Blanchard Perotti (2002)
Blanchard Perotti (2002)
Blanchard Perotti (2002)
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access
to The Quarterly Journal of Economics
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE DYNAMIC
EFFECTS OF CHANGES IN GOVERNMENT SPENDING
AND TAXES ON OUTPUT*
I. INTRODUCTION
* We thank the editor and the two referees for useful comments. We thank
James Poterba, Robert Solow, and seminar participants at Bocconi University,
Catholic University in Milan, Columbia University, New York University, Prince-
ton University, University of Mannheim, the Bank of Italy, the ESSIM conference
in Sintra, Portugal, and the NBER Summer Institute for comments and sugges-
tions. Conversations with Christopher Sims also helped us clarify several issues.
We thank Eric Hilt and Douglas Smith for excellent research assistance, Jonas
Fisher for sharing his data, and Jonathan Gruber for help with the data. We
thank the National Science Foundation for financial support. The data, together
with the details of data construction and estimation, and the results mentioned
but not reported in the text, are available at http://www.iue.it/Personal/Perotti
and http://web.mit.edu/blanchar/www/.
o 2002 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of
Technology.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 2002
1329
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1330 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1331
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1332 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
A. The VAR
1. Any decomposition and choice of two fiscal variables reflects one's theoretical
priors. Ours is no exception and reflects our belief that, in the short run, fiscal policy
works mainly through the effect of spending and taxes on aggregate demand and the
effect of aggregate demand on output. A researcher who viewed fluctuations instead
as real business cycles and believed in Ricardian equivalence, would likely choose a
different two-variable decomposition, such as government consumption and govern-
ment investment, or government spending and the marginal tax rate.
2. We use the GDP deflator to express the variables in real terms. This allows
us to express the impulse responses as shares of GDP. Results using the own
deflator to express spending in real terms are very similar.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1333
it will be equal to zero and thus will not depend on GDP.3 We have
collected evidence on quarter dependence in tax collection over
the sample period from various institutional sources. The Appen-
dix lists the main relevant features of the tax code.4
B. Identification
We now discuss our identification methodology. Without loss
of generality, we can write
(2) tt = a ix + a2eg + et
(3) gt bxt + b2et + e
and
and spending programs
b1. A priori, to construct could
these coefficients the parameters al
capture two
different effects of activity on taxes and spending: the
automatic effects of economic activity on taxes and spend-
ing under existing fiscal policy rules, and any discretion-
ary adjustment made to fiscal policy in response to unex-
pected events within the quarter. The key to our
identification procedure is to recognize that the use of
quarterly data virtually eliminates the second channel.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1334 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
(5)~ a1 = j Th'B, i
ThY
(5) a, =I~~al-- Z q Oti ,.
where T1Ti,Bi denotes the elasticity of taxes of type i t
their tax base, and Bi,,X denotes the elasticity of the ta
base to GDP.
To construct these elasticities, we extend earlier work
by the OECD [Giorno et al. 1995], who have constructed
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1335
7. The value ofa 1 varies over time, both because the ratios of individual taxes
and transfers to net taxes-the terms Ti/T in expression (5) above-and the tax
base elasticities of tax revenues-the terms ITq Bs-have changed over time. The
fact that a1 varies over the sample sugges& 'time variation in the dynamic
responses of spending and taxes to activity, and thus time variation of the VAR.
Except for tests of subsample stability reported later, we have not explored this
time variation further.
One implicit assumption in our construction of a, is that the relation between
the various tax bases and GDP is invariant to the type of shock affecting output.
For broad-based taxes, such as income taxes, this is probably fine. It is more
questionable, say, for corporate profit taxes: the relation of corporate profits to
GDP may well vary depending on the type of shock affecting GDP.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1336 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
C. Impulse Responses
Having identified the tax and spending shocks, we can study
their effects on GDP. We face two issues here. The first is that the
constructed elasticity of net taxes to output, a1, varies over time.
We ignore this here and compute the impulse response using the
mean value of a1 over the sample, i.e., 2.08. Second, one of the
implications of quarter dependence is that the effects of fiscal
policy vary depending on which quarter the shock takes place. To
avoid estimating four different impulse responses, we estimate
the covariance matrix from the quarter dependent VAR, and then
use a VAR estimated without quarter dependence (except for
additive seasonality) to characterize the dynamic effects of the
shocks. Thus, our impulse responses give, admittedly only in a
loose sense, the average dynamic response to fiscal shocks.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1337
eral government, i.e., the sum of the federal, state, and local
governments, and social security funds.9 All the data are season-
ally adjusted by the original source, using some variant of the X11
method.10
A. High-Frequency Properties
Figure I displays the behavior of the ratio of government
spending (i.e., purchases of goods and services) and of net taxes
(i.e., taxes minus transfers) to GDP over the longest available
sample, 1947:1 to 1997:4. It is obvious that these series display a
few extremely large quarterly changes in taxes and spending,
well above three times their standard deviations of 4.3 percent
and 1.9 percent, respectively.
There are two particularly striking changes in net taxes.
First, the increase in 1950:2 by about 26 percent (more than six
times the standard deviation), followed by a further increase in
1950:3 by about 17 percent (or about four times the standard
deviation). These episodes represent in part the reversal of the
temporary 8 percent fall in net taxes in 1950:1, caused by a large
one-time payment of National Service Life Insurance benefits to
the war veterans; but mostly they represent a genuine increase in
tax revenues. The second episode is the large temporary tax
rebate of 1975:2, which results in a net tax drop by about 33
percent for one quarter.11
On the expenditure side, the Korean War stands out: in
1951:1, at the onset of the Korean War buildup, government
spending increases by 10 percent (more than five times the stan-
dard deviation), and continues to grow at about the same quar-
terly rate during the next two quarters, 1951:2 and 1951:3; after
this, spending continues to increase at more than twice the stan-
dard deviation in 1951:4 and again in 1952:2. It is difficult to
think of the early 1950s as being generated by the same stochas-
9. We do not have data on the corporate profit tax on a cash basis for
state and local governments. This represents about 5 percent of total cor-
porate profit tax receipts at the beginning of the sample, and about 20 percent at
the end.
10. Corporate profit tax receipts are only reported without a seasonal adjust-
ment. We use the RATS EZ-X11 routine to seasonally adjust this series.
11. See Blinder [1981] for a detailed analysis of this tax cut, and its effects on
consumption. The 1975:2 tax rebate (which was combined with a social security
bonus for retirees without taxes to rebate) corresponded to an increase in dispos-
able income of about $100 billion at 1987 prices; by comparison, the 1968 surtax
decreased disposable income by $16 billion and the 1982 tax cut increased dis-
posable income by $31.6 billion, always at 1987 prices (see Poterba [19881).
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1338 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
taxlgdp
0.225
0.200 -
0.175 -
0.150 -
0.125 1 47
. . . .54
. 1 I.. ..1 1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . ..1. . . . . . . . . .
61 68 75 82 89 96
gcn/gdp
0.26
0.24 -
0.22
0.20 -
0.18 -
0.16 -
47 54 61 68 75 82 89 96
FIGURE I
Net Taxes and Spending, Shares of GDP
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1339
B. Low-Frequency Properties
The general visual impression from Figure I is one of no clear
trends, but clear low-frequency (say decade-to-decade) move-
ments in both spending and taxes. One may be surprised by th
general absence of upward trends in spending and net taxes; b
recall that we are looking at government spending not including
transfers, and that net taxes are taxes net of transfers. Thus, th
figures hide the trend increases in taxes and transfers, which
have indeed taken place during this period.
The main practical issue, for our purposes, is how to treat
these low-frequency movements in our two fiscal series in relatio
to output. We have conducted a battery of integration tests for T
G, and X. Formal tests (Augmented Dickey-Fuller and Phillips
Perron, with a deterministic time trend) do not speak strongly o
whether we should assume stochastic or deterministic trends for
each variable. We have also conducted a battery of cointegration
tests. One obvious candidate for a cointegration relation is the
difference between taxes and spending, T - G:12 in fact, the
stationarity of the deficit is the basic idea underlying the tests of
"sustainability" of fiscal policy by Hamilton and Flavin [1986] and
Bohn [1991].13 Figure II displays the logarithm of the tax/spend-
ing ratio. Again, formal test results do not speak strongly: one can
typically reject the null of a unit root at about the 5 percent level,
but no lower.14
In light of these results, we estimate our VARs under two
alternative assumptions. In the first, we formalize trends in all
three variables as deterministic, and allow for linear and qua-
dratic terms in time in each of the equations of the VAR. In the
second, we allow for stochastic trends. We take first-differences of
each variable, and, to account for changes in the underlying drift
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1340 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
log(tax)-log(gcn)
0.2 -
0.1
-0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0 .6 1 1 1 I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I
47 54 61 68 75 82 89 96
FIGURE II
log (Net Taxes) - log (Spending)
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1341
TABLE I
LARGE CHANGES IN NET TAXES AND SPENDING
15. Note that, in constructing the cyclically adjusted tax shock t', we use the
time-varying elasticity a , not its mean.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1342 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
TABLE II
ESTIMATED CONTEMPORANEOUS COEFFICIENTS
cl c2 b2 a2
DT
16. Note that the initial value of the change in taxes is not exactly 1. A unit
tax shock e' translates into a less than unit change in taxes tt, since GDP falls in
response to the shock, decreasing tax revenues.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
resp. of tax, DT resp. of tpe, DT resp. of gdp
10 1010
5 0 os 05 -
5 05 - -05 -
05- 05 05 -
00 - 00 00
-- - - - - - - - -
10 -10 0 -o
-15 1 - 15 9
-20 - I I - 2 0 -20 -. . . .
1 4 7 10 13 16 19 1 4 1 10 13 16 19 1 4 7 1
FIGURE III
Response to a Tax Shock
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1344 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
TABLE III
RESPONSES TO TAx SHOCKS
ST
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1345
17. Note that this exercise can be given a structural interpretation only if the
tax cut captured by the dummy variable was unanticipated and was not a
response to a contemporaneous output shock. In other words, identification in the
"event-study" approach requires the same two assumptions that allowed identi-
fication in the "structural VAR" approach.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
resp. of tax, DT resp. of spe, DT resp. of gdp
10 10 1
6- 6- -
4 4- 4
2 2 -- - --- 2
-2 -2 .2
S- -6
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 1 3 5 7 9
1
resp. of tax, ST resp. of ape, ST resp. of gdp
1
6 a 6 /
4 4 - 4
2 -2 - 2 /2
-8 --/----
/ 2- -
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 1 3 5 7
FIGURE IV
Response to a Shock to the 1975:2 Dummy
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1347
TABLE IV
RESPONSES TO SPENDING SHOCKS
DT
ST
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
resp. of ape, DT resp. of tax, DT resp. of gdp
25 - 25 25
20 -20 - 20 -
15 15 15 s /
05 05 05
00 o00 . 00 o
\ /
Is. 15 I
I
-05 -05 -05
FIGURE V
Response to a Spending Shock
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1349
TABLE V
STABILITY OF RESPONSES TO TAX SHOCKS
excl. period max. GDP response excl. period max. GDP response
DT
ST
VII. ROBUSTNESS
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1350 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1351
etl,+ 1but
Tt in (8)will
are typically be correlated
correlated with the compositewith
error eterm.
+1. As
Hence,
in our both Tt and
benchmark case, Tt is correlated with e', through the effect of e'
on output and in turn on tax revenues. Also, now Tt+1 is corre-
lated with both components of the error term: with e+ 1 through
the effects of the latter on taxes in quarter t + 1, and with e',
through the effect of the latter on Tt and therefore on Tt+ .
Can equation (8) be estimated by instrumental variables?
The answer is yes, if we are willing to make stronger identifica-
tion assumptions. The reasoning follows the logic of our previous
identification strategy. If we can construct a series for e, then et
and its value led once, e t1, can be used as instruments for Tt and
T,,+ 1 Both are correlated with Tt or Tt+ 1 and uncorrelated with
the two components of the composite error term. Put another
way, if we can identify et in the tax equation, we can then use it
and its value led once as instruments in the output equation.
With this in mind, let us turn to the tax equation, and for
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1352 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
19. Clearly if fiscal policy were anticipated, say two quarters ahead, identi-
fication would require that policy cannot respond to output shocks this quarter
and in the last two quarters.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1353
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5 -
[] no anticip.
a121 = .16
A a121 = 0.0
-2.0
-2.0 a121=.5 5 10 15 2
0 5 10 15 20
FIGURE VI
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1354 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
2.5
2.00 00
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5 [] no anticip.
a121 = .16
A a121 = 0.0
a-1.0 21 = .5
0 5 10 15 20
FIGURE VII
Response of Output to an Anticipated Spending Shock, ST
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1355
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1356 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
reap. of ape, DT reap. of tax, DT reap. of gdp
20 20 20 ,
\15
5 15 15 /
10 10 10
5 s -
0
'I 0
,o
07
1
-5
3 5 7 9 11 13 15
i/ ( -
-5
17 19 1 3 5
20 20 20
Is 15 - 15 /
10 10 - -- - - - 10 I
5 5 - 5--
II
- i /
0 : _-? I 0, 0
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17. 19 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 11 19 1 3 5 7 9
FIGURE VIII
Response to a Shock to the 1950:1 Dum
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1358 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1359
20. Results from twelve large macroeconometric models are reported in Bry-
ant [1988]; under the assumption of an unchanged path for money, the average
effect of a permanent government spending increase of one percentage point of
GDP is an increase of 1.27 percent of GDP in the first year, declining slowly to 0.65
percent after five years.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1360 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1361
tt = alxt + a2eg + et
where
generalxi,t indicates a component of GDP, so ex and et' are in
be correlated.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1362 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
TABLE VI
RESPONSES OF GDP COMPONENTS
DT, TAX
ST, TAX
DT, SPE
ST, SPE
Sample: 1960:1-1997:4.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1363
21. Note also the decline in imports (after a brief initial surge), which is
surprising in light of the considerable increase in GDP. This decline may consist
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1364 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
XII. CONCLUSIONS
APPENDIX
A. 1. The Data
All the data, unless otherwise noted, are from the Nationa
Income and Product Accounts. The Citibase mnemonics are giv
in parentheses. FG stands for Federal Government; SLG stand
for State and Local Governments.
Government spending
Purchases of goods and services, FG (GGFE) + Purchases of
goods and services, SLG (GGSE).
Net taxes
Receipts, FG (GGFR)22 + Receipts, SLG (GGSR)23 - Federal
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1365
A.2. Elasticities
(X) as the product of the tax elasticity to its own base, ITL,,, and
the elasticity of the tax base to GDP, IqB,x (see expression (5) in
the text). For each tax, we must take into account the possible
presence of collection lags and of quarter dependence. On the expen-
diture side, we also construct an approximate output elasticity of
total transfers. The rest of this section describes our assumptions.
Indirect taxes
We take the tax base to be GDP. This is an approximation. In
many states, food consumption is excluded. In most states, the
sale of materials to manufacturers, producers, and processors is
also excluded (see Advisory Committee of Intergovernmental Re-
lations [1995]). Hence,
BINDX = 1. O
qIND,BIND = 1.0 (from Giorno et al. [1995])
Collection lags: 0
Quarter dependence: none.
Personal income taxes
We start from the formula for the elasticity to GDP from
Giorno et al. [1995]. Let T = t(W)W(E)E(X), where T is total
revenues from the personal income tax, t is the tax rate, W is the
We do not, however, have this series for the state and local governments, so
we use accruals (the proportion of corporate profit tax receipts collected by state
and local governments is about 5 percent at the beginning of the sample, and
about 20 percent at the end of the sample). We also could not find data on indirect
taxes on a cash basis; however, the difference between receipts and accruals
appears to be very small.
23. Corporate income taxes collected by state and local governments are not
included.
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1366 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
TBINc, = HI(F + 1)
TINCBINc = (FD + 1)/(F + 1).
We obtain values of D from Giorno et al. [1995]. We estimate
F from a regression of the log change of the wage of production
workers on the first lead and lags 0 to 4 of the log change in
employment of production workers. We estimate H from a regres-
sion of the log change of employment of production workers on the
first lead and lags 0 to 4 of the log change in output. The values
of F and H are the estimated coefficients of lag zero of the
dependent variable. We find F = .62 and H = .42.
Collection lags: 0
Quarter dependence: none.
Note that for personal income taxes we assume the same
elasticity for employees and the self-employed: the former have
their taxes withheld at the source, while the latter make quar-
terly payments based on the estimated income of that quarter. So
long as there is no systematic pattern in the end-year adjust-
ments (as it should be if the tax system is well designed), our
assumption does not introduce any substantial bias in our aggre-
gate elasticity.
Social security taxes
We follow exactly the same procedure as for personal income
taxes. The only difference is in the value of the elasticity of taxes
to earnings, D, which we also obtain from Giorno et al. [1995].
Corporate income taxes
Each corporation can have its own fiscal year different from
the tax year. Large corporations are required to make quarterly
installment payments, of at least 0.8 of the final tax liability.
Until 1980, no penalty was applied if the estimated tax liability
was based on the previous year's tax liability; this exception has
been gradually phased out since 1980. Hence,
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
AN EMPIRICAL CHARACTERIZATION OF THE EFFECTS 1367
Transfers
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1368 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
REFERENCES
This content downloaded from 34.192.2.131 on Thu, 13 Sep 2018 21:50:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms