The Theory of Individual Behaviour
The Theory of Individual Behaviour
The Theory of Individual Behaviour
Unit Objectives
By the end of this unit, you should be able to:
Introduction
This chapter develops tools that can help a manager to understand the behaviour of
individuals, such as consumers and workers, and the impact of alternative incentives on their
decisions. The human brain is capable of processing vast amounts of information and making
complex decisions. The brain can perform tasks that even supercomputers and advanced
‘artificial intelligence’ are unable to do.
Consumer behaviour
Consumers are individuals who purchase goods and services from firms for personal
use. Behaviour refers to the way a person or organism responds or reacts to a normal or
specific situation. Consumer behaviour is concerned with how consumers react to various
choices and alternatives. Managers must focus not only on the consumer but the purchaser of
the product as well. For example, a baby food manufacturer should understand the parents'
behavior, not the baby's.
Understanding consumer behaviour is the first step in making profitable pricing,
advertising, product design, and production decisions. Firms spend a great deal of time and
money trying to estimate and forecast the demand for their products. Obtaining accurate
estimates of demand requires more than a superficial understanding of the underpinnings of
demand functions. A manager’s need for practical analysis of demand, both estimation of
demand and demand forecasting, requires an economic model of consumer behaviour to
guide the analysis.
In characterizing consumer behavior, there are two important but distinct factors to
consider: consumer opportunities and consumer preferences. Consumer opportunities
represent the possible goods and services consumers can afford to consume. Consumer
preferences determine which of these goods will be consumed. The distinction is very
important: While I can afford (and thus have the opportunity to consume) one pound of beef
liver each week, my preferences are such that I would be unlikely to choose to consume beef
liver at all. Keeping this distinction in mind, let us begin by modeling consumer preferences.
Complete Preference Ordering: For any given pair of consumption bundles, consumers
must be able to rank the bundles according to the level of satisfaction they would enjoy from
consuming the bundles. A consumption bundle would be ranked higher (i.e., preferred) than
another bundle if the preferred bundle yields more satisfaction than the other, less-preferred
bundle. Or, if the two bundles yield exactly the same level of satisfaction, the consumer
would be indifferent between the two bundles and would give the two bundles the same
ranking. When a consumer can rank all conceivable bundles of commodities, the consumer’s
preferences are said to be complete.
Transitive preference ordering: Consumer preferences are transitive when they are
consistent in the following way. If bundle A is preferred to bundle B, and bundle B is
preferred to bundle C, then bundle A must be preferred to bundle C. Using the symbols
presented above: If A s B, and B s C, then it follows that A s C. Consumer preferences must
be transitive, otherwise inconsistent preferences would undermine the ability of consumer
theory to explain or predict the bundles consumers will choose
U= f (X, Y)
where X and Y are, respectively, the amounts of goods X and Y consumed, f means “a
function of” or “depends on,” and U is the amount of utility the person receives from each
combination of X and Y. Thus, utility depends on the quantities consumed of X and Y. The
actual numbers assigned to the levels of utility are arbitrary. We need only say that if a
consumer prefers one combination of goods, say, 25X and 35Y, to some other combination,
say, 10X and 25Y, the amount of utility derived from the first bundle is greater than the
amount from the second
U= f(25,35) ˃ U f (10,25 )
Indifference curve
Limitations
In making decisions, individuals face constraints. There are legal constraints, time
constraints, physical constraints, and, of course, budget constraints. To maintain our focus on
the essentials of managerial economics without delving into issues beyond the scope of this
course, we will examine the role prices and income play in constraining consumer behavior.
Budget constraint
Simply stated, the budget constraint restricts consumer behavior by forcing the consumer to
select a bundle of goods that is affordable. If a consumer has only $30 in his or her pocket
when reaching the checkout line in the supermarket, the total value of the goods the consumer
presents to the cashier cannot exceed $30. To demonstrate how the presence of a budget
constraint restricts the consumer’s choice, we need some additional shorthand notation. Let
M represent the consumer’s income, which can be any amount. By using M instead of a
particular value of income, we gain generality in that the theory is valid for a consumer with
any income level. We will let Px and Py represent the prices of goods X and Y, respectively.
Given this notation, the opportunity set
also called the budget set(The bundles of goods a consumer can afford) may be expressed
mathematically as
PxX + PyY ≤ M
In words, the budget set defines the combinations of goods X and Y that are affordable for the
consumer: The consumer’s expenditures on good X, plus her or his expenditures on good Y,
do not exceed the consumer’s income. Note that if the consumer spends his or her entire
income on the two goods, this equation holds with equality. This relation is called the budget
line (The bundles of goods that exhaust a consumer’s income)
PxX + PyY = M
In other words, the budget line defines all the combinations of goods X and Y that exactly
exhaust the consumer’s income.
It is useful to manipulate the equation for the budget line to obtain an alternative expression
for the budget constraint in slope-intercept form. If we multiply both sides of the budget line
by 1/Py, we get
Px M
X +Y=
Py Py
Solving for Y yields
M Px
Y= − X
Py Py
M Px
Note that Y is a linear function of X with a vertical intercept of and a slope of – . The
Py Py
upper boundary of the budget set in the Figure below is the budget line.
Opportunity set
Budget Line
M Px
Y= − X
Py Py
n
M
Py
Unaffordable
H
PPPP
M
0
Px
Affordable
Similarly, if the consumer spent his or her entire income on good Y, expenditures on Y would
exactly equal income:
Py Y = M
Consequently, the maximum quantity of good Y that is affordable is
M
Y=
Py
Px
The slope of the budget line is given by – and represents the market rate of substitution
Py
between goods X and Y.
Market rate of substitution
To obtain a better understanding of the market rate of substitution between goods X and Y,
consider in the Figure below, which presents a budget line for a consumer who has $10 in
income and faces a price of $1 for good X and a price of $2 for good Y. If we substitute these
values of Px, Py, and M into the formula for the budget line, we observe that the vertical
M 10
intercept of the budget line (the maximum amount of good Y that is affordable) is = =¿
Py 2
M 10
5. The horizontal intercept is = =10and represents the maximum amount of good X
Px 1
that can be purchased. The slope of the budget line is –
Px
Py
=−
1
2
. ()
The reason the slope of the budget line represents the market rate of substitution between the
two goods is as follows: Suppose a consumer purchased bundle A in the Figure below, which
represents the situation where the consumer purchases 3 units of good Y and 4 units of good
X. If the consumer purchased bundle B instead of bundle A, she would gain one additional
unit of good Y. But to afford this, she must give up 2 units (4 − 2 = 2) of good X. For every
unit of good Y the consumer purchases, she must give up 2 units of good X in order to be able
to afford the additional unit of good Y. Thus the market rate of substitution is
Δ Y 4 – 3 −1
= = ,which the slope of the budget line is.
ΔX 2–4 2
Y
5
4
X
2 4 10
Changes in income
The consumer’s opportunity set depends on market prices and the consumer’s income. As these parameters
change, so will the consumer’s opportunities. Let us now examine the effects on the opportunity set of changes
in income by assuming prices remain constant.
If a consumer spent the entire income on good X, the expenditures on good X would exactly equal the
consumer’s budget constraint is graphed in Figure 4–3. The shaded area represents the consumer’s budget set, or
opportunity set. In particular, any combination of goods X and Y within the shaded area, such as point G,
represents an affordable combination of X and Y. Any point above the shaded area, such as point H, represents a
bundle of goods that is unaffordable. consumer’s income:
Px X = M