Democracy and Development: The Global Polity
Democracy and Development: The Global Polity
Sean Cleary
Chairman, Strategic Concepts
1. Clarify development
Democracy is defined in the Oxford English Dictionary as “government by the people; that
form of government in which the sovereign power resides in the people and is exercised either
directly by them or by officers elected by them.” Abraham Lincoln famously described it as
“government of the people, for the people, by the people.”
Development is defined by the OECD as “gradual unfolding, fuller working out; growth,
evolution; well grown state, state of advancement; product; more elaborate form…” The
essence of this definition is thus “evolution to a more advanced state.”
When we move beyond the abstract, problems arise. The concept of development is em-
ployed, in the technical literature and by institutions charged to advance it, in a wholly im-
precise way. We cannot claim to have a coherent theory of development, let alone success-
fully to have implemented it. So what is the development we are considering?
Economic development: For many years development was thought of as economic develop-
ment. Many would still consider the concepts equivalent. “Sustained increase in the economic
standard of living of a country’s population, normally accomplished by increasing its stocks of
physical and human capital and improving its technology” (Deardorff's Glossary of Inter-
national Economics).
A developed country is “[a] country whose per capita income is high by world standards;” and
a developing country is “[a] country whose per capita income is low by world standards; same
as less developed country. As usually used, it does not necessarily connote that the country's
income is rising.”(Deardorff)
Human development: But economic advancement is not the only meaning of the word
development: For the purposes of its Human Development Index, the United Nations Develop-
ment Programme defines and assesses three aspects of human development: life expectancy
and health; knowledge; and standard of living.
Poverty reduction: The World Bank group – whose World Development Reports are com-
prehensive essays on global development – describes itself as “a vital source of financial and
technical assistance to developing countries…[through]…two unique development institutions…
– the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) and the International
Development Association (IDA)” – both of which aim to reduce poverty, (i) the IBRD “by
promoting sustainable development through loans, guarantees, risk management products,
and analytical and advisory services in middle-income and creditworthy poorer countries; and
(ii) the IDA “by providing interest-free credits and grants for programs that boost economic
growth, reduce inequalities and improve people’s living conditions” in those still poorer, or less
creditworthy. The Bank’s current developmental focus is therefore on poverty reduction based
on national Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers.
Where to? Wealth cannot be the sole measure of development! Measures of economic
performance based on GDP are inadequate in an inter-dependent world. The relevance of
GDP as a measure of societal well-being, or of economic, environmental and social sustain-
ability, is also questionable. In 2008, French Prime Minister Nicholas Sarkozy created a Com-
mission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress, which
includes Nobel laureates Amartya Sen and Joseph Stiglitz. Professor Sen also contributed to
3
the 2004 report Human Security Now and has prepared a set of indicators to complement
GDP.
4
Easterly debunks (i) the Harrod-Domar model: “[T]here is no stable short-run link between
investment and growth” (William Easterly, The elusive quest for growth: economists’ ad-
ventures and misadventures in the tropics, MIT Press, 2002, p. 44); (ii) the emphasis on
education: “the growth in output per worker [despite an explosion in education] was 3% in the
1960s, 2.5% in the 1970s; –0.5% in the 1980s, and 0% in the 1990s” (Easterly, 2002, p. 74);
(iii) a focus on population control: “there is no association… between success at slowing
population growth and success at raising per capita growth” (Easterly, 2002, p. 92), (iv)
“adjustment with growth” programmes: despite some successes, “[a]djustment lending did not
create the right incentives for either the lenders or the recipients” (Easterly, 2002, p. 103);
“[t]here was too little adjustment, too little growth and too little scrutiny of the results.” (Easterly
2002, p. 115); and (v) debt forgiveness: “…two decades of debt relief failed to prevent
negative growth in [most] HIPCs” (Easterly, 2002, p. 129); “Debt relief is futile for countries
with unchanged government behaviour…to avoid the incentive to borrow more, the debt relief
programme has to attempt to establish a credible policy that debt relief will never again be
offered…” (Easterly, 2002, pp. 136–137).
He suggests that aid policies are, in part, accountable for this failure.
“As countries’ incomes rise because of their favourable policies for economic growth, aid
should increase in matching fashion. This is the opposite of what happens in actuality…giving
a negative incentive against getting richer” (Easterly, 2002, p. 119).
Easterly’s core contribution is his emphasis on the importance of incentives! Governments can
frustrate growth: Inflation, high taxes, supply-side controls and regulations inhibiting trade and
investment restrictions all inhibit citizens’ ability to better themselves. Political regulation of the
economy promotes privilege and corruption. Politically-connected people become wealthier
and society becomes poorer.
• Effective institutions must promote market-based incentives to foster savings, honesty,
trust, industry, creativity and responsibility.
• Education is optimized when students see future income possibilities from the knowledge
and skills they acquire.
• The acquisition, generation and dissemination of knowledge enables increasing returns to
capital invested, as technological adoption translates into higher productivity, enabling
sustained growth.
Drawing on Schumpeter’s concept of creative destruction, he also emphasizes the importance
of innovation.
Replacing existing means with new ones is necessary to achieve rising standards of living,
although some will always be negatively affected in the short run, by changes in the
competitive landscape.
Growth flows directly from the adoption of new technologies and the postponement of
consumption which is needed to introduce them.
6
More robustly, Glaeser et al. (Edward L. Glaeser, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silane,
and Andrei Shleifer, Do institutions cause growth? NBER working paper no. 10568, June,
2004) conclude that “economic growth and human capital accumulation cause institutional
improvement, rather than the other way around.” “[I]nstitutions have only a second order effect
on economic performance. The first order effect comes from human and social capital, which
shape both institutional and productive capacities of a society.”
They note that while countries with high human capital in 1960 grew faster than countries with
low human capital, constitutional rules, judicial independence and proportional representation
do not predict the growth of income per capita, and argue that the economic success of East
Asia “has been a consequence of good-for-growth dictators, not of institutions constraining
them.”
The important insight emerges, however, from their two key conclusions: “…countries that
emerge from poverty accumulate human and physical capital under dictatorships, and then,
once they become richer, are increasingly likely to improve their institutions.”
Economic growth and social development cannot be sustained in an integrated, global
knowledge-based economy in the absence of the freedoms that are prized by educated,
skilled humans. If they are unable to express themselves at home, they vote with their feet.
Erich Gundlach
Kiel Institute for the World Economy
Acknowledging the immense diversity of countries with regard to historical, economic, political,
and cultural factors, it is almost self-evident that there will be no one-size-fits-all solution for
policy makers that would help promote peace and prosperity on a global scale, “anytime and
anywhere, under any circumstances” (Jeanne Kirkpatrick).
But despite ongoing controversial academic debates, it is probably fair to say that a consensus
view would emphasize that the degree of democracy in a particular country is shaped by its
institutional framework and by its economic performance. This is not to deny that there may
also be reverse causality, but the first order effects appear to run from institutions and
economic performance to democracy. So these are the two principal avenues that policy
makers could use to increase the degree of democracy.
If history is any guide, the evidence appears to suggests that counties which have achieved
the status of a full democracy are (very) unlikely to revert to an autocratic regime. But
according to the same logic, democracy is unlikely to last in poor countries which have not
developed a set of deep institutions that are conducive for sustained growth. The focus of
international policy makers should be on middle income countries, where the degree of
democracy appears to be rather volatile, sometimes even in the presence of strong economic
growth.
Placing effective constraints on executive authority appears to be the number one strategy if
democracy is to consolidate and prosper in fragile middle income countries. This is not to deny
that there are many open questions on the details and on the implementation of such a
strategy, which may require country-specific answers. It would be essential to identify which
parts of an institutional framework would matter most for a given country, conditional on the
historical, political, cultural, and economic context.
A successful strategy will also have to redistribute political and economic power. This problem
is acute in deeply divided societies, where ethnic fragmentation and the extraction of resource
rents may dominate the political and economic decision making of the elites. Strong economic
growth is probably necessary but not sufficient to overcome the institutional status quo, which
may be the very reason for the absence of a sustainable path of development in the first place.
7
While it is fairly obvious that the prevailing type of institutions matter for the success of
democracy, the type of economic growth may also matter. Pro-poor growth is much more likely
to gather support for democracy compared to a growth regime where most benefits go into a
few pockets only. This channel should be kept in mind by international policy makers when
deciding on foreign aid. However, it would be important to recognize that (domestic) politics
will greatly matter for economic outcomes, so both areas should never be considered in
isolation.
Support for democracy by the international community will also depend on the geopolitical
situation. Democracies that developed after the demise of the Former Soviet Union apparently
had a much better start than democracies that emerged during the Cold War. It is an open
question for debate whether the ongoing financial crisis will rebalance contemporary world
politics towards a model of authoritarian capitalism, or whether economic forces will finally
generate a change towards democracy in fast-growing authoritarian societies.
Seth D. Kaplan
Managing Partner, Alpha International Consulting
The dichotomy between democracy and development is a false one. Far from being discrete
phenomena, the democratization of a society and the development of an economy are in fact
two facets of a much larger transformative process: modernization.
By “modernization” I mean a process that transfigures not just the political and economic life of
a country but also familial, commercial, technological, intellectual, and cultural values,
behaviors, and relationships. Modernization is a long – multigenerational – process that rarely
occurs in an orderly, bloodless fashion. Progress on different fronts (economic, political,
cultural, and so forth) is uneven, bedeviled by setbacks, and difficult to measure. Yet, once
started, progress is hard to arrest if a country possesses the requisite degree of cohesion
among its elite and within its broader population. Such cohesion, however, is often lacking in
developing countries today – a deficiency that explains much of their stagnation and instability.
8
Outside Northeast Asia, the countries that have achieved the most progress have likewise
been able to depend on the social cohesion and social capital of people with common
backgrounds. The most successful countries in Africa, the Middle East, and Latin America –
Botswana, Somaliland, Turkey, Kuwait, Chile, and Costa Rica – are all built upon common
identities and institutions accepted by the great majority of their citizens. In contrast, countries
with the most socially divisive populations – such as Nigeria, the Democratic Republic of the
Congo (DRC), Somalia, Syria, Lebanon, Bolivia, and Guatemala – are much more likely to
have corrupt officials, illegitimate states, and struggling economies with great income
inequities. These latter states have made little progress toward building the kind of institutions
that foster democratization and development.
Once a consensus on institutions and a shared mission has been forged, economics begins to
play the dominant role in the modernization process, with businesses leading a process of
market-driven change that eventually reaches every aspect of a country’s life. This process
usually occurs slowly, with change seeping through a society gradually, often fueled by the
demands of expanding companies and new taxpayers. Competition plays an important – and
underappreciated – role here. When people try to meet customer needs and raise productivity,
they change their outlooks on how to manage time, assess information, and judge their
leaders. Growth feeds rising incomes and expectations, which in turn generate increasing
demands on private firms and public service providers. Where a government must depend on
taxes from local businesses and citizens, it, in turn, becomes more accountable and
responsive to a population’s needs. The cycle feeds upon itself: progress generating
confidence, profits yielding more investment, rising expectations forcing reform upon one
sector after another. As Adam Smith wrote in The Wealth of Nations, “commerce and
manufacturers gradually introduced order and good government and, with them, the liberty
and security of individuals among the inhabitants of the country who had before lived . . . in a
state of servile dependency upon their superiors.” The more compact the entity or region, the
faster the transformation; in larger populations, such as in China and India, the ripples of
development and democratization naturally take longer to spread.
9
In states such as Syria containing combustible mixes of identity groups living side by side,
formal bodies should be designed to institutionalize cross-group cooperation and to minimize
the potential for ethnic, religious, tribal, or clan divisions sparking verbal or violent conflict that
undermines the state. Instead of introducing the kinds of sweeping political and economic
changes that many in the West claim to be the keys to improving the wellbeing of populations,
divided countries need to create a secure and unified environment before introducing
significant change. Iraq shows what can happen when cross-group trust completely breaks
down; Bolivia, Pakistan, Azerbaijan, and Lebanon also stand as cautionary tales.
10
services, and may even play a major role in judicial, police, real estate, and corporate regulation
and oversight.
Given that many developing countries are riven by identity, cultural, and linguistic differences,
and that their different parts are weakly connected because of poor infrastructure, dis-
advantageous political geographies, and feeble administrative systems, locally driven models
of government are more likely to succeed than top-down models. A locally based model would
emphasize the construction of a series of competent city-based provincial bureaucracies built
around relatively cohesive populations and based upon locally accepted institutions rather
than trying to build a robust national government, especially in large countries such as the
DRC and Sudan.
Establishing various forms of iterative accountability loops and decentralized democratic
bodies such as oversight committees, deliberative forms of public participation, and traditional
forms of consultation, can institutionalize processes whereby the state is tied more closely to
society, thereby making it more legitimate, more accountable, more reflective of people’s
needs, and more effective in the delivery of public services. Focusing on the iterative
relationship on multiple fronts will strengthen civil society and the state-society relationship,
making both democratization and development more likely.
11