China Japan Sericulture, Final Draft Version, Nov. 2003
China Japan Sericulture, Final Draft Version, Nov. 2003
China Japan Sericulture, Final Draft Version, Nov. 2003
Debin Ma*
Research Fellow,
Foundation for Advanced Studies on International Development (FASID)
Tokyo, Japan
And
Associate Professor GRIPS/FASID Joint Graduate Program,2-2 Wakamatsu-cho, Shinjuku-
ku,Tokyo, 162-8677 JapanEmail: [email protected]
Abstract
Raw silk exports constituted the most important foreign currency-earning item for China and Japan during
the period of 1860-1929. In the 1870s, China exported three times as much as Japan, but by the late 1920s,
Chinese exports became less than 30% of Japanese exports. This paper focuses on the comparative
performance of sericulture in Japan and the Lower Yangzi delta of China and constructs productivity
indices including a price dual total factor productivity index. These indices, supported by a comparative
narrative of the cocoon production and distribution sectors, suggest that Japan’s competitive success
resulted from a set of interrelated technical and institutional innovations. It was the different reform
policies pursued by Meiji Japan and Late-Qing China that created different conditions leading to the rise
and absence of innovations respectively in these two regions.
Key words: raw silk, cocoon, sericulture, total factor productivity, induced innovation, diffusion.
Economic Development and Cultural Change Jan. 2004, vol. 52, no. 2.
I thank comments and suggestions from Robert Gallman, Paul Rhode, Miles Fletcher, Takeshi
Abe, Loren Brandt, Yoshihisa Godo, Yujiro Hayami, Ryou Kambayashi, Paul Kandasamy,
Christopher Isett, Akinobu Kuroda, Yukihiko Kiyokawa, Angus Maddison, Ramon Myers,
Konosuke Odaka, Keijiro Otsuka, Jan Pieter Smits, Osamu Saito, Bart van Ark, and Claudio
Zanier as well as the participants of seminars at Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo University,
University of Groningen in the Netherlands, Washington University and University of Toronto.
My thanks also go to the editor, D. Gale Johnson, and referee of this Journal. Research grants
from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science, University of Missouri at St. Louis, and
Foundation for Advanced Studies on International Development are gratefully acknowledged.
The author alone is responsible for all errors.
Why Japan, not China, was the First to Develop in East Asia: Lessons from
Sericulture, 1850-1937
Abstract
Raw silk exports constituted the most important foreign currency-earning item for China and Japan during
the period of 1860-1929. In the 1870s, China exported three times as much as Japan, but by the late 1920s,
Chinese exports became less than 30% of Japanese exports. This paper focuses on the comparative
performance of sericulture in Japan and the Lower Yangzi delta of China and constructs productivity
indices including a price dual total factor productivity index. These indices, supported by a comparative
narrative of the cocoon production and distribution sectors, suggest that Japan’s competitive success
resulted from a set of interrelated technical and institutional innovations. It was the different reform
policies pursued by Meiji Japan and Late-Qing China that created different conditions leading to the rise
and absence of innovations in these two regions.
Although Japan and China are geographically and culturally close, today their levels of
economic development are worlds apart. The origin of this gap is relatively recent. As late as the
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, Japanese exports competed directly with Chinese in the
international market in such low value-added, labor-intensive products as raw silk. Between
1850 and 1930, raw silk ranked as the leading export for both countries, accounting for 20-40%
Raw silk consists of bundles of long, continuous silk threads used for silk weaving. Its
production starts with sericulture that involves the cultivation of mulberry trees and the
harvesting of the leaves to feed the silkworms that develop into self-spun cocoons. Traditionally,
cocoons were hand-reeled into raw silk within rural households. However, by the latter part of
the nineteenth century, the spread of mechanization was steadily shifting the reeling process to
modern factories.
The performance of the Japanese raw silk exports contrasted sharply with that of China. In
1873 China exported three times as much raw silk as Japan, but by 1905, Japanese raw silk
exports exceeded the Chinese, and in 1930, Japanese raw silk exports tripled those of China,
gaining a dominant 80% share in the global market.2 This contrast is puzzling given that as late
as the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, Chinese raw silk dominated the Japanese market, and
even in the mid-nineteenth century, Chinese silk enjoyed a more favorable global reputation than
that of Japan.
1
This paper presents a comparative analysis of this dramatic contrast by focusing on the cocoon
sector that contributes between 60% and 80% in the value added of raw silk, leaving the reeling
sector to future study.3 It also adopts a regional approach by comparing Japan with the Lower
Yangzi, the most advanced region of China. They are comparable in size, population and climate,
and are part of the wet-rice economies characterized by intensive agriculture, high population
density and small-scale farming. The broad similarities in initial conditions, factor endowment
ratios, crop choice and geographic environment offer us a rare case study of a relatively
controlled experiment.4
I argue that the Japanese success in silk export largely derived from the capacity of its
combination of traditional technology and modern science to overcome its resource constraints.
These accord well with the so-called induced innovation hypothesis advocated by Yujiro Hayami
to explain the overall success of Japanese agriculture for the same period.5 Thus, the absence of
the Japanese style of innovation was the cause of the stagnancy of the Lower Yangzi sericulture.
Why did broadly similar conditions induce innovations in one place and not the other? I argue
that important physical and social infrastructure built up after the Meiji reform in Japan, but
largely ignored by the Qing bureaucrats of the conservative Self-strengthening movement in the
Lower Yangzi during the latter part of the nineteenth century are the key to understanding this
contrast. This paper shows further that the Japanese success in turn profoundly impacted the
Lower Yangzi and elicited a dynamic technological and institutional response in the 1930s when
a minimal set of necessary conditions were gradually being put into place since the Meiji-inspired
voluminous survey reports on the Chinese silk sector written by Japanese specialists between the
1890s and the 1930s, and offers various technical and productivity indices including a price dual
2
total factor productivity (TFP) index. The quantitative analysis is further supported by a careful
examination of the institutional and technological developments in the cocoon production and
The rest of the paper is divided into three sections followed by a conclusion. Section I
presents comparative data on output, input and prices and estimates of partial and total factor
productivities. Section II, consisting of three parts, offers a comparative narrative of technology
and commercialization and a summary of growth accounting results. Section III describes the
Annual Japanese cocoon output (for both domestic consumption and export) almost quintupled
from the 1890s to the 1930s to about three hundred thousand tons. Comparable data were not
available for the Lower Yangzi. Robert Eng’s collection of various French and Japanese
scholars’ cocoon output estimates gave a range of between seventy thousand and one hundred
thousand metric tons, with growth rates largely stagnant for the Lower Yangzi between 1875 and
1930. Despite the data problem, it seems plausible that the cocoon output performance largely
mirrors the regions’ contrasting performance in raw silk exports; i.e., that circa 1930, Japan was
Various household and land productivity data seem to confirm a similar story of contrasting
performance between 1890 and 1929. Annual cocoon output per household in the late 1920s
Lower Yangzi was about 50 to 65 kilograms, about a third of the Japanese level during the same
period, but roughly equivalent to its 1900 level. Annual cocoon output per acre of land in the
Lower Yangzi was estimated to be about 150 and 142 kilograms in 1897 and 1932 respectively,
about 70% of the Japanese level in the 1920s but equal to the Japanese level around 1910. The
actual cocoon productivities in the Lower Yangzi would be even lower in comparison to Japan if
cocoon quality deterioration in the 1910s and 20s were taken into account.7
3
These partial productivity indices suffer various shortcomings. For the Lower Yangzi, most
estimates were based on scattered individual observations. For Japan, as will be shown later, land
and labor productivity improvements were exaggerated by the rapid intensification in Japanese
sericulture that occurred between 1900-20. These problems posed formidable obstacles to the
construction of Total Factor Productivity (TFP) based on the primal input-output approach.
In this context, the cost (or price) based TFP approach is more viable as time series data of
input and output prices were relatively consistent and reliable. The dual equivalence of
production and cost side TFP based on a Cobb-Douglas production function requires the
assumption of constant returns to scale and long run competitive market assumptions (with cost
4
side TFP expressed as A t = ∏ witα i AC t , wit and αi being price and weight respectively for the
d
i =1
ith input at time t, ACt as average cost of production and Σαi=1). Both these assumptions are
reasonably satisfied for the small-scale and scattered rural sericultural production taking raw silk
To calculate the dual TFP, I have used cocoon price for AC and four price series of input,
namely, labor, land, sericultural inputs (fertilizer, silkworm egg seeds and etc.) and capital
(silkworm rearing room, tools) for the period between 1903 and 1928. Their summary statistics
Figure 1 shows the annual cocoon (as well as raw silk) prices for Japan and the Lower-Yangzi
all converted into Japanese yen. The cocoon price of the Lower Yangzi is from Wuxi, the most
important cocoon-marketing center in the region. Notice that the Wuxi cocoon price, which
roughly paralleled that of the Japanese cocoon price until the mid-1910s, began to dip
The abrupt but sustained lowering of the level of cocoon prices after the mid-1910s reflected a
systematic deterioration of cocoon quality in the Lower Yangzi as captured by the rising silk
yield ratio – the amount of cocoons needed to produce a certain unit of raw silk. Shigema Uehara,
4
the most authoritative specialist on Chinese silk industry at the time, presented data showing that
the amount of dried cocoon required for producing 100 kilograms of raw silk increased from 500
in 1915 to more than 600 kilograms in 1924 – a decline of more than 20 percent.8
[Insert Figure 1]
Adjusting the cocoon price by the quality change is essential for an accurate calculation of TFP
changes for the Lower Yangzi. The quality adjusted cocoon price in Wuxi (obtained by
multiplying the cocoon price by the standardized silk-yield ratios) is displayed in Figure 1 as
q
Wuxi(q). The price dual TFP adjusted by cocoon quality (A t ) can be written as
4
A t = ∏ witα i S t p t with St and pt denoting the standardized silk-yield and market cocoon price
q
i =1
respectively. For the Lower Yangzi, St pt is equivalent to Wuxi(q). The results for both regions
are presented in Table 1. Japanese TFP growth accelerated during these three decades. The
Lower-Yangzi showed very promising TFP growth from about the 1900s to the 1910s but this
then turned negative in the 1920s as the silk yield decline took its toll. Overall, the Lower Yangzi
TFP growth rate of 0.52% was only about a quarter of Japan’s 2.05% in the first three decades of
[Insert Table 1]
The leaders that came to power through the 1868 Meiji Restoration made no pretense to
“restore” Japan to her old days, but instead proclaimed, in the new imperial “Charter Oath,” that
“knowledge shall be sought throughout the world…” and subsequently embarked on a reform
program to forge a modern nation state modeled after the West. Japan’s decisiveness in turning
outward in the face of the Western imperial challenge was matched by contemporaneous Qing’s
determination to reinstate an orthodox Neo-Confucian ruling ideology to an empire that had been
5
The Qing bureaucrats did recognize the superiority of Western military technology and, under
military through a series of either government financed, or government controlled Western style
industrial enterprises. The attitude of the Self-strengthening movement towards private initiatives
in the modern sector ranged from indifference to hostility and displayed little interest in
supplying modern public goods and in most cases, was even opposed to private efforts to build
In comparison, Meiji’s sell-off of its limited number of government enterprises in the 1880s
gave a powerful signal that the private sector was the mainstay of Japan’s industrialization. The
government concentrated on building crucial social and physical infrastructures such as a legal
system, public education, research and technological diffusion, a modern monetary and banking
China’s shocking naval military defeat by Japan in 1895 was soon to spell the end of the Self-
strengthening movement and subsequently set off a process of intellectual awakening that
questioned the fundamentals of the traditional system. The Qing constitutional reform in 1903-
11, itself inspired and modeled after the Meiji reform, recognized the importance of the private
sector and the government’s role in public goods provision. But the imperial Qing collapsed in
The following three sections will show that these crucial changes in the late nineteenth and
early twentieth centuries set the production and commercialization in Chinese and Japanese
sericulture along increasingly divergent paths of technology and institutions despite similar
starting points. This divergent path impacted directly the productivities and competitiveness of
6
1. Technology
Japan was a latecomer in the global silk market. The rise of a domestic Japanese raw silk
sector, originated in Tokugawa shoguns’ 1685 restrictions against Chinese silk imports, was a
case of import substitution based on the borrowing of the Chinese, particularly the Lower Yangzi
sericulture technology. In the 1860s and 1870s, Japan became the most important supplier of
quality silkworm eggs for Europe. Japan’s comparative advantage in the export of silk-worm
eggs, a product lower in value-added than raw silk, seems to corroborate other evidences that
overtaking that of the Lower Yangzi in the area of silkworm rearing, still lagging behind in
Meiji reform opened the Japanese sericulture to the world of European science and technology.
The Iwakura mission that sent Meiji ministers on a two-year study tour of Europe and America in
1871-73 enlightened Japanese sericulturalists as well. Following the official Iwakura mission to
Italy was a group of Japanese sericultural experts headed by Nagaatsu Sasaki who visited
At the time of Sasaki’s visit, Northern Italy represented the frontier of Europe’s sericultural
technology, being transformed by the application of modern science, particularly the discovery
and diffusion of Louis Pasteur’s microscopic examination method of pebrine disease. The
sericultural institute that Sasaki visited and studied for one full month in Gorizia (in Northern
Italy) was the first of its kind set up in 1869. Sasaki returned to Japan with the most up-to-date
silkworm rearing tools such as microscopes and hygrometers, and actively advocated the
establishment of modern sericultural research and education in Japan. The visit heralded the
beginning of Japan’s own national system of technological innovation, diffusion and education.
In the period between the 1890s and 1940s, Japanese sericultural specialists produced a steady
7
stream of survey reports on foreign sericultural technology and commercial practices, with a total
Such keen awareness of the on-going technological revolution in European sericulture could
not be found in the Lower Yangzi before the twentieth century.13 Preparation for the grueling,
classics continued to engross the intellectual energies of the Chinese elites. Among the limited
efforts by the Self-strengthening bureaucrats to diffuse Western science and technology was the
translation of a series of Western texts by the translating department of the Jiangnan Arsenal, a
government industrial venture established to build Western style military ships. One of these
texts translated in 1899 is a classic Italian sericulture book, published originally in the late 1810s.
The Chinese translation, itself possibly based on a late English translation, involved the work of
three non-specialists in sericulture - an Englishman by the name of John Fryer provided the oral
interpretation of the text and two Chinese writers converted Fryer’s verbal explanation into
classical Chinese. This Chinese style of acquiring a classic but out-dated Italian technology
through a multiple of indirect media forms a direct contrast to the Japanese style of learning as
By the turn of the century, Japanese surveys on Lower Yangzi sericulture had already shown
important traces of technological divergence. These reports often criticized silkworm rearing
practices in the Lower Yangzi as backward, naïve, and superstitious, and most interestingly,
“very much like our practices in the pre-Meiji era.”15 It confirms that Japanese sericultural
technology only began to decisively forge ahead of the Lower Yangzi around the turn of the last
century. The following comparative narrative illustrates two of Japan’s most important
technological breakthroughs in the early twentieth century that laid the foundation for its global
dominance. 16
8
Silkworm eggs are an essential input to cocoon production. While there were numerous
varieties, the fundamental breakthrough came with the discovery of the so-called first filial (F1)
hybrid silkworm in the early 1910s. The performance of the F1 variety surpassed the previous
The concept of hybrid vigor behind the F1 variety is ancient in East Asia. However previous
studies and experiments with silkworm crossbreeding, including those done in the early Meiji era,
were not supported by the theory of heterosis as expounded by Mendel’s genetic principle. The
key element of Mendel’s discovery was that the superior traits of the two pure strain parent
varieties were stable in their first generation of crossbreeds, but not in the succeeding generations
derived from this cross. This important theoretical recognition led to the rise of modern
experimental labs that specialized in the selection and breeding of pure strain varieties and the
mass production of the crossed F1 variety silkworm eggs for cocoon production.
It is important to note that the success of the F1 variety was founded on a series of cumulative
research on embryology and cellular biology. Unlike other minor innovations, government
sponsored research labs and university departments were responsible for most of the basic
industrial silk reelers and associations, the F1 variety diffused rapidly among sericultural farmers.
The diffusion started in the early 1910s, and by 1923, the F1 variety’s share in the spring crop
reached one hundred percent; by 1929, one hundred percent of the summer and fall crop used the
F1 breed.19
The diffusion of the F1 variety had a direct impact on both the productivity and quality of
cocoons in Japan. The most commonly used indicator for the performance of silkworm varieties
and rearing was the so-called cocoon-egg yield -- the weight of cocoons obtained from a certain
9
amount of hatched silkworm eggs. Table 2 shows clearly that the improvement of cocoon yield
accelerated from 1900-09 to 1910-19, which corresponded well with the timing and rate of
diffusion of the F1 variety. This also matched the acceleration of my TFP index for Japan. By
the late 1920s when the diffusion of the F1 variety was complete, Japanese egg yields surpassed
[Insert Table 2]
In contrast, silkworm eggs used in the Lower Yangzi before 1925 were almost entirely
produced by traditional breeding methods, with little use of the microscopic method of disease
prevention. Based on various Japanese survey reports, the final column of Table 2 presents a
direct comparison of the cocoon yield for these two regions. This contrast is compelling. Around
1900, the cocoon egg-ratio in Japan and the Lower Yangzi were roughly equal, but for the next
two decades, the Japanese cocoon-egg ratio surged, as opposed to a largely immobile cocoon
The next major Japanese innovation was the rearing of a second crop of silkworms in the fall
in addition to the main spring crop. Again like so many other Japanese innovations, it has its
roots in East Asia.20 However, instability in hatching and other technical problems constrained its
growth. The great merit of the fall crop was that the timing of its rearing fell in the period when
rice-cultivation required the least labor, thus enabling cocoon growth without the sacrifice of
cereal production.21 In Japan, studies of artificial hatching started in the late 1880s and Japanese
farmers had also experimented with various crude methods of preserving and hatching the
silkworm eggs in autumn. But it was not until Japanese scientists’ discovery of hydrochloric acid
processing in 1911-12 that the timing and outcome of artificial hatching stabilized.
Innovation in silkworm egg preservation and hatching was only half of the tale. The more
binding constraint on the fall crop was the supply of mulberry leaves in the fall season when
10
mulberry trees were no longer yielding fresh leaves. Technical innovation in this area had gone
through several phases of search and experimentation and eventually converged to a set of three
variety, known as “Lu” from the Lower Yangzi; a new tree-pruning technique called stem-
Japan had learnt of the superior “Lu” mulberry trees through Chinese sericultural texts in the
Tokugawa era but only started widespread introduction after Meiji through the advocacy of the
energetic Sasaki. Stem-pruning applied to the Lu types of trees reduced the tree trunks to bushes
which matured faster, carried a higher yield and could bloom multiple times within a year, but
In China, the stem pruning technique and bush type of mulberry trees (not the Lu type) were
tropical technique to the temperate zone was complementary with the diffusion of new
commercial fertilizers in 1900-1930. Among the types of commercial fertilizer used, soybean
cake imported from Manchuria in northeast China was the most important.24 The commercial
adoption of the soybean cake from Northern China was a major historical achievement of the
Lower Yangzi agriculture in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. But by the twentieth
internal distribution and transportation effectively diverted this trade flow towards Japan.25
This combination of technological innovation led to the rise of the ratio of the summer and fall
crop to total output from just over 20% in the 1880-1900 period to 34% in 1900-09 and after
1920, the summer and fall crops consistently made up about half of the total output, rivaling the
spring crop.26
By contrast, the early twentieth century mulberry cultivation in the Lower Yangzi displayed
an eco-system formed since the late Ming (about the late sixteenth century). Mulberry trees,
11
mostly of the Lu type, trunk-pruned, clustered along the banks of the canal system, fertilized by
the canal sediments, with mulberry leaves transported to markets through the canal network.27
Scattered estimates show that 1910-30 average Lower Yangzi mulberry yields per acre while still
higher than those for Gunma and Nagano prefectures for the period of 1880-90, the two most
important sericultural regions in Japan, became only half of Japan’s national average yield in
1927. Consequently, the share of summer and fall crops in the late 1920s Lower-Yangzi
2. Commercialization
In the 1880s the Suwa district of Nagano prefecture became the center of mechanized reeling
factories. As Suwa was in the heart of the sericultural regions in eastern Japan, initially silk
reeling factories acquired cocoons directly from the rural households in neighboring areas. With
the phenomenal growth of modern reeling factories over the next two decades however, silk
reelers began to reach into other prefectures for additional supplies of cocoons at cheaper prices.
Nationwide cocoon procurement by silk reelers induced the growth of cocoon collection and
marketing centers in all of the major sericultural regions from the 1880s to the 1910s. These
collection and marketing centers usually consisted of cocoon merchant houses as well as
individual merchants, some equipped with cocoon drying and storage facilities.
Therefore, the rapid extension of the radius of the cocoon supply region was a feat of man’s
triumph over geography. Nakabayashi has carefully documented how the adoption of modern
insurance and transportation methods, the building of railroads, and the cooperation of silk reelers
and railroad authorities had managed to break, one by one, the bottlenecks that would have
otherwise constrained the enormous expansion of cocoon supply. The building of railroads,
starting in the early 1880s, instantly opened up new cocoon supply regions for the Suwa silk
12
reelers, turning more and more traditionally integrated producers of silk reeling and silkworm
From the 1910s, the development of direct purchase arrangements between reelers and farmers
expanded at the expense of intermediary markets or middlemen. After WWI, the direct exchange
between reelers and farmers or farmers’ cooperatives markedly increased. Statistics show that by
1923, cocoons sold directly to the reelers were 46.6 % of total sales, higher than the 23.9% and
29.5% sold through the cocoon market and merchants respectively.29 Out of the direct exchange
system evolved another institutional innovation that brought reelers and rearers even closer, the
so-called “Sub-Contractual Direct Purchase” system. This system, which probably originated in
1905, entailed a long-term exchange contract between farmers and reelers. From 1926 to 1933,
the share of cocoons sold through this system grew from 12.5% to 40.1% in Japan.30
Compared with the almost linear progression of Japanese cocoon commercialization, the
process for the Lower Yangzi was far more twisted. The period before the mid-1890s saw much
activity but little real spread of modern silk reeling factories. The exports of machine-reeled raw
silk from Shanghai before 1894 were so insignificant that they were counted as hand-reeled raw
This is no surprise as private modern industry, distinguished from those supported by the Self-
strengthening bureaucrats, had no legal status before the 20th century. The few mechanized silk
reeling factories that did survive under the dubious extraterritorial protection in the treaty port of
Shanghai were repeatedly harassed by the local officials representing the interests of the
traditional silk weavers who feared for their source of raw silk supply.31 The issue was swept
away by the treaty of Shimoneseki in 1895 signed after China’s defeat by Japan granting legality
13
In Shanghai, the number of modern silk reeling factories more than doubled between 1895 and
1896.32 But the take-off of the Shanghai reeling industry, itself located about two to three
hundred kilometers from sericultural regions, soon ran into the constraint set by the nascent
cocoon marketing and distribution infrastructure in rural Lower Yangzi, sending the cocoon price
In the nineteenth century, the Lower Yangzi lowlands relied on its intricate waterways for
cocoon transportation, thus barely surviving Qing’s prohibition of railroads in China. Attempts
by Shanghai silk reelers and merchants to introduce steamships into inner rivers were thwarted by
local officials who were protecting the interests of traditional shippers. It was after 1896 with the
signing of the Shimonoseki treaty that steamship and later, regular steamer routes in the inner
river and canal system began. 33 In 1908 and 1912, two railroads linking Shanghai to the
Lower Yangzi cocoon distribution was largely in the hands of the cocoon hangs. The hangs
received fresh cocoons from farmers, dried them in their ovens and then shipped them to
Shanghai. Cocoon hangs belonged to the traditional Ya-hang system where the Ya-hang obtained
local trading privileges by its purchase of government issued licenses and payment of commercial
taxes.34
The rising demand in the twentieth century induced a steady increase of cocoon-hangs. In
Wuxi, the number of cocoon hangs increased from fewer than 50 in 1895 to 140 in 1910. By
1917, Jiangsu and Zhejiang provinces had over 700 cocoon hangs scattered in major sericultural
regions.35 In 1902, Wuxi hang merchants, whose organizing activities to regulate market
practices and coordinate collective action could be traced back to the 1880s, founded their official
cocoon guild. This was absorbed in 1909, into a joint guild organization representing both the
14
Still, cocoon commercialization in the twentieth century Lower Yangzi was no smooth sailing.
In the mid-1910s, at the peak of the Lower Yangzi cocoon commercialization, the traditional silk
place a ceiling on the number of cocoon hangs allowed within a certain geographical area in the
Lower Yangzi. Subsequently, the pace of growth of cocoon hangs and shipments to Shanghai
and hangs was a legacy of the traditional imperial system. In the Late-Qing, strained by its
deteriorating fiscal condition, the government increasingly resorted to commercial taxes in place
of the rigid land tax. But the collection of commercial tax, particularly the infamous Lijing tax
levied on goods in domestic transit, was in the hands of local governments whose revenue
extracting measures were often arbitrary and extortionary. It was the organized guilds, taking
tax collection agents. Through the practice and spread of commercial tax-farming, merchant
guilds wielded additional leverage over the rural cocoon distribution in the Lower Yangzi.38
Throughout this period, the Cocoon Guild, like the other guilds, resorted to all means to
protect their trading privileges by shutting out independent cocoon intermediaries. Their efforts
to collectively bargain down the purchase price for cocoons alienated cocoon farmers who were
created a division of labor between silkworm rearing and silk reeling. In scattered rural
households where silkworms were reared, cocoon farmers had private information about their
rearing process and the quality of their products. By the 1910s and 20s, fraudulent and dishonest
practices of selling low quality cocoons had turned the cocoon market into something like
15
Interestingly, Tokugawa Japan especially in the eighteenth century may have been no less
guild-oriented than the Lower Yangzi. Official chartered merchant guilds paid license fees and
contributed tax revenue to the Bakufu in exchange for trading privileges. It was Meiji reform that
abolished the merchant guild system and upheld the legality of free commercial transactions.41
arrangements of cocoon transactions in Japan and created possibilities for institutional innovation,
as seen in the case of the “Subcontractual Direct Purchase” system. Through the long-term direct
purchase contract, industrial silk reelers, by providing scientifically bred silkworm eggs and
detailed technical guidance, acquired monitoring capacity of farmers’ silkworm rearing process.
In Japan, large-scale, high quality raw silk manufacturers such as Katakura and Gunze were the
main users of this system.42 The asymmetric information problem that had plagued the Lower
Yangzi in the 1910s and 1920s, possibly causing the regions’ silk yield decline, was eased by a
The differential pace and sequence of cocoon commercialization in the two regions have
productivity implications. Both visual observation and the standard statistical co-integration test
on the price series in Figure 1 reveal the much higher degree of market integration between
Japanese cocoon markets and the Yokohama raw silk market than that between Wuxi and
Shanghai in the first two decades of the twentieth century. Sericulture in the twentieth century
Lower Yangzi, possibly at a similar stage of commercialization as that in Japan in the latter half
of the nineteenth century, might have realized significant productivity gains from new
infrastructures and greater specialization. Such gains, however, may have been relatively
insignificant for Japan in the twentieth century as major infrastructures and a cocoon-marketing
network were already well established. If we could assign the 0.52% annual Lower Yangzi TFP
16
explain the 2.05% Japanese rate of TFP growth in 1903-28 in the context of the momentous
Table 3 presents the growth accounting to calculate separately the contributions of input
expansion (extensive growth) and TFP growth (intensive growth) to cocoon output growth for
Japan. It shows that TFP growth (from Table 1) made up 37% of the total growth in cocoon
output leaving the remaining 63% to input expansion in 1903-28. Out of this 63% input
expansion, I calculate the pure intensification effects from summer and fall using the following
counter-factual calculation:
Qh1927 = 1927 spring cocoon output + (Q1927 x 1903 summer and fall ratio).
This calculation, as presented in Table 3, shows that intensification through the summer and fall
crop (as a part of the input expansion) was equivalent to an annual 1.15% input growth (about
21% of the total growth in cocoon output). Altogether, TFP growth and intensification accounted
for 58% of the annual growth in Japanese cocoon output, leaving the remaining 42% to pure
I showed earlier that the TFP growth was directly related to the discovery and diffusion of the
F1 variety, while intensification was achieved through the application of artificial hatching in
constituted the core of the induced innovation in Japanese sericulture. Had such innovation not
occurred, that is if we remove the 58% contribution of the induced innovation from the 5.5%
annual cocoon growth rate in 1903-27, Japanese growth would have been only 2.3%. This is
roughly equivalent to the 2.8% growth rate of the raw silk exports in the Lower Yangzi in the
same period. Clearly, what ultimately made the difference between these regions is the race-
seed-fertilizer transformation.44
17
[Insert Table 3]
The lackluster sericultural performance in twentieth century Lower Yangzi has to be placed in
the larger context of China’s political disintegration and social and economic dislocation that
occurred after the Qing collapse in 1911. Under a series of weak governments or sometimes no
government in the Republican period, real reforms made little headway. Yet the legacy of reform
In 1897, a local magistrate founded China’s first modern sericultural institute in Hanzhou,
Zhejiang province. Sericultural manuals with titles using the newly introduced term
“experiment” appeared after 1900. The Late-Qing reform, which abolished the Civil Service
Examination, paved the way for a modern education system with a new curriculum. Slowly but
The first two decades of the century also heralded the so-called golden age of Chinese
capitalism in the treaty port of Shanghai. Rapid industrial and financial growth in Shanghai was
spilling over to the Lower Yangzi especially along the recently completed Shanghai-Nanjing
railroad on which Wuxi was located. By the mid-1920s, Wuxi, with its cheap labor and
proximity to raw materials, had emerged as a second center of modern silk reeling production in
The scattered mosaics of economic growth seemed to really come together with the founding
of the new Nationalist government in Nanjing, Jiangsu province in 1927. The restoration of
general peace and stability was an invaluable public good that a government could offer. By
1933, for the first time the number of modern silk reeling machines in Wuxi exceeded those in
Shanghai.46 Most notable was the rise of a giant silk reeling conglomerate, the Yongtai Company,
18
which moved from Shanghai in 1926. It soon emerged as the industry leader in pushing for
In 1928, the Nationalist government abolished the trading privileges of the Cocoon
Merchant Guild and lifted the restrictions on the opening of cocoon hangs, and started reforms in
commercial taxation and tax-farming. Between 1928 and 1929, the number of cocoon hangs in
Wuxi county jumped by about thirty percent. 47 The government encouraged the establishment of
Silkworm Rearing Cooperatives to sell cocoons directly to reeling factories. In 1932, the Yongtai
Reeling Company began to set up long-term exclusive contracts with farmers or cooperatives in
the Lower Yangzi, a system very similar to the Sub-Contractual Direct-Purchase system
Starting in 1932, the provincial governments of both Jiangsu and Zhejiang began to take a
model districts across the region. In 1934, the government founded a national level sericultural
The outcome was a 1930s Lower Yangzi catch-up with Japan that was nothing short of
remarkable. Figure 2 plots the Lower Yangzi diffusion curve for the scientifically improved
variety, mostly of the F1 types. For Jiangsu province, the percentage of scientifically produced
silkworm eggs increased from 5% to almost 100% within only 5 to 7 years. Diffusion lagged
somewhat in Zhejiang, but the overall rate of diffusion in the Lower Yangzi in the 1930s was
comparable to the Japanese diffusion of the F1 Hybrids in the 1910s and 1920s.
[Insert Figure 2]
Following the Japanese method of artificial hatching, Jiangsu province took the leadership in
rearing fall silkworms. In 1935, the ratio of fall crops to total crops was 42% for Jiangsu and
19
The distinctive imprint of Japanese technology and institution on the Lower Yangzi path of
catch-up was unmistakable. This came about by no accident but was the outcome of two decades
of conscious Japanese learning on the part of Chinese sericulturalists and later the Wuxi
sericultural model attests to the binding power of comparable conditions of factor endowments
and a common cultural and technological heritage between the two regions. It also bears witness
to the early twentieth century momentous reversal of the historical direction of knowledge
Cocoon output and raw silk exports from the Lower Yangzi increased in 1935 and 1936.
Equipped with the newly imported Japanese reeling technology, raw silk by Yongtai
conglomerate cut into the U.S silk stockings market, formerly the exclusive territory of the giant
Japanese high quality raw silk producers such as Katakura and Gunze.
The positive developments centered around Wuxi sent alarms to the Japanese competitors.
Despite its global dominance in the 1930s, Japanese competitiveness in this labor-intensive
product was rapidly eroding due to rising labor cost brought about by decades of economic
growth. The massive outflow of Japanese technology was only chipping away its last line of
defense.52 Therefore, the 1930s Lower Yangzi catch-up was riding the historical shifting tides of
Conclusion
Around the middle of the nineteenth century when Western imperialism opened up East Asia,
China, by all measures of comparative advantage, seemed set on a course of regaining her
historical supremacy in the global silk market. Instead, the six decades to follow were to witness
20
This paper demonstrates that induced technological and institutional innovation brought
Japanese sericulture decisive productivity advantages over that of the Lower Yangzi, the key to
its dominance in the twentieth century global raw silk market. It further argues that the rise of
induced innovation in Japan and its absence in the Lower Yangzi during this period has to be
analyzed in the context of the two countries’ contrasting ideological and political responses to the
in the provisioning of public goods, the structuring of economic incentives, and the alignment of
interest groups. Therefore, the case of the Lower Yangzi’s remarkable convergence to Japan in
the 1930s was as much in the areas of technology and commercialization as in ideology.
This, however, begs the larger question: why, when confronted with the same Western
challenge, had Japan’s ideological or cognitive switch been earlier, and more decisive? This is a
question of enormous import to our understanding of economic development that would call upon
a much more comprehensive and multi-disciplinary approach than the scope of this paper allows.
This comparative analysis contributes both a historical and an East Asian perspective to the
theory of induced innovation. In Japan and the Lower Yangzi, the development of technology
biased towards using labor and saving capital and land as a response to the rising labor-land ratio
had been a long-standing tradition traceable to Tokugawa Japan and Southern Song China (1127-
1279).53 Even in the twentieth century, the two Japanese epochal technical innovations in cross-
breeding and summer and fall crops were ancient in origin, but achieved fundamental
breakthroughs with the infusion of modern science, the establishment of a national diffusion
network, the build-up of modern physical and social infrastructure and the rise of new systems of
Clearly, what set the Japanese induced innovation in the modern era apart from that of the pre-
modern is not its direction of technical bias, but rather its sharply accelerated pace of technical
progress due to the availability of the newly supplied public or social capital to create economy
21
wide externalities. While some of these externalities, as shown by the Japanese experience, can
be partially internalized by the large and integrated reeling firms who acted as powerful agents of
change, such a possibility was stymied in the Lower Yangiz – the growth of its mechanized
reeling industry was both belated and geographically removed from the rural sector as a
Judged in this light, the late nineteenth and early twentieth century growth record of the Lower
Yangzi sericulture was quite impressive and historically unprecedented if measured by the
standards of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries when Chinese raw silk still reigned supreme
globally. It only pales in comparison to Japan in its fast track of modern economic growth.
Finally, this paper also sheds light on the on-going historical debate on China related to the so-
called Needham puzzle - why China, with its significant scientific achievements and relatively
flexibly economic institutions, failed to become the first country to industrialize. The related
grand hypotheses ranging from “high level equilibrium trap”, to “involution” and to the recent
California school’s resource constraint argument, all grounded in some form of resource and
factor endowment explanation seem to have neglected the important lesson from Japan’s rapid
industrialization in the twentieth century in the face of over-population, labor abundance and
resource scarcity.54 Openness, by which I mean not only opening the country to trade, but also
22
Table 1. Quality Adjusted TFP Index for Japan and the Lower Yangzi (numbers in
parenthesis are growth rates compared with the earlier period)
Japan Lower-Yangzi
1903-9 105 1904-9 68
1910-19 119 (1.3%) 1910-19 86 (2.35%)
1920-28 157 (3.2%) 1920-28 79 (-0.9%)
Average annual growth 2.05% Average annual growth 0.52%
rate 1903-1928 rate 1904-1928
Sources:
1. For sources of input and output prices and Chinese silk yield data, see the Data Appendix.
Japanese silk yield data from LTES, vol.11, Table 49, col.4.
3. The shares of labor, land, capital and input (fertilizer being the major item) used for Japan are
0.5, 0.12, 0.2, 0.18 respectively, and 0.5, 0.17, 0.15 and 0.18 for the Lower Yangzi respectively
The Japanese factor share information is from Central Committee of Japanese Sericultural
Association (1924, 1925) Souen oyobi yousan keieihi no kenkyu (Studies on the Cost of Mulberry
Cultivation and Silkworm Rearing, No.1,2,3), (1924 and 1925), p.11 in report No. 1, and p.19 in
report No.2. For the Lower Yangzi, I have used information from Uehara, pp.83-84 and p.160
and also Chen, Zi-yu, pp. 60-70.
23
Notes:
1. For the Lower-Yangzi TFP, I used 1904 as the starting year because 1901-3 corresponded to an
extraordinary period of cocoon market speculation in Wuxi due to a sudden surge of silk reeling
factories in Shanghai. This is explained on Section IIB in the text. If I use 1901 or 1903 as the
starting year, annual TFP growth rate in 1901-28 would be 1.5% and 1.1% respectively.
2. To test for the robustness of my TFP calculation, I have performed a sensitive test by applying
alternative weights. Applying Chinese share weights on the Japanese data gives an average
annual growth rate of 2.1% for Japan in 1903-28. Using Japanese share weights on Chinese data
gives an annual TFP growth rate of 0.67% for the Lower Yangzi in 1904-28. Neither of these
two rates was significantly different from those in Table 1.
Table 2. Yield of Silkworm Eggs (Kilograms of Cocoons per gram of Silkworm Eggs
Hatched)
Italy France Japan (all crops) The Lower Yangzi as a
percentage of the Japanese
level in that year
1878-87 1.02 0.94
1888-1902 1.48 1.43 0.86 (1899)
1903-13 1.76 1.55 0.80 (1900-09) 100% (1900)
1910-19 1.06(3.8%) 74% (1917)
1920-29 1.74 1.75(5.2%) 50% (1927)
Source Notes: Italian and French data are from Federico, Economic History, 1997, Table XV in
Appendix. I choose the c) column for the Italian yield, which is the more consistent but also
higher than the other estimate.
Japanese data are from Fujino et al, LETS, vol.11, Table 62.
For Chinese data, 1904 yield is by Kizo Minemura, Shinkoku Sansigyou Sisatu Fukumeisho
(Survey Report on Chinese silk sector), (Tokyo: Ministry of Agriculture and Commerce, 1900),
pp.105-8. The yield for 1917 is for Zhejiang province given by Akaishi quoted in Ikawa, Kindai,
p.223. The 1927 data is from Uehara, Shina, p.30. Various estimates by Chinese scholars put the
24
average cocoon yields in Jiangsu province of the late 1920s and early 30s at roughly less than 1
kg per gram of eggs. See Yue, Zhongguo, page 78 and Wang, Minguo, p.50.
Table 3. Average Annual Growth Rates of Input, Output and TFP in 1903-1927 (Numbers
in parenthesis indicate percentage contribution to growth rate of cocoon output)
Japan Lower
Yangzi
Input Input (excluding summer and 2 (42) -
Expansion fall)
Intensification (summer and 1.15 (21) 0
fall)
Total Factor Productivity 2.05 (37) 0.52
Cocoon Output 5.5 -
Raw Silk Exports 7.9 2.8
Notes:
1. For Japan, cocoon, raw silk data from LTES, vol.11, Table 57,61,63.
2. The 5.5% number is the Japanese cocoon growth rate adjusted by the silk yield. The growth rate
without the quality adjustment is 5.2%.
3. For the Lower Yangzi, raw silk data from Xu, Zhongguo, pp.690-2.
25
Figure 1. Cocoon and Raw Silk Prices in Japan and the Lower-
Yangtze
450
400
350
300 Japan
Japanese Yen
Wuxi
250
Wuxi(q)
200
Yokohama
150 Shanghai
100
50
0
95
98
01
04
07
10
13
16
19
22
25
28
31
18
18
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
Notes: The “Japan” and “Wuxi” series are for Japanese and the Lower-Yangzi cocoon prices in 100
kilograms. For sources, see Data Appendix. Wuxi(q) stands for the quality adjusted price series.
The “Yokohama” and “Shanghai” series are for raw silk export prices in 10 kilograms from Japan
and the Lower-Yangzi. The Shanghai series is from Chen, Zi-yu p.62 for 1896-1917, and Xu, pp.
692, 698 for 1917-1932. The Yokohama series is from LTES, vol. 11, p.296-7.
26
Exchange rates are from Hsiao, Liang-lin, China’s Foreign Trade Statistics, 1864-1949.
(Cambridge, MA:Harvard University Press, 1974),p.190-3.
F ig u r e 2 . D if f u s io n o f S c ie n tif ic a lly P r o d u c e d
S ilk w o r m V a r ie tie s in J a p a n a n d th e L o w e r -Y a n g z i
100% 100%
80% 80%
J ia n g s u ( A )
60% 60% J ia n g s u ( S )
Z h e jia n g (A )
40% 40% Z h e jia n g (S )
J a p a n (A )
20% 20%
0% 0%
1913
1915
1917
1919
1921
1923
1925
1927
1929
1931
1933
1935
1937
Source Notes: Diffusion figures for Japan were adapted from Kiyokawa, “Diffusion,” p.41,
Figure 1. (A) includes all crops while (S) only includes spring crop.
For China, see Benno, “Chugoku,” p. 43 and Wang, Minguo, p. 10, and 49, Eng, Economic
Imperialism, p.136.
27
Data Appendix
I. Averages of Nominal Input and Cocoon Price Indices for Japan and the Lower-Yangzi
The Lower-Yangzi Japan
Labor Land Capital Input Cocoon Labor Land Capital Input Cocoon
(Draft (Bean (fertilizer)
Animal) Cake)
1901-09 100 100 100(1906) 100 100 100 100(1903) 100 100 100
1910-19 169 152 149 109 98 173 200 140 127 118
1920-28 220 197 202 130 119 369 369 261 173 215
Sources: for the Lower Yangzi, cocoon price in Wuxi: 1901-1920 From Ikawa, Kindai Nihon,
Table 2, p.304-5, 1920-24 converted from Uehara, Shina, p.225. Data for 1925-27 unavailable, I
projected it from the 1924 cocoon price level using the 1925-27 market price of raw silk. The
1927-29 cocoon price is from Gao and Yan, Jindai, pp.88-9. The market price of raw silk in
Shanghai is from D. K. Lieu, The Silk Industry of China, (Shanghai-Hongkong-Singapore: Kelly
and Walsh, Ltd.),Appendix, Table IV. The original 1912 price for fresh cocoon in Ikawa is 24,
which seems implausibly low. I adjusted it to 28.5 using cocoon price in Chen, Jindai, p62.
Farm wage index, land price index and farm animal price index in the Lower-Yangzi from John
Buck, Land Utilization in China, (Nanjing: University of Nanking, 1937), Vol.3, Tables 5, p 151-
2, Table 10-1, p.168, and Table 6, p.153. Soybean cake price is from Hsiao, Foreign Trade, p.80-
81. There were no consistent long-term price series data for fertilizer and capital stock in the
Lower Yangzi, I used the prices of bean cake and draft animal as proxy prices. None of these two
inputs were used on a large scale in the Lower Yangzi and their inclusion could lead to possible
biases in TFP. Considering their share is relatively small (12 and 18%), the biases may not be so
serious and could potentially offset each other.
Japanese cocoon price, land price, current input and capital prices are from col.11 of Table 7,
cols.3 and 13 of Table 34, col.6 of Table 31 in M. Umemura, S. Yamada, Y. Hayami, N.
Takamatsu, M. Kumazaki, Agriculture and Forestry, vol. 9, Estimates of Long-term Economic
Statistics of Japan Since 1868. (LTES) (Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shinposha, 1966);
Number in parenthesis indicates the earliest available data.
28
Year Before 1916 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924
Wuxi 520 550 510 560 620 600 670 590 680 620
Uehara also listed silk yields of three other sericultural districts in the Lower Yangiz. They all
showed similar declining trend as in Wuxi.
Silk yield in the 1900s and the early 1910s were around 500. (See Minemura, p.148 for 1903, and
Ootori, Kouhisa, Shina Seijyou no Kenkyuu, [Tokyo: Houbunsha, 1919], pp.177-8 for 1910).
Various reports confirm that by the late 1920s and early 1930s, it had become a standard practice
in the Lower-Yangzi to use 620 to 650 for cocoon silk conversion (Gao and Yan, p.75, Benno,
p.32 and 43).
For computing the TFP, I used the Wuxi silk yield. For 1903 and 1910, I used the silk yield of
500. Linear interpolation is applied for the interval years between 1903 and 1916. For silk yields
after 1924, the averages of 1920 through 1924 are used.
1
Lillian Li, China’s Silk Trade: Traditional Industry in the Modern World 1842-1937. (Council
on East Asian Studies, Harvard University, 1981) p.77. Estimates of Long-Term Economic
Statistics of Japan Since 1868 (LTES) vol. 14. by Ippei Yamazawa and Yuzo Yamamoto, Tokyo:
Toyo Kiezai Shinposha, 1979, p.5. . Globally, the combined exports of China, Japan, and Italy
consistently accounted for more than three-fourths of world raw silk trade.
2
See Giovanni Federico, An Economic History of the Silk Industry, (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1997) Chap. 3, p. 36, Table 3.4, p.200, Table AIII.
3
Except for Lillian Li’s “Silks by Sea, Trade, Technology and Enterprise in China and Japan”
Business History Review 56 (1982): 192-217, and Yukihiko Kiyokawa’s “Senzen Chugoku No
Sanshi-gyo Ni Kansuru Jyakkan No Kousatsu” (A Few Observations on the Pre-war Chinese Silk
Sector). Keizai Kenkyu. Vol. 26, No. 3 July 1975, p. 240-255, most studies as seen in the
references usually focus either on China or Japan. Federico’s work (n.2 above) covers the global
raw silk industries.
4
The Lower Yangzi region, located in the central eastern part of China, consists of the provinces
of Jiangsu, Zhejiang and Anhui. The average size of a sericultural farm in Japan was about 0.5
acre in the 1900s and 0.7 acre in the 1920s. For the Lower Yangzi, the average size was a little
less than 0.5 acre in the early 1930s. For Japan, see Shozaburo Fujino, Shiro Fujino and Akira
Ono, Estimates of Long-Term Economic Statistics of Japan since 1868. (LTES,) vol.11 (Tokyo:
Toyo Keizai Shinposha, 1979) p.151. For the Lower Yangzi, see Toua Kenkyujyo, Keizai ni
Kansuru Shina Kanko Chosa Houkokusho (Investigative Report on Chinese Customs Related to
Economic Activity) (Tokyo: Toa Kenkyuu Jyo, 1944), pp.26-8. In this study, I did not
specifically include, another major export-oriented silk producing region, the Guangdong
province in the southern China. The subtropical Guangdong reared the multivoltine type of
silkworms that could hatch and spin cocoon 5 or 6 times in a year. The quality of Guangdong
raw silk was inferior and possibilities for technological transferability from the temperate zones
were also more limited.
5
Yujiro Hayami and Vernon Ruttan, Agricultural Development, an International Perspective
(Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1985).
29
6
For Japanese cocoon output data, see Fujino et al (n. 4 above) Table 57, Col.5. For the Lower
Yangzi, see Eng, Y. Robert, Economic Imperialism in China, Silk Production and Exports, 1861-
1932. (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1986),Table 2.7 on p. 35.
7
The Japanese data from Fujino et al (no. 4 above), p.306-7. The Lower-Yangzi delta in the late
20s was based on the following sources: Toua Kenkyujyo (no. 4, above), pp.27-8; Shigemi
Uehara, Shina Sanshigyo Taikan (Overview of the Chinese Silk Sector) (Tokyo: Ogada
Nichieido, 1929) p.132-3; Su-Ping Yue, Zhongguo Cansi (Chinese Silk) (Shanghai: World Press.
1935), p.169-70; and Ziyu Chen, Jindai Zhongguo de Zisi Saosi Gongye, 1860-1945 (The Silk
Industry of Modern China, 1860-1945), Taipei: Institute of Modern History, Academia Sinica,
1989),pp.68-69.
8
Uehara’s book (n. 7, above), totaling over 1000 pages, was an encyclopedic coverage of the
Chinese silk sector, based on five years of travel through 18 provinces. For details on silk yield
data by Uehara, see Data Appendix.
9
Federico did a primal input-output based TFP calculation for Japanese sericulture from about
1890 to 1929 using only land and labor as inputs. His estimate of annual TFP growth of 2.6%
(for spring crop only), ignoring other inputs such as fertilizer and equipment that grew much
faster than land and labor, represents an over-estimate. (Federico, n. 2, above, p.85). This lends
further support to my 2.05% price dual TFP estimate based on a more complete coverage of
inputs.
10
For the Tongji-Restoration, see Mary Wright, The Last Stand of Chinese Conservatism: the
T’ung-Chih Restoration 1862-187, (Stanford University, 1962). For the Self-Strengthening
Movement, see chapters 9 and 10 in John K. Fairbank (ed.), The Cambridge History of China,
Vol. 10, Late Ch’ing, 1800-1911, Part I. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1978). For
the Late-Qing reform, see chapters 5 and 7 in John K. Fairbank and Kwang-ching Liu, ibid, Vol.
11, Late Ch’ing, 1800-1911, Part II, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1980). Tomoo
Suzuki, Yo Mu Undou No Kenkyu (A Study of the Westernization Movement in China) (Tokyo:
Kyuko Shoin, 1992). For Japan, see Thomas Smith, Political Changes and Industrial
Development in Japan: Government Enterprise, 1868-1880, (Stanford: Stanford University Press,
1955). For Meiji’s “Charter Oath,” see Marius B. Jansen, The Making of Modern Japan.
(Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2000), p. 355.
11
For Chinese influence on Japanese sericultural technology, see Tosio Furushima Tosio (1975)
Furushima Tosio Cyosakusyu (Collected Works of Tosio Furushima), (Tokyo: University of
Tokyo Press, 1975) Vol.5, p.384, Vol.6, p.630. Zenjirou Inoue, “Yousan Gijutus no Tenkai to
Sansho” (Sericultural Technique and Manuals) in Nihon Nousho Zenshuu, ed. Nousan Gyouson
Bunka Kyoukai (Tokyo: Nousan Gyosan Bunkka Kyoka, 1976), vol. 35, p.465-70. For pre-Meiji
Japan’s relative position in sericultural technology, see Lillian Li (n. 3 above) and Kanji Ishii,
Nihon SanshiGyo Shi BunSeki (Analysis of Japanese Silk Industry), (Tokyo: Toyo Keizai
Shinpousha, 1972) p.374.
12
Editorial Committee of Japanese Silk History, Nihon Sanshigyousi (History of Japanese
Sericulture and Reeling) Tokyo: Japanese Sericulture and Silk Association, 1935), vol. 4, p.282,
and Vol.3, p. 503 and p.219. For Sasaki’s visit, see Istituto Bacologico Sperimentale di Gorizia,
Annuario dell' Istituto Bacologico Sperimentale di Gorizia, Seitz, Gorizia 1874.Annuario, p.VI.
30
13
In the 1880s, Paul Brunat, the French silk reeling expert and entrepreneur who had helped
found Japan’s large-scale government run Tomioka Silk Reeling plant in the 1870s, was the
manager of a American-funded silk reeling plant in Shanghai. In 1886, when Li, Hongzhang, the
leader of the Self-strengthening movement, visited his factory, Brunat made a direct appeal for
the need of introducing microscopic examination in China. Brunat’s appeal, reported in the
Shanghai newspapers but clearly ignored by Li and others, caught the attention of Japanese
bureaucrats at the Ministry of Agriculture and Commerce who translated this news piece into
Japanese. Alarmed by the potential possibility of silkworm disease in Japan, technicians at the
Ministry conducted microscopic examinations on silkworms eggs in Japan - only to be shocked
by the prevalence of disease already in Japan. This finding, according to these bureaucrats, was
one important reason behind the promulgation of the Silkworm Disease Prevention Law in Japan
in that year. See Dai Nippon Sanshi Kaihou (Report of the Sericultural Association of Japan), No.
178, March 20th 1907, p.39. Also see Kazuko Furuta “Kindai Seishikyou No Douryu to Kounan
Shakai no Taiou” in Kindai Nihon to Ajia (Modern Japan and Asia) edited by Hirano
Keniichirou, Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press, 2000. p.96.
14
This Chinese translation of this Italian sericulture book by Vincenzo Dandolo, can be found at
the East Asia Library of the Hoover Institute at Stanford University. I thank Claudio Zanier for
the information on Dandolo. For John Fryer, see Fairbank (n.10, above) Vol.10, part I, p.536.
For the tradition of Japanese directly translating Chinese and Western works (especially in the
Dutch Studies period in Tokugawa) and the contrasting tradition of Chinese intellectuals
dependent on Western scholars’ oral interpretation of Western works in Ming and Qing, see
chapter 8 of Tingjiu Li, Atsushi Yoshida, Zhongre Wenhua Jaoliu Shi Dashi: Keji Juan (History
of Sino-Japan Cultural Exchange: Science), (Hangzhou: Zhejiang People’s Publishing, 1996).
15
See Nakajiro Takatsu, Shinkoku Sanshigyo Shisatsu Houkokushou (Reports on China’s
Sericultural Sector). (Ministry of Agriculture and Commerce, 1898), p.16. Zenshino Oishi,
Shinkoku Kouso Sekko Ryoushou Sanseishi Chousahoukokusho (Survey Reports on the Silk
Sectors of Jiangsu and Zhejiang provinces), (Tokyo High School of Commerce, 1908), p.8. Hitosi
Matunaga, Shinkoku SanGyo Sisatsu Fukumeisho (Survey Report on Chinese Sericulture),
(Ministry of Agriculture and Commerce, 1898), p.3-5.
16
It is worthwhile to note that Europe had for long sought East Asian sericultural technology
whose global leadership may have been maintained as late as the eighteenth century. This
European quest culminated in the publication of two translated works of Chinese and Japanese
sericultural texts in 1837 and 1848. See Claudio Zanier, Where the Roads Met, East and West in
the Silk Production Processes (17th-19th Century) (Kyoto: Italian School of East Asian Studies,
1994), pp. 71-94.
17
Lab tests confirmed that the F1 variety shortened the rearing period, produced longer fibers,
yielded fewer defective cocoons and were better suited to the demands of machine reeling. See
Yukihiko Kiyokawa, Nihon No Keizai Hatten To Gijutsu Fukyu (Japanese Economic
Development and Technological Diffusion), (Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shinpousha, 1995), pp.91-92.
18
Yukihiko Kiyokawa, “The Diffusion of New Technologies in the Japanese Sericulture
Industry: The Case of the Hybrid Silkworm,” Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics 25 (1984) 31-
59, p.37-38.
31
19
For a diffusion curve, see Kiyokawa (n.18, above). The diffusion of the F1 variety led to the
standardization of silkworm egg varieties used nationally, thus more uniform types of raw silk, a
feature highly favored by the increasingly mechanized U.S. market. For the growing importance
and eventual dominance of the U.S market for raw silk in the twentieth century, see Debin Ma,
“The Modern Silk Road: the Global Raw-Silk Market, 1850-1930” Journal of Economic History
(1996) Vol.56, No.2. pp.330-355.
20
Zhu, Xin-yu pointed out a method of artificially prolonging the silkworm egg hibernation
period in low temperature recorded in a Chinese sericultural manual dated 1273 AD, see XinYu
Zhu, Zhong Guo Si Chou Shi (History of Chinese Silk), (Beijing: Textile Publishing Co., 1992).
21
For a linear-programming based study analyzing the gains of allocative efficiency from
summer and fall crops, see the work by Le Thanh Nghiep and Yujiro Hayami included as chapter
6, The Tradeoff between Food and Industrial Crops: Summer-Fall Rearing of Cocoons, in Yujiro
Hayami and Saburo Yamada, The Agricultural Development in Modern Japan, A Century's
Perspective, (Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press, 1991). Pp. 175-198.
22
For the cumulative improvements of the Lu mulberry trees in the Lower Yangzi over almost a
millennium, see chapter 4 of Shichou zi Fu Huzhou yu Sichou Wenhua (Silk City Huzhou and
Silk Culture) Fagen Ji (ed.) (Beijing: China International Brodcasting Publishing House, 1994).
European sericulturalists had long learnt of and experimented with the “Lu” variety in Europe
(which they named as the “Philippine variety”), see Zanier (n. 16, above), p. 74. Sasaki himself
recalled that he owed his knowledge of the “Lu” tree to the works of Kaibara Ekiken (1630-
1714), Tokugawa Japan’s foremost scholar on Confucius philosophy and Chinese botany. See
Dai Nippon Sanshi Kaihou (Reports of the Sericultural Association of Japan), No. 176. 1907,
p.24-26, Editorial Committee (n.12, above), Vol. 4, p.80.. For the advantages of stem-pruning
technique see Katsuhiko Ikawa, Kindai Nihon Seishigyo to Mayu Seisan (Modern Japanese Silk
Reeling Industry and Cocoon Production), chapter 3, (Tokyo Economic Information, 1998).
23
For stem-pruning method in China, see Jiamian Liang (ed.), Zhongguo Nonye Kexue Jishu
Sigao (History of Chinese Agricultural Science and Technology) (Beijing: Agricultural
Publishing.Liang, 1989), p.219-220. For the bush type of mulberry trees in Guangdong province,
see C. P. Howard and K. P. Buswell, A Survey of the Silk Industry of South China. (Canton,
1925),chapters III.
24
Other commercial fertilizers used were fish cakes and later modern chemical fertilizer, see
Ikawa (n.22, above),chapter 8 and Hayami and Yamada (n.21, above), chapter 4.
25
For soybean in the Lower Yangzi, see Adachi, Keiji, “Daizukasu Ryutsuu to Shindai no
Shougyouteki Nougyo” (Distribution of Soybean cake and the Commercialization of Qing
Agriculture) in Touyoushi Kenkyu, Vol. 37, No. 3, 1978, p. 35-63. For Japan’s internal
transportation and distribution improvements and the activities of large Japanese shipping
companies and trading houses, such as Mitsui and Mitsubishi in Manchuria, see Ikawa (n.22,
above), chapter 8.
26
Data on the ratio of summer and fall crop in the 1880-89 are from Kiyokawa (n.17, above),pp.
60-2. The rest is from Fujino et al (n. 4, above), vol.11, cols. 6 & 7 of Table 57. The Lu type and
its close relatives represented the single most important variety, accounting for one-fifth of
mulberry acreage in Japan by 1920. Lu trees also crossed with other varieties and could use
different names. Besides Lu, Meiji Japan introduced other varieties of mulberry from other
32
sericultural regions in China as well as other parts of the world that included Italy, India, and
South America. By the 1910s and 1920s, the stem-pruned type of mulberry tree formed about
60% of all mulberry trees in Japan. By the 1920s, almost 70% of the mulberry fields in Japan
could supply leaves for both the spring and fall crops in a year. See Editorial Committee (n. 12,
above),vol.4, p.114 and p.105-113, Ikawa (n. 22, above),chapter 3 and Fujino et al (n.4, above),
vol.11, p.155.
27
Ikawa (n.22, above), p.227-231.
28
For Chinese mulberry yield, see Ikawa (n.22, above), p.231; Yue (n.7, above), p. 19 and 71;
Jing-Yu Gao and Xue-xi Yan, Jindai Wuxi Cansi Ye Ziliao Xuanji (Selected Materials on the
Modern Silk Industry and Sericulture) (Jiangsu People’s Press and Jiangsu Classics Press. 1987),
p.10-11; Shanghai International Testing House, A Survey of the Silk Industry of Central China,
(Shanghai:1925), p. 88 and 92. The Gunma and Nagano yield are from Ikawa (n.22, above),
p.230-1. Japanese national average yield in the 1920s from Editorial Committee (n.12,
above),Vol. 4, p.319-20. For Lower Yangzi share of summer and fall crop in the 1910s and
1920s, see Ikawa, p.225 and Toua Dobun Kai, Shina Nen Kan (China Annals), (Tokyo: 1917 and
1919).
29
The narrative so far is based on Ishii (n.11, above), p.397-405 and Masaki Nakabayashi,
Masaki, “SeishiGyo no Hattatsu to Kansen Tetsudo” (Development of Silk Reeling and Main
Rail Lines) in Meiji no Sangyo Hatten to Shakai Shihon (edited by Naosuke Takamura) (Meiji
Industrial Development and Social Capital) (Tokyo: Minerva, 1997).
30
Ishii (n.11, above), pp.423-9.
31
For the troubles of modern silk reeling factories in Shanghai, see Tommo Suzuki, (no.10,
above), pp. 325-333. The fragility of private enterprise in nineteenth China can best be illustrated
by the fate of an indigeneous modern private silk reeling industry in rural Guangdong. The
mechanized silk reeling factories, set up by a overseas Chinese merchant in 1872 grew rapidly
within a few years but were met with riots from traditional silk weavers and subsequently ordered
to close by the local magistrate. See Debin Ma (1998), “Europe, China and Japan: Transfer of
Silk Reeling Technology in 1860-95” in Asia Pacific Dynamism 1550-2000, edited by A.J.H.
Latham and Heita Kawakatsu, (London: Routledge Press, 1998).
32
Xu, Xin-wu (ed.), Zhongguo Jindai Saosi Gongyeshi (Modern History of Chinese Silk-reeling
Industry), (Shanghai: People’s Publishing House, 1990), p.615.
33
Steamship companies were allowed to ply the Yangzi river and the coast under the treaty
system, but not in the inner rivers or canals. The government did compromise in 1889 to grant
the use of steamers in towing traditional boats in 1889. Suzuki (n.10, above),p.347.
34
For commercial organization in Qing China, see Susan Mann, Local Merchants and the
Chinese Bureaucracy, 1750-195, (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1987); For cocoon hangs,
see Li (n. 1, above), p.176-185; Saburo Soda, Chugoku Kindai Seishi Gyo Shi No Kenkyu (Study
on the Modern Chinese Silk Industry) (Tokyo: Kyuko Shoin, 1994), p389-404; Gao and Yan,
(n.28, above), p.18-9.
35
Soda (n.33, above), p.417.
33
36
See Chapter 4 of Lynda Bell’s One Industry, Two Chinas, Silk Filatures and Peasant-Family
Production in Wuxi County, 1865-1937, (Stanford University Press, 1999); Suzuki (n.10, above),
p.406; Soda (n.34, above),pp. 416-22.
37
Soda (n.34, above),pp.423-444 and Bell (n.36, above), p.79-80. The average metric tons of
annual cocoons shipped from the sericultural regions in the Lower Yangzi to Shanghai in the
period of 1900-09 were 9767. This number increased to 21303 tons for 1910-19 but only to
27152 tons for 1920-28. See Uehara (n. 7, above), pp.227-8 for 1913-28 and Akira Sitou,
Shinkoku Sansigyou Ippan (An Examination of Chinese Silk Sector), (Tokyo: Raw Silk
Inspection Bureau of Ministry of Agriculture and Commerce, 1911), pp.120-22 for 1898-1911.
38
For Qing’s fiscal system, see Wang, Yeh-chien, Land Tax in Imperial China, 1750-1911.
(Harvard University Press, 1993). Bell (n. 36, above), p.83-87; Mann (n.33, above).
39
Bell (n.36, above), p.82 and Soda (n. 34, above), p.427. The cocoon hang system had a control
of about 40 to 60% of all total cocoons sold in the Lower Yangtze. Federico (n. 2, above),
pp.148-9.
40
There were systematic efforts by the farmers to mix inferior quality cocoons with better quality
cocoons. See Li (n.1, above), p.185 and Soda (n.34, above), p.433-444.
41
For an English language account of the rise, fall and revival of the Merchant Guild System
(Kabu Nakama) in the Tokugawa period, see Charles Sheldon, The Rise of the Merchant Class in
Japan, 1600-1868, (New York: J. J. Augustin Inc. Publisher, 1958). For Meiji abolishment of
guilds, see Ryousuke Ishii, Houseishi (Legal History) (Tokyo: Yamagawa Publishing, 1965),
p.261.
42
Ishii (n. 11, above), pp.57-83 and p.429. Among the eight variables used in Kiyokawa’s probit
regression, the Subcontractual Direct Purchase system was the leading variable in explaining the
rapid diffusion of the F1 variety, (n.18, above), p.47.
43
For efficiency gains from commercialization in twentieth century China, see Earnest Liang
“Market Accessibility and Agricultural Development in Prewar China” Economic Development
and Cultural Change vol. 30, No.1, Oct. 1981.pp.77-105, and Loren Brandt, Commercialization
and Agricultural Development, Central and Eastern China 1870-1937, (Cambridge University
Press, 1989).
44
In chapters 5 and 6 of Hayami and Yamada (n.21, above) conducted counter-factual statistical
analysis on what the performance of Japanese agriculture would have been like had developments
in commercial fertilizer and summer and fall crop not occurred. Had Hayami conducted a
comparative study of China and Japan, he would have felt less need for his counter-factual
exercise. The Lower-Yangzi sericulture unfortunately supplied exactly the factual side of the
Hayami’s counter-factual of Japanese agriculture in the early twentieth century
45
Zhuang-Mu Wang (ed.), Minguo Sichou Shi (History of Silk in the Republic Era), (Beijing:
China Textile Publishing House, 1995), pp. 45-6 and p. 87. For a list of sericultural texts, see Zhu
(n.20, above),Appendix 1. For the growth of modern academic communities and institutions after
the twentieth century, see chapter 8 of John Fairbank and Albert Feuerwerker, The Cambridge
History of China, Vol. 13, Republican China 1912-1942, Part 2, (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1986).
34
46
It is important to note that the emergence of the Suwa district as Japan’s premium silk reeling
production center was the spread of modern banking and other service facilities throughout Japan
in the nineteenth century. See Ishii (n.11, above), chapter 2. For banking and service
developments in Wuxi, see Chen (n.7, above), chapter 2 and Gao and Yan (n.28, above).
47
Susan Mann argued that tax-farming practices did not disappear but was taken over by
specialized tax-farming agent, (n.34, above), chapter 9.
48
See Toua Kenkyujyo (n.4, above), pp.63-69, Gao and Yan (n.28, above), pp.305-8.
49
Tetsu Okumura, “Kyoko Ka Kosetsu Sanshigyo no Saihen” (Restructuring of the Jiangsu and
Zhejiang Silk Industry under the Great Depression) Toyoshi Kenkyu, Vol. 37, No. 2, 1979, p. 80-
116.Okumura; Saiichi Benno, “Chugoku No Nogyo Kindaika Ni Taisuru Teiko” (Resistence
Towards Chinese Agricultural Modernisation). Shakai Keizai Shigaku Vol. 59, No.2, 1993.
pp.30-59; Wang (n.45, above), pp. 64-86.
50
For a penetrating analysis of factors accounting for the lag in diffusion of the improved variety
in Zhejiang, see Benno (n.49, above). Ratio of fall crops is calculated from Toua Kenkyujyo (n.4,
above), p.298.
51
Although European and American individuals and organizations also made positive
contributions to sericultural improvements, the Japanese model eventually took dominance in the
Lower Yangzi as confirmed by the large number of sericultural reformers holding Japanese
degrees, direct participation of Japanese specialists in Lower Yangzi sericultural schools and
extensive introductions of Japanese sericultural technology in journals and books in the 1920s
and 30. See Kazuko Furuta, Technology Transfer and Local Adaptation: the Case of Silk-Reeling
in Modern East Asia, (A Dissertation submitted to Princeton University, 1988), pp.117-182 and
Wang (n.45, above). For a description of Chinese copying the Japanese model of reform, see
Douglas Reynolds, China, 1898-1912, The Xinzheng Revolution and Japan. (Harvard University
Press, 1993).
52
For cocoon output and raw silk exports, see Chen (n.7, above), p.109 and Okumura (n.49,
above). For imports of Japanese silk reeling technology in Wuxi and Yongtai’s marketing
activities in the U.S, see Gao and Yan (n.28, above), pp.325-9, 362-4. For Japanese investigators’
warnings of the Lower Yangzi competition in the 1930s, see Benno (n.49, above), p.32 and p. 39.
53
Francesca Bray, Science and Civilisation in China, vol 6, Biology and Biological Technology,
Part II: Agriculture. (Cambridge University Press, 1984), pp. 609-610.
54
For a recent debate on this issue, see articles appeared in The Journal of Asian Studies 61, no. 2
(May 2002), pp. 501-663.
35
36