Business & Economic Forecasting: Managerial Economics
Business & Economic Forecasting: Managerial Economics
Economic
Forecasting
Managerial Economics
“Part of my advantage is that my strength is economic
forecasting, but that only works in free markets, when
markets are smarter than people. That’s how I started. I
watched the stock market, how equities reacted to
change in levels of economic activity, and I could
understand how price signals worked and how to forecast
them.” –Stanley Druckenmiller (an American investor,
hedge fund manager and philanthropist)
Economic forecasting is the process of attempting to predict the future condition of the economy using a
Economic forecasting involves the building of statistical models with inputs of several key variables, or
indicators, typically in an attempt to come up with a future gross domestic product (GDP) growth rate.
Primary economic indicators include inflation, interest rates, industrial production, consumer
activities. Private sector companies may have in-house economists to focus on forecasts most
pertinent to their specific businesses (e.g., a shipping company that wants to know how much of GDP
growth is driven by trade.) Alternatively, they might rely on Reports or academic economists, those
The classical approach to business forecasting assumes that an economic time series can be
decomposed into four (4) components: trend, seasonal variation, cyclical variation, and irregular
movements.
If the trend in a time series is LINEAR, simple regression may be used to estimate an equation
The seasonal variation in a particular time series is described by a figure for each month (the
seasonal index) that shows the extent to which the month’s value typically departs from what
would be expected on the basis of trend and cyclical variation. Such seasonal indexes can be used
to deseasonalize a time series, that is, to remove seasonal element from the data.
A seasonal index is a measure of how a particular season through some
This cyclical variation, as well as trend and seasonal variation, is reflected in many time series. It is
customary to divide business fluctuations into four phases: TROUGH, EXPANSION, PEAK and RECESSION.
Variables that go down before the peak and up before the trough are called leading series. Some important
leading series are new orders for durable goods, average work week, building contracts, stock prices, certain
a turning point is about to occur. If a large number of leading indicators turn downward, this is viewed
as a sign of a coming peak. If a large number turn upward, this is thought to signal an impending
trough. Although these indicators are not very reliable, they are watched closely and are used to
for seasonal variation, such an extrapolation can be multiplied by the seasonal index (divided
by 100) for the month to which the forecast applies. This entire procedure is simply a
In recent years, managerial economists have tended to base their forecasts less on simple
extrapolations and more on equations (or systems of equations) showing the effects of various
independent variables on the variable (or variable) one wants to forecast. These equations (or
Managerial Economics
Reference: Managerial Economics by Luke M. Froeb, etal
In 1906, three entrepreneurs launched the French Battery Company in
demand for radio batteries, and its most successful product was the Ray-
O-Vac battery, leading the firm to change its name to Rayovac in 1930.
Over the next 60 years, it grew to become one of the top three battery
fall.
In 2003, Rayovac purchased Remington Products (electric razors); in 2005, it purchased
United Industries Corporation (lawn and garden care, household insect control, and pet
supplies) and Tetra Holding GmbH, a German supplier of fish and aquatic supplies. To
reflect its position as a provider of a broad portfolio of products, the company changed its
name to Spectrum Brands in 2005.
Managers often justified the company’s expansions into these new areas with claims of cost
savings.
For example, as part of its acquisition of United Industries, Spectrum’s managers anticipated
“that there would be synergies*, better performance, and all that.”
As is often the case, it is much easier to describe synergies than it is to capture them, and
although it’s not clear whether this was the case for Spectrum, the company declared
bankruptcy in 2009.
*Synergy is the concept that the value and performance of two companies combined will be greater than
the sum of the separate individual parts. If two companies can merge to create greater efficiency or scale,
the result is what is sometimes referred to as a synergy merge. (Source: Investopedia)
Since emerging from bankruptcy, Spectrum has
strategy.
A reduction in average cost translates to an immediate increase in profit. If marginal cost
(MC) goes down as well, you get an “extra” increase in profit from the increase in output;
remember that if MC falls below marginal revenue (MR), it becomes profitable to increase
output.
Many business decisions, like break-even analysis, can be made using very simple
characterizations of cost (like a fixed cost plus a constant per-unit cost). With economies
of scale or scope, however, decision making may require more complex (and realistic) cost
functions.
INCREASING MARGINAL COST
Most firms will eventually face increasing average costs as they try to increase output.
The firm finds that each extra unit of output requires more inputs to produce than
The law of diminishing marginal returns states that as you try to expand output, your
marginal productivity (the extra output associated with extra inputs) eventually declines.
INCREASING
MARGINAL
COST
THE LAW OF
DIMINISHING RETURNS
Diminishing marginal returns occur for a variety of reasons, among them are the difficulty of
monitoring and motivating larger workforces, the increasing complexity of larger systems, or the
Bottlenecks often arise when more workers, or any variable input, must share a fixed amount of
Here’s a famous example: In 1955, Akio Morita brought his newly invented $29.95 transistor
radio to New York. He shopped it around, and after turning down an original equipment
manufacturer (OEM) deal from Bulova, he eventually found a retailer that would sell it under
his “Sony” brand name. The problem was that the retailer had a chain of around 150 stores
and wanted to buy 100,000 radios, 10 times more than Mr. Morita’s capacity. Mr. Morita
turned the offer down. He knew that he would lose money producing 100,000 units because
increasing output would require hiring and training more workers and an expansion of
facilities, raising his average cost or break-even price.
After being turned down, the retailer agreed to
settle for 10,000 units at the lowest unit price,
and the rest is history. The Sony brand radios
became very popular, and the company evolved
into the giant electronics firm it is today. The
moral of the story is to know what your costs look
like—otherwise, you could end up making
unprofitable deals. In this case, using a more
realistic cost function, Morita was able to compute
his break-even prices, allowing him to bargain
effectively with the retail chain.
ECONOMIES OF SCALE
the long run, however, you can increase the size of the
✓ If long-run average costs are constant with respect to output, then you have
✓ If long-run average costs rise with output, you have decreasing returns to scale or
diseconomies of scale.
✓ If long-run average costs fall with output, you have increasing returns to scale or
economies of scale.
ECONOMIES
OF SCALE
Economies of scale can result from a variety of areas.
Obviously, you want to exploit economies of scope by producing both Q1 and Q2. This
is a major cause of mergers.
For example, about eight years ago, we saw a consolidation in the food distribution
business. Companies like Kraft, Sara Lee, and ConAgra sell a variety of meat products,
hotdogs, sausage, and lunchmeats because they can derive economies of scope by
distributing these products together. Once you set up a distribution network, you can
easily pump more products through the network without incurring additional costs.
ECONOMIES OF SCOPE
These low costs put pressure on their competitors, in particular, a regional breakfast
sausage manufacturer in 1997. This manufacturer used 18 trucks and a single
distribution center that served retail customers located in 21 southern and Midwestern
states. Unfortunately, the demand for breakfast sausage is seasonal, with a peak in
November and December. During the heavy winter months, the manufacturer had to pay
outside carriers a premium to handle excess product, but for the other eight months, half
of its trucking fleet sat idle.
ECONOMIES OF SCOPE
Because the firm sold only a single product—breakfast sausage—it could not exploit the
scope economies associated with distributing a full product line. The manufacturer had several
choices. It could have acquired other companies to have a full product line to distribute. It
could have sold out to one of the larger, full-line companies, like ConAgra. Such a company
could exploit the scope economies associated with distribution, thus placing a higher value on
the firm. Or it could have outsourced its distribution function. Several regional and nationwide
distribution companies distribute a variety of food products, and these companies could take
MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
LECTURE #6
Reference: Managerial Economics by Luke M. Froeb, etal
In 1971, three partners opened a coffee shop in Seattle’s Pike
Place Market. Two of the partners wanted to name the store after
the ship Pequod from the Moby Dick, but the third disagreed.
Eventually they agreed to name the store after the Pequod’s first
mate. The company enjoyed mild growth until 1988 when the
partners agreed to sell the company to their former director of
retail operations and marketing.
Over the following 20-plus years, that director has overseen the
expansion of the company to over 17,000 worldwide stores as yet
- Starbuck was the first mate on the Pequod and that former
director of retail operations is Howard Schultz, the current CEO
of the world’s largest coffee retailer, Starbuck’s.
system) create a moat around the business such that it can keep
less expand, its moat over time. Moats are rarely enduring for
company to achieve superior margin compared to its competition and generates value for
There are two schools of thought that offer differing points of view:
possess market power, which allows them to keep prices above the
cost of capital).
SOURCES OF Here’s the logic:
ECONOMIC PROFIT
Industry structure determines firm conduct, and that conduct, in
ECONOMIC PROFIT
If industry structure told the whole story about the strategy, we wouldn’t
expect to find performance differences across firms within industries.
SOURCES OF The Resource (Internal) View
ECONOMIC PROFIT
These differences do exist, however, and the resource-based view
(RBV) gained favor in the 1990s as an explanation for the inter-firm
differences.
ECONOMIC PROFIT
Two primary assumptions underlie the RBV:
1. Resource heterogeneity
2. Resource mobility