioner literature2. These
papers emphasize the role of financing risk in generating the negative basis, as well as deleveraging
in generating downward price pressure on cash-bonds. In the academic literature, (Garleanu and
Pedersen, 2011) provide a theoretical model, where leverage constraints can generate a pricing
difference between two otherwise identical financial securities that differ in terms of their margin

2
For example, D.E. Shaw Group JP Morgan “The bond-CDS basis handbook" (2009), Mitchell and Pulvino,
2012.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


requirements or haircuts. Specifically, their theory predicts that the difference between two bases
should be related to the difference in margin requirements (i.e., haircuts) times the difference
between the collateralized and uncollateralized borrowing rate. Our study differs from previous
papers in that we focus on the cross-sectional variation in individual firm bases (rather than on the
average basis level) and try to relate it to firm, bond and CDS characteristics. Two contemporaneous
papers have also investigated the CDS-bond basis. (Fontana, 2011) studies the time-series variation
in the average basis using cointegration techniques. (Kim, Li, and Zhang, 2016, 2017) examine a
long-short basis risk factor and study their implications on corporate bond returns.

The paper proceeds as follows. The next section discusses practical issues regarding an actual
basis trade and isolate the various sources of risk in such a trade. Section 3 introduces the data. In
Section 4 and 5 we construct limits-to-arbitrage measures and examine their impact in explaining
the cross-sectional variation of the bases. Section 6 concludes.

2. The CDS-Bond Basis


A credit default swap is essentially an insurance contract against a credit event of a specific
reference entity. It is an over-the-counter transaction between two parties in which the protection
buyer makes periodic coupon payments to the protection seller until maturity or until some credit
event happens. When a credit event occurs,3 typically the protection buyer delivers a bond from an
eligible pool to the protection seller in exchange for its par value.4

The contract is designed so that the owner of a particular bond can hedge her credit risk
exposure to the issuer of that bond by buying CDS protection on that counterparty. As a result we
would expect CDS spreads to be similar to credit spreads observed on corporate bonds that are
deliverable into the CDS contract. In fact, under some conditions, an exact arbitrage relation exists
which implies that the CDS spread should equal the credit spread on the deliverable corporate

3
In the 2003 definition, the International Swap and Derivative Association (ISDA) lists six items as credit
events: (1) bankruptcy, (2) failure to pay, (3) repudiation/moratorium, (4) obligation acceleration, (5)
obligation default, and (6) restructuring. For more detail, see “2003 ISDA Credit Derivatives Definitions,"
released on 11 February 2003.
4
See Duffie and Singleton (2003) for a detailed description.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


bond.5 This leads to the theoretical definition of the CDS-bond basis as the CDS spread minus the
corporate bond credit spread.

While the CDS spread is observable in the market, it is not obvious how to compute the
appropriate corporate bond spread. As discussed by Duffie (1999) the ideal corporate bond spread
would be the spread over Libor of a floating rate note with the same maturity as the CDS referenced
on the same firm. In practice, this spread is often not observable as firms rarely issue floating rate
notes. Instead, we have to rely on other available fixed rate corporate bond prices. Several
methodologies have been proposed in the literature. Following Elizalde, Doctor, and Saltuk (2009),
we adopt the par equivalent CDS (PECDS) methodology. This method, which we present for
completeness in Appendix A, essentially amounts to extracting the default intensity consistent with
the prices of the corporate bonds observed in the market and using the Libor swap curve as the
risk-free benchmark curve. Then one can calculate the fair CDS spread consistent with the bond
implied default intensity and the risk-free benchmark curve, given a standard recovery assumption.
It is this theoretical bond-implied CDS spread, called the PECDS spread, that we compare to the
quoted CDS spread on the same reference entity to define the CDS-bond basis:

(1)

where is the maturity and indicates the reference entity. This methodology has several
advantages, as reviewed in Elizalde, Doctor, and Saltuk (2009). It has also been used by previous
academic studies such as Nashikkar, Subrahmanyam, and Mahanti (2011).

Another important issue for the measurement of the basis is the funding or ‘risk-free’ rate
benchmark (Hull, Predescu, and White, 2004).

Several authors have argued that the Treasury curve is not the appropriate risk-free benchmark
and indeed, that it is lower than the typical funding cost an investor can achieve via collateralized
borrowing.6 In fact, Hull, Predescu, and White (2004) use the basis package (a portfolio long several
corporate bonds and long CDS protection) to define a risk-free asset available to any investor. They

5
Duffie (1999) discusses the specific conditions and shows why this relation might not exactly hold in practice.
6
Studies that document the special status of the US Treasury curve, –presumably due to its greater liquidity–
include Longstaff (2004), Feldhutter and Lando (2008) among others.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


argue that since the average CDS-bond basis is zero when measuring funding cost using swap rate
minus 10 bps and the CDS-bond basis exhibits little cross-sectional variation, this is evidence that the
‘true’ shadow risk-free rate for a typical investor is around swap minus 10 bps (or approximately
Treasury plus 50 bps).

We emphasize that the very large cross-sectional variation in the basis (across rating categories)
documented in Figure 1 allows us to immediately dismiss the fact that mis-measurement of the
risk-free rate benchmark is the explanation for the puzzling behavior of the CDS-bond basis during
the crisis. If we were simply mis-measuring the risk-free benchmark we would observe an
approximately constant CDS-Bond basis across firms reflecting the spread between our benchmark
risk-free curve and the true (unobserved) risk-free curve. Let us stress, however, that since we do
not observe the true risk-free benchmark curve, it is important to focus on the cross-sectional
variation in the basis, rather than focusing on the average level, which could be affected by the
‘flight-to-quality’ effect documented in the Treasury and swap literature.

When the basis is positive, the credit default swap spread is larger than the bond spread. An
investor could then short the bond and sell CDS protection to capture the basis. When the basis is
negative, the credit default swap spread is lower than the bond spread. By buying the bond and
buying CDS protection, investors could lock in a risk-free annuity equal to the absolute value of the
basis.

As discussed in the introduction, during normal times the CDS-bond basis tends to be very small
and, if anything, slightly positive. This has been studied extensively by Blanco, Brennan, and Marsh
(2005), Longstaff, Mithal, and Neis (2005), and recently by Nashikkar, Subrahmanyam, and Mahanti
(2011). However, Figure 1 reveals that the CDS-bond basis was significantly and persistently negative
during the financial crisis, and even so after the crisis. Furthermore, there was substantial
cross-sectional variation in the negative basis as we can see from the conspicuous difference in the
bases between IG and HY bonds.

While a positive basis can often be traced back to some inability to implement the ‘arbitrage’
trade because either bonds are difficult to short (see liquidity concern in Nashikkar, Subrahmanyam,
and Mahanti (2011)),or there exists a cheapest-to-deliver option (see Blanco, Brennan, and Marsh
(2005)), a negative basis is harder to explain. Indeed, in the negative basis case, the ‘arbitrage’ trade
requires buying the bond, financing its purchase, and buying protection to hedge against the default
event. Figure 1 suggests that the return to the ‘negative basis’ trade would have been between 243
bps and 560 bps for IG and HY bonds respectively. These seem like very high arbitrage profits. So it is

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


important to review the details of such a basis trade implementation to better understand where
the ‘limits to arbitrage’ may arise.

2.1 Negative Basis Trade


In practice, there are several reasons why a negative basis trade is not a pure arbitrage. These
risks are discussed in detail in Elizalde, Doctor, and Saltuk (2009) (see, in particular, their Table 2 on
page 23). The main issues when implementing a negative basis trade have to do with funding risk,
sizing the long CDS position, liquidity risk, and counterparty risk.

Suppose we find a bond with negative basis that trades at a price below its notional of .A
negative basis trade requires buying the bond. The purchase is funded via the repo market where
investors face a haircut . This effectively implies that arbitrageurs will have to provide dollars
of ‘risk-capital’ funded at where is the funding spread over Libor faced by the
arbitrageur. The repo contract is typically overnight (up to a few months at most) with an
agreed-upon repo rate, and needs to be rolled over repeatedly until the maturity of the basis trade,
which is the lesser of default and maturity (e.g., 5 years).

At the same time, the investor buys the protection in the CDS market to offset the default risk. A
question arises as to how to size the CDS position. A conservative approach from a viewpoint of
minimizing exposure to a jump to default is to buy protection on the full notional of the bond.

Market participants typically prefer to buy less protection to improve the carry profile of the
trade (pay less in insurance premium). The justification is that the maximum capital at risk in the
transaction is the initial purchase price of .7 In fact, a customary approach is to make an
assumption about recovery (for example, assume that in case of bankruptcy a fraction of the
notional of the bond is recovered) and buy protection on a CDS notional of so as to cover the
loss in capital, i.e., such that . This will increase the carry of the trade (since
the CDS premia are now reduced), but expose the investor to a jump to default in case the recovery
is smaller than expected. An alternative approach is to choose the notional of the CDS position to
match the spread duration on the risky bond (this approach tries to minimize mark-to-market
differences between the bond and CDS position over the life of the bond as opposed to thinking

7
For bonds that trade at a premium one may in fact buy more protection than the nominal!

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


about the jump-to-default risk). As explained in Duffie (1999), there is no perfect arbitrage when the
underlying bond is not a floating rate note with the same maturity as the CDS contract.8

For illustration, suppose the investor buys protection on a notional . This requires a margin
payment of and periodic mark-to-market margin calls. The margin has to be funded at
.9

After one day, the profit or loss (P&L) on the trade can be written as:

(2)

where is the duration of the CDS such that the P&L on the CDS is the product of the duration
with the change in CDS rate—note that if CDS increases, the short-credit/long-protection position
makes money. In the P&L analysis, we explicitly consider trading costs in the form of bid-ask spreads
on the bond and the CDS contract. For illustration, suppose we size our position in the CDS contract
10
to match the Libor-spread duration on the corporate bond, then we can rewrite the P&L as:

(3)

8
In fact, even in that case the arbitrage is not perfect (e.g, Lando (2004)).
9
We assume conservatively that the investor does not earn any interest on the posted margin. If the investor
was paid interest on the Margin then the margin would be funded at where would be the
funding spread net of the interest earned on the posted margin.
10
We use the approximation , where is the bond yield credit spreads.
We size the position in the CDS so that . Further, we define the CDS bid-ask spread
. Then we assume . Therefore
. Putting all together we get the above expression with
is the average of the bid-ask spread on the bond and on the CDS.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


is the average of the bond yield bid-ask spread and the CDS bid-ask spread. Specifically, this
relation shows that a typical basis trade, when rolled over repeatedly, is exposed to:

• An increase in funding cost as measured by the benchmark Libor rate.

• An increase in the arbitrageur’s own credit risk, which would lead to a larger markup ( ). We
note that if the arbitrageur has a large position in basis trades, then this could be tied to the basis
becoming more negative (i.e., the trade running away from him).

• A worsening of the collateral quality of the bond, which would lead to an increase in the
haircut ( ) and the repo rate ( )

• An increase in the margin requirements on the CDS position ( ).

• An increase in trading costs as measured by the average bid-ask spread on the bond and CDS.
This component is important for two reasons. First, it affects the daily mark-to-market positions.
Second, if the position does need to be unwound before the maturity of the contract (or default),
trading liquidity matters.

Finally, the trade is also affected by counterparty risk in the sense that if a default on a bond
occurs at time , then the P&L will be:

(4)

where denotes the default time of the counterparty selling protection and denotes the
realized recovery on the bond. Specifically, if the counterparty defaults (or has defaulted) when the

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


underlying firm defaults then the CDS protection expires worthless. This highlights the fact that from
an ex ante perspective counterparty risk depends on the correlation between the default risk of the
underlying name and the counterparty selling the protection, which is typically a large bank such as
J.P. Morgan, Lehman Brothers, and Goldman Sachs.

It is important to stress that counterparty risk is typically viewed as likely to be small, since if the
counterparty defaults prior to the default event (i.e., ) and if the marking to market were
perfect, then the investor could reopen a new position at no cost with another counterparty. Thus,
in theory, counterparty risk only affects the investor if the counterparty defaults on the exact same
day as the underlying bond ( ). In practice however, it is likely that the failure of the
counterparty, especially during an extraordinary period like the financial crisis, would be associated
with more substantial costs and risks for the investor. These losses would typically be related to the
likely mark-to-market loss in the position on the day of the counterparty default as well as more
technical considerations, which have to do with the specific bankruptcy provisions in the ISDA
covering the CDS trade (e.g., if the mark-to-market limits were insufficient, or if the collateral posted
with the counterparty was rehypothecated, or if the cash settlement upon bankruptcy of the
counterparty is based on mid-market quotes).

Below we try to use the cross-sectional variation in individual bond bases to disentangle the
effects of various risks outlined above that affect the risk-return tradeoff of a basis trade. Our
working hypothesis is that an arbitrageur having limited access to capital will try to exploit the basis
trade opportunities that offer the best expected return per unit of risk capital. So she will choose
basis trades that have the most negative basis (highest expected return) but controlling for ex ante
measures of exposure to market and funding liquidity. All else equal she will prefer basis trades on
bonds with low haircuts, low exposure to funding cost (in the sense that for two bonds with equally
negative basis, the one which correlates more with funding costs is more attractive, since the basis
trade converges when funding costs rise), low counterparty risk (in the sense that the probability of
the underlying firm defaulting at the same time as the counterparty in the CDS is lower) and low
trading liquidity risk (i.e., lower current transaction costs and lower future risk-adjusted transaction
costs). If this hypothesis is correct then we expect that the risk characteristics of the basis trade
(counterparty risk, funding risk, liquidity risk, collateral quality) should be related to the
cross-sectional variation of the bases.11

11
A more sophisticated analysis would be to solve the optimal capital allocation decision of the arbitrageur to
the available basis trades and test her first order condition.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


3. Data
The data used to study the CDS-bond basis come from several sources. We start with the
universe of firms whose single-name CDS is traded in the derivative market and transactions are
recorded in the Markit database. Then we identify corporate bonds issued by these firms from the
Mergent Fixed Income database and collect bond characteristics. We further download corporate
bond transaction records from the enhanced version of the Trade Reporting and Compliance Engine
(TRACE). Finally we match each firm’s credit default swap and bond spread to corresponding equity
returns in the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP). All data are in daily frequency from July
1, 2006 through December 30, 2014. The whole sample is further partitioned into four phases: Phase
1 is the period before the subprime credit crisis, named ‘Before Crisis’ (7/1/2006 - 6/30/2007);12
Phase 2 is the period between the subprime credit crisis and the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers,
called ‘Crisis I’ (7/1/2007 - 8/31/2008); Phase 3 is the period after Lehman Brothers’ failure, ‘Crisis II’
(9/1/2008 - 9/30/2009);13 and Phase 4 is the period after the financial crisis, ‘Post-Crisis’ (10/1/2009
- 12/30/2014).

Our goal is to examine the arbitrage relationship between the corporate bond cash and
derivative market. The cornerstone of our analysis is an accurate measure of the CDS-bond basis. As
shown in Section 2 and Appendix A, the basis is constructed from the credit default swap spread, the
corporate bond transaction price, and the reference interest rate.

3.1 Corporate Bond


Corporate bond transaction data are downloaded from Trace. Bond characteristics are collected
from Mergent Fixed Income Databases including coupon, rating, interest rate frequency, option
features, and so on. For bond-level rating information, if a bond is rated only by Moody’s or by

12
There is not an unanimously agreed day for the beginning of the subprime crisis. Popular opinion is that the
subprime crisis started in August 2007. Here we take a conservative stance by starting the crisis period in July
2007.
13
It’s unclear of the earliest ending date of the U.S. financial crisis. According to NBER business cycle dates,
the recession ended by June 2009. We allow for another three months in the Crisis II period.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Standard and Poor’s, we use that rating. If a bond is rated by both rating agencies, we take the
average rating as the final one.

We highlight the following filtering criteria in order to choose qualified bonds. First, we remove
bonds that are not listed or traded in the U.S. public market, which include bonds issued through
private placement, bonds issued under the 144A rule, bonds that do not trade in US dollars, and
bond issuers not in the jurisdiction of the United States. Second, we focus on corporate bonds that
are not structured notes, not mortgage backed or asset backed. We also remove the bonds that are
agency-backed or equity-linked. Third, we exclude convertible bonds since this option feature
distorts the basis calculation and makes it impossible to compare the basis of convertible and
non-convertible bonds.14 Fourth, we remove bonds with floating rate; that means the sample
comprises only bonds with fixed or zero coupon. This rule is applied based on the consideration of
the accuracy in the basis calculation, given the challenge in tracking floating-coupon bond’s cash
flows.

The Enhanced TRACE provides the information on bond transactions at the intraday frequency.
Beyond the above filtering criteria, we further clean up TRACE transaction records by eliminating
when-issued bonds, locked-in bonds, and bonds with commission trading, special prices, or special
sales conditions. We remove transaction records that are cancelled, and adjust records that are
subsequently corrected or reversed. Bond trades with more than 2-day settlement are also removed
from our sample.

Lastly, we focus on bonds which have 3 to 7.5 years remaining to maturity (time-to-maturity is
measured each day during the sample period).15 This criterion is due to the concern that in the CDS
market which we introduce in the next subsection, the five-year CDS contracts often have the best
liquidity. In order to match the five-year term, we limit the calculation of the CDS-bond basis only for
bonds with time-to-maturity ranging from 3 to 7.5 years.

14
Bonds also contain other option features such as putable, redeemable/callable, exchangeable, and fungible.
Except callable bonds, bonds with other option features are relatively a small portion in the sample. However,
callable bonds constitute about 67% of the whole sample. Hence, we keep the callable bonds in our final
sample, but we also conduct robustness check for a smaller sample filtering out the bonds with option
features.
15
The restructuring rule used in our CDS contract, ‘Modified Restructuring’, restricts the deliverable bonds to
be within 30 months of the contract maturity. Therefore, we consider a qualified deliverable bond have
time-to-maturity up to 7.5 years, which is 30 months later than the 5-year CDS contract, the target maturity in
this paper.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


3.2 Credit Default Swap
We download single-name credit default swap data from Markit Inc. for U.S. firms. The prices
are quoted in basis points per annum for a notional value of $10 million and are based on the
standard ISDA contract for physical settlement. The original dataset provides daily market CDS prices
in various currencies and different types of restructuring documentation clauses. Following a
conventional rule, we choose the CDS price in US dollar and the documentation clause type as
‘Modified Restructuring’ (MR).16

There are several caveats in matching CDS with underlying reference entities. First, the MR rule
restricts the deliverable bonds to be within 30 months of the contract maturity. We check the bond
maturity to follow the MR rule. Second, the underlying bond should be deliverable into the CDS
contract. However, it is very difficult to identify whether bonds are deliverable into CDS contracts for
a large sample of firms over a long time period, “since CDS conventions are often bilaterally defined
in the over-the-counter market," as pointed out by Nashikkar, Subrahmanyam, and Mahanti (2011).

The original dataset provides a CDS spread term structure incorporating maturities of 1y, 2y, 3y,
4y, 5y, 7y, and 10y. We use all maturities in conjunction with matching interest rate swaps to
calculate a term structure of default probability, which is an integral component in deriving the
bond-implied CDS spread (PECDS) and hence the CDS-bond basis (see Appendix A). In the end we
focus on the CDS-bond basis with a maturity of five years, because the 5-year CDS is by far the most
liquid in the credit derivative market, and this is also the one mostly used in the literature.

The CDS data and corporate bond data are manually matched via company names. There are
originally 1842 unique CDS underlying entities during 2006 - 2014. After matching to corporate bond
data and applying the aforementioned filtering criteria, we finally have a total of 1.1 million daily
observations during July 1st, 2006 to December 31st, 2014, representing 4415 pairs of CDS-bond

16
Under the 2003 Credit Definitions by the International Swap and Derivative Association (ISDA), there are
four types of restructuring clauses: Cumulative Restructuring (CR), Modified Restructuring (MR),
Modified-Modified Restructuring (MM), and No Restructuring (XR). ‘Modified Restructuring’ is used by most
broker-dealers in the U.S. market. This convention holds till April 8, 2009. Afterwards the U.S. market adopts
the ‘No Restructuring’ convention. For consistency, we choose the MR documentation clause throughout our
sample.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


basis for 679 unique CDS names. To reduce the influence of outliers in the cross-sectional
regressions, we further winsorize the bases at the 0.5% and 99.5% level.17

3.3 Reference Rate


We use the U.S. dollar interest rates swaps as reference rates for the risk-free funding curve for
computing credit spreads. An alternative choice might be to use government bond yields. However,
as Blanco, Brennan and Marsh (2005) point out, “government bonds are no longer an ideal proxy for
the unobservable risk-free rate" due to tax treatment, repo specialness, legal constraints, and other
factors. Importantly, the Libor swap rate represents a better indicator of the funding cost for
financial intermediaries and typical basis swap traders than the Treasury curve. Therefore we use it
as our benchmark funding curve for the basis calculations.18

As discussed in Section 2, we focus on the cross-sectional variation in the CDS-bond basis rather
than its absolute level since we do not observe the true risk-free reference rate.

3.4 Summary Statistics


Table 1 presents summary statistics of the CDS-bond basis. The basis across all firms was slightly
negative before the crisis, 10 bps on average between 7/1/2006 to 6/30/2007 (which is consistent
with the evidence in Hull, Predescu, and White (2004)), but fell to 118 bps in the first phase of the
financial crisis and to 324 bps after the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers. The average basis
remained negative around 137 bps after the financial crisis. Meanwhile the volatility of the basis
kept increasing for all types of firms from an average of 59 bps before the crisis to 192 bps and
further to 369 bps during the turmoil of the financial crisis. The volatility fell back to 152 bps after
the crisis, still far away from the pre-crisis level. Firms with both the IG and the HY ratings share the
same pattern as firms overall, whose bases became more and more negative and volatile as the
financial crisis progressed. Moreover, the basis of HY firms is always more volatile than that of IG

17
Our empirical results in Section 5 are similar if winsorizing at the 1% and 99% level, or at the 0.25% and
99.75% level.
18
See also the swap-Treasury spread discussions in Hull, Predescu, and White (2004), Collin-Dufresne and
Solnik (2001), and Longstaff, Mithal, and Neis (2005).

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


firms. Financial firms and non-financial firms share similar time-series patterns in their bases, except
that financial firms have slightly higher volatility of basis during the peak of the financial crisis.

Table 1 also provides additional basis results across ratings from AAA/AA to CCC. Firms with
lower credit rating tend to have more negative and more volatile bases during the crisis while the
bases display a right-skewed ‘smile’ from AAA/AA to CCC before and after the crisis.

Figure 1 provides an illustration of the basis dynamics for IG and HY bonds. The solid blue line is
the median value of the aggregated CDS-bond bases for bonds in each rating category, weighted by
bond outstanding amounts. The dotted red lines are the 10th and 90th percentile of the aggregated
bases. It is worth noting that the average CDS-bond basis for both IG and HY bonds after the financial
crisis, though improved, are still far below their pre-crisis levels. Moreover, there exists a large
dispersion of the basis values throughout the whole sample period. We focus the analysis on the
cross-sectional variation in the negative basis, because the basis sample became predominantly
negative. As shown in the table below, 92.7% of the observations in the whole sample have negative
bases. The proportion is even larger during the crisis period and the post-crisis period for about
94.4% and 93.9% respectively.

Negative Positive

Before Crisis 69.30% 30.70%

Crisis I 87.60% 12.40%

Crisis II 94.40% 5.60%

Post Crisis 93.90% 6.10%

Total 92.70% 7.30%

3.5 Preliminary Evidence on the Cross-sectional Variation in the Basis


Garleanu and Pedersen (2011) make the point that haircuts are typically around 25% for IG
firms (and very similar across firms rated from AAA to BBB) and of the order of 55% for HY bonds
(rated BB or lower). In their model, the basis differential between IG and HY bonds should be equal
to the difference between haircut margins multiplied by the collateral funding spread (i.e., the

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


difference between the collateralized and the uncollateralized funding rates). While indeed an
important plausible determinant of the basis, our data suggests that there exist additional important
factors. Indeed, as clearly shown in Table 1 there is tremendous amount of variation in the basis
within a credit rating category, and certainly a lot of differences in the basis within the IG and the HY
category.19

Number of Days with Positive Basis

Crisis I
Firm Crisis II (T=271) Rating Industry
(T = 295)

Newmont Mng Corp 286 250 BBB Basic Materials

Berkshire Hathaway 127 244 AAA Financials

Amern Tower Corp 237 226 BB Technology

Emc Corp 259 188 BBB Technology

MetLife Insurance Co 12 178 A Financials

Boyd Gaming Corp 253 163 BB Consumer Services

General Electric Co 89 154 AAA Industrials

Windstream Corp 54 131 BB Telecommunications

Penn Natl Gaming Inc 134 130 B Consumer Services

Mylan Inc 204 122 BB Health Care

AutoNation Inc 1 117 BB Consumer Services

Las Vegas Sands Corp 108 106 B Consumer Services

Note: Ratings are based on the values at the end of September 2008.

19
Overtime, there are also a lot of variations in the basis in a way that cannot solely be explained by the
variation in the collateral funding spread, and as we argue below, is unlikely to be explained solely by changes
in haircuts.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


To illustrate this point even more dramatically, we present examples for twelve firms in our
sample that have positive basis for more than 100 days during the second phase of the crisis
(9/1/2008 - 9/30/2009, with 271 days) . These firms have diverse credit ratings ranging from B (Las
Vegas Sands Corp and Penn Natl Gaming Inc) to AAA (Berkshire Hathaway, and GE), and belong to six
separate industries. This is clearly at variance with a model that would have a single factor, such as
haircuts or margins, to explain the basis.20 Clearly, the haircut and margin requirement on Las Vegas
Sands were much larger than for Berkshire bonds, and yet both display a positive basis (when most
IG and HY bonds displayed strongly negative bases at the time). Some factors driving the individual
basis are likely to be highly idiosyncratic. For example, it was suggested to us that the very positive
basis on Berkshire was due to the large demand from CDS protection buyers by dealers who had
non-mark-to-market in-the-money long-term volatility exposures to Berkshire. This would have
driven the CDS on Berkshire up relative to the bond yield generating the positive basis.

We focus more systematically on the cross-sectional variation in the CDS-bond basis below.

4. Limit-to-Arbitrage Factors
The deviation between the same underlying bond’s transaction price and its CDS spread,
according to Section 2, could be driven by four types of factors: i) the collateral value of the
underlying corporate bond, ii) the liquidity of bond trading, iii) the counterparty risk in buying a CDS
contract, and iv) the funding constraints faced by investors who want to explore the arbitrage. In this
section we construct various proxies for these factors and discuss their likely relationship to the
cross-section of the CDS-bond bases.

4.1 Collateral Quality Proxy


In the basis trade, the purchase of a bond is funded via the repo market and two key variables
determine the cost of the purchase: haircut and repo rate, which we label as the proxies of collateral
quality. Haircuts of corporate bonds in the repo market often have narrow range in the

20
Indeed, the general model in Garleanu and Pedersen (2011) predicts that other factors (such as the
covariance of the underlying cash-flows with aggregate consumption) in addition to the margin differential
should predict the difference in the basis. It is only for the specific application to the CDS basis that they focus
on the margin difference. Our data suggests it is important to look for additional factors.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


investment-grade or non-investment-grade categories. That is, bonds have similar haircuts across
ratings from AAA to BBB, or across ratings from BB and CCC. Garleanu and Pedersen (2011) make the
point that haircuts are typically around 25% for most investment-grade firms and around 55% for
most non-investment-grade firms. This rough haircut convention thus cannot help distinguish the
wide range of the bases as shown in Figure 1. Given that haircut is dominantly driven by a bond’s
credit risk, we thus use credit rating as one proxy for collateral quality, noted as . In detail, we
assign numeric values for bond ratings ranging from 1 for CCC, 2 for CC , all the way to 21 for AAA
rated bonds, thus we have a granularity in capturing the collateral quality of bonds. The higher the
rating indicator, the higher the expected collateral quality.

An alternative proxy for the collateral value is the repo rate, but the bond-level data on the
repo rates are not publicly available. We thus rely on the bond lending fee as a second proxy of
collateral value based on a unique corporate bond loan data. The data, provided by Markit, record
daily corporate bond loan transactions where beneficial owners such as insurance companies,
pension funds, and other institutional investors lend out bonds to end-users such as hedge funds
and collect lending fees. We collect the real borrowing cost for each bond in our sample, Fee, as the
transaction value-weighted average lending fees over all open transactions. The lending fee is
typically negatively correlated with the repo rate of a bond and thus positively related to the bond’s
collateral quality. It is a source of additional return for bondholders. On the other hand, a high
lending fee signals a higher shorting demand for a particular bond, thus it can also signal a negative
view on the bond by market participants (see Bai (2018)).

To do the negative basis trade, an arbitrageur needs to buy bonds that are funded via the repo
market using the same bonds as collateral. The haircut and the repo rate imposed on the repo
transaction reduce the amount of leverage available to the arbitrageur. All else equal, we expect
bonds with lower collateral quality, that is, a higher haircut or a lower lending fee to have a less
profitable basis trade per unit use of expected risk capital. Thus, the lower the collateral quality the
more negative the basis to equalize expected returns per unit of risk capital. So we expect a positive
coefficient in cross-sectional regressions of the bases on collateral quality.

4.2 Bond Trading Liquidity


As the basis trade P&L analysis in Section 2.1 reveals, individual bond (and CDS) trading costs
affect the profitability of the CDS-bond basis trade. Therefore, all else equal, arbitrageurs will seek
basis trades with bonds that are more liquid and that have less (trading) liquidity risk in the sense

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


that they are less likely to become illiquid when the basis trade further diverges. Recent studies,
such as Bao, Pan, and Wang (2011), Dick-Nielsen, Feldhütter, and Lando (2012), find severe
deterioration of liquidity in the corporate bond market during the financial crisis. In this section we
construct three different measures of bond liquidity and liquidity risks, following the decomposition
method proposed in Acharya and Pedersen (2005).

1. Bond illiquidity level (noted as Liq): measured by the baopanwang11 gamma ( ), which
aims to extract the transitory component in the bond price.21 Specifically, let
be the daily log price change from to . The is defined as

(5)

We compute for each bond per month and assign the monthly value for weeks within that
particular month. We expect bonds that are more illiquid to have more negative basis, that is a
negative coefficient of the bases on the measure in cross-sectional regressions.

2. Bond iliquidity beta (noted as ): the co-movement between bond s illiquidity and the
market illiquidity, where the market illiquidity is calculated as the average of individual bond
illiquidity in the sample. As explained in Acharya and Pedersen (2005), investors want to be
compensated for holding a security that becomes illiquid when the market in general becomes
illiquid. Similarly, we expect basis trade arbitrageurs to prefer (all else equal) basis trades with bonds
whose trading costs co-vary less with the overall bond market illiquidity. Hence, we expect a
negative coefficient in the cross-sectional regression of bases on bond liquidity betas.

21
There is no agreement on the best measure for corporate bond liquidity. Thus, we also construct alternative
liquidity measures such as the bid-ask price spread and the Amihud (2002) measure. These measures generate
similar empirical results.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


3. Bond liquidity market beta (noted as ): the co-movement between bond s illiquidity
and the market return, where the market return is measured by the CRSP value-weighted stock
market return. As in Acharya and Pedersen (2005) we expect arbitrageurs to prefer at the margin
negative basis trades for bonds that tend to have trading costs that co-vary more with market
returns. Indeed, bonds with high trading costs in market down turns potentially lead to lower profits
upon an unwind precisely in bad states. Therefore we expect (all else equal) a less negative basis on
bonds with larger bond liquidity market betas, that is, a positive regression coefficient.

The three measures provide a characterization of bond liquidity risk. Intuition suggests that the
three measures should be correlated. In Table 2, we show that the correlation between liquidity
(risk) measures is low during the non-crisis period, ranging from 2% to 8% in the absolute value,
however the correlations increase to 27 39% during the crisis period.

4.3 Counterparty Risk


Counterparty risk has become a primary concern facing participants in the financial markets
during the 2007 2009 crisis. Counterparty risk is the risk that the protection seller, typically a broker
dealer, cannot make good on its commitment to the protection buyer in case of default. Therefore
counterparty risk should make the insurance less valuable and lower the CDS spread, possibly
contributing to the negative basis. As explained previously, the higher the correlation between the
default events of the underlying entity and the protection seller the bigger the expected
counterparty risk.22 The challenge is how to measure the correlation between the default risk of the
underlying entity and the counterparty selling the CDS protection.23

22
That counterparty risk is not irrelevant, can be seen from the Lehman Brothers case. Suppose an investor
had bought protection on Washington Mutual from Lehman Brothers. Washington Mutual defaulted only a
few days after Lehman. Without marking to market, the investor would be a regular claimant in bankruptcy for
the protection purchased from Lehman, leading to at best a partial loss. Of course, if ISDA agreements were
well enforced, and provided the investor had negotiated full-two-way mark to market with Lehman, then the
risk would be further mitigated. However, in practice, it is likely that most funds would have ended with at
least some partial loss as a result of this double default.
23
Arora, Gandhi, and Longstaff (2012) look for counterparty fixed effects using a proprietary data set of CDS
transaction prices by 14 CDS dealers selling credit protection on one underlying firm to identify the
counterparty risk component of CDS spreads.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


The CDS market is over-the-counter and the exact nature of counterparties is not known.
Furthermore, the process of netting makes it difficult to establish an aggregate measure of
counterparty risk for individual reference entities.24

To establish a measure of the counterparty risk faced by an investor engaging into a specific
basis trade, we notice that throughout our sample, the primary dealers on average trade more than
90% of total transaction dollar volume. It seems therefore reasonable to construct a counterparty
risk measure for a representative CDS issuer using the list of primary dealers designated by the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.25 These primary dealers are banks and security broker-dealers
that trade in the U.S. government securities with the Federal Reserve System. To become qualified
as a primary dealer, a firm must be in compliance with capital standards under the Basel Capital
Accord, with at least $100 million of Tier I capital for a bank or above $50 million of regulatory
capital for a broker-dealer. As trading partners of the central bank, these primary dealers often are
the biggest and most competitive financial institutions who happen to be dominant issuers of credit
default swap contracts. As of September 2008, there were 19 primary dealers such as Citigroup, J.P.
Morgan Chase, and Goldman Sachs (the complete list is documented in Appendix B). The list changes
over time since some primary dealers may fail to meet required capital standards. Accordingly, we
update the components of the primary dealer index. For example, the index includes Lehman
Brothers’ Holdings before its bankruptcy on September 15, 2008, but exclude it afterwards and adds
Nomura Securities International, Inc. starting from July 27, 2009.

For the primary dealer index, we calculate its CDS spread weighted by each constituent’s market
capitalization. As shown in Figure 2, the primary dealers have a strikingly increase in their default risk
during the financial crisis of 2008 2009 and the peak of the European sovereign debt crisis of
2011 2012. A direct implication is that the insurance contracts sold by these dealers should be less
valuable and the protection buyers face higher counterparty risk. We measure an underlying entity’s
counterparty risk as the beta coefficient of regressing the change of firm-level CDS to the change of
the primary dealer CDS:

24
In September 2008 the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers caused almost $400 billion to become payable to
the buyers of CDS protection referenced against the insolvent bank. However, the net amount that changed
hands was around $7.2 billion. This difference is due to the process of “netting". Market participants
cooperated so that CDS sellers were allowed to deduct from their payouts the funds due to them from their
hedging positions. Dealers generally attempt to remain risk-neutral so that their losses and gains after big
events will on the whole offset each other.
25
Data source: http://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/pridealers_current.html.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


(6)

The higher the , the larger the likelihood of a joint default and the less valuable we expect the
protection to be when purchased from that counterparty. So we expect a negative coefficient in the
cross-sectional regression of the bases on counterparty betas.

4.4 Funding Liquidity Risk


For an arbitrageur entering a basis trade, the risk is that the basis becomes more negative at the
same time as her funding costs widen. We thus proxy funding liquidity risk by the regression
coefficient of the change in the basis on a measure of the change in funding costs or funding liquidity
premium.

The literature has considered many proxies to measure the funding liquidity premium including
the Libor-OIS spread, the TED spread (Libor-TBill), the Repo-TBill spread and the OIS-TBill spread.
One concern with the Libor-indexed spreads is that they are contaminated by financial intermediary
credit risk and hence might be correlated with counterparty risk, especially during the financial crisis.
For this reason, we follow Nagel (2016) and use the three-month Repo-TBill spread. Bai,
Krishnamurthy, and Weymuller (2018) propose an alternative measure of the OIS-TBill spread. Both
the Repo-TBill spread and OIS-TBill spread have similar time-series patterns, and they have a
correlation value of 0.90. All our empirical results remain unchanged in magnitude and significance if
we use the OIS-TBill spread as the alternative proxy of funding liquidity premium.

Our estimate of the funding liquidity beta is therefore defined as:

(7)

The lower the funding liquidity beta, the less aggressively an arbitrageur would invest in that basis
trade, as the basis will become more negative when her funding cost increases. So we expect a
positive coefficient in the cross-sectional regression of the bases on funding liquidity betas.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


4.5 Summary
We summarize the expected signs of the cross-sectional determinants of the CDS-bond basis
in the following table based on our previous discussion.

Factors Expected cross-sectional correlation with negative basis

Lending fee +

Credit rating +

Bond illiquidity -

Bond liquidity risk -

Bond liquidity mkt risk +

Counterparty Risk -

Funding liquidity risk +

Panel B of Table 2 presents the correlation values of limit-to-arbitrage factors. In the non-crisis
period, the correlations among collateral quality proxies, bond trading liquidity, counterparty risk,
and funding liquidity risk are trivial. For example, funding liquidity beta is almost uncorrelated with
any other factors with the correlation values between -0.01 to 0.03; bond illiquidity or liquidity risk
also have negligible correlation with other factors. In the crisis period, the correlation between bond
illiquidity and bond liquidity risk increases, but the correlation values among other risk factors
remain small. The low correlations relieve the concern of colinearity across limit-to-arbitrage risk
factors.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


5. Cross-sectional Determinants of the CDS-Bond Basis
We now investigate the cross-sectional variation in the CDS-bond basis using Fama and MacBeth
(1973) regressions. To mitigate the impact of noise in the daily data, we adopt the weekly frequency
throughout our empirical analysis, where the bond-level weekly basis is the average value of daily
basis within each week for a particular bond. For limit-to-arbitrage factors except collateral quality,
all beta coefficients are estimated for each bond at each week using a rolling window of past
60-week observations.26,27 For collateral quality we calculate the weekly averages of the daily
corporate bond loan lending fee and of its credit rating.

5.1 Bond-level Results


We report the Fama-MacBeth regression results for four subperiods: Before Crisis, Crisis I, Crisis
II, and Post Crisis. In detail, weekly cross-sectional regressions are run for the following specification
and nested versions thereof:

(8)

where is the CDS-bond basis on bond in week . is the bond credit rating in
numeric values, is the bond lending fee, is the bond trading illiquidity level,
denotes bond liquidity risk, denotes bond liquidity market risk, and denote the
counterparty risk and funding liquidity risk, — all measures are defined in Section 4. We standardize
explanatory variables cross-sectionally each week, therefore the coefficients are comparable across
variables and over sample periods.

Table 3 reports the time-series average of the estimated coefficients ’s and the average
adjusted R-squared values over the 466 weeks from July 2006 to December 2014 for the negative

26
A bond is included in our sample if it has at least 24 weekly basis observations in the 60-week rolling
window before the test week. Our data start from July 2001 and we report regression results since July 2006.
27
Our results are also robust to different rolling windows in estimating limit-to-arbitrage risk factors, that is i)
36-week rolling window instead of 60 weeks using weekly data, or ii) 60-day rolling window using daily data.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


CDS-bond basis. The -statistics based on Newy-West adjusted standard errors are given in squared
brackets.

Focusing on the multi-variate regressions (since the results remain largely similar to the
univariate case) in the last column, we see that collateral quality, bond illiquidity, counterparty risk,
and funding liquidity risk, all enter significantly especially during the crisis period, achieving an
of 36.6%. The sign of the significant coefficients are consistent with our expectations summarized in
Section 4.5. During the peak of the crisis from September 2008 to September 2009, the most
important factors driving the cross-sectional differences in basis are credit rating with an estimated
coefficient of 1.902 ( -stat=6.78), bond illiquidity with an estimated coefficient of 0.676
( -stat= 3.16), funding liquidity risk with an estimated coefficient of 0.794 ( -stat=3.71), and
counterparty risk with an estimated coefficient of 0.545 ( -stat= 5.22). In the first stage of the
crisis from July 2007 to August 2008, the same set of factors have significant explanatory power,
though to a relatively smaller degree. For example, the coefficient for credit rating drops from 1.902
in Crisis II to 0.570 in Crisis I, the coefficient for counterparty risk drops from 0.545 to 0.181,
and that for funding liquidity risk drops from 0.794 to 0.132.

During the non-crisis period (both before and after the crisis) however, only credit rating
remains consistently significant in explaining the cross-sectional variations of the basis, indicating
that collateral quality is always relevant for a basis arbitrage trade. The estimated coefficients for
counterparty risk are also statistically significant in the non-crisis period, but have much smaller
magnitude (the coefficient is 0.059 before and 0.163 after the crisis). Also, the signs of the
counterparty risk coefficient in the non-crisis period are positive, which is counter to our
expectation; this is likely due to the strong colinearity of counterparty risk with credit rating and
lending fee (the correlations are 0.31 and 0.21, respectively). Lastly, the bond liquidity factors
(both illiquidity and liquidity risk) lose explanatory power in the non-crisis period.

There is one surprising finding, namely that lending fee has a significant but negative coefficient
in the cross-sectional regressions throughout the crisis and non-crisis periods, which is at variance
with our expectation. Our interpretation is that lending fee is also a proxy for the short interest in a
bond. That is, a high lending fee not only arises when a bond is highly valued as a collateral and thus
in high demand in the securities lending market (in this case, the bond has a low repo rate), but also
may arise when a bond is being heavily shorted and thus is in scarce supply in the securities lending
market. If the lending fee during the crisis mostly captures short interest, then the negative sign on
lending fee could reflect the fact that arbitrageurs refrain from entering a basis trade on the related
bond which is heavily shorted. In effect, arbitrageurs may worry about ‘catching a falling knife’ when

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


entering such a basis trade, as the negative market view on the bond signaled by the high short
interest suggests that the basis might diverge even further in the near future.

To conclude, the empirical model is reasonably successful in explaining the cross-sectional


variation in the bases. All factors (except for lending fee) have the signs as expected, consistent with
the hypothesis that the marginal investor being a leveraged hedge fund trade off risk and return
when allocating scarce risk-capital to different basis investment opportunities.

5.2 Portfolio-level Results


To minimize the noise in the bond-level cross-sectional regression results, we also consider
running the Fama and MacBeth (1973) regression at the portfolio level. We first examine the
distribution of bond size throughout the sample and categorize bonds into four bins by the 25th,
50th, and 75th percentile. Within each bin of bond size, we further categorize bonds into another six
bins by their credit ratings: AAA/AA, A, BBB, BB, B, CCC&Below. In so doing, we construct the time
series of 24 corporate bond portfolios sorted by size and rating. We report in Panel A of Table 4 the
average basis of the 24 portfolios. The basis is clearly monotonically increasing with bond credit
quality and also monotonically decreasing with size as one might have expected.

In Panel B we report the portfolio-level cross-sectional regression result. We find a very high
of around 80% for the bases of 24 portfolios. Most coefficients are statistically significant throughout
the subsample periods. The signs on credit rating, bond illiquidity and liquidity risk, counterparty
risk, and funding liquidity risk are also consistent with our expectation during the crisis. However, we
note that outside the crisis period counterparty risk and bond illiquidity remain significant but
surprisingly their signs flip likely due to the correlation with other risk factors.

6. Conclusion
We have analyzed the cross-sectional variation in the CDS-bond basis during the crisis. Focusing
on the cross section of the CDS-bond basis is interesting as it provides a natural testing ground for
the literature that models limits to arbitrage, and specifically the behavior of arbitrageurs with
limited capital facing multiple arbitrage opportunities.

We find that, most notably during the post-Lehman crisis period, several limit-to-arbitrage
measures such as collateral quality, bond illiquidity and liquidity risk, counterparty risk, and funding

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


liquidity risk can ‘explain’ a significant fraction of the cross-sectional variation in the CDS-bond basis.
After the crisis the explanatory power of risk measures decreases substantially, but collateral quality
proxies such as credit rating and lending fee remain significant. Interestingly, throughout the sample
bond lending fee remains highly negatively related to the bond basis. We interpret this as evidence
for the fact that arbitrageurs refrain from entering the basis trade that have large trading frictions
(i.e., that are costly to fund or to trade) associated with them and especially when there is a large
amount of short interest in the bond (signaled by a high lending fee), which indicates that the basis
might further diverge in the short run.

References

Acharya, V. V., Pedersen, L. H., 2005. Asset pricing with liquidity risk. Journal of Financial Economics
77, 375–410.

Amihud, Y., 2002. Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-section and time series effects. Journal of
Financial Markets 5, 31–56.

Arora, N., Gandhi, P., Longstaff, F. A., 2012. Counterparty credit risk and the credit default
swap market. Journal of Financial Economics 103, 280–293.

Bai, J., 2018. What bond lending reveals? The role of informed demand in predicting credit spread
changes, working paper, Georgetown University.

Bai, J., Krishnamurthy, A., Weymuller, C.-H., 2018. Measuring liquidity mismatch in the
banking sector. Journal of Finance 73(1), 51–93.

Bao, J., Pan, J., Wang, J., 2011. Liquidity and corporate bonds. Journal of Finance 66, 911–946.

Blanco, R., Brennan, S., Marsh, I. W., 2005. An empirical analysis of the dynamic relation between
investment-grade bonds and credit default swaps. Journal of Finance 60, 2255– 2281.

Coffey, N., Hrung, W. B., Sarkar, A., 2009. Capital constraints, counterparty risk, and deviations from
covered interest rate parity, staff Reports 393, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Collin-Dufresne, P., Solnik, B., 2001. On the term structure of default premia in the swap and libor
markets. Journal of Finance 56, 1095–1115.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


D.E. Shaw Group, 2009. The basis monster that ate wall street. Market Insights March.

Dick-Nielsen, J., Feldhütter, P., Lando, D., 2012. Corporate bond liquidity before and after
the onset of the subprime crisis. Journal of Financial Economics 103, 471–492.

Duffie, D., Singleton, K., 2003. Credit Risk. Princeton University Press.

Duffie, D., 1999. Credit swap valuation. Financial Analysts Journal 55, 73–87.

Elizalde, A., Doctor, S., Saltuk, Y., 2009. Bond-cds basis handbook. J.P. Morgan Credit Derivatives
Research February 05.

Fama, E. F., MacBeth, J. D., 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political
Economy 81, 607–636.

Feldhütter, P., Lando, D., 2008. Decomposing swap spreads. Journal of Financial Economics 88, 375–
405.

Fleckenstein, M., Longstaff, F., Lustig, H., 2014. The tips-treasury bond puzzle. Journal of Finance
69(5), 2151–2197.

Fontana, A., 2011. The negative CDS-bond basis and convergence trading during the 2007/09
financial crisis, working paper 694, National Centre of Competence in Research Financial Valuation
and Risk Management.

Garleanu, N., Pedersen, L. H., 2011. Margin-based asset pricing and deviations from the law of one
price. Review of Financial Studies 24(6), 1980 – 2022.

Gromb, D., Vayanos, D., 2010. Limits of arbitrage: The state of the theory. Annual Review
of Financial Economics 2, 251 – 275.

Hull, J., Predescu, M., White, A., 2004. The relationship between credit default swap spreads, bond
yields, and credit rating announcements. Journal of Banking and Finance 28, 2789 – 2811.

Kim, G. H., Li, H., Zhang, W., 2016. CDS-bond basis and bond return predictability. Journal
of Empirical Finance 38, 307–337.

Kim, G. H., Li, H., Zhang, W., 2017. The CDS-bond basis and the cross section of corporate
bond returns. Journal of Futures Markets 17(8), 836–861.

Lando, D., 2004. Credit Risk Modeling - Theory and Applications. Princeton University Press.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Longstaff, F. A., 2004. The flight-to-liquidity premium in U.S. treasury bond prices. Journal of
Business 77, 511–526.

Longstaff, F. A., Mithal, S., Neis, E., 2005. Corporate yield spreads: Default risk or liquidity? new
evidence from the credit default swap market. Journal of Finance 60, 2213–2253.

Mitchell, M. L., Pulvino, T. C., 2012. Arbitrage crashes and the speed of capital. Journal of
Financial Economics 104(3), 469 – 490.

Nagel, S., 2016. The liquidity premium of near-money assets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 131,
1921–1971.

Nashikkar, A., Subrahmanyam, M. G., Mahanti, S., 2011. Liquidity and arbitrage in the market for
credit risk. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 46, 627–656.

Reed, Adam, 2013, Short Selling, Annual Review of Financial Economics 5, 245-258.

Shleifer, A., Vishny, R. W., 1997. The limits of arbitrage. Journal of Finance 88, 35–55.

A. Investment-grade bonds

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


B. High-yield bonds

Figure 1: Dispersion of the CDS-Bond Basis by Credit Rating

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Source: Markit Inc. and Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Figure 2: The Average Five-Year CDS Spread for the Primary Dealers (bps)

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Table I: Summary Statistics of Discrepancies in CDS and Cash Bond Spreads

This table provides descriptive statistics for the average CDS-bond basis in four phases: Phase 1 is
the period before the subprime credit crisis, named “Before Crisis" (July 2006 - June 2007), Phase 2 is
the period between the subprime credit crisis and the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, called “Crisis
I" (July 2007 - August 2008), Phase 3 is the period after Lehman Brothers’ failure, “Crisis II"
(September 2008 - September 2009), and Phase 4 is the period after the financial crisis, “Post Crisis"
(October 2009 - December 2014). The basis is calculated as the difference between the CDS spread
and the par-equivalent corporate bond spread, using the methodology in Appendix A. The summary
statistics are reported for all bonds (ALL), investmeng-grade bonds (IG), high-yield bonds (HY), bonds
issued separately by financial firms (F) and non-financial firms (NF), as well as across rating categires:
AAA/AA, A, BBB, BB, B, and CCC. We calculate the cross-sectional mean, standard deviation, the 10th
and the 90th percentile value of the bases across all bonds each day, and report the time-series
average of these statistics. All entries are in basis points.

Before Crisis Crisis I Crisis II Post Crisis

Jul 2006 - Jun Jul 2007 - Aug Sep 2008 - Sep Oct 2009 - Dec
2007 2008 2009 2014

Me S P1 P Me S P1 P Me S P9 Me S P1 P
P10
an D 0 90 an D 0 90 an D 0 an D 0 90

1 3 1
5 -5 -11 -2 -32 -66 -5 -13 -2 -3
ALL -10 45 9 14 6 5
9 7 8 73 4 7 5 7 68 2
2 9 2

1 2
3 -5 -1 -1 -24 -45 -4 -10 7 -1 -3
IG -17 17 -83 0 5
0 1 50 0 3 1 8 1 1 73 2
8 6

1 2 5 2
-1 14 -18 -4 -56 -12 -1 -23 -4 -3
HY 12 0 6 57 0 4
07 2 0 86 0 48 14 7 77 5
4 5 4 2

1 4 1
2 -5 -11 -3 -35 -91 -11 -2 -2
F -24 3 6 12 5 -4 0
6 5 7 43 1 3 6 05 7
1 0 2

NF -6 59 1 15 3 1
6 -5 -11 -2 -31 -62 -7 -14 -2 -3
9 2 6

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


5 6 9 6 54 3 1 5 1 5 5 94 4

AAA/ 3 -3 6 -9 -11 8 -21 -1 4 -1 -2


0 51 -35 32 -68
AA 4 1 1 0 1 4 8 2 0 21 3

1 1
2 -4 -1 -2 -18 -35 -3 5 -1 -2
A -15 17 -88 0 8 -86
9 9 54 0 7 9 2 8 45 7
7 0

3
2 -5 -10 6 -1 -3 -35 -60 -1 -12 7 -2 -4
BBB -23 11 0
9 6 3 8 73 7 7 7 35 2 7 02 9
2

1 3 1
4 -5 -10 -2 -49 -85 -1 -19 -3 -5
BB -7 43 2 18 1 2
0 2 7 31 3 2 82 5 63 4
6 3 7

2 4 2
9 -1 12 -19 -4 -50 -11 -7 -22 -4 -2
B 13 4 62 8 0
0 04 5 0 99 1 78 2 1 45 9
9 6 5

1 3 5 4
-1 16 -29 -8 12 -11 -17 -5 -41 -9
CCC 27 5 9 6 1 -8
28 7 6 07 0 13 47 34 3 51
1 8 8 8

Table II: Limit-to-Arbitrage Risk Factors

This table shows the summary statistics of limit-to-arbitrage factors in Panel A, and their correlation
values in Panel B, which is further divided into the crisis period (July 2007 - September 2008) and the
non-crisis period (July 2006 - June 2007 and October 2009 - December 2014).

Panel A: Summary Statistics

Variable Notation Mean Std Med P10 P90

Lending fee Fee 0.12 0.40 0.09 0.04 0.16

Credit rating Rat 12.64 3.53 13.50 7.00 16.50

Bond illiquidity (level) Liq 0.42 1.68 0.11 0.00 0.88

Bond liquidity risk  Liq 0.62 2.72 0.21 -0.67 2.28

Bond liquidity mkt risk  LiqM -0.03 0.36 -0.01 -0.19 0.13

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Counterparty risk CP 0.13 0.29 0.05 0.00 0.36

Funding liquidity risk  FL -0.03 1.32 -0.03 -0.68 0.69

Panel B:

Correlation in the non-crisis period

Fee Rat Liq  Liq  LiqM CP  FL

Fee 1.00

Rat -0.29 1.00

Liq -0.01 -0.05 1.00

 Liq 0.00 -0.04 0.02 1.00

 LiqM 0.00 0.02 -0.07 -0.08 1.00

CP 0.21 -0.31 0.03 0.00 0.00 1.00

 FL -0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03 1.00

Correlation in the crisis period

Fee Rat Liq  Liq  LiqM CP  FL

Fee 1.00

Rat -0.20 1.00

Liq -0.04 -0.02 1.00

 Liq 0.00 -0.05 0.27 1.00

 LiqM 0.03 0.07 -0.38 -0.39 1.00

CP 0.03 -0.03 0.03 0.02 0.02 1.00

 FL 0.00 0.05 -0.03 -0.01 0.08 -0.06 1.00

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Table III: Multivariate Fama-MacBeth Regression of the Negative CDS-Bond Basis

This table reports the average coefficients from the Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions of the
CDS-bond bases on risk factors including collateral quality proxies such as lending fee and credit
rating, three proxies of bond trading liquidity and liquidity risk, counterparty risk, and funding
liquidity risk. The sample is limited to negative basis only. The regression is conducted at the weekly
frequency for 444 weeks from July 2006 to December 2014. Except collateral quality, all other
factors are calculated for each bond at each week using a rolling window of past 60-week
observations. The weekly lending fee or credit rating is calculated as the weekly average of daily
observations. Credit rating is a series of numeric values with 1 referring to CCC, 2 to CC-,... and 21 to
AAA. The t-statistics based on Newey-West adjusted standard errors are given in squared brackets.
*, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Panel A. Before Crisis (Jul 2006


- Jun 2007) Panel B. Crisis I (Jul 2007 - Aug 2008)

-0.005 -0.003
Lending Fee 0.000 0.000 *** ***

[-1.4 [0.718 [-4.61 [-3.00


99] ] 3] 8]

0.070** 0.074* 0.622 0.570


Credit Rating * ** *** ***

[7.24 [3.863 [6.79 [7.246


5] ] 3] ]

Bond Illiquidity 0.000* -0.00


(level) * -0.020 4 -0.236

[-2.05 [-1.45 [-1.22 [-0.85


5] 3] 5] 0]

Bond Liquidity -0.345 -0.465


Risk 0.003 0.001 *** ***

[0.114 [0.080 [-2.86 [-4.09


] ] 1] 6]

Bond Liquidity -0.807


Mkt Risk -0.004 -0.022 *
-0.82

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


2

[-0.23 [-1.16 [-1.58 [-1.92


7] 6] 6] 1]

Counterparty 0.000 0.059* -0.003 -0.181


Risk *** ** *** ***

[3.05 [4.363 [-4.50 [-2.56


1] ] 8] 3]

Funding [0.019 0.00 0.132


Liquidity Risk 0.000 ] 1 **

[1.15 [1.038 [1.5 [2.336


8] ] 98] ]

0.14 [0.356 0.04


Adj. R2 7 0.101 0.056 0.022 ] 0.263 0.113 0.057 3 0.408

Panel D. Post Crisis (Oct 2009 -


Panel C. Crisis II (Sep 2008 - Sep 2009) Dec 2014)

-0.004 -0.004 -0.002* -0.001


Lending Fee *** *** ** ***

[-2.6 [-2.57 [-5.00


89] 8] [-5.640] 7]

2.12 1.902* 0.739** 0.779


Credit Rating 4*** ** * ***

[7.77 [6.780 [27.213 [22.58


1] ] ] 0]

Bond Illiquidity -0.009 [-0.67 -0.001


(level) *** 6] *** 0.002

[-4.12 [-3.15 [-2.8 [0.107


3] 6] 16] ]

Bond Liquidity 0.538 -0.00


Risk ** 0.101 1 0.006

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


[2.34 [0.391 [-0.0 [0.508
4] ] 65] ]

Bond Liquidity 1.269 0.517* -0.01 0.033


Mkt Risk *** * 7 *

[4.72 [1.722 [-1.4 [2.172


5] ] 94] ]

Counterparty -0.007 -0.545* -0.002 0.163


Risk *** ** *** ***

[-6.0 [-5.21 [-7.7 [8.313


33] 6] 14] ]

Funding 0.010* 0.794* 0.00


Liquidity Risk ** ** 0 0.039

[5.30 [3.706 [0.7 [0.767


2] ] 52] ]

0.21 0.03 0.08 0.02 0.14


Adj. R2 5 0.075 7 0 0.366 0.287 2 0.025 5 0.442

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Table IV: The CDS-Bond Basis Portfolios Sorted by Size and Rating

Each week we construct corporate bond portfolios based on bond outstanding amount and bond
rating. Bond size is divided into four categories based on the 25th, 50th, 75th percentiles of the
whole sample, and bond rating is categorized into six bins including AAA/AA, A, BBB, BB, B, and
CCC&Below. There are a total of 24 portfolios. The sample is limited to negative basis only. Panel A
reports the average basis value (bps) for each portfolio. Panel B reports the average coefficients
from the Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions of the CDS-bond bases for 24 portfolios on risk
factors including collateral quality, three proxies of bond trading liquidity and liquidity risk,
counterparty risk, and funding liquidity risk. The regression is conducted at the weekly frequency for
444 weeks from July 2006 to December 2014. Except collateral quality proxies, all other factors are
calculated for each bond at each week using a rolling window of past 60-week observations. The
weekly collateral quality is calculated as the weekly average of daily corporate bond loan lending
fee. The t-statistics based on Newey-West adjusted standard errors are given in squared brackets. *,
**, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Panel A. Average basis (bps) for portfolios sorted by size and rating

AAA/AA A BBB BB B CCC&Below

Small -126 -125 -201 -258 -318 -534

2 -79 -103 -146 -229 -283 -487

3 -75 -105 -132 -240 -285 -436

Large -79 -98 -130 -238 -266 -631

Panel B. Fama-MacBeth Regression Results

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Before Crisis Crisis I Crisis II Post Crisis

Lending Fee 0.000 -0.007*** -0.005*** -0.004***

[1.371] [-4.927] [-3.224] [-6.431]

Credit Rating 0.111*** 0.542*** 1.268*** 0.702***

[-5.431] [12.294] [10.039] [35.092]

Bond Illiquidity (level) -0.083*** 0.013 -0.261 0.261***

[-2.650] [0.081] [-1.119] [5.831]

Bond Liquidity Risk -0.053 -0.622*** -0.421 0.312***

[-1.007] [-5.803] [-1.430] [4.691]

Bond Liquidity Mkt Risk 0.020 -0.503*** 0.809*** 0.000

[0.517] [-2.491] [2.506] [0.040]

Counterparty Risk 0.145*** -0.281*** -0.800*** 0.118***

[5.598] [-3.924] [-6.425] [2.450]

Funding Liquidity Risk -0.011 0.111 0.720*** 0.156***

[-0.371] [1.150] [3.431] [2.696]

Adj. R2 0.799 0.759 0.774 0.839

Appendix

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


A. The Par-Equivalent CDS Methodology

We present the Par Equivalent CDS methodology developed by J.P. Morgan to calculate the
CDS-bond basis in Section 2. This survival-based valuation approach provides an apple-to-apple
measure across the cash-bond spread and the credit default swap spread.

The fair value of the coupon on a CDS is set so that the expected present value of the premium
leg is equal to the expected present value of the contingent payment (see Duffie (1999)). Assuming
that we have a zero-coupon discount curve extracted from swap spreads and assuming a
constant intensity survival probability , the expected present value of the premium leg is given
by:

∑ ∑ (9)

where the second component is the present value of the accrued interest upon default (assumed to
occur halfway between and ). The expected present value of the contingent leg is:

∑ (10)

where stands for the recovery rate. The fair credit default swap spread is the number that
sets

(11)

The par-equivalent CDS uses the market price of a bond to calculate a spread based on
CDS-implied default probabilities. First, we need to get a CDS-implied default probability curve
by sequentially plugging in CDS spread with maturity from 1-year to 10-year. Second, we
need to get a bond-implied survival probability curve . Using the CDS-implied survival

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


probability as a prior, we calculate the bond-implied survival probability curve as the one that
minimize the pricing error between the market price and derived bond price:

(12)

(13)

Then the bond-implied CDS spread term structure is defined by substituting the survival probability
term structure fitted from bond prices, , into the following equation for par equivalent CDS
spreads, denoted as PECDS:


(14)
∑ [ ]

B. The Primary Dealers List

Below is the list of primary dealers as of July 27, 2009, reported on the website of the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York.

BNP Paribas Securities Corp.

Banc of America Securities LLC

Barclays Capital Inc.

Cantor Fitzgerald & Co.

Citigroup Global Markets Inc.

Credit Suisse Securities (USA) LLC

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.


Daiwa Securities America Inc.

Deutsche Bank Securities Inc.

Goldman, Sachs & Co.

HSBC Securities (USA) Inc.

Jefferies & Company, Inc.

J. P. Morgan Securities Inc.

Mizuho Securities USA Inc.

Morgan Stanley & Co. Incorporated

Nomura Securities International, Inc.

RBC Capital Markets Corporation

RBS Securities Inc.

UBS Securities LLC.

This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.

You might also like