Incentive-Based Strategies: Market Trading Systems: General Principles
Incentive-Based Strategies: Market Trading Systems: General Principles
13
Incentive-Based
Strategies: Market
Trading Systems
An effluent charge requires that some central public authority establish a charge
rate, monitor the performance of each polluter, and then collect the tax bills. It
is essentially an interaction between polluters and public authorities in which
we might expect the same type of adversarial relationship we get in any tax
system. In this chapter we take a look at a policy approach that, while incorpo-
rating economic incentives, is designed to work in a more decentralized fash-
ion. Rather than leaving everything to a centralized public agency, it works
through decentralized market interactions in which polluters may buy and sell
emission permits, and pollution is controlled by linking emissions with the
number of permits held.
These programs have proliferated in recent years. The most well known
in the United States is the sulfur dioxide (SO2) trading scheme introduced
as part of the Clean Air Act of 1990. A nitrous oxide (NOx) trading plan was
started among a group of eastern states in 1999. California has started several
programs within its own borders. The countries of the European Union have
recently inaugurated a multicountry trading plan to reduce carbon dioxide
(CO2) emissions.
General Principles
We can distinguish three types of trading systems for achieving more efficient
pollution control:
r Offset trading
r Emission rate trading
r Cap-and-trade (CAP)
245
Offset trading initially came about to address a very practical problem: how
to limit environmental pollution but still be able to accommodate economic
growth. Under the original Clean Air Act of 1970, situations evolved (espe-
cially in Southern California) where all existing firms were subject to regula-
tory emission standards, but the air quality in the region was nevertheless still
below standard. How to allow the growth of new firms, but avoid making air
pollution worse? The answer was to allow new firms to pay existing firms to
reduce their emissions below standard so as to offset the added emissions of
the new firms. Trades of this type, since it involved transactions between two
firms subject to regulatory control, were sometimes called credit trading. But
offset-type trading can also occur between any two, or more, entities, whether
or not they are under regulatory control. For example, if the selling firm is not
under regulatory limits, they may be able to reduce their emissions below the
level that would exist if an agreement was not reached, and sell the resulting
offset to another entity that wishes to offset its emissions, either because it is re-
quired to, or it voluntarily choses to. One of the most well-known examples of
offset trading is the Clean Development Mechanism under the Kyoto Protocol
to reduce greenhouse gases. We will encounter this in Chapter 18.
Emission rate trading takes place in terms of the rate that a pollutant con-
stitutes in total output. For example, a greenhouse gas emission rate might be
defined in terms of tons of CO2 per 1,000 megawatt hours of power produc-
tion. After a base rate is set, either voluntarily or through regulation, trading
would take place between sources. Sources that are willing and able to reduce
their emission rate below the base would sell allowances to sources that want to
continue to operate at a rate higher than the base. We will discuss this in more
detail later in this chapter.
Cap-and-trade programs work a little differently. The first step in a CAP pro-
gram is to make a centralized decision (by a regulatory agency or some other
collective entity) on the aggregate quantity of emissions to be allowed. Permits
are then written in accordance with this quantity. These permits are then dis-
tributed among the sources responsible for the emissions. Some formula must
be used to determine how many permits each source will receive; we will come
back to this problem later. Assuming that the total number of permits is less
than current total emissions, some or all emitters will receive fewer permits
than their current emissions.
Cap-and-Trade
Suppose, for example, that a CAP program has been instituted to reduce the
amount of sulfur emitted by a group of power plants. Current total emissions
are, say, 150,000 tons of sulfur per year, and policymakers have decided that
this must be reduced to 100,000 tons per year. Let’s focus on the situation
of one of the power plants, which is depicted in Figure 13.1. We suppose
it is emitting 5,000 tons of sulfur currently. Under the program, the plant
$ MAC
60
40 Permit price
20
0 18 25 35 50
Emissions (100 tons)
is initially given 2,500 discharge permits. The plant manager now has three
choices:
1. Reduce the emissions to the level covered by the number of permits the plant
was initially awarded.
2. Buy additional permits and emit at levels higher than the original award
level (e.g., buy 1,000 permits to add to its 2,500 initial distribution, so its
emissions would now be 3,500 tons/year).
3. Reduce emissions below the level of the original award, then sell the permits it
doesn’t need (e.g., reduce emissions to 1,800 tons/year and sell 1,000 permits).
Note that whether the firm is a buyer or seller of permits depends on the
relationship of the price of permits and their marginal abatement costs at the
emission level corresponding to their initial permit holding.
1. If the original award is 1,800 permits, the firm’s marginal abatement costs
would be $60/ton; with a permit price of $40, it can improve its situation by
buying 700 permits and increasing its emissions to 2,500 tons.
2. If its original allocation is 3,500 permits, its marginal abatement costs
would be lower than the permit price; it can improve its situation by selling
1,000 permits and reducing its emission to 2,500 tons.
Now think of a situation involving an industry where there are a large num-
ber of firms and each one is emitting a pollutant we wish to control with a cap-
and-trade program. An overall level of aggregate emissions is set by the
authorities, and transferable permits are allocated to each firm according to some
formula. Marginal abatement costs can be expected to differ among firms, based
on different production and pollution-control technologies available to each.
Some sources will be potential buyers of permits (MAC > permit price), and some
firms will be potential sellers (MAC < permit price). There are gains from trade to
be had by the sources, by buying and selling permits, in effect rearranging the to-
tal number of permits (which has been fixed by the authorities) among the plants.
It is important to note, now, that each firm will be in a situation analogous
to the one depicted in Figure 13.1. By buying or selling permits, they move to
a situation where marginal abatement costs are equal to the price of permits.
Assuming there is a single overall market for permits, and therefore a single
market price for them, this means that the trading of permits among the firms
will result in a cost-effective reduction in total emission, because each firm will
end up equating its marginal abatement costs to the single permit price. Cost-
effectiveness in cap-and-trade programs requires that that there be a single
market for permits, where suppliers and demanders may interact openly and
where knowledge of transactions prices is publicly available to all participants.
The normal forces of competition would then bring about a single price for
permits. The permits would in general flow from sources with relatively low
marginal abatement costs to those with high marginal abatement costs.
A permit market is depicted in Figure 13.2. The demand for permits is simply
the aggregate marginal abatement cost functions of all the firms participating
in the market. The supply of permits is the quantity in the cap as initially estab-
lished by public authorities; the supply curve is vertical at that quantity.
Demand
$ for permits
Supply of permits
p2
p1
q2 q1
Quantity of permits
argue that those firms that, out of a good conscience or for any reason, have
already invested in emission reduction should not now be penalized, in effect,
by receiving emission permits in proportion to these lower emission levels.1
This tends to reward firms that have dragged their feet in the past.2 It could go
even further. If polluters believe that permits will soon be allocated in this way,
1
When we study (in Chapter 15) the Clean Air Act of 1990, we will see that this was the source of
great conflict when the details of the SO2 trading program were being hammered out.
2
This is just another example of the perverse incentives built into any program that asks
everybody to cut their consumption by x percent from their current rate. It favors those who have
consumed at high rates in the past and hurts those who have tried hard to live frugally.
they may have the incentive to increase today’s emission rate because this would
give them a larger base for the initial allocation of permits.
Each allocation formula has its problems, and those setting the cap must find
some workable compromise if the approach is to be widely accepted. Closely re-
lated to this issue is the question of whether the rights should be given away or
perhaps sold or auctioned. In principle it doesn’t matter as long as the permits
get distributed fairly widely. Subsequent market transactions will redistribute
them in accordance with the relative marginal abatement costs of polluters,
whatever the original distribution may have been. But free distribution of per-
mits will confer windfall gains on the recipients, the amount of which would
depend on the market price of the permits. What a sale or auction would do is
transfer some of the original value of the rights into the hands of the auctioning
agency. This might be a good way for public agencies to raise funds for worthy
projects, but it has to be recognized that a plan like this would create political
objections. A hybrid system would be to distribute a certain number of permits
free and then auction some number of additional permits. Or a small surcharge
might be put on permits in the original distribution.
3
David Freestone and Charlotte Streck, Legal Aspects of Carbon Trading: Kyoto, Copenhagen, and
Beyond, Oxford University Press, Oxford, U.K., 2009.
prevailing
wind
Nonuniform Emissions
Suppose we are trying to design a CAP program to control total airborne SO2
emissions in a region where there are numerous different sources—power plants,
industrial plants, and so on—scattered rather widely around the area. A sche-
matic of this situation is depicted in Figure 13.3. All of the emission points are not
equally situated relative to the prevailing wind or to the area of highest popula-
tion density. Some sources are upwind, others are downwind, of the populated
area. We assume they are not all equal in terms of marginal abatement costs, but
neither are they equal in terms of the impact of their emissions on ambient SO2
levels over the populated area. In technical terms, they have different transfer
coefficients linking their own emissions with damages in the urban area.
Having distributed discharge permits, we now allow them to be traded.
As long as the number of permits in circulation is held constant, we have
effectively controlled total SO2 emissions. But if we allow straight trading, unit
for unit, of permits among all sources, the damage caused by that total could
change. For example, if a downwind firm sold permits to an upwind firm, the
total number of permits would remain the same but there would now be more
emissions upwind of the population, and therefore more damage.4
The problem is similar to the one encountered under the effluent charge pol-
icy; in effect each firm is differently situated relative to the damage area, so the
4
This is sometimes called the “hotspot” problem.
emissions of each will have a different impact on ambient quality in that area.
If the program were simply to allow trading of permits among all sources on a
one-for-one basis, it could easily come to pass that a firm or group of firms with
higher transfer coefficients, whose emissions therefore have a greater impact on
ambient quality, could accumulate larger numbers of permits.
One way to get around this might be to adjust the trading rules to take
into account the impacts of individual sources. Suppose the emissions from
Source A were twice as damaging as the emissions of Source B simply because
of the location of the two sources. Then the administrators of the program
might set a rule that if Source A is buying permits from Source B, it must buy
two permits to get one. If this principle is extended to a situation with many
sources, things can quickly get very complicated. Authorities would have to
determine, for each source, how many permits would have to be purchased
from each other source in order for the purchasing source to be credited with
one new permit. If there were five sources, the agency would have to figure
out only 10 such trading ratios, but if there were 20 different sources, it would
have to estimate 190 of these ratios.5 One way around this would be to use a
zoned system, analogous to the zoned effluent charge we talked about earlier.
Authorities would designate a series of zones, each of which would contain
sources that were relatively similar in terms of their location and the impact of
their emissions on ambient quality. Four such zones are shown in Figure 13.3.
Authorities then could do one of two things: (1) allow trading by firms only
with other firms in the same zone or (2) make adjustments for all trades across
zone boundaries similar to the technique discussed previously. Thus, for ex-
ample, if sources in Zone A were judged to have transfer coefficients twice the
size, on average, as sources in Zone B, any trade between sources in these two
zones would be adjusted by that same factor of two: Any firm in Zone A buy-
ing permits from any firm in Zone B would have to buy two permits in order
to get credit for one new one; any source in Zone B would have to buy only
half a permit from a firm in Zone A to get credit for one new permit.
5
In general, if there were n sources, there would have to be [n(n − 1)]/2 trading ratios established.
But this may work against the ecological facts. In many cases there may be
meteorological or hydrological reasons for limiting the trading area to a rela-
tively narrow geographical area. If the objective was to control airborne emis-
sions affecting a particular city, for example, we would probably not want
to allow firms located there to trade permits with firms in another city. Or if
our concern is controlling emissions into a particular lake or river, we could
not allow sources located there to trade permits with sources located on some
entirely different body of water. Thus, for environmental reasons, it may well
be desirable to have trading areas restricted, whereas for economic reasons we
would want to have trading areas defined broadly. There is no magic rule to
tell exactly how these two factors should be balanced in all cases. Authorities
can only look at specific cases as they arise and weigh the particularities of the
environmental features with the subtleties of the competitive conditions in the
industries where trading will occur.
MAC1
MAC2
$
p Price of permits
c
e a
d
b
0
e2 e1
Emissions (tons/year)
at least in theory. Consider the firm in Figure 13.4. Suppose that at present the
firm’s marginal abatement cost function is MAC1. Emission permits sell for p
each, and let us assume that this price is not expected to change. The firm has
adjusted its holdings so that it currently owns e1 permits.6 Its emissions are
therefore e1 and its total abatement costs are (a + b). The incentive to do research
and development (R&D) is to find a less costly way of controlling emissions, so
the firm can cut emissions and sell the surplus permits. How much would it be
worth to get marginal abatement costs shifted to MAC2? With MAC2, the firm
would shift to an emissions level of e2. Its total abatement costs here would be
(b + d), but it would be able to sell (e1 − e2) permits for a revenue of p(e1 − e2) =
(c + d). The change in its position would thus be:
Total abatement costs Total abatement costs Receipts from
− − CAP sale
with MAC1 with MAC2
or (a + b) − (d + b) + (c + d), which equals (a + c). Check this with the savings un-
der an effluent charge (see Chapter 12). It is exactly the same. The market price
of the permit has the same incentive as a pollution charge; by not reducing their
emissions, firms are forgoing the increased revenues they could have obtained
by selling some of their permits.
6
These marginal abatement cost functions apply to a year; that is, they are the costs per year of
changing emissions. The price p is therefore a one-year purchase (or sale) price—what it would
cost to buy or sell a permit for just one year.
Offset Trading
Most emissions trading carried out in the absence of an authoritative cap comes un-
der the heading of offset trading. Purchasers of offsets are entities who wish to com-
pensate for their increase in emissions; sellers of offsets are entities who will reduce
emissions in a quantity sufficient to compensate for the emissions of the buyers.
Offset demand may result from firms subject to legal limits on their activities.
Many states now have statutory requirements that power companies generate
some portion of their output from renewable sources (often called renewable
portfolio requirements). It is acceptable, in most cases, that they are allowed to
meet this requirement in part by buying renewable power offsets, usually from
firms who build and operate new renewable power plants.
Offset markets may also be formed as a result of voluntarily accepted limits
on emissions. For a number of years, the Chicago Climate Exchange provided
this type of institution. Each voluntary participant agreed to a reduction in
emissions of greenhouse gases, for example, perhaps by 5 or 10 percent. Indi-
vidual participants who exceeded this reduction could sell the resulting cred-
its to participants who were unable or unwilling to reduce emissions by the
required amount. 9
7
This happened in the early stages of the European greenhouse gas program.
8
This happened in the California Reclaim market in the 1990s.
9
The Chicago Climate Exchange was merged into the Intercontinental Exchange in 2010.
10
Molly Peters-Stanley and Gloria Gonzalez, Sharing the Stage, State of the Voluntary Carbon Markets
2014, Report by Forest Trends’ Ecosystem Marketplace, July 2014.
The lead market, which was national in scope, was widely used in the transi-
tion to low-lead gas. The EPA estimates that it probably saved several hundreds
of millions of dollars in total transition costs. Its success has been chalked up to
two main points:
r initial widespread agreement on the overall goal of phasing out leaded gas and
r the ease of monitoring the amount of lead in gas.
Although the lead trading program was a success in easing the lead “phase-
down,” getting lead out of gas was not achieved without compensating envi-
ronmental costs. People wanted less lead, but they also still wanted high engine
performance. Thus, the octane ratings of gasoline were to some extent main-
tained by substituting other compounds for lead.
Summary
Programs of transferable discharge permits have become popular. One of
the first such programs was the SO2 control CAP in the 1990 Clean Air Act
Amendments. CAP programs for the control of greenhouse gas emissions have
been initiated in Europe and in California. The spirit behind this approach, the
transfer of emission rights from sources with low control costs to those with
high costs, is also behind some recent developments in the control of nonpoint-
source waterborne emissions; we will discuss these in the chapter on water
pollution (see Chapter 14). There is the expectation that this approach could
give us pollution control at a substantially lower cost than the current system
of technology-based effluent standards, and also a sense that, politically, these
programs would be more acceptable than emission charges.
But CAP programs come with their own set of problems. Most especially,
CAP programs take some of the burden of pollution control out of the hands
of engineers and place it under the operation of a market. How that market
operates is obviously critical to whether this type of policy will work. There is a
host of important factors: who gets the permits at the beginning, the strength of
their incentives to minimize costs, the degree of competition in the market, the
transaction rules set by the administering public agency, the ability to monitor
and enforce compliance, and so on. Besides CAP programs, several other trad-
ing systems are common. Offset markets, both voluntary and regulatory, are
widespread, particularly in efforts to reduce global greenhouse gas emissions.
Emission rate trading systems have also been used, for example, in phasing out
leaded gasoline.
Both transferable discharge systems and emission charge systems seek to take
the burden and responsibility of making technical pollution-control decisions out
of the hands of central administrators and put them into the hands of polluters
themselves. They are not, we should stress, aimed at putting pollution-control ob-
jectives themselves into the hands of the polluters. It is not the market that is going
to determine the most efficient level of pollution control for society. Rather, these
systems are the means of enlisting the incentives of the polluters themselves in
finding more effective ways of meeting the overall objective of reducing emissions.
4. What are the pros and cons of letting anybody (banks, private citizens, envi-
ronmental groups, government agencies, etc.) buy and sell transferable dis-
charge permits, in addition to emission sources themselves?
5. Most of the carbon offsets traded globally are being bought by corporations,
many of which are not currently subject to emission restrictions. Why do you
think this is the case?
For additional readings and Web sites pertaining to the material in this chapter,
see www.mhhe.com/field7e.