Venezuela Building A Socialist Communal
Venezuela Building A Socialist Communal
Venezuela Building A Socialist Communal
In 2005, Chavez declared that the Bolivarian Revolution was building “socialism for the 21st
century.” Almost a decade later, however, the economy remains dominated by a parasitic
capitalist sector which obstructs efforts to build alternative socio-productive relations. In
avoiding a head-on confrontation with the bourgeoisie, the government is experimenting
with the introduction of a parallel communal economy in which the social product is
communally owned and invested on improvements to the habitat and wellbeing of the poor
Venezuelan majority. This explains the strategic importance of the Communal Economic
System (CES), as the principal vehicle for the introduction of socialist relations of
production in the Venezuelan economy. The article discusses the challenges facing the
development of the CES, based on my experience of working with the Vice Ministry of the
Communal Economy, the institution responsible for fostering and regulating that system.
Among Venezuelan government teams there is interest in Ernesto Che Guevara’s
contribution to the transition to socialism in Cuba. While Guevara’s methodological and
theoretical approach to socialist political economy can serve as guides to action, in
Venezuela its potential is blunted by the lack of state control over the economy and
socialisation of the means of production.
Keywords: Venezuela; Bolivarian Revolution; communal economy; socialism; Ernesto Che
Guevara
In autumn 2013, I spent time in Venezuela at the invitation of the Ministry of Communes and
Social Movements. Mostly I worked with the Vice Ministry of the Communal Economy
(VMCE), which is responsible for stimulating production and services within grassroots commu-
nities to complement their political organisation through communal councils and communes.
These “socio-productive” units are organised under the Communal Economic System (CES)
(Sistema Económico Comunal). Having read my book about Che Guevara’s work in revolution-
ary Cuba as Minister of Industries and his contribution to socialist political economy debates, the
VMCE was interested in discussing whether elements of Guevara’s Budgetary Finance System of
economic management could serve as useful tools in the CES and other areas of the Venezuelan
economy.1 This brief but intense visit provided me with an insight into the complicated processes
underway in the country. It also strengthened my appreciation of the intellectual and practical
battles fought in the earlier stages of Cuba’s transition to socialism, confronting similar problems
to those in contemporary Venezuela.
∗
Email:
[email protected]
1
See Yaffe (2009). The compañeros of the VMCE read the Spanish edition published in Cuba as Che
Guevara: Economı́a en Revolución in 2012. A Venezuelan edition is due for publication in autumn 2014.
The book has also been published in South Korea, Indonesia and Turkey.
There were two aspects to my participation. First, at ministries, universities, and to commu-
nity and political organisations, I gave presentations about Guevara’s Budgetary Finance System.
On some occasions I was asked to focus on Guevara’s analysis and policies in specific areas, such
as education, training and the role of salaries, or science, technology and innovation. Second, I
engaged in internal discussions about legal and policy documents previously sent to me.2 The
VMCE management team sought to relate Guevara’s approach to the issues raised in those docu-
ments. Discussions were organised according to the following themes: (1) the centralisation of the
administration and budgeting of finances; (2) “Economic Calculus” versus the Budgetary Finance
System; (3) education and training in the new productive economic model; (4) a management
model—the significance of social property for the management of the state, producers and
popular power; (5) reinvestment of the social surplus; and (6) moral and material incentives.
The themes are fundamental concerns for the transition to socialist relations of production gener-
ally but they are also specific issues confronting the development of the CES in Venezuela.
Endeavouring to apply a theoretical and historical understanding of Guevara’s approach to
socialist transition in early 1960s Cuba to a dramatically different reality in Venezuela today
was challenging. The economic, political and international conditions are distinct from those
that generated—and resulted from—the Cuban Revolution. Despite the obvious differences, in
broad terms the countries share historical socio-economic and political characteristics. Like
1950s Cuba, Venezuela can be described as having an unbalanced trade-dependent economy
dominated by foreign interests, principally from the United States. While Venezuela is far
more developed than Cuba (of the 1950s and of today) in technological and infrastructural
terms, the domination by foreign interests of the oil industry (as with Cuba’s sugar industry
pre-1960) and a form of “Dutch disease”3 had led to endemic unemployment, poverty and
inequality. While the revolution in Cuba dismantled the old system and swept away its represen-
tatives, creating new institutions, new power structures and new social relations, the Venezuelan
electoral system has brought forward a radically new government, but not an entirely new state or
social relations. In his important cabinet address published as “Golpe de Timón,” shortly after his
2012 presidential election victory, Chavez (2012, 13) said: “It always has to be this way: first the
political revolution, political liberation and after comes the economic revolution.” He insisted on
the need to make advances in the creation of a productive socialist economy in the “new stage”
commencing after the election. The “Bolivarian” government has declared its intention to build
“socialism of the 21st century” and, regardless of the deliberate differentiation from previous
socialisms implied by the label, this endeavour makes the Cuban experience and Guevara’s
approach to the political economy of the transition to socialism worth consideration.4
2
These documents were: (1) The Organic Law of the Communal Economic System (Ley Orgánica del
Sistema Económico Comunal), 2010; (2) Bolivarian Socialist Management 2013–2019, known as Home-
land Programme: Bolivarian Socialist Management 2013–2019 (Programa de la Patria: Para la
Gestion Bolivariana Socialista 2013–2019), published in June, 2012; (3) Proposal for a New Financial
Architecture for the CES (Propuesta para una Nueva Arquitectura Financiera del SEC), a VMCE draft
policy document, 2013; (4) Antimanual of the Communal Economic System (Antimanual del Sistema Eco-
nómico Comunal), a VMCE draft document providing an overview of the organisational and theoretical
aspects of the CES, 2013; (5) Partial regulation article on the CES printed in the Official Gazette (Gaceta
Oficial), 2012. All quotes from Spanish-language texts are my own translations.
3
“Dutch disease” describes the situation when the exploitation of natural resources, or any other source of
increased (foreign exchange) revenues, increases the strength of the national currency relative to other cur-
rencies. The consequent lack of competitiveness in the manufacturing or agricultural sector leads to a decline
in those areas and the economy becomes increasingly dependent on the natural resource.
4
Likewise, the experiences of all those countries which have endeavoured to build socialism.
International Critical Thought 25
The challenge is to strip away the different particular circumstances to address the core
questions:
This is not easy given that Marxism, if it is to be a living and revolutionary method, must be
concrete. Concrete conditions must determine the approach taken to analysing and changing
reality. This is the essence of “praxis.” Guevara’s contribution in Cuba was decisive and impress-
ive precisely because of his capacity to devise practical policies, which were appropriate to Cuba’s
concrete conditions and operated within a Marxist theoretical framework. For Guevara, the
problem of socialist transition was how to achieve economic development with equity from a pos-
ition of underdevelopment without relying on capitalist methods that would undermine the col-
lective consciousness and the new social relations necessary for socialism and later communism.5
This article does not claim to present a solution to the problem of building “socialism of the
21st century,” nor to present an economic history of Venezuela or predict its future. The purpose is
to discuss the issues that were encountered through my work with the VMCE—just one state
institution among many. It is not claimed that that experience was representative; it was influenced
by the focus and political and ideological commitments of the compañeros (as socialists and com-
munists) of the VMCE. It is important to recognise that within the government, and the governing
United Socialist Party of Venezuela (Partido Socialista Unido de Venezuela, PSUV), there are
significant conflicts and contradictions representing different political agendas and interests.
Nonetheless, given the strategic importance of the CES in the endeavour to introduce socialist
forms of production to Venezuela, there are lessons and implications that merit careful analysis.
Clearly, as my invitation confirms, Venezuelan government teams are interested in, and influenced
by, the experience of socialist transition in Cuba and Guevara’s revolutionary Marxism, so it is
important to understand what this implies for the process.6
5
It is important to distinguish between two stages which are often conflated: the transition from capitalism to
socialism, and the transition from socialism to communism.
6
Such interest is not new. Dr Orlando Borrego, deputy to Guevara between 1959 and 1965, has had a close
relationship with Chavez and the leadership of the Bolivarian Revolution for over a decade.
26 H. Yaffe
managers, technicians and engineers after 1959. Second, he proposed to centralise the finances of
all the production units into one bank account for the payment of salaries, to control investment and
sustain production in essential industries that lacked financial resources. With the establishment of
the Ministry of Industries in February 1961, the BFS evolved into a comprehensive apparatus that
embedded these organisational structures within a Marxist theoretical framework, to foster Cuba’s
industrialisation, increase productivity and institutionalise collective management. My book
(Yaffe 2009) details the policies developed and how they relate to the overriding objective of under-
mining and displacing the operation of the law of value in the socialist transition period.7
Central to the BFS was Guevara’s opposition to relying on capitalist mechanisms, conceding
to the operation of the law of value to determine production and consumption. The dispute about
the law of value in “transition economies” is at the heart of the question about the feasibility of
constructing socialism in a country without a fully developed capitalist mode of production,
where development has been stunted by imperialist exploitation. The debate is integral to the pro-
blems of production, distribution, investment and social relations. The notion of an eventual com-
munist stage of social development requires a highly productive society in which the political
conditions already exist for social production to be directed towards the needs of the masses.
“From each according to his ability, to each according to his needs” (Marx 1875, 11)—the
essence of communism—implies that socialism has already been constructed and that the
“market mechanism” has been largely displaced as a rationing mechanism in society. Commun-
ism should permanently block the reappearance of the law of value.
However, those countries that have experimented with socialism have lacked (and been
deprived of by imperialist aggression) the necessary productive base to complete the process
and so create the material abundance necessary to facilitate the transition to communism.
Under such underdeveloped or economically frustrated conditions, the problem of how to organ-
ise and direct the use of the social product is fundamentally shaped by the problem of underde-
velopment and scarcity. The questions for socialist transition economies are how far they are from
the point where work is remunerated on the basis of need, why, and how they should strive to
move towards a “communist” society. One answer which (re)emerged in the socialist bloc
by the 1950s was to utilise methods of production and distribution that allowed the operation
of the law of value through spontaneous and centrally unregulated processes of exchange with
the aim of hastening the development of the productive forces.8 This urgent material concern
was seen as a precondition to developing a socialist consciousness.
Guevara warned that depending on the law of value to foster development would jeopardise
the creation of a collective consciousness in the transition to socialism, and undermine the con-
ditions necessary for a future transition from socialism to communism. He said:
A socialist economy without communist moral values does not interest me. We fight poverty but we
also fight alienation. One of the fundamental aims of Marxism is to eliminate material interest, the
factor of “individual self-interest” and profit from man’s psychological motivations. Marx was
7
The analysis is organised into the following areas: education, training and salaries; administrative control,
supervision and investment; collectivising production and workers’ participation; science and technology;
consciousness and psychology. There are two theoretical chapters: one analysing the “Great Debate” of
1963– 65 about which economic management system was appropriate to Cuba in the transition to socialism
and the other synthesising Guevara’s critique of the Soviet Manual of Political Economy. There are also chap-
ters on Guevara’s role in Cuba’s revolutionary consolidation, the emergence of the BFS and Guevara’s
legacy.
8
Market mechanisms were adopted in the USSR between 1921 and 1928 under the New Economic Policy
introduced by Lenin. However, even after the end of this system, similar methods continued to exist in a
latent form gaining strength in the socialist bloc in the post-Stalin era.
International Critical Thought 27
concerned with both economic facts and their reflection in the mind, which he called a “fact of con-
sciousness.” If communism neglects facts of consciousness, it can serve as a method of distribution
but it will no longer express revolutionary moral values. (Quoted in Tablada 1990, 77)9
9
“If communism neglects . . . ” Guevara is clearly referring to the so-called “communist countries,” he is not
contemplating the idea that communism could be reached without a new consciousness developing along
with new social relations.
28 H. Yaffe
(8) As the collective owners of the means of production, workers must appropriate the pro-
duction process determining the plan and developing the productive forces. This is essential to
transform the social system, so that surplus products no longer appear as privately appropriated
surplus value, obtained via the market exchange mechanism (capitalism), but are directly allo-
cated through democratic decisions, to meet directly identified needs (socialism).
(9) Under capitalism, competition for profits constantly revolutionises the productive forces.
Socialist society must foster the application of science and technology to production without the
profit motive. Research institutes should work closely with ministries, enterprises and student
faculties.
(10) Development strategy should focus on the full chain of production, from raw materials to
electronics and automation.
(11) There is a dialectical relationship between consciousness and production. Incentives are
the key to raising productivity and efficiency. However, material incentives should gradually be
replaced by moral incentives and the concept of work as a social duty, replacing alienation and
antagonism with integration and solidarity.
(12) Create forums for criticism and open debate. Leaders must be responsible and accoun-
table. Work with technical experts regardless of their political affiliations, harnessing their
expertise in the interests of socialist production and integrating them into the revolutionary
process.
While these principles are arguably relevant to any socialist transition process, the current
domination by the private sector in Venezuela obstructs their meaningful application.
10
This is from the personal discussion with Ana Maldonado in September of 2013. Ana Maldonado was Vice
Minister of the Communal Economy during my trip. She subsequently transferred to work in the Great
Mission Knowledge and Work Venezuela (Gran Misión Saber y Trabajo Venezuela).
11
According to the Central Bank of Venezuela’s 2012 GDP calculations.
12
Personal communication from Jesus Castro, Statistical Director, VMCE, on May 5, 2014.
International Critical Thought 29
productive investments, boosting domestic consumption and leading to an increase in trade, tele-
communications, banks and services. Consequently, “the economy continues to be based on rent,
not productive work” (Caicedo 2014, 3). Public expenditure has not sufficiently promoted pro-
duction. Venezuelan economist Manuel Sutherland (2013, 1) states that, “The result of the expan-
sion of public expenditure, accompanied with the production weakness and massive
overvaluation of our currency, is a grotesque import growth at all levels.” Between 2003 and
2012, imports grew by 454% while exports increased 257% (including oil-price rises) (Sutherland
2013, 1).
In 2011, 98% of foreign exchange was generated by the state sector, compared to just 2%
(US$2 billion) earned by the private sector. However, in the same year the private sector spent
US$40 billion on imports, 20 times more than their export earnings—up from 2003, when the
value of their imports was three times their export earnings (Sutherland 2013, 2). This reflects
“a drastic worsening of the country’s productive situation and clearly shows the solidification
of the parasitic, unproductive and inefficient role of the local importing-business sector” (2).
The disproportion between the private sector’s hard currency earnings and expenditure is only
possible because the government, which controls foreign exchange, transfers US$40 billion
annually to that sector at preferential government rates: five times cheaper than on the parallel
market in 2013. Sutherland explains: “our entrepreneurs have no globally competitive potential
and their main activity is the passive absorption of oil revenues, through the importation of mer-
chandise based on overvalued currency” (2). Exchange controls were introduced in 2003 to halt
capital flight. Between then and 2012 the Venezuela state has sold US$317 billion dollars (at offi-
cial prices) to foreign and Venezuelan private businesses operating in the country (3). Instead of
taking advantage of the over-evaluation of the Bolivar to purchase machines and equipment for
productive investments, they have created a cycle of importing cheap commodities and reselling
them at inflated prices—speculating—or even importing empty boxes and keeping the US dollars
for resale at spiralling prices on the parallel market. Conservative estimates calculate that the
Venezuelan elite have deposited more than US$145 billion overseas between 2003 and 2012.
The government’s international foreign exchange reserves have fallen from US$12 billion in
1997 to US$3 billion in 2013 (3).13
The government has used its oil revenue to fund popular social welfare (and empowerment)
programmes. Popular support has allowed the Bolivarian government, on the whole, to set the pol-
itical agenda.14 There has long been recognition of the need to change the fundamental character-
istics of the Venezuelan economy if the Bolivarian Revolution is to advance; in the words of
Sutherland, “to stop procrastinating in the true socialist revolution which we must impel” (2013, 5).
According to the Homeland Programme, the official aim of the Bolivarian government is to:
“Insert new productive schemes tending to socialism that will radiate out in their environment
new relations of production and exchange that are complementary and give solidarity” (Republica
Bolivariana de Venezuela 2012b, 19). This is a vision, not a prescription. What is to be done? That
is the debate underway in Venezuela. Arguably, there are three broad options:
(1) Continue state/communal production and services, with a degree of planning, at the
margins of the economy in coexistence with the dominant private sector. How sustainable is
this coexistence?
(2) Encroach upon the capitalist sector through political action? Guevara said:
13
However, an estimated 70% of Venezuela’s international reserves are held in gold.
14
In February 2014, the right-wing opposition initiated a renewed attempt to reset the political agenda by
instigating violent protests and disturbances in the streets.
30 H. Yaffe
The characteristics of the period of transition are those of a society that is throwing off its old bonds in
order to move quickly into the new stage. The tendency should be, in our opinion, to eliminate as fast
as possible the old categories, including the market, money, and, therefore, material interest—or,
better, to eliminate the conditions for their existence. (Guevara 1971b, 142; emphasis added)
In Venezuela this would mean the expropriation, nationalisation and socialisation of the means of
production beyond the PDVSA.
(3) Compete with and overtake capitalist production/relations (“radiating out”). Achieving
this implies raising productivity in the state and communal sector above that of the private
sector. How can this be achieved whilst prioritising human welfare and sustainable development?
The CES is an expression of the attempt to take this third approach. The Bolivarian govern-
ment has not been prepared for (or concluded the necessity of) a head-on confrontation—with the
potentially violent class struggle that entails. Instead of dismantling the old apparatus and infra-
structure of capitalism, it has attempted to build a parallel apparatus to create an alternative system
of social-relations, production, distribution and political power. The capitalist class itself is losing
patience with “coexistence” and has been waging an economic war to destabilise the Bolivarian
government. This in turn is bolstering the socialist-revolutionary wing within the government and
the Bolivarian movement, which advocates political action against the capitalist sector; including
the nationalisation of the banking system, centralisation of foreign trade and initiating a massive
state industrialisation plan (see, for example, Caicedo 2014, and Sutherland 2013).15 In autumn
2013, President Maduro announced an “economic offensive” to combat the hoarding, speculation
and price rises which are the principal armaments of the bourgeoisie’s economic war.16
There are moves both to strengthen planning and organisation, and to expand state and com-
munal ownership. A VMCE document Premises for the Economic Offensive proposed a strategy
to combat these problems. It began by highlighting weaknesses in the current approach:17
We respond to the bourgeoisie’s illegal extraction with emergency imports; we confront the economic
slowdown in its final distribution and allocation stages. It is necessary to deal with paralysis in the
15
The Centro de Investigación y Formación Obrera CIFO-ALEM, where Sutherland and Caicedo work,
advocates such measures (www.alemcifo.org).
The basic way to stop the bleeding of foreign exchange and the dramatic devaluation-inflation spiral,
is to create a Single State Importation Centre (CEUI) that snatches the speculative field of the parasitic
speculative-importing Venezuelan bourgeoisie . . . The CEUI would seek to centralise in one state
entity all the countries imports that depend on dollars which are dispensed by the state. (Sutherland
2013, 7–8)
The fusion of all the banks into one national bank, without this implying the expropriation of the
money kept in the banks, but with the modification of the property relations of the banks acquired
by the state. Members of Centro de Investigación y Formación Obrera (CIFO) advocate nationalisa-
tion of the banks . . . accompanied by a comprehensive policy in political economy, that is, planning,
taxes, exchange rate, credit, a Single State Importation Centre (CEUI), creating a massive state indus-
trialisation plan, improving expropriated factories and using the land to obtain economies of scale.
(Caicedo 2014, 6)
16
The popularity of that move was reflected in improved election results for the United Socialist Party of
Venezuela in the December 2013 municipal elections. The opposition’s response was seen in the explosion
of violent protest which began in February 2014, resulting in the death of dozens of Venezuelans, with
calls by the protest organisers for regime change and even US intervention.
17
On page 3 of Premises for the Economic Offensive (in Spanish), a document not formally published, which
exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
International Critical Thought 31
production process; on the issue of inflation we respond with reflections about prices, rather than
seeing inflation as part of an economic war: speculation, shortages and hoarding; we respond to
supply shortages with supplementary supplies. . . .
The document outlined steps to be taken in the “new stage” introduced by Chavez in October
2012.18 Those include: developing a new productive economy—creating and strengthening the
communal economic system; organising the new, productive economy according to the pro-
ductive capacity and potential of the municipalities and with new social relations of production;
developing a method for establishing national production costs that is not distorted by import
prices—“as an importing economy we have always taken the benchmark of import price”; pur-
chasing imports directly and in large quantities in a centralised way.19 The document then pro-
poses measures to be taken in the areas of production, distribution and “commercialisation”
within the CES.
In autumn 2013, a government “subcommission for the promotion of the productive economy
of the communes” was set up for vice ministers and directors from institutions related directly to
the economy and production. The VMCE was the coordinating body and I attended the second
weekly meeting. The then Vice Minister Ana Maldonado gave an overview of how communal
production is being obstructed, or made excessively expensive, by the private sector. Other par-
ticipants discussed possible collaboration to confront such hurdles. The question is whether these
obstacles can be overcome by fostering a parallel economy, under communal and state ownership,
or whether it necessitates political action against the capitalist sector. The third weekly meeting
was cancelled, however, as the vice ministers were enrolled to participate in the second round
of “street governments” (gobierno de la calle) in the run-up to the local elections.20 The impera-
tive of gaining control over the economy was postponed by the call for direct interaction of the
leadership with the population. Such communication is important, but the daily work of organis-
ing and resolving problems must also be a priority.
18
On page 4 of Premises for the Economic Offensive (in Spanish), a document not formally published, which
exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
19
In December 2013, a new National Centre for Foreign Trade and a Corporation for Foreign Trade were
established to manage imports and exports through state enterprises in order to tackle this issue.
20
I had been due to present on Che Guevara’s BFS and Cuba’s socialist transition.
21
Solidarity Exchange Groups are basically monthly markets of small, predominantly agricultural, produ-
cers. In autumn 2013, there were 14 groups and four more being established. These are not productive
units, but units of exchange. They are discussed below in relation to the issue of “communal money.”
32 H. Yaffe
22
As a comparison: in 2012, around 40% of the state budget, nearly US$28 billion, was allocated to
social spending.
23
Personal communication in September 2013.
24
Comments following my presentation to Ministry directors on October 8, 2013.
International Critical Thought 33
international trade independently, without authorisation, is as likely to result in chaos and waste as
it is to be efficient.
Among the “direct” ESPs is a communal minibus service (ruta communal) run by Las Torres
communal council in the Caracas barrio Antimano. Set up with government support, Las Torres
community now owns 17 minibuses for transporting locals up and down the mountain at prices
well below those charged by the private companies. This service employs 30 locals. Since 2008,
with government support in resources and technical experts, the community has constructed a
new concrete road, over 100 houses and other social facilities such as a playground, which I saw
during my visit.25 The community was improving the medical clinic run by Cuban doctors and
had plans to build a small community school. The construction of additional social facilities had
been funded with the surplus earned from the communal minibus service. A good portable drinking
water service had been established. The community’s own ironworks and brickyard produce con-
struction materials. The ironworks employed three locals and the other construction teams employed
36, but this was set to rise to 70 with new projects underway and more residents incorporated into the
community’s socio-productive system. Work has started on the construction of another ESP, a work-
shop to make household products like detergents and soaps, to employ an additional 15 locals.
Many of the ESPs produce components for the Great Housing Mission Venezuela (Gran
Misión Vivienda Venezuela), which aims to construct three million new houses between 2012
and 2019.26 ESPs are responsible for producing 26% of the concrete blocks used in the
Housing Mission, 23% of the beds, 15% of the windows, 33% of the industrial overalls, and
24% of gloves.27 However, the private businesses that transport or produce materials needed
for the housing construction process charge exorbitant prices. Through this means the private
sector booms while obstructing state and social production. The state is obliged to pay several
times over the production cost because it does not own the full chain of production.28
The Premises document cites an example of the market undermining the plan that I observed at
the carpenter’s in Guarena. They have a contract to produce 45,000 pallets to supply an enterprise
producing concrete blocks for the Housing Mission. However, production has been paralysed due
to the lack of coil gun nails. The private company, Alambricos Venezolanos CA, which supplied
the ESP with the nails first raised prices and then claimed it could not get hold of the wire necessary
to produce them. The ESP took steps to import the nails directly from Colombia, to avoid paying
exorbitant prices to private sector importers. We discussed the problem with this solution, and
with dependence on capitalist enterprises in general in a situation of class war; the profit motive
can be subjugated to the political objective of sabotaging the Bolivarian Revolution. The nails them-
selves are produced with a simple machine. The carpenters discussed importing the machine and
producing the nails themselves. An investigation was immediately launched which found that the
private company was hoarding nails. They lied about the lack of supply in order to paralyse pro-
duction in the ESP. The company was fined for manipulating prices and supply. Arguably,
25
Las Torres had 109 “ranchos,” precarious homes made from slim wooden planks, many of them donated by
the Coca Cola Corporation. Since 2008, the community itself had built 108 new homes from scratch with
more under construction. The National Land Institute evaluates safety and conditions on the site of each con-
struction. Each new concrete house has three bedrooms, a sitting room, kitchen and a bathroom.
26
Given that the average family size in Venezuela is 5.28, this amounts to the provision of new homes for
more than a half of Venezuela’s nearly 30 million people.
27
On page 16 of Premises for the Economic Offensive (in Spanish), a document not formally published,
which exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
28
In an interview by CNN, Maduro revealed that “in November, December [2013], we’ve found prices that
were up 2000% . . . this happened not in one product, but in the whole of the economy . . . inflation has been
used as a political strategy to harm the economy and then to destroy, to unravel, a new model that has been
created, a new model of society, of economy” (Maduro and Amanpour 2014).
34 H. Yaffe
however, the fine was an insufficient deterrent given the scale and consequences of such economic
sabotage. This, however, reflects the preference in Venezuela that has been to get around supply and
production problems by establishing alternative sources, rather than transferring control of private
production to the state or community.
The visits to the ESPs clarified many issues that had arisen from reading the CES documents.
Nonetheless, inevitably, there were important issues insufficiently addressed in the establishment
of this new system. A summary of several such problems and contradictions within the CES
appears below. The material is organised into the following sections: the objectives of CES; pro-
duction and productivity; remuneration; management and responsibility; planning and prices; the
bank and money.
Generate mechanisms for the circulation of capital, that constitute a new economic metabolism for
stimulating the functioning and the development of national industry, as much in sources of
finance and the dynamics of productive scale, as in the flow of resources that confront the logic of
capital. (Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela 2012b, 30)
29
The term “Anti-manual” is inspired by the Venezuelan philosopher Ludovico Silva, who wrote the “Anti-
manual para uso de marxistas, marxólogos y marxianos” (Anti-manual for the use of Marxists, Marxologists
and Marxianos) in 1975, which called for a return of the essence of Marx’s philosophy, through reading his
original works, rather than leaning on Soviet and other “Marxist” manuals.
30
On page 21 of Antimanual of the Communal Economic System (in Spanish), a document not formally pub-
lished, which exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
International Critical Thought 35
Circulating capital in order to confront the logic of capital?31 This apparent contradiction is
because the first reference to “circulating capital” actually means making finance or funds avail-
able. This highlights the need for conceptual clarity and terminological precision. Part of the on-
going debate must concern the search for a terminology, which more appropriately expresses the
characteristics of a society in transition to socialism. Additional questions follow: Where are the
“funds” which must circulate to come from? Who controls, budgets and plans that funding? What
is the relationship of the banks and the plan to this objective?
31
In his most scathing criticism of Soviet political economy, Guevara complained: “All the residues of capit-
alism are used to the maximum in order to eliminate capitalism. Dialectics is a science not some joke. No one
scientifically explains this contradiction” (Guevara 2006, 188).
32
On page 1 of Proposal for a New Financial Architecture for the Economic Communal System (in Spanish),
a document not formally published, which exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
36 H. Yaffe
months of the enterprises’ costs, but this part should start being repaid after the first six months in
60 equal instalments at 0% interest. Repayments form part of the ESP costs, which will obviously
reduce any possible surplus until the credit is repaid. The Antimanual states that socio-productive
organisations not generating a surplus should nonetheless allocate 6% of their total income to pay
into the three funds: productive maintenance, attention to the producers and social reinvestment,
which results in an increased deficit.33 How will this deficit be reduced and how can enterprises be
safeguarded from bankruptcy?
33
On page 78 of Antimanual of the Communal Economic System (in Spanish), a document not formally pub-
lished, which exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
34
In 1964, the new salary scale which Guevara worked on in Cuba, introduced 24 different salary levels. This
was a reduction from “some 90,000 different salaries in Cuba and some 25,000 different salary grades”
(Guevara 1977b, 164). The payroll was based on skill and output norms (averages), laboriously calculated
throughout the national economy and it promoted training (Yaffe 2009, 95 –99).
35
On page 62–63 of Antimanual of the Communal Economic System (in Spanish), a document not formally
published, which exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
International Critical Thought 37
is constituted by two “institutional spokespersons,” one representing the public institution respon-
sible and the other representing FONDEMI, the funding institution. Every six months they must
submit reports to the community and state authorities. The third person is elected by the Assembly
of Producers. This arrangement provides the government with a mechanism for guiding, monitor-
ing and evaluating the progress of the ESP as two out of three members of the Administrative Unit
represent government institutions. Both the public institution and FONDEMI representatives are
local people, not outsiders. In “direct” ESPs, however, all three delegates on the Administrative
Unit are directly selected by the Assembly of Producers. In a situation where a significant pro-
portion of the Venezuelan population vote against the Bolivarian government, the absence of
an administrative lever of control at this grassroots level could become an obstacle to the objec-
tives of the CES.
The other three ESP “units” are for productive management, training and social control. The
unit of “social control” (contralorı́a social) is responsible for: “supervising, controlling, monitor-
ing, oversight and auditing the implementation of plans and projects for the socio-productive
organisation and its internal funds”; “to produce reports on activities undertaken”; to be “publicly
accountable” and “to convene extraordinary meetings of the socio-productive organisation, when
it deems this appropriate to improve the performance of its functions.”36 The question which
Guevara constantly raised and addressed is: who supervises the supervisors?
What measures can be taken to ensure that the interests of the ESP coincide with the national
plan and development strategy? Guevara argued for political cadre to act as the “ideological
motor” of society and the economy. No similar role has been assigned to Venezuela’s PSUV.
Different entities of the social economy are organised through Public Power (state and public
institutions) or Popular Power (grassroots and community groups). What are the advantages/dis-
advantages of each organisational form and how do they interact between them?
There is currently no mechanism for ensuring that workers trained through the CES are
obliged to “pay back” the community or the state, via future commitment, for training received.
Effectively there is nothing stopping individuals who have benefited from such a social invest-
ment from incorporating themselves into the private sector, in search of higher wages or better
conditions.
36
On page 55 of Antimanual of the Communal Economic System (in Spanish), a document not formally pub-
lished, which exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
38 H. Yaffe
complementary socio-productive units, but with the system’s expansion regulations may be
needed to prevent competition developing between different ESPs.
Guevara argued that once a plan has been formulated, through democratic discussion and
economic analysis, administrative controls were necessary to guarantee its implementation
(Yaffe 2009, 100– 130). There is a need to devise such methods within the CES, and to
provide a lever of control over the private sector if its output is to be incorporated within the
national plan. How can this be achieved with a private sector that evades plans and avoids
cooperation? The plan will have the dual function of incorporating the economic contribution
of the private sector and planning its control and transformation in the transition to a socialist
economy.
The problem of establishing prices under socialist production remains unsolved. Under the
CES, price is mainly determined by the cost of inputs.37 As a result, given the dependence on
(domestic and international) capitalist production, prices are determined by market forces. The
development of the full chain of production in the CES, removing dependence on the capitalist
sector for inputs, introduces the possibility of setting prices in accordance with political objec-
tives. However, establishing prices in an administrative way in relation to costs could lead to a
divergence with the (national and international) market price, resulting in CES products being
more expensive (and therefore less desirable) than products in the capitalist sector, including
imports. These are complex but important problems to be addressed.
37
On page 49 of Antimanual of the Communal Economic System (in Spanish), a document not formally pub-
lished, which exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
International Critical Thought 39
an equivalent value for their produce—say three bananas for one avocado. In just three of the 14
Solidarity Exchange Groups, communal money has been introduced apparently to “facilitate” the
exchange process. This is a bit like an experiment to re-enact the historical process through which
the money commodity originally emerged. The communities themselves name, design and
produce their own currency and bring the paper notes to the market to use in exchanges with
similar producers with different communal monies. A bureaucratic arbitration process is
needed to establish the ratio of equivalence between the monies and goods. Although I did not
have the opportunity to visit an Exchange Group operating with “communal money,” I did par-
ticipate in one based on simple barter. Against a backdrop of music and dancing, at the flat peak of
the mountain, which hosts Barrio 23 de Enero in Caracas, I discovered that the whole experience
was more a cultural (and political) celebration, than a “market.” The rural representatives, some of
whom had travelled over night to Caracas, were not concerned with material gain or finding
outlets for their produce. They participated for the sociability and solidarity. Political emphasis
was given to the importance of organic production and against the imposition of transgenics
by multinational agribusinesses.
Architecture, however, contains a more complex and expanded vision for the use of commu-
nal money under the CES. The “main functions” proposed are: (1) operate as a compensation
system to facilitate the exchange of inputs between production units; (2) remuneration of a
portion of the foodstuff goods from the basic basket; (3) fixed income assets for the recognition
of labour liabilities; (4) medium of internal exchange in the communes; and (5) a value reserve.
The document states that “The relationship of equivalence between the bolivar and the communal
money will be one to one.”38
How could the communal money serve to undermine commodity relations (which are
expressed by money)? Who would benefit from the system? The document also asserts that, “it
should be a similar compensation scheme to that which functions in the SUCRE.”39 The compari-
son is not convincing. The SUCRE and other regional payment schemes reduce the transaction
costs and political risks otherwise involved in transacting currencies into US dollars and euros
to facilitate trade between countries with different legal tenders. The proposed “communal
money,” however, creates nominally new “monies” and then adopts a system of exchange for them.
More convincing is the proposal that “one part of the producers remuneration is denominated
in communal money, for purchasing foodstuffs and products in the basic basket which are part of
the productive activity of their own commune.”40 In this sense it would serve as a kind of “certi-
ficate” received by workers in exchange for their labour, as Marx envisaged for a communist
society emerging from capitalist society, rather than “money” which can be used as capital.
This would promote communal production, still constrained by bourgeois “equal right” (Marx
1875, 11).
Guevara asserted, money reflects the relations of production and cannot exist without a
society based on commodity production (Guevara 1971a, 298). His BFS relegated the role of
money to “money of account,” a price reflection of an enterprise’s performance, not as means
of payment or as a form of financial compulsion. The administrative levers Guevara adopted
38
On page 4 of Proposal for a New Financial Architecture for the Economic Communal System (in Spanish),
a document not formally published, which exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
39
SUCRE (Unique System for Regional Compensation) is a virtual currency or shared accounting unit for
trade between member states of the Bolivarian Alliance for the Americas, or ALBA. It was set up in
2010 and has been pioneered by Venezuela, Cuba, Ecuador and Bolivia.
40
On page 4 of Proposal for a New Financial Architecture for the Economic Communal System (in Spanish),
a document not formally published, which exists as an internal document of the VMCE in Caracas.
40 H. Yaffe
could serve as more useful tools than communal money for promoting production and pro-
ductivity in the CES.
4. Conclusion
In 2005, Chavez declared that the Bolivarian Revolution was building socialism for the 21st
century. Almost a decade later, however, the economy remains dominated by a parasitic capitalist
sector, which obstructs all efforts to build alternative socio-productive relations. In avoiding a
head-on confrontation with the bourgeoisie, the government is experimenting with the introduc-
tion of a parallel communal economy in which the social product is communally owned and
invested on improvements to the habitat and wellbeing of the poor Venezuelan majority. This
explains the strategic importance of the CES, as the principal vehicle for the introduction of
socialist relations of production in the Venezuelan economy. The objective of this communal pro-
duction is as much political and cultural as economic. However, arguably, the potential develop-
ment of the socio-productive units into a comprehensive system, rather than a “network” of
associated entities, is obstructed by machinations from the capitalist sector. Private interests
exploit the dependence of the ESPs on goods and services under their control to manipulate
supply and prices. Some sectors within the Bolivarian movement argue that greater political
action must be taken to prevent economic sabotage and undermine the power of the Venezuelan
bourgeoisie.
Among those arguing in favour of greater state/social ownership and centralised control over
imports and exports, there is an interest in Cuba’s socialist revolution and in Guevara’s BFS.
While Guevara’s methodological and theoretical approach to the political economy of the tran-
sition to socialism can serve as a guide to action, in Venezuela their potential is blunted by the
lack of state control over the economy and socialisation of the means of production. Guevara
argued for Cuba to be considered as “one big factory,” in which production is planned and organ-
ised according to social rationality, or need, not through market mechanisms. Ultimately, in Vene-
zuela the first step would be to take measures that transfer control of the means of production from
the private to the social/communal sector. The aim should not be to build a parallel socialist
economy, but an alternative socialist economy in Venezuela. There is a great deal at stake, not
just in Venezuela, but throughout Latin America and the world. This process merits careful obser-
vation and analysis.
Acknowledgements
I am grateful to Venezuelan economist Judy Valencia, who brought my book to the attention of her col-
leagues in Venezuela, and to the Ministry of Communes and Social Movements for inviting and hosting
me. I am especially grateful to Ana Maldonado, then Vice Minister of the Communal Economy, and to
the management team at the VMCE for arranging a hectic but fascinating programme of work and for the
stimulating debates. Thanks also to Paul Bullock for the engaging discussions about Venezuela and socialist
political economy prior to and following my trip.
Notes on Contributor
Dr Helen Yaffe has multidisciplinary expertise in economic, social and political history, Latin American
studies, political economy and human geography. Her doctoral thesis, undertaken at the London School
of Economics, was published as Che Guevara: The Economics of Revolution and has been translated into
several languages. She has taught and published on Cuban and Latin American history and development
and the political economy of socialism. She is an honorary visiting fellow at the University of Leicester.
In 2013 she advised the Ministry of Communes in Venezuela.
International Critical Thought 41
References
BBC. 2012. “In Depth: Media in Venezuela.” http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-latin-america-19368807.
Caicedo, J. 2014. The Concentration of Banking Capital and the Need to Nationalise the Bank of Venezuela.
[In Spanish]. Centro de Investigación y Formación Obrera CIFO-ALEM. www.rebelion.org/docs/
183720.pdf.
Chavez, H. 2012. Striking the Steering Wheel, 1st Council of Ministers in the New Cycle of the Bolivarian
Revolution. [In Spanish.] www.aporrea.org/media/2012/12/golpe-de-timon.pdf.
Guevara, E. C. 1971a. “Banking, Credit and Socialism.” In Man and Socialism in Cuba: The Great Debate,
edited by B. Silverman, 23–41. New York: Atheneum.
Guevara, E. C. 1971b. “On the Budgetary Finance System.” In Man and Socialism in Cuba: The Great
Debate, edited by B. Silverman, 122 –56. New York: Atheneum.
Guevara, E. C. 1977a. Writings and Speeches, vol. 4. [In Spanish.] Havana: Editorial de Ciencia Sociales.
Guevara, E. C. 1977b. Writings and Speeches, vol. 7. [In Spanish.] Havana: Editorial de Ciencia Sociales.
Guevara, E. C. 2006. Critical Notes on Political Economy. [In Spanish.] Havana: Ciencias Sociales.
Lenin, V. I. 1917. “Can the Bolsheviks Retain State Power?” https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/
1917/oct/01.htm.
Maduro, N., and C. Amanpour. 2014. “Interview with Nicolas Maduro by CNN’s Christiane Amanpour.”
CNN, March 7. http://amanpour.blogs.cnn.com/2014/03/07/full-transcript-nicolas-maduro/.
Marx, K. 1875. “Critique of the Gotha Programme.” www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/download/
Marx_Critque_of_the_Gotha_Programme.pdf.
Ministerio de Azucar. 1966. Che in the Cuban Revolution: Ministry of Industries. [In Spanish.] Havana:
Ministerio de Azucar.
Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela. 2010. “Organic Law of the Communal Economic System.” [In
Spanish.] Official Gazette, no. 6,011 Special, December 21.
Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela. 2012a. Official Gazette. [In Spanish.] February 2. http://www.worldcat.
org/title/gaceta-oficial-de-la-republica-de-venezuela/oclc/6266112.
Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela. 2012b. Homeland Programme: Bolivarian Socialist Management
2013–2019. [In Spanish.] http://www.worldcat.org/title/gaceta-oficial-de-la-republica-de-venezuela/
oclc/6266112.
Sutherland, M. 2013. “To Nationalise Foreign Trade Is to Curb Fraudulent Imports, Inflation and the Next
Devaluation.” [In Spanish.] Rebelion, July 11. http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=170973.
Tablada, C. P. 1990. Che Guevara: Economics and Politics in the Transition to Socialism. 2nd ed. New York:
Pathfinder.
Yaffe, H. 2009. Che Guevara: The Economics of Revolution. London: Palgrave Macmillan.