Closed-Economy Macroeconomics: A Quick Historical Review: John E. Floyd
Closed-Economy Macroeconomics: A Quick Historical Review: John E. Floyd
J. E. Floyd
May 13, 2002
Contents
i
7.2.2 The Search Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88
7.2.3 The Contract Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
7.2.4 Some Implications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
7.3 Rational Expectations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
ii
Chapter 1
This book outlines the standard closed-economy model of money, prices and
employment found in most current intermediate textbooks. The theory is
developed from an historical perspective in steps, beginning with the early
simple-minded classical model, proceeding to the crude Keynesian model of
the late-nineteen thirties, and then refining both to present a unified modern
treatment that incorporates contemporary notions of price adjustment and
rational expectations.
The reader should be reminded that, apart from the world considered
as a single unit, there are essentially no closed economies. In the modern
world every economy trades with other economies and some of the capital
stock employed in every economy is owned by residents of other economies.
Why then bother with closed-economy analysis? There are two reasons.
First, some tools of analysis are easier to develop and understand without the
complications of international trade and capital movements. Insights gained
from the analysis of a theoretical closed economy carry over to the analysis of
more realistic situations. Second, most modern courses in macroeconomics
deal in considerable detail with closed-economy issues. Students who devote
most of their energy to open economy analysis frequently have to bone up
on features of closed-economy analysis in order to pass their exams. For
this they should find this book useful. In addition, they will also improve
their understanding of analytical concepts used in open economy analysis
by seeing them presented in a different context.
In this chapter we begin by outlining briefly some basic concepts nec-
essary for understanding the material presented in later chapters. We can
think of the economy as a collection of resources together with the institu-
tions that govern their use. The people in the economy own, individually
1
2 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION: BASIC CONCEPTS
and collectively, a stock of capital which produces a flow of goods and ser-
vices that can either be consumed or plowed back as an addition to capital.
This stock of capital, the distinguishing feature of which is its ability to
produce a flow of output of goods and services, represents the communities’
wealth and is the source of its income.
There are four main components to the capital stock: physical capital,
human capital, knowledge, and money holdings. Physical capital consists
of machinery, buildings and structures, materials in process and natural re-
sources. A part of the physical capital existing at any point in time has
been produced by redirecting output to that purpose rather than consum-
ing it. The rest represents the powers of nature—earth, coal, water, sun-
shine, etc.—that are freely available in the environment. Producible capital
normally deteriorates from use. The powers of nature may be exhaustible
(e.g., coal and oil) or inexhaustible (e.g., air and water). Human capital
is skills and knowledge embodied in people. It is acquired partly through
formal education and on-the-job training, and partly by osmosis as a by-
product of the process of growing up in a home and community. The stock
of knowledge can be thought of as the understanding of how the natural
and social environment works, what might be called basic knowledge, and
the understanding of how the resources at the society’s disposal can be mod-
ified, extended and combined to produce various kinds of goods and services.
This ability to apply basic knowledge in using resources to produce goods
and services is called technology or technological capital, and increase in it
are commonly referred to as technical change. The stock of knowledge and
technology is possessed by the community as a whole but not embodied in
all of its members. It is the set of skills, techniques and attributes available
for embodiment in individuals and physical capital. The ‘quality’ of human
and physical capital depends on the technology actually embodied in them
and on the knowledge base that permits that level of technology.
A part of the output of the economy can be used to add to the stock of
physical capital and human skills and to the stock of knowledge. Investment
in knowledge, and associated expansions of technology, involves improving
the understanding of how nature works as well as discovering new prod-
ucts, resources, skills and ways of combining human and physical capital in
production.
The fourth type of capital is the public’s holdings of money balances.
Money is held to facilitate exchange. Without it, anyone wanting to sell
something would have to barter it for something else—this would require
that another person be found with the right product to sell. These costs of
barter can be avoided by making all exchanges in return for money. In a
3
3
In practical terms, the level of output of a closed economy is measured by the real gross
national product (see footnote 1). Gross national product is the aggregate money value of
goods produced in the economy—a sum of the outputs of the various goods and services
weighted by their prices. When prices in the current year are used as weights, nominal
gross national product—i.e., gross national product in current dollars—is obtained. When
prices from some base period in the past are chosen as weights, the result is gross national
product in constant dollars. The latter is the customary measure of real output—output
measured in the dollars of the chosen base period. By dividing nominal gross national
product by real gross national product we obtain a measure of the price of output. This
is defined as the implicit income deflator—the price level that nominal gross national
product would have to be divided by to obtain real gross national product. These terms,
together with the distinction between gross and net investment are discussed carefully in
Robert J. Barro, Macroeconomics, 4th Edition, 1993, pp. 1–16.
5
i = r + Ep (1.3)
Note that the real interest rate as defined above will normally differ
from the interest rate that will actually be realized on the transaction. This
6 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION: BASIC CONCEPTS
difference between the realized and contracted real interest rates will arise
whenever the parties to the loan are incorrect in their expectation of the
inflation rate. If the inflation rate is higher than expected, the realized real
interest rate will be below r. If it is lower than expected, the realized real
interest rate will be above r.
We can observe nominal interest rates but not contracted real rates.
The latter depend on the expectations of borrowers and lenders as to the
future inflation rate. After the event, we can calculate the realized real
interest rate by subtracting the actual rate of inflation from the nominal
interest rate. For example, suppose that the lending rate of the Canadian
chartered banks is 7.75% and the actual rate of inflation is around 3%. The
real interest rate at which borrowing and lending is currently taking place
equals 7.75% minus the inflation rate expected by borrowers and lenders
over the next year. Since we have no way of knowing what this expected
inflation rate is, we cannot observe the contracted real interest rate. We
can, however, observe the realized real interest rate. If the rate of inflation
over the next year actually turns out to be 3%, the realized real interest rate
will be 4.75%. If the inflation rate turns out to be 2% the realized real rate
of interest will be 5.75%.4
The study of the behaviour of economic aggregates has tended to divide
into two branches. One branch deals with the growth of the economy over
long periods of a decade or more and from one generation to the next. The
other deals with fluctuations in economic activity around its long-run trend.
The former deals with long-run capital accumulation and the determinants
of the growth rates of aggregate output, population, and per capita income.
The latter is concerned with short-term variations in output, in the fraction
of the labour force employed, in nominal and real interest rates and in the
level of prices. Although it is quite often a long-term phenomenon, inflation
is usually analyzed in conjunction with the fluctuations in economic activity
as well as long-term growth.
Our focus in this book will be almost entirely on short-run fluctuations
in output, employment and prices within the framework of given rates of
long-term output growth and inflation. Some attention will nevertheless
be devoted to the short-run effects on economic activity of changing the
long-term inflation rate.
4
For a simple but rigorous discussion of the distinction between real and nominal
interest rates, see pages 173–182 of Barro’s book cited above.
7
Exercises
1. Explain the distinction between stocks and flows. Which of the following
are stocks and which are flows: clothes, money, government bonds, interest
on a loan, income taxes, inheritance taxes? Briefly explain your reasoning
in each case.
2. Write brief one or two sentence explanations of the following concepts:
human capital, physical capital, stock of knowledge, technological change,
stock of money, income, aggregate income, consumption, saving, investment,
depreciation, real vs. nominal magnitudes, general price level, inflation, nom-
inal interest rate, real interest rate, expected rate of inflation, inflation pre-
mium.
3. True or False: Explain your answer briefly.
f) “What with the recent inflation and all, bonds are a good investment
because interest rates are high.”
g) “Since the inflation rate is currently around 5 percent while the inter-
est rates on treasury bills and other short-term securities are over 12
percent, real interest rates are currently very high.”
9
10 CHAPTER 2. THE CRUDE CLASSICAL MODEL
Output
F(N)
Yf
Yo
0 No N f Employment
Y = F (N ) (2.1)
Real Wage
Rate
S
D
w0
w1
S
D
No Nf Employment
in the economy will expand employment until the marginal physical product
of labour has fallen to equal the wage rate. A reduction of the real wage
rate will thus lead to an increase in the quantity of labour demanded.
The demand for labour is thus given by the marginal physical product
of labour, which is the derivative of the production function
W dF (N )
=w= = F 0 (N ), (2.2)
P dN
and can be expressed as the curve DD in Figure 2.2. In that figure, the
real wage rate is on the vertical axis and the quantity of labour employed
is on the horizontal one. W is the money wage rate and w is the real wage
rate. The real wage rate is equal to the money wage rate paid per unit of
labour divided by the price of output—a money wage of $10 per hour, for
example, divided by a price level of $2 per unit of output will yield a real
wage rate of 5 units of output per hour. The vertical distance of DD from
the horizontal axis equals the marginal physical product of labour. DD is
negatively sloped because the marginal physical product of labour declines
as the quantity of labour employed increases.
labour, see pp. 41–44 of the Barro book cited previously.
12 CHAPTER 2. THE CRUDE CLASSICAL MODEL
The quantity of labour supplied will depend upon how people choose
to allocate their time between work and leisure. Two general forces are
present. A rise in the real wage rate will increase the opportunity cost of
leisure, inducing a substitution in the direction of more work. At the same
time, the rise in the real wage rate increases the amount of income that can
be obtained from the existing amount of work. If leisure is a normal good,
this increase in real income will induce workers to increase their consumption
of both goods and leisure and to reduce the amount worked. It is generally
believed that at low levels of income the first effect, called the substitution
effect, dominates while the second effect, called the wealth effect, dominates
at high levels of income. Thus, the supply function for labour, which we
formally express as
µ ¶
W
N = N (w) = N , (2.3)
P
can be represented by a curve like SS in Figure 2.2. At low wages the
quantity of labour supplied increases as the real wage rate rises but beyond
some point a rise in the real wage rate leads to a decline in the quantity of
labour offered for employment. For most of our analysis nothing will be lost
by simply assuming that the classical supply curve for labour is vertical—
that is, that the full-employment quantity of labour offered is independent
of the real wage rate.
Labour market equilibrium is given by the solution of equations (2.2)
and (2.3). If the labour market functions properly, the real wage rate will
adjust until everyone who wishes to work is employed. At real wages above
w1 in Figure 2.2, the amount of labour people want to supply will exceed
the amount firms are demanding. The money wage rate will be bid down
until the real wage rate has fallen to w1 . Similarly, if the real wage rate
is below w1 there will be an excess demand for labour and nominal wages
will be bid up until the real wage rate has risen to w1 . The equilibrium
quantity of labour employed will thus be Nf . This can be referred to as full
employment. Full employment of labour results in a full-employment level
of output of Yf in Figure 2.1.
While the model developed thus far determines the equilibrium level of
real wages, it says nothing about what determines the nominal wage rate
and the price level. Equilibrium in Figure 2.2 is consistent with any level
of nominal wages and prices as long as the ratio of W to P equals w1 . Our
model tells us that, in order to maintain equilibrium real wages, the level of
money wages determined in the labour market would double if something
should happen to cause the price level to double. It does not tell us what
13
AD
P
AD AS AS
P2
P1
AD
P0 AD
Y
Yo Yf
determines the price level. Since the price level is the price of output, it
is only appropriate that it be determined by the supply of and demand for
output—by aggregate supply and aggregate demand.
The line ASYf in Figure 2.3 gives the aggregate supply curve. That
curve, which can be represented formally as
Y = F (Nf ), (2.4)
is vertical at the output level Yf because the workings of the labour market
will produce the level of employment Nf regardless of the level of prices—if
the price level is higher the money wage rate will be higher in the same
proportion to maintain the real wage rate w1 .
The aggregate demand curve traces out the quantities of output that
will be demanded in the economy at various price levels. It is derived from
the demand function for money, which the classical economists represented
in a very simple fashion.3 They postulated that the public will choose to
3
As in the rest of the model, the presentation here is stereotypical—many classical
economists had a much more sophisticated understanding of the issues than is implied by
the discussion that follows.
14 CHAPTER 2. THE CRUDE CLASSICAL MODEL
hold a stock of real money balances equal to some constant fraction of real
income. The demand for real money balances could thus be expressed as
µ ¶d
M
= kY (2.5)
P
where k is the public’s desired ratio of real money holdings to real income.
This implies that the nominal quantity of money demanded will equal k
times nominal income—that is,
M d = kP Y. (2.6)
If the public wants to hold more nominal money balances than are in
existence it will attempt to sell goods in return for money. This will cause
the price of goods to be bid down. As P falls in Equation (2.6) the amount
of nominal money balances demanded will fall. Equilibrium will occur where
P has fallen sufficiently to reduce the nominal quantity of money demanded
to the point where it equals the amount of money in circulation. Similarly, if
the quantity of money in circulation exceeds the quantity the public wishes
to hold, people will try to spend these excess money holdings on goods.
While any one person can do this, everyone together cannot. The price level
will be bid up, increasing the nominal quantity of money demanded until it
equals the quantity of money in circulation.
When the nominal quantity of money demanded is equal to the quantity
in circulation, equation (2.6) can be rearranged to yield
M
P = . (2.7)
kY
or alternatively,
M
Y = , (2.8)
kP
where M is the nominal quantity of money that the authorities have created.
This latter equation gives the amount of output flow the public will demand
for each level of the nominal money stock, prices and the parameter k.
Equation (2.7) is the equation of the aggregate demand curve AD in Figure
2.3. This curve is a rectangular hyperbola—a rise in P will reduce the flow
of output the public will demand at each level of the nominal money stock
in the same proportion.
The aggregate supply and demand functions, given by equations (2.4)
and (2.7) solve for the equilibrium price level, given by P0 in Figure 2.3. If
15
P falls below P0 , the public will try to rid itself of excess money holdings
by purchasing more output than is being produced, and the general price
level will be bid up. If P rises above P0 , there will be an excess supply of
output (accompanied by an excess demand for money) and the price level
will be bid down. An increase in the nominal money stock as a result of
the monetary policy of the government will increase the amount of output
the public will want to buy at the initial price level—the curve AD shifts
to AD 0 in Figure 2.3. The price level will be bid up to P1 . Since output
must be constant at Yf in the face of the increase in money and prices, it is
clear from equation (2.8) that the price level must rise in proportion to the
increase in the nominal money stock. This is also evident from the demand
function for money given by (2.5)—if Y and k are constant the ratio M/P
must also be constant. In classical models such as this, money is said to be
neutral in the sense that changes in the size of the nominal money supply
will have no effect on real output or real money holdings.
Interest rates are determined in the classical analysis by the supply and
demand for loanable funds. The demand for loanable funds arises from the
investment process while the supply is generated by savings. Firms finance
their investment plans by issuing new securities in one form or other. Savers
purchase these securities either directly or through the intermediation of
banks and other financial institutions. The level of investment, and hence
the borrowing of firms, is generally regarded as negatively related to the
real interest rate. As the real rate of interest falls firms can borrow at lower
rates. More potential investment projects become profitable and the level
of investment expands. The supply of new securities coming on the market,
or alternatively, the demand for loanable funds, can thus be represented by
a negatively sloped curve such as II in Figure 2.4. For the time being we
can think of the level of savings as being positively related to the rate of
interest, as indicated by the curve SS in Figure 2.4. In general, a rise in
the real interest rate will have two opposing effects on the level of savings.
On the one hand, the rise in r makes future consumption more attractive
relative to current consumption since more future goods can be obtained
by sacrificing a unit of current goods. This will cause people to substitute
future consumption for current consumption by saving more. On the other
hand, a rise in r will increase the amount of future consumption that will
be obtained from peoples’ initial levels of saving, thereby increasing the
opportunities for present and future consumption and, hence, the level of
wealth. Normally we would expect people to increase both their current
and their future consumption in response to these expanded opportunities.
This would have a positive effect on current consumption. Consumption
16 CHAPTER 2. THE CRUDE CLASSICAL MODEL
Real Interest
Rate
S
I
r0
S
I Savings and
Io Investment
Figure 2.4: Savings and Investment
S = Y − C = I, (2.9)
PY 1
V = = , (2.10)
M k
and we can alternatively express equation (2.8) as
MV
Y = (2.11)
P
or
M V = P Y. (2.12)
supply in the labour market. At the real wage rate w0 firms will employ
only N0 units of labour and there will be unemployment in the economy.
The level of output will be Y0 in Figure 2.1, and the aggregate supply curve
will be AS 0 Y0 in Figure 2.3.4 If the nominal quantity of money and the
income velocity of circulation are the same as before, the equilibrium price
level will be P2 . the level of money wages will be equal to w1 times P2 . This
inability of the real wage rate to find its equilibrium level is the essential
basis for less than full employment in Keynesian models.
4
Note here that we are assuming that the real wage rate is fixed. It will be seen later
that rigidity of the nominal wage rate will imply a quite different aggregate supply curve.
19
Exercises
1. True or False: Explain your answer briefly.
a) In the short run, when the quantity of capital is fixed, an increase in
employment will be associated with a more or less equivalent increase
in aggregate output.
b) The aggregate demand curve for labour is negatively sloped because
the marginal product of labour declines as more output is produced.
c) Generally speaking, higher wages induce people to work more and take
less leisure. The aggregate supply curve of the economy is therefore
upward sloped.
d) When the labour market is in equilibrium, there will be full employ-
ment in the sense that everyone wanting to work at the existing wage
rate has a job.
e) When there is full employment in the economy the aggregate supply
curve is vertical.
f) The aggregate demand function is the relationship between the aggre-
gate quantity of goods and services the public wants to buy and the
level of employment.
g) Inflation is a fall in the value of money caused by an increase in the
supply of money relative to the demand for it.
Find the equilibrium wage rate and demonstrate that a law that forces
money wages above the equilibrium level will create unemployment.
4. Consider a simple economy in which a single output good is produced by
the production function
X = L1/2 ,
where L is the quantity of labour employed and X is output. This implies
a demand function for labour
W 1 1
= L−1/2 = √ ,
P 2 2 L
where W is the money wage rate and P is the price level. Assume that the
economy is endowed with 100 workers, all of whom chose to work a fixed
amount independently of the real wage rate. Suppose, in addition, that the
public tends to hold one dollar of money balances for every two dollars of
money income. Finally, assume that the government has created a stock of
money equal to 5 dollars.
a) Write down the equation giving the demand function for money.
b) Calculate the level of real income, the price level, the level of nominal
income and the money wage rate.
c) Show the effects on real income, the price level, nominal income and
the money wage rate of an increase in the stock of money from 5 dollars
to 10 dollars.
d) Show the equilibrium of the economy on two graphs, one portraying
the market for labour and the other the market for output.
Suppose that a single union successfully organizes the entire labour force
and manages to impose on employers a cost of living clause that establishes
a nominal wage rate according to the formula
W = .1P
e) Calculate the equilibrium levels of output, nominal income, the price
level, the money wage rate and employment when the money stock is
alternatively 5 dollars and 10 dollars.
f) Show the effect of the union on equilibrium in the labour and output
markets respectively using two graphs like those in d) above.
Chapter 3
Y =C +I +G (3.1)
21
22 CHAPTER 3. THE KEYNESIAN MODEL
diture is an exogenous variable that drives the model and is not solved for
within it.
Consumption, by contrast, is an endogenous variable. Keynes argued
that it depends on consumers’ current income. The early Keynesians posited
a consumption function of the form
I = I(r) (3.3)
where I is the level of investment and r is the real rate of interest. As the
negative slope of the curve II in Figure 3.2 indicates, the derivative of I(r)
with respect to r is negative. This is essentially the same II curve that
23
Consumption
C=a+bY
A
Co
Disposable
0 Income
Yo
Figure 3.1: The Keynesian Consumption Function
Real Interest
Rate
rm I
ro
I
Investment
Io Im
Figure 3.2: The Investment Function
24 CHAPTER 3. THE KEYNESIAN MODEL
o
C+I+G 45
C+I+G = Ye
0 Y
Ye
Figure 3.3: Equality of Income and Expenditure
appeared in Figure 2.4. When the central bank sets the interest rate at r0
the level of domestic investment becomes
I0 = I(r0 ) (3.4)
which can be represented graphically as the line EE in Figure 3.3. This line
has a positive intercept with the vertical axis and a slope that is flatter than
the 45o line through the origin because the sum of desired consumption,
investment, and government expenditure increase as income increases by
less than the increase in income—this reflects the fact that the marginal
propensity to consume is less than unity. In equilibrium the level of real
income will equal the sum of real consumption, investment and government
expenditure and will be given by the intersection of the line EE and the 45o
line. This yields an output level Ye on the horizontal axis equal to the sum of
25
M = L1 (Y ) + L2 (r) (3.8)
where L1 (Y ) is the transactions demand for money and L2 (r) is the specu-
lative demand. The derivatives of L1 (Y ) and L2 (r) with respect to Y and
r are positive and negative respectively. The negative relationship between
the speculative demand for money and the rate of interest was the result
of a particular assumption about expectations. It was assumed that when
interest rates are high the majority of the public will expect them to fall
(and bond prices therefore to rise), and when they are low the majority will
expect them to rise (and bond prices to fall). High interest rates will thus
cause a speculative switch out of money and into bonds in anticipation of
the future rise in bond prices and low interest rates will cause a speculative
shift out of bonds and into money in anticipation of the future fall in bond
prices.
The two equations (3.5) and (3.8) can now be combined to determine
the two variables Y and r. To portray this solution graphically, it is useful
to express the two equations as curves in (Y, r) space as shown in Figure
27
r
IS
LM
ro
LM
IS
Y
Y0 Y1 Y2
Figure 3.4: The IS-LM Model
3.4. The curve IS gives the combinations of income and the interest rate
that satisfy equation (3.5). These are the combinations of the two vari-
ables for which desired expenditures on consumption and investment plus
government expenditure equal the real value of output. Alternatively, they
are the combinations of Y and r for which savings and investment in the
private and government sectors taken together are equal.1 This curve is
negatively sloped because a fall in the rate of interest increases the level of
desired investment, leading to an increase in the demand for output and the
quantity of output produced. The equation of the IS curve is (3.7) in the
case where the consumption function is linear. A cut in taxes, an increase
in government expenditure or an expectations driven increase in investment
expenditure will shift the IS curve to the right.
The curve LM in Figure 3.4 traces out the combinations of the interest
rate and income for which the demand for money equals the supply. It
is positively sloped because a rise in the rate of interest will reduce the
quantity of money demanded, requiring a rise in income to re-equate it with
the existing money supply. An increase in the supply of money will require
a higher price of bonds and a lower rate of interest to get the public to hold
1
Here we would split government expenditure into its consumption and investment
components.
28 CHAPTER 3. THE KEYNESIAN MODEL
the new stock of money at the original level of income. The LM curve will
thus shift downward to the right. An increase in liquidity preference will
have the opposite effect, causing the LM curve to shift to the left—bond
prices will have to fall and the interest rate will have to rise to induce the
public to be satisfied with the existing stock of money at the original level
of income in the face of the increased demand for money. The equation of
the LM curve is simply a rearrangement of (3.8) to move the real interest
rate to the left-hand side.
In the formulation presented in Figure 3.4, a monetary expansion by the
central bank shifts the LM curve to the right, easing credit conditions and
lowering the interest rate. Output and income expand as the equilibrium
point moves downward to the right along the IS curve. A fiscal expansion,
taking the form of either an increase in government expenditures or a de-
crease in taxes and consequent expansion of consumption expenditure, shifts
the IS curve to the right and causes the interest rate and income to both
rise as the equilibrium point moves up to the right along the LM curve.
The early Keynesians made much of the fact that there is no appar-
ent mechanism in equations (3.5) and (3.8) and Figure 3.4 to ensure that
the equilibrium level of output is the full-employment level. In the late
1930s and early 1940s, this was regarded by a significant fraction of the eco-
nomics profession as a major analytical break-through which destroyed the
old classical notion that the economy tended to move automatically to the
full-employment level of income. The Keynesian theory was thought to be
more general in the sense that it held under all circumstances, whereas the
classical theory was only valid in the special case where one assumed the
existence of full employment. The Keynesian theory also admitted the pos-
sibility that the government could affect output and employment by varying
taxes and government expenditure—this avenue was ruled out in the clas-
sical theory by the assumption that the quantity of money demanded is
independent of the interest rate.
29
Exercises
1. Suppose that investment expenditure is 10,000 and is under rigid control
of the government. Let the consumption function be
C =α+βY
C = α + β (Y − T )
and
I = δ + µ r + γ Y.
Derive the IS curve under the assumption that there is no foreign trade and
government expenditure and taxes are exogenously determined.
Suppose that income is initially equal to 1000 and that government expen-
diture and taxes are both initially equal to 100. Show the effects on income
of the following changes when β = 0.5, γ = 0.3 and µ = −2.0.
a) The IS curve gives the combinations of income and the real interest
rate for which aggregate demand equals aggregate supply.
c) The IS curve gives the combinations of income and the real interest
rate for which savings equals investment.
d) What are the equilibrium levels of income and the interest rate?
The Keynesian-Classical
Synthesis
In the early days of the Keynesian revolution many economists thought that
Keynes had proven that there is no tendency of the modern economy to go
to a full-employment equilibrium—the equilibrium position depends on the
magnitudes of consumption and investment expenditure generated by sav-
ings propensities and business expectations and on the level of government
expenditure. This simplistic view was soon discredited on the grounds that
it depended almost totally on the underlying assumption that money wages
do not adjust in the labour market in response to conditions of excess sup-
ply. The second major Keynesian innovation, the notion that the quantity of
money demanded depends on interest rates, held firm in subsequent debate
and remains a cornerstone of modern macroeconomic theory.1
31
32 CHAPTER 4. THE KEYNESIAN-CLASSICAL SYNTHESIS
r
Yf
IS
LM
ro
LM
IS
Y
Y0 Y f
Figure 4.1: The Effect of Downward Wage Flexibility
r
Yf
IS IS
LM
LM
ro
IS IS
Y
Y0 Y f
Figure 4.2: The Liquidity Trap and the Pigou Effect
the LM curve could become flat within the relevant range and insensitive in
a downward direction to increases in the real money supply resulting from
declines in the price level, a situation called a liquidity trap. As a result, it
was argued, the IS and LM curves may continue to intersect at an output
level below full employment regardless of how low prices fall.2 This argument
loses force when we recognize that as prices continue to fall the increase in
real money holdings makes the public wealthier. It is likely that part of
the increased wealth will be spent on consumption with the result that the
level of consumption will increase at each level of current income—i.e., the
consumption function C(Y − T ) will shift upward—a result known as the
Pigou effect. This will shift IS to the right until it eventually crosses LM at
full employment.3
A more sensible formulation of the demand for money also casts doubt
on the notion that increases in the stock of real money balances will be
ineffective in driving the LM curve downward. The Keynesian rationale for
2
And how much the authorities might choose to increase the nominal money supply.
3
To incorporate the Pigou effect formally into our model we would have to include M/P
as an argument in the consumption function. For the classic treatment of this issue, see A.
C. Pigou, “The Classical Stationary State,” Economic Journal, Vol. 53, 1943, pp. 343–351,
and Don Patinkin, “Price Flexibility and Full Employment”, American Economic Review,
Vol. 38, 1948, 543-564.
34 CHAPTER 4. THE KEYNESIAN-CLASSICAL SYNTHESIS
the negative relationship between the quantity of money demanded and the
interest rate was based on an assumption about the public’s expectations.
The public was assumed to expect interest rates to fall when the current
level of interest rates are high and to rise when current interest rate levels
are low. This is not a useful assumption on which to build a model because
it involves essentially a presumption about how people will react that is not
based on the convexity of indifference curves or some other proposition that
can be demonstrated to be true in a wide variety of circumstances. It leaves
one open to the contrary presumption, which is equally valid because there
is no firm evidence one way or the other, that when interest rates rise the
public will expect them to rise further and when they fall the public will
expect them to fall further. If that were the case, a rise in the interest rate
would lead to portfolio shifts from bonds to money and a fall would lead
to a switch from money to bonds, making the demand for money positively
related to interest rates.
While it is obvious that the transactions demand for money will vary di-
rectly with income, there is no reason to expect a rigid relationship between
desired real money holdings and real income. The amount of money desired
at any given level of income will depend on the opportunity cost of holding
money. Since the cost of holding money (instead of bonds and other non-
monetary assets) is the interest earnings forgone, it is reasonable to expect
that the transactions demand for money will be inversely related to the rate
of interest. Of course, the amount of money held to satisfy the transactions
demand will also depend on expectations—if the interest rate is expected to
rise more money will be held and if it is expected to fall less money will be
held. While expectations could operate in either direction in response to an
increase in the interest rate, the substitution effect away from money when
the cost of holding it rises will always operate in one direction. The available
empirical evidence suggests that the real quantity of money demanded is,
in fact, negatively related to the rate of interest as well as positively related
to the level of income. An appropriate form for the demand function for
money is thus
M
= L(r, Y ) (4.2)
P
where the partial derivative of L( ) with respect to Y is positive and the
partial derivative with respect to r is negative, with no distinction made
between various motives for holding money. It is generally held that the
negative slope results from the fact that a rise in r increases the opportunity
cost of holding money.
4.1. REFINEMENTS OF THE KEYNESIAN MODEL 35
When the demand function for money is formulated in this way the LM
curve always shifts downward to the right when the real money stock in-
creases. Only if money and non-monetary assets are perfect substitutes in
portfolios, so that the partial derivative of L( ) with respect to r becomes
infinite, will the LM curve be unresponsive to changes in the real money
stock. In this case the curve would be horizontal throughout its length at
the level of interest rates at which the public was indifferent about holding
money vs. other assets.4 There is thus no basis for the liquidity trap argu-
ment that the economy will not be driven to full employment by downward
wage flexibility.
The early Keynesian models can also be refined by enriching the produc-
tion specifications. The classical production function and demand function
for labour can (and should) be incorporated into the IS-LM model pre-
sented above. The full-employment level of output, given by the vertical
line Yf in Figure 2.2 (which is reproduced here as Figure 4.3) and derived
from equations (2.1), (2.2) and (2.3) should be incorporated directly into
the Keynesian analysis. When the money wage rate is fixed, the level of
employment varies along the demand curve for labour as the price level rises
and falls changing the real wage rate. Since it is impossible for employment
and output to change without a change in the real wage rate, constant wages
cannot imply a constant price level in the face of changing employment as
assumed in the simple Keynesian model. Nevertheless, the price level is
almost invariably assumed constant in standard classroom analysis. This is
an example of an assumption that is wrong but very useful—it simplifies the
analysis without having an adverse effect on the qualitative conclusions.
The IS-LM model in Figure 4.1 can be easily modified to incorporate the
fact that constancy of money wages does not imply constancy of the price
level. Equation (2.2) can be expressed
W dF (N )
=w= = F 0 (N ) = F 0 [F −1 (Y )] = G(Y ) (4.3)
P dN
4
It has been suggested in the literature that certain other short-term assets might
be such good substitutes for money that it will become impossible for the monetary
authority to control interest rates by controlling the money stock. See John G. Gurley
and Edward Shaw, “Financial Intermediaries and the Saving-Investment Process”, Journal
of Finance, Vol. 11, 1956, pp. 257-276. For an excellent short discussion of this issue, see
Abba P. Lerner, “Discussion of Financial Intermediaries and Monetary Policy,” American
Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 1963, pp. 401-407. The conclusion is that if
money and other assets are less than perfect substitutes, as the evidence suggests they are,
there will be no loss of monetary control. Although induced changes in money substitutes
will occur, these will be only partially offsetting—some fall in the rate of interest will
always be required to induce the public to hold additional money balances.
36 CHAPTER 4. THE KEYNESIAN-CLASSICAL SYNTHESIS
Real Wage
Rate
S
D
w0
w1
S
D
No Nf Employment
Figure 4.3: Employment Changes in Response to Price Level Variations
Since G(Y ) falls as Y increases, the price level rises as output increases
holding the money wage rate constant. Also, P increases proportionally with
an increase in the money wage rate holding output constant. Substitution
of (4.3) into (4.2) yields
M L(r, Y )
= = L̃(r, Y ) (4.5)
W G(Y )
where L̃(r, Y ) is the demand function for real money balances measured in
units of labour (as compared to L(r, Y ) which is the demand function for
real money balances measured in units of output). For example, if W is $10
4.1. REFINEMENTS OF THE KEYNESIAN MODEL 37
per hour, a nominal money stock of $100 would represent a real money stock
of 10 labour-hours. The LM curve would remain the same except that the
constant underlying it is now M/W instead of M/P and its slope would be
steeper. None of the conclusions reached earlier change.
A final refinement of the Keynesian model is the modification of the con-
sumption and investment functions to let consumption be a function of the
interest rate as well as the level of income and investment be a function of
the level of income as well as the interest rate. In the case of investment,
it will be recalled that the II curve in Figure 3.2 represented a ranking of
projects by the interest rate at which their present values would become
positive and at which they would therefore be undertaken. Since the pro-
duction function Y = F (N ) has a constant capital stock embedded in it,
the marginal product of capital will increase when the quantity of labour
employed increases relative to the quantity of capital. This increase in the
marginal product of capital as employment and output increase results in
higher earnings on all investment projects in the economy. An increase in
the level of income will thus cause the II curve to shift upward in Figure 4.4
and the investment function must be rewritten
I = I(r, Y ) (4.6)
r
I
rm I
ro
I
I
Y
I0 I1 Im
Figure 4.4: The Investment Function Responding to and Increase in In-
come
Y1 in the two years. The maximum that could be consumed in year 0 (leaving
nothing for consumption in year 1) is given by m0 and the maximum that
can be consumed in year 1 if nothing is consumed in year 0 is m1 . These
quantities are given by
Y1
m0 = Y0 + (4.7)
1+r
and
m1 = (1 + r)Y0 + Y1 (4.8)
Given the rate of interest, the consumer can allocate her consumption in-
tertemporally along the straight line joining the points m1 and m0 . The
slope of this line can be obtained by dividing (4.8) by (4.7) to yield −(1+r).
The negative sign is added because the slope is obviously negative. Given
the budget constraint, the consumer will choose that allocation of her in-
come to consumption in the two years that maximizes her utility, putting
her on the highest possible indifference curve. This occurs at point a in
Figure 4.5.
Now suppose that the rate of interest rises. This will increase the slope
of the budget constraint, rotating it around its position at point b. At point
4.1. REFINEMENTS OF THE KEYNESIAN MODEL 39
Period 1
m1
c
d
C1 a
Y1
b
C0 Y0 m0 Period 0
Figure 4.5: The Consumption-Saving Decision in Response to Interest Rate
Changes.
position and convexity of the new indifference curve the consumer ends up
being on. Since we can say little about the shape of the indifference curves,
we cannot rule out either an increase or decrease in current consumption in
response to a rise in the interest rate.
In any event, equation (3.2) must be written as
C = C(Y − T, r) (4.9)
1 − ∂C/∂Yd − ∂I/∂Y
∂C/∂r + ∂I/∂r
is negative.5 The IS curve remains negatively sloped and shifts to the right
with increases in government expenditure and cuts in taxes.
These refinements leave the policy implications of the model unchanged.
While the early radical conclusion that there is no natural tendency of the
economy to gravitate to full employment is unjustified, the Keynesian anal-
ysis contributed in an important way to our knowledge of macroeconomics.
First, to the extent that wages are inflexible downward (and upward as well)
in the short run, the model provides us with a vehicle for analyzing the ef-
fects on output, employment, and interest rates of a variety of exogenous
influences including the policies of the government.
Second, the Keynesian analysis brought out implications of government
tax and expenditure policies for output and price level determination that
5
The slope is obtained from the total derivative of (4.10) which can be expressed
The slope is the ratio dr/dY . Stability of the model requires that (1−∂C/∂Yd −∂I/∂Y ) be
positive. The combined terms (∂C/∂Yd + ∂I/∂Y ) are defined as the marginal propensity
to spend, the sum of the marginal propensity to consume and the marginal propensity
to invest. ∂I/∂r is clearly negative, but there is ambiguity about the sign of ∂C/∂r.
Nevertheless, economists usually assume that ∂C/∂r will never be large enough if it is
positive to offset ∂I/∂r so the overall expression (∂C/∂r + ∂I/∂r) is always negative.
4.1. REFINEMENTS OF THE KEYNESIAN MODEL 41
were not present in the simplistic classical formulation. In the crude classical
model, the composition of aggregate expenditure—i.e., its division between
consumption, investment and government demand—had no effect on the
level of aggregate demand and prices. Exogenous shifts in consumption and
investment resulted in changes in the interest rate but the interest rate had
no effect on the quantity of money demanded. As a result, the aggregate
demand curve of Figure 2.3 remained unchanged. If one were to impose
on the crude Keynesian model the classical assumption that desired money
holdings are a rigid proportion of current income—i.e., that the income
velocity of money is constant—the LM curve becomes vertical as shown in
Figure 4.6. Since changes in the interest rate have no effect on desired money
holdings, a specific real income is necessary to get the public to hold each
particular real stock of money. The partial derivatives of the real money
stock with respect to the interest rate become zero in equations (4.2) and
(4.5) and the partial derivatives with respect to output become equal to k
or 1/V . We can replace equation (4.2) with
M
= kY (4.11)
P
or, if we wish to express the money stock in labour rather than output units,
with
M kY
= . (4.12)
W G(Y )
r
IS LM LM
IS
IS IS
Y
Y0 Y f
Figure 4.6: IS-LM Diagram when the Demand for Money is Insensitive to
Interest Rates
Y = Yf . (4.13)
excess money holdings to purchase goods. A rise in the price level will be
required to induce them not to do this.
AD
P
AD AS
KAS
KAS
P0
P1
a
P2 AD
AD
Y
Y0 Yf
Figure 4.7: Aggregate Demand and Keynesian and Full-Employment
Aggregate Supply Curves
M
= k(r + Ep , Y ) Y = L(r + Ep , Y ). (4.15)
P
A rise in the rate of interest arising from, say, a shift in the investment
function, a cut in taxes, an increase in government expenditure or an increase
in the expected rate of inflation, will now reduce desired money holdings and
shift the AD curve upward to the right.
44 CHAPTER 4. THE KEYNESIAN-CLASSICAL SYNTHESIS
As was noted in Chapter 2, the classical model can also be easily mod-
ified to introduce money wage rigidity. Equation (4.4) is derived from the
classical production relationships. If we fix W in that equation, it gives a
positive relationship between Y and P . As P rises, the real wage rate falls,
inducing firms to hire more labour and leading to an increase in employ-
ment. When the money wage is fixed, therefore, equation (4.4) becomes the
aggregate supply curve instead of (4.13). Shifts in the AD curve arising from
changes in the nominal money stock, in the demand for money, or in taxes
or government expenditure (in the case where the aggregate demand curve
is represented by (4.15)) now lead to changes in the level of employment just
as in the Keynesian model.
This refined version of the classical model is portrayed in Figure 4.7. The
curve KAS, representing equation (4.4) can be referred to as the Keynesian
aggregate supply curve since it gives the relationship between the price level
and the level of output produced under the Keynesian assumption that the
money wage rate is fixed. Shifts in the aggregate demand curve arising from
monetary or fiscal policy or other exogenous forces now lead to changes in
output and employment as the intersection of AD and KAS moves along the
curve KAS. In the classical case where money wages are flexible, W adjusts
so that the Keynesian aggregate supply curve always intersects AS at the
point where AD intersects AS.
Y = Yf (4.13)
4.3. THE SYNTHESIZED MODEL 45
When wages are fixed, the top three equations solve for r, Y , and P . In
classroom analysis, equation (4.4) is often replaced with the simple price
level constraint
P = P̄ . (4.16)
r = E(Y − T, G) (4.17)
M
P = (4.18)
L(E(Y − T, G) + Ep , Y )
which is the equation of the AD curve. Since this equation is the solution of
the IS and LM equations, the AD curve traces out all the alternative com-
binations of P and Y for which the IS and LM curves intersect, holding the
nominal money supply, the expected inflation rate, government expenditure
that the nominal money supply remains constant, is generally correct but we have to
recognize that technological improvements may also shift the demand function for money.
For these reasons, the entire analysis in this book assumes that the level technology is
constant—to analyze economic growth problems we need different tools.
48 CHAPTER 4. THE KEYNESIAN-CLASSICAL SYNTHESIS
Exercises
1. A school teacher earns $1000 per month, each month of the year. As soon
as her income is received each month she goes to the bank and cashes her
paycheck, pays her rent of $350 and puts $50 into an RRSP. The remainder
she keeps on hand as cash, spending it evenly over the month.
a) How much money (i.e., cash) does she hold on the first day of the month
after paying her rent and purchasing her RRSP but before making any
expenditures? On the last day of the month after making that day’s ex-
penditures? On average during the month? What would be a reasonable
estimate of her demand for money? Of her propensity to hold money (i.e.,
her level of k)?
b) Now suppose that the teacher has the opportunity of putting money into
an non-chequable savings account at the beginning of the month and then
making an extra trip to the bank at the middle of the month to draw it out
in anticipation of her daily expenditures during the latter half of the month.
Suppose that she earns 1% per month (12% per year) on her savings account.
Suppose further that it costs her 24 cents to make the extra trip to the bank.
How much does she gain by doing this? What will be her demand for money
and propensity to hold money now?
c) If we now assume that the teacher can make as many trips to the bank as
she wants, at a cost of 24 cents per trip, what will be the optimum number
of trips? The optimum demand for money? The optimum propensity to
hold money?
d) Suppose now that the interest rate falls to 12 % per month. What will be
the optimum number of trips to the bank now? Her demand for money?
Her propensity to hold money?
e) What does this example suggest about the relationship between the quan-
tity of money demanded and the rate of interest, holding the level of income
constant? Why does this relationship arise?
f) Now suppose that the teacher gets promoted to Head of Department and
receives a pay raise to $1500 per month. Suppose now that she decides to
put $150 per month into an RRSP and gets a better apartment costing $450
per month. What now will be her demand for money when the interest
rate is 1% per month? When it is 12 % per month? What does this suggest
about the effect of a change in income on the demand for money, holding
the interest rate constant? Why does this effect occur?
50 CHAPTER 4. THE KEYNESIAN-CLASSICAL SYNTHESIS
1) The IS curve.
5) The LM curve when the real money supply is measured in labour units.
b) How does the LM curve derived in 5) above compare with the one derived
in 4)?
c) Assume the following values for the exogenous variables:
T = .5 taxes
G = .5 government spending
M =1 money supply
4.3. THE SYNTHESIZED MODEL 51
4. Using the standard IS-LM framework, analyze step by step the effects on
output and employment and prices of
a) an increase in the money supply.
b) an increase in the demand for money.
c) a cut in taxes.
d) an increase in government expenditure.
e) an economy-wide increase in the money wage rate brought about by union
activity.
Use, alternatively, both Keynesian and classical assumptions about the func-
tioning of the labour market—assume that the former apply to the short run
and the latter to the long-run.
53
54 CHAPTER 5. MONETARY POLICY CONTROVERSIES
r
IS Yf
IS
LM
LM
r0
r1
r2
LM
LM IS IS
Y
Y0 Y f
Figure 5.1: Interest Rate vs. Money Supply Targeting
expanded sufficiently to shift the LM curve to LM0 and drive the interest
rate all the way down to r2 . Had the authorities looked at the money sup-
ply instead of the interest rate, they would have realized that no increase in
the money supply had occurred as the interest rate fell to r1 . Easy money
implies an increase in the money supply—a fall in the interest rate does not
necessarily imply that the money supply has increased.
But interest rates would be a better indicator of monetary tightness or
ease than the nominal money supply if the exogenous shock to the economy
was a shift of the demand function for money rather than a shift in the
investment function. Suppose in Figure 5 that the initial equilibrium is at
r2 and Yf and that the demand for money increases, shifting the LM curve
from LM0 to LM. The interest rate rises to r1 , reducing the levels of output
and employment. If the authorities conclude from the high level of interest
rates that money is too tight, they will be correct. If they look at the
money supply they will conclude that monetary policy has not changed. In
this case, stabilization of the interest rate will stabilize employment while
stabilization of the money supply will not. It can be argued, however, that
even in this case the authorities can usefully focus on the money supply—
whenever there is less than full employment the money supply is too low and
whenever there is inflation the money supply is too high. The money supply
should be increased or reduced accordingly, regardless of what is happening
to interest rates. Unfortunately, this argument is weakened by the fact that,
in the real world, money supply changes (and interest changes as well) affect
employment and output with a lag. By the time unemployment is observed,
money will have been too tight for several months, and it will take several
more months for an easing of monetary policy to have its effect on the
unemployment rate.
The case for using the money supply rather than market interest rates as
an indicator of monetary tightness or ease is strengthened when the expected
inflation rate is not zero. The observed market interest rate is the nominal
interest rate, which equals the real rate plus the expected rate of inflation.
Higher nominal interest rates need not signify higher real rates because the
expected inflation rate may have risen. And it is the real interest rate
that affects consumption and investment. Thus in the midst of continuing
inflation the authorities could be led to conclude from increasingly higher
market interest rates that monetary policy is becoming increasingly tight,
when the higher interest rates in fact indicate that the public is expecting
greater and greater inflation on account of increasingly high rates of nominal
money growth. Correct monetary policy in this case requires keeping careful
track of the rate of expansion of the nominal money supply.
56 CHAPTER 5. MONETARY POLICY CONTROVERSIES
3
Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, The Great Contraction: 1929-33, Princeton
University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 1963.
4
This is not to suggest that bank failures caused the Great Depression. It is agreed
that in their absence a major recession would still have occurred. Opinions differ as to
the cause of that recession.
57
the authorities know it. Given the lag between an increase in the nominal
money supply and its effect on economic activity, it is virtually impossible
to produce a countercyclical pattern of monetary growth.
Friedman argued that the role of the monetary authority should be to
create a stable rate of monetary growth. Attempts to exercise discretion—
that is, to adjust money growth to offset current movements in economic
activity—are doomed to failure because by the time a specific policy action
to cure a recession takes effect the economy is moving out of the recession
and into the next expansion. As a result, the authorities tend to increase
rather than reduce the cyclical variability of the economy.
There are two problems with the constant money growth rule argument.
First, the money supply can be defined in different ways as follows:
M1 CP + DD c+d
= = (5.1)
H CP + BR c+f
M2 CP + DD + TD c+1
= = (5.2)
H CP + BR c+f
CP
c =
DD + TD
DD
d =
DD + TD
BR
f = .
DD + TD
These different monetary aggregates often behave differently through time,
the growth rates of some increasing while the growth rates of others are
decreasing. It is not clear which aggregate the authorities should stabilize.
The second problem is the difficulty of dealing with changes in the rates
of growth of the ratio of desired money holdings to income. An upward
59
Since a constant money growth rule has never been adopted in the past,
there is no historical evidence to bring to bear in settling this debate. Both
sides are forced to argue on the basis of predictions about how the economy
will function under a set of institutions and forces that have never been
experienced.
61
Exercises
1. True or false: Explain your answer briefly.
b) Neither the level of market interest rates nor the observed level of the
nominal money supply give a clear indication of whether monetary
policy is tight or easy.
d) The basic goal of monetary policy is to keep the market rate of interest
equal to the natural rate of interest—that is, to keep the LM curve
stable through time.
2. Outline briefly the case for using rules rather than discretion in the exer-
cise of monetary policy. Then outline the case for using discretion instead of
rules. What information do we need to make it worthwhile to use discretion?
62 CHAPTER 5. MONETARY POLICY CONTROVERSIES
Chapter 6
The Keynesian notion that the government could keep the economy at full
employment by judicious manipulation of taxes and expenditure ushered in
a radical change in the focus of policy discussion. That simplistic view of
the government’s policy options was challenged, however, and has since been
considerably eroded in debate. The major focus of the attack was on the
effects of tax cuts, although the Keynesian conclusions regarding the effects
of shifts in government expenditure are equally, if not more, open to dispute.
1
See Milton Friedman, A Theory of the Consumption Function, Princeton University
Press, 1957.
63
64 CHAPTER 6. FISCAL POLICY
and permanent income can be defined as the interest rate times that level
of wealth
Yp = r W. (6.2)
Since individuals will, at least at some stages of their lives, want to increase
their permanent income through time, consumption will be some fraction,
less than unity, of permanent income. Accordingly, an increase in current
disposable income will lead to an increase in consumption only if it represents
an increase in wealth and permanent income.
In this respect, one can think of three kinds of increases (or decreases)
in current income. First there could be an increase in current income ac-
companied by the anticipation of an equally higher income level in all future
years. This increase in current income reflects an equivalent increase in
permanent income, and consumption in the current and all future periods
will increase. Second, there could be an increase in current income that
the consumer views as a random fluctuation to be offset next year or in
some subsequent year by a decline current income of equal present value.
In this case wealth has not increased—the increase in current income was
transitory. Third, there could be an increase in the present period’s income
with no anticipation that income in the next or subsequent periods will be
higher or lower than if the current income change had not occurred. This
can be referred to as a windfall —a one-time receipt. Current income and
wealth will increase by an amount equal to the windfall but future income
will remain unchanged. Permanent income will increase by the interest rate
times the windfall increase in wealth—i.e., by the interest rate times the
increase in current income. Of course, a windfall need not be restricted to
just the current period. There may be an anticipation of higher income for
the current period, next year and the year after, with income returning to its
initial level in all subsequent years. In this case wealth will increase by the
present value of the windfall receipts and permanent income will increase by
the interest rate times that increase in wealth.
This has important implications with respect to the effects of a tax cut
on current consumption. If the cut in taxes is a permanent one, expected
to last forever, then disposable income will rise permanently as a result of
the tax cut. If disposable income equals consumers’ actual income (which
6.2. FINANCING A TAX CUT BY PRINTING MONEY 65
implies that anything produced with the taxes the government is levying is
worthless!) the effect will be an increase in consumption by some fraction of
the tax cut, that fraction being the proportion of permanent income being
consumed. A permanent tax cut of, say, $100 would increase permanent
income by $100 and consumption would rise permanently by $80 where the
fraction of permanent income being consumed—or the marginal propensity
to consume out of permanent income—is 0.8. On the other hand, suppose
that the tax reduction applies to this year only, with taxes returning to their
previous level in subsequent years. In this case wealth will rise by the $100
and, given an interest rate of, say, 5% the increase in permanent income
will be only $5. In this case, the resulting increase in consumption would
be only $4.
The first question that must be asked when analyzing the effects on
aggregate demand of a given tax cut is: For what period will taxes be
lowered? It is inappropriate to routinely assume that any cut in taxes will
be a permanent one.
are going to be eroded by precisely the amount of the cut in taxes. Sup-
pose, for example, that current real output is 100 units, real government
expenditure is 50 units and real taxes are 50 units. Suppose further that
the price level—the price of a unit of current output—is $1 and that the
nominal money stock is $50. It follows that the real money stock, measured
in units of output, is 50. Assume now that the government cuts taxes from
50 units to 45 units, financing its budget deficit of $5 by increasing the
nominal money stock to $55. When the economy is at full employment, the
price level must rise proportionally with the increase in the money stock to
$1.1 per unit of output and the real money stock must remain at 50. The
public has received a tax reduction of $5 from the government but is forced
to spend the entire amount to acquire sufficient additional nominal money
balances to maintain its real money holdings at the desired level (which has
not changed because there has been no prior change in wealth or in the rate
of interest). Since after reestablishing its equilibrium real money stock the
public has no more funds, in real terms, than it had before the tax cut,
consumption cannot increase. The government gave the public a reduction
in taxes but forced it to accumulate $5 of money balances to hold its real
money stock intact. These additional $5 of money holdings were given to the
public in return for the same goods the government would have purchased
with the revenue lost by reducing taxes. There are no effects on any real
variables in the economy. In fact, the government has not really cut taxes
at all. It gave the public a reduction of $5 of, say, income taxes, while at
the same time reducing the real value of the nominal money stock it held
before the tax cut by exactly the same amount—the public has, in effect,
paid a $5 tax on its money holdings. The government has replaced a tax on
income with a tax on money.
How will this change if there is less-than-full employment? Suppose for
the sake of argument that the public expects the lower taxes and the result-
ing addition to nominal money holdings to continue every year. Suppose
further that there is less-than-full employment and the price level is ex-
pected to remain constant. In continuation of the previous example, the
public is now expecting to receive a cash payment of $5 in every period
from now to infinity. This case payment will be treated in the same way
as a $5 increase in income receipts in the current and all future years from
any source. Permanent income will increase by $5 and consumption in all
periods will rise accordingly.
But the increased flow of money transfers from the government cannot
possibly be regarded as permanent because as the money supply expands
full employment will be reached. We have already shown that tax cuts fi-
6.2. FINANCING A TAX CUT BY PRINTING MONEY 67
r
IS IS Yf
LM
LM
LM
ro
LM a
LM IS
LM IS
Y
Y0 Yf
Figure 3.4: A Tax Cut Financed by Printing Money
government has, in effect, arranged $100 loans from the B-people to the
A-people. The community as a whole has paid the government $100 per
capita for bonds in lieu of paying the $100 in taxes. Every year it receives
$10 interest per capita on the bonds and pays $10 per capita in additional
taxes to cover that interest. Clearly, people are on average no better off
than if they had paid the taxes in the first place. All that has happened
is that the A-people have been allowed to defer $100 in taxes in return for
paying $10 interest per year to the B-people.
This is as one might expect—as long as government expenditure is the
same, the government is taking the same amount of real resources from the
private sector whether the funds are acquired by taxes or bond sales. To
the extent that consumers’ wealth is unaffected, it is realistic to assume
that their current and future consumption will be unaffected. There thus
appears to be no basis for assuming that a tax cut will cause consumption
to increase.
The notion that it makes no difference whether government expenditure
is financed by bonds or taxes is known as Ricardian equivalence. If it holds,
and if the inflationary effects of monetary finance are fully anticipated, T
does not belong in the consumption function—a cut in taxes will not shift
the IS curve to the right, and Keynesian tax policy will be impotent.2
they will earn $10 interest, while at the same time paying $10 annually in
taxes to finance these interest payments. The wealth of neither the A-heirs
nor the B-heirs will be affected by the tax cut. During their lifetimes, A-
people will shift consumption from their old age to their youth as a result of
having borrowed from B-people, while B-people will shift consumption from
their youth to their old age as a result of having lent to the A-people. At the
ends of their lives, however, they will leave the same bequests to their heirs
as originally planned. The heirs will start with a clean slate, their interest
earnings on government bonds exactly covered by additional taxes. The net
effect of the shift from tax to bond finance will be zero.
Suppose that in the face of the tax cut and bond issue, the A-people
do not want to borrow from the B-people. Nothing says that they have to.
They can themselves buy $100 of the new bonds, an amount equal to their
tax cut, leaving the B-people to do the same. If the B-people remain anxious
to buy more than $100 worth of bonds per capita they will bid down the
interest rate the government will have to offer on the bonds until this excess
demand for bonds has been eliminated.
As long as the current owners of wealth are voluntarily leaving bequests
to their children, they choose the magnitude of these bequests on the basis of
utility maximization. If the government cuts taxes on the current generation
and raises taxes on future generations, the public will simply adjust the level
of bequests to re-establish the utility maximizing intergenerational transfer.
Indeed, if the public wishes to consume now at the expense of future gen-
erations, it can do so without the fiscal machinations of the government by
simply reducing bequests.3
The intergenerational argument makes clear, however, that if some mem-
bers of the community have no heirs or do not care about the welfare of their
heirs, a tax cut financed by selling bonds can have an effect on the perceived
wealth of the current generation and on its consumption. But there is no
reason to assume that the impact effect on consumption of this intergenera-
tional transfer will equal the marginal propensity to consume times the tax
cut, as crude Keynesian models assert. Most people have heirs and most
3
The classic analysis of this problem can be found in Robert Barro, “Are Government
Bonds Net Wealth?” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 82, No. 2, 1974, 343–348. See
also the attacks on Barro’s position by Martin Feldstein, “Perceived Wealth in Bonds
and Social Security: A Comment” and James M. Buchanan, “Barro on the Ricardian
Equivalence Theorem”, and Barro’s reply, “Reply to Feldstein and Buchanan”, Journal
of Political Economy, Vol. 84, No. 2, 1976, 331–349. An additional and extensive critique
of Barro’s position is given in James Tobin, Asset Accumulation and Economic Activity,
Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1980.
72 CHAPTER 6. FISCAL POLICY
4
For a fuller treatment of this argument, see J. E. Floyd and J. Allan Hynes, “Debt
Illusion and Imperfect Information”, European Economic Review, Vol. 4, 1979.
6.6. HUMAN CAPITAL MARKET EFFICIENCY 73
that tax cuts in recessions will have a positive effect on what we measure
as consumption and tax increases in booms will tend to cause measured
consumption to be lower than otherwise. These effects of tax changes are in
the directions postulated by Keynesian theory. And it might be reasonable
to expect that the full amount of these tax changes will feed into consump-
tion because the consumption changes involved are really transitory changes
in savings that directly involve changes in durable investment. Depending
upon the proportion of consumers who find it useful to vary their purchases
of durables rather than borrow in the credit market in bad times and pay
back in good times, the effects of tax changes on measured consumption
through this avenue could be quite large.
Individuals who borrow and lend from themselves by varying their pur-
chases of consumer durables can be thought of as credit constrained in the
sense that they cannot borrow and lend freely at rates of interest equivalent
to the returns they earn on personally held durable goods. The returns on
durable goods are the value of the services received from using these goods
as a proportion of their cost. Their cost has two components—the interest
foregone on other assets that could be held instead of the durables, and
depreciation per period.
Y = C + I + G = Cp + Cg + Ip + Ig (6.4)
C = Cp + Cg = C(Y − T, r) (6.5)
Y = C(Y − T, r) + Ip + Ig . (6.6)
6.8. CHANGES IN GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE 77
Real Interest
Rate
I
I
ro
I I
Investment
Io I1
Figure 3.2: Total Private and Public Investment
C = C(Y, r, Ω) (6.7)
in the deficit is financed and the circumstances regarding the public’s inter-
pretation of that change in the deficit. Indeed, the fact that consumption
will decline when the public realizes that wealth effects of past deficits were
illusory suggests that, for many problems, past deficits should also be in-
cluded as arguments in the function C(. . .).
It is also clear that increases in government expenditure can not be rou-
tinely viewed as having the standard Keynesian multiplier effects on output.
The most sensible way to handle crowding out complications would be to
treat the level of government expenditure as an argument in the investment
function, with investment now incorporating both private and public capital
formation, rather than as a separate component of aggregate demand. And,
since government investment may have a negative or positive wealth effect
and government consumption may under some circumstances cause total
consumption, of both private and government supplied goods, to increase,
government expenditure should appear as an argument in the consumption
function as well. Accordingly, equation (6.6) would become
where the functions C(. . .) and I(. . .) now refer to all consumption and
investment expenditure, public and private, and the derivatives ∂C/∂G and
∂I/∂G will be positive, negative, or zero, depending on the nature of the
particular increase in government expenditure, its wealth effects, and its
division between consumption and investment goods.
The conclusion is that Keynesian tax and expenditure policies will in
many cases shift the IS curve to the right as the traditional analysis pos-
tulates, but in some circumstances the effects may be non-existent or even
perverse.
80 CHAPTER 6. FISCAL POLICY
Exercises
1. True or false: Explain your answer briefly.
a) The present value of income plus bequests received from the previous
generation must equal the present value of consumption plus bequests
to one’s heirs.
c) A switch from bond to tax finance will lower consumption and ag-
gregate demand because it makes the market for human capital less
efficient.
f) A one year income tax rebate of $200 will increase current consumption
by the marginal propensity to consume multiplied by $200.
2. Suppose that the government gives the public an income tax rebate
of $100 million in the aggregate, and finances the deficit by printing $100
million of nominal money balances. Assume that the nominal money stock
is originally $1 billion and nominal income is originally $3 billion.
a) Demonstrate that when the economy is at full employment the govern-
ment has really not cut taxes at all, but has simply substituted a tax on
money holdings for a reduced tax on income.
b) Does your argument in a) also hold if there is less than full employment?
Why or why not?
c) What would have been the effect on the IS curve had the government,
instead of cutting taxes by $100 million, printed up $100 million and used it
to purchase bonds from the private sector? Assume that any interest earned
on these newly purchased bonds will be used to reduce taxes in the future.
3. Suppose that the government establishes an airline and purchases a num-
ber of jet aircraft from a domestic manufacturer for that purpose. Outline
6.9. REQUIRED MODIFICATIONS OF THE MODEL 81
the effects of this policy on the level of investment, the IS curve, the LM
curve, and the level of output and employment when the economy is initially
at less-than-full-employment. How would your analysis change if there is full
employment?
5. Suppose that there are two types of people, A-people and B-people.
The two groups are equal in number and each person has a life expectancy
of two years. Assume that the A-people are childless but the B-people
each have two heirs whose consumption they value as highly as their own.
In particular, suppose that each multi-generational B-family—that is, each
B-person, his/her heirs, and his/her heirs’ heirs, etc.—acts like a single
infinitely lived consumer who consumes each year a constant fraction, equal
to 0.8, of permanent income. Suppose that the A-people, on the other hand,
choose to distribute their consumption equally in the two remaining years of
their life, regardless of the rate of interest. Assume that the government cuts
everyone’s taxes in the first of the two remaining years of this generation’s
lifetime by $1000 and floats $1000 worth of debt per capita in that period.
Taxes then revert to their old level plus an amount necessary to finance
the interest on the new debt in all subsequent years. Assume that the
equilibrium market interest rate on government bonds is constant and equal
to the real return to investing in real capital in the economy, namely 10%
per year. Suppose further that all individuals are fully informed of all the
consequences of the government’s policy.
a) Which people, the A-people or the B-people will buy the government
bonds?
f) How would your answer change if it happened that the A-people were
the same as the B-people with the exception that all members of both
groups have a single heir?
Chapter 7
While the traditional classical model assumed that wages adjust instanta-
neously to excess demand and supply, everyone knew that unemployment
is a characteristic of depressed periods. Various loosely formulated argu-
ments, most of them familiar today, emerged over the years to explain this
phenomenon. Keynes, spurred by the need to explain the massive unem-
ployment of the Great Depression, adopted the extreme assumption that
money wages are rigidly fixed when aggregate demand falls below the full
employment level. This view that for institutional and other reasons money
wages do not respond to excess supply in the labour market dominated pro-
fessional thinking for two or three decades. Yet everyone knew that this was
an extreme assumption—money wages frequently fall during recessions.
83
84 CHAPTER 7. RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
UNEMPLOYMENT RATE
Chart 7.2:
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
5 5.5 6 6.5 7 7.5 8 8.5 9 9.5 10
UNEMPLOYMENT RATE
Chart 7.3:
86 CHAPTER 7. RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS
curve extending over long periods is extremely shaky.2 Chart 7.2 plots the
scatter diagram of inflation and unemployment for the whole period 1956–
1989. No clear negative relationship between the two variables is present.
Nevertheless, for the sub-period 1974–89, plotted in Chart 7.3, a negative
Phillips relationship, albeit rather weak, is again observable. Since the aver-
age inflation rate in the 1974-79 period is substantially higher than that in
the 1956–69 period, as can be seen from the scales of the respective charts,
the evidence is consistent with a Phillips curve that shifted upward between
the two periods.
What, then, is the process by which wages and prices change in im-
perfectly competitive markets? Is it possible in such markets for rational
workers and firms to set wages that will result in less labour being employed
than would, in retrospect, be optimal? The conclusion that emerges from
the analysis of these questions over the past forty years is that there is no
one single process by which prices are set. Three different types of wage and
price setting mechanisms which can result in observed ‘unemployment’ have
been identified.3
expected and the pool of unemployed workers shrinks below its natural size.
Once workers realize that the state of aggregate demand has shifted
reservation wages will adjust and the unemployment rate will return to its
natural level. Indeed, deviations of employment from the natural rate can
be viewed as an integral part of the process by which workers acquire infor-
mation about changes in aggregate demand and labour market conditions.
This story applies equally well whether firms set offering wages and work-
ers search for employment or workers set asking wages and firms search for
workers. A crucial ingredient of the search process, however, must be a
degree of non-homogeneity of both workers and jobs. Workers are slightly
different and are thus worth slightly different amounts to firms that know
about them. Jobs and employers are also slightly different and yield differ-
ent amounts of non-pecuniary utility to workers. Negotiation between buyer
and seller is therefore a necessary ingredient of labour market equilibrium.
The search theory goes part of the way in explaining both normal fric-
tional unemployment and the positive correlation of the unemployment rate
with the business cycle. And it is more realistic and the auction theory in
that it allows for the fact that workers are actively searching for jobs rather
than simply making employment decisions at existing market wage rates.
Like the auction theory, however, it implies that quit rates should increase
in recessions and decrease in booms, as workers will tend to regard their
current employment situations as firm specific. When firms lower wages
in a recession, some workers will quit and begin a search for employment
elsewhere at wages that have not fallen. In fact, quit rates decrease during
recessions and increase during booms, the opposite of what the search the-
ory predicts. The search theory also fails to explain another very important
fact—that firms actually lay workers off during recessions and refuse to hire
workers who are clearly willing to work for them at the wages they currently
are paying. Firms do not cut wages and maintain employment during peri-
ods of slack demand—instead, they tend to maintain wages and reduce the
number of workers employed.
workers are risk averse they will seek ways of insuring themselves against
fluctuations in their incomes arising from variations in the demand for the
narrow range of labour services they provide. The owners of firms, on the
other hand, can diversify easily by owning little pieces of a large number
of firms together with a variety of other assets. To the extent that the
individual firm assumes some of the risk associated with fluctuations in the
demand for its workers’ human capital, it can diversify that risk away. It is
profitable, therefore, for the firm to assume some of that risk in return for
the acceptance by workers of a lower than average level of wages. And it is
profitable for workers to accept lower wages if the stability of their incomes
can be increased. Firms and workers thus make a contract according to
which workers accept a lower wage in return for a guarantee of long-term
income stability. This theory of price adjustment is thus referred to as the
contract theory.6
The contract between the firm and its workers may be an explicit one,
hammered out in union-management negotiations, or it may be implicit,
guaranteed solely by the fact that the firm must maintain its reputation as
a ‘good employer’ if it is to be able to successfully hire workers at reasonable
wages over the long run. The essence of these contracts, whether explicit
or implicit, is that the firm guarantees employment for a large fraction of
its employees at real wage rates that reflect their mean or average marginal
productivities over periods that may extend as long as a lifetime. In the
most extreme cases the current wage paid could be viewed as one of many
instalment payments in a lifetime contract. As a result of these considera-
tions, the wage paid at any particular point in time may be above or below
the workers’ marginal products at that point in time. The losses to firms
from paying wages that differ from workers’ marginal products is compen-
sated for by the gain in profits by paying lower wages, on average, than
would otherwise be the case.
The firm can be thought of as having several classes of employees, ranked
by seniority. The lowest class gets laid off first when the demand for the
firm’s output declines, the next lowest class gets laid off next, and so forth,
with the very senior employees getting laid off only if demand declines to the
point where the survival of the firm is in jeopardy. Wages are maintained
in the face of these layoffs and employment is kept at a point where the
6
Donald F. Gordon, “A Neo-Classical Theory of Keynesian Unemployment”, Economic
Enquiry, Vol. 12, 1974, 431–459, develops an early version of the contract theory in detail
and presents, as well, a clear summary of the auction and search theories. John Taylor,
“Staggered Wage Setting in a Macro Model”, The American Economic Review, Papers
and Proceedings, May 1979, 108-113, presents a modified and refined version.
92 CHAPTER 7. RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS
marginal product of labour is substantially below the wage rate the firm is
paying to its employed workers. Similarly, employment will expand in times
when demand is high but the marginal product of labour will remain above
the wage rate being paid, the latter being equal to the average of labour’s
marginal productivity over the business cycle.
The contract theory thus explains why quit rates are low in recessions
and high in boom periods. And it also explains why firms lay off workers
in slack periods, refusing to hire individuals willing to work at wage rates
currently being paid.7
While wages are set under explicit or implicit contractual arrangements
with a time horizon that may be several years long, they nevertheless are
affected by current market conditions. Wages will be routinely increased
each year by the expected rate of inflation, and adjusted in response to in-
formation about the level of aggregate demand to maintain real wages at
the contractually agreed upon level. When, due to misinformation about
market conditions, wages are set too high in relation to product demand,
firms will end up hiring too few workers and producing too little output.
When workers and firms eventually realize that they are pricing labour too
high and firms are unable to product average output levels at a cost consis-
tent with market demand, the rates of increase of wages and perhaps even
the level of wages will be lowered. And when wages are set too low in rela-
tion to product demand, firms will find themselves using too many workers
on average and producing in excess of the normal full-employment output
level. Steps will be taken to bring wages up to a level consistent with the
productivity of labour at normal average output levels. It follows that when
aggregate demand unexpectedly increases as a result either of changes in
monetary and fiscal policy or exogenous shocks arising from factors beyond
anyone’s control, firms will employ too many workers and the unemployment
rate will fall below its normal or natural level. And when aggregate demand
unexpectedly declines, firms will lay workers off and unemployment will rise
above the natural rate.
7
Another argument that can explain why firms keep workers on the payroll at value
marginal products below the wage rate being paid under conditions of slack demand
relates to past investment of firm-specific capital by the firm in its workers. During their
employment, workers acquire specific knowledge and skills that will be lost to the firm
if they go to another firm after a layoff. It pays the firm to keep these workers around
because otherwise resources would have to be used to train someone new. Also, the firm
knows about the work habits and capabilities of its current workers, having fired at great
cost those hires who did not possess the necessary qualities. Since the firm does not
initially know the capability of new hires, another costly process of hiring and firing will
be required to acquire replacements for workers lost.
7.2. THEORIES OF PRICE ADJUSTMENT 93
Real Wage
Rate
S
D
w0
w1
S
D
No Nf Employment
Figure 7.1: Employment Changes in Response to Price Level Variations
higher Phillips curve during the later period. The Phillips curve shifted
upward because the higher average inflation rates experienced in the 1970s
became anticipated by wage and price setters.
Thus, policy makers do not face a tradeoff between inflation and unem-
ployment in the long run. A tradeoff appears in the short-run only if wage
and price setters are uninformed about what is happening.
W
P = (7.1)
G(Y )
This curve, portrayed as the curve KAS in Figure 4.7, was derived in Chapter
4.
If we hold the money wage rate fixed in Figure 7.1, which is a reproduc-
tion of Figures 2.2 and 4.3 with the added convenience assumption that the
7.3. RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS 97
ADe
P
ADe AS
EAS
EAS
Pe
Pe ADe
ADe
Y
Yf
Figure 7.2: Rational Expectations Equilibria
supply curve of labour in the economy is vertical, a rise in the price level
will cause the level of employment to increase as the real wage rate falls
from, say, w1 to w0 and we move downward to the right along the demand
curve for labour DD. The increase in employment results in an increase in
output and income, so the rise in the price level is associated with a rise in
income. It is this relationship between the price level and output that we
called the fixed (nominal) wage aggregate supply curve and portrayed as the
curve KAS in Figure 4.7 and we now rename EAS for reasons that will be
made clear shortly.
We can interpret the fixed wage as the wage rate chosen by price setters
on the basis of available information about the state of the economy. This
will be the wage rate, call it We , that they expect will lead to the normal
level of output and employment, which we continue to represent by Yf .
When employment is at the natural rate, the price level will be equal to
We
Pe = (7.2)
G(Yf )
Let us call Pe the expected price level and We the expected full-employment
equilibrium nominal wage rate. The actual level of P will exceed Pe when
98 CHAPTER 7. RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS
output is above normal and will be below Pe when output is below normal.
This relationship between P and Y is the curve EAS in Figure 7.2. If the
expected full-employment nominal wage rate rises as a result of an expected
economy-wide increase in aggregate demand, the expected level of prices
will also rise, say to Pe0 , and EAS will shift upward to EAS0 . Because the
level of the EAS curve depends on the level at which the wage rate is set,
which depends in turn on price setters’ expectations about the state of the
economy, we call this curve the expectations augmented aggregate supply
curve.
The slope of the expectations augmented aggregate supply curve in the
neighbourhood of the price-output combination represented by Pe and Yf
can be expressed as
P − Pe
λ=
Y − Yf
P − Pe = λ (Y − Yf ). (7.3)
AS
EAS
P2
Pe
AD 2
P1 ADe
AD 1
P3
AD 3
Y
Y3 Y1 Y f Y2
Figure 7.3: Alternative AD-AS-EAS Equilibria Variations
aggregate demand actually realized may be AD1 or AD2 and the associated
full-employment equilibrium prices P1 or P2 .
Only by chance will aggregate demand equal the level expected by price
setters. If it is above the expected level, the price level and level of output
will be above Pe and Yf ; if it is below the expected level, the price and output
levels will be below Pe and Yf . Note that if aggregate demand happens to be
AD2 the price level that actually occurs will be below the full-employment
price level P2 —this is because the level of employment will increase above
Yf . Similarly, if aggregate demand is AD1 the price level will be above the
full-employment level P1 because the level of employment will fall below
Yf . If the actions of the authorities or other unforseen forces unexpectedly
reduce aggregate demand to AD3 , the full-employment price level will be P3
and the level of output will fall to Y3 and the realized price level to somewhat
above P1 .
Nothing here implies that market participants’ expectations are not
rational—they based their judgments on all the information available. This
highlights a very important point about rational expectations. To be ratio-
nal, wage and price setters do not have to be right in their expectations—
they merely have to use all information available in forming them. If their
information about the future course of government policy and the structure
100 CHAPTER 7. RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS
Taylor.12 If workers and firms have formed explicit contracts with respect
to the future course of wages, they may not be able to reduce or increase
them even if they know they should. In this case the EAS curve is too high
and cannot be reduced. A solution would be for the government to conduct
expansionary policy to compensate, thereby shifting AD to the right to
achieve full-employment equilibrium. In this case expansionary policy has a
beneficial result even though private wage and price setters fully understand
what the government is doing.
If market participants form their expectations using all information avail-
able to them, and are free to readjust wages and prices accordingly, any
fully anticipated increase in aggregate demand resulting from fiscal expan-
sion will also result in an increase in wages and prices sufficient to offset
its effects on the level of employment. Since most tax and government ex-
penditure changes are either announced in advance or result from known
effects of changes in the level of economic activity on tax revenues and pub-
lic expenditure obligations, it would seem more likely that they will be fully
anticipated than would future changes in the rate of money growth.
One type of fiscal policy for which this is particularly true is built-in
stabilization. It has been frequently argued over the years that the govern-
ment should adopt tax policies that make tax revenues positively related
to the level of income and expenditure policies that lead to increases in
expenditures on unemployment insurance, make-work projects, welfare pay-
ments, and so forth, in hard times. As a result, a government deficit will
emerge to exert an expansionary effect on the economy in bad times and a
budgetary surplus will occur in good times to act as a brake on aggregate
demand. Such policies have been adopted by most industrial countries since
the Second World War.
Rational expectations considerations suggest that these built-in stabi-
lizers will have little effect on the level of employment. Everyone in the
economy who is affected by these policies is likely to have a clear idea of the
effects on his or her wealth position over the business cycle. It is thus almost
certain that wages and prices will be set with a view to these effects, with the
result that aggregate demand changes that result from built-in stabilizers
will be fully reflected in current wage and price levels.
Rational expectations considerations also suggest that government bud-
get deficits and surpluses may contain information about future monetary
changes that market participants will take into account when setting wages
12
John B. Taylor, “Staggered Wage Setting in a Macro Model”, The American Economic
Review, Papers and Proceedings, May 1979, 108–113.
102 CHAPTER 7. RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS
and prices. If the government is running a budget deficit, then it must ei-
ther raise future taxes to pay off the public debt that is being accumulated
as a result of that deficit or monetize that debt by exchanging it for newly
printed money. In either case the present value of all taxes, present and
future, including the tax on money resulting from the inflationary conse-
quences of monetizing the debt, must be the same whether or not there is
a budget deficit. If the debt resulting from budget deficits has been fre-
quently monetized in the past, current changes in the government deficit
may affect the public’s expectations about the degree of future monetary
expansion and inflation. The extent of these effects will depend on market
participants’ assessment of the likelihood that the government, in response
to political pressure, will try to ‘hide’ future taxes from some members of
the public by levying them on money holdings via inflation rather than on
incomes or on the consumption of particular commodities such as alcohol,
tobacco and gasoline. If monetization of the deficit is expected to occur not
too far in the future, it will affect the desired level of current money holdings
and the current level of wages and prices.
7.3. RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS 103
Exercises
1. Short answer questions.
g) How can one explain the simultaneous existence of inflation and un-
employment?
a) Fully anticipated inflation shifts the demand and supply curves for
labour upward in proportion.
b) The demand for labour depends on the actual price level while the
supply of labour depends on the expected price level.
a) A rational expectation of the price level is the price level agents expect
on the basis of all information available to them.
c) A rational expectation of the price level is that price level that will
occur if all currently available information turns out to be correct.
4. Using the standard aggregate demand and supply graphing, with the
price level on the vertical axis and the level of output on the horizontal one,
show the effects of
and
ys (t) = Yf + z[p(t) − pe (t)],
7.3. RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS 105
where b > 0, z > 0, and the characters y, m and p refer to the logarithms
of Y , M and P respectively, and the functional forms a(t), m(t), p(t), etc.,
indicate that the variables a, m, and p are functions of time.
Assume that expectations are rational and demonstrate that output at any
point in time will equal its full-employment level plus a component, positive
or negative, equal to the effects of unanticipated changes in a(t) and m(t).
Demonstrate from this that a fully anticipated increase in the money supply
will increase prices but have no effect on output, while an unanticipated
increase in the money supply will raise both output and the price level.
7. Suppose that the economy is characterized by the following behavioral
relationships and parameters:
y = 1 + .5 n + .04 t production function
y = .8 c + .2 k income identity
c = .5 + .75 y consumption function
k = .3 − .025 r investment function
m − p = −.95833 + y − .5 i demand function for money
y − yf = .2 [p − pe ] Lucas supply curve
where t is time and y, n, c, k, m and p are the logarithms of indexes of
output, employment, consumption (private plus government), investment
(private plus government), nominal money holdings and the price level, all
normalized at 1.0 in the initial year t = 0. The variables i and r are the
nominal and real interest rates in percent per year. The economy is initially
at its natural level of output and employment and the actual and expected
inflation rate is zero.
Calculate the effects on output and the price level of
a) A 10% increase in the nominal money supply that is fully anticipated
by wage and price setters.