Garch X
Garch X
TAE-HWY LEE*
Department of Economics, Louisiana State University,
Baton Rouge LA 70803, USA
*I would like to thank Richard Baillie for providing the data used in this paper, two anonymous
referees, Ji-Chai Lin, Doug McMillin, Ted Palivos and Hector Zapata for valuable comments, and LSU
College of Business Administration for financial support.
I. The model
Much empirical research on the risk premium in forward foreign exchange relies
on intertemporal asset pricing models such as that of Lucas (1978). An important
relationship in an international environment that can be derived from there is
the conditional pricing relation for a forward premium: &Q,+&z,+~ =O, where
E, is the conditional expectation given an information available at time t,
Q t+k=(U’(Ct+k)/U’(Ct))(Pt/P,+k) is th e marginal rate of substitution between
dates t and t + k, U’(C,) is the marginal utility of real per capita consumption C,,
P, is a price index in the domestic economy at time t, z~+~=(S/+~-F/,~) is the
forward premium, Sj is the spot exchange rate between the domestic currency
j at time t, F:,k is the forward exchange rate which is the domestic currency price
of a unit of currency j established at t for payment at t + k. Then we have
&Q, + k&Z, + k + p,(Q, + k, 2, + k) a,@r + k) C’,h + k) = 0, where PC is the conditional
correlation and or is the conditional standard deviation. The premium on forward
foreign exchange is seen to be related to the conditional second moments.’
Although asset pricing theories relates first moments to second moments, most
empirical studies (e.g. Giovannini and Jorion, 1989; Kaminsky and Peruga, 1990;
McCurdy and Morgan, 1991; Attanasio, 1991) have focused on a specification
in which first moments are explained by second moments, especially using
GARCH in mean (GARCH-M) model of Engle et al. (1987). Exceptions are
Cumby and Obstfeld (1984) and Hodrick (1989), who consider the converse. While
the GARCH-M specification is useful to explain excess return in terms of
conditional second moments, examining the converse is also interesting due to
the reason discussed before especially when the system is cointegrated. The
purpose of the paper is to examine this converse specification using a multivariate
GARCH specification in vector error correction models. Error correction terms
TAE-HWYLEE 311
often turn out to be the most important terms for conditional means, especially
in the long horizons. Since most finance theory links conditional means to
conditional second moments, it is naturally interesting to see if the most important
variables for conditional means do in fact affect conditional variances. This allows
us to examine the potential relationship between disequilibrium and uncertainty
in the cointegrated system.
Now we turn to our econometric model. Consider a 2 x 1 vector of cointegrated
series X,. They may be considered to be generated by the following ECM
(2) H,=C’C-~A’E,_~E~_~A+B’H~_~B+D’DZ:_,,
where A, B, C and D are 2 x 2 matrices, C is an upper triangular matrix with cl,
c:! in its diagonal and c3 off the diagonal, and D has the same form as C with
corresponding elements dl, d2 and d3. The model will be referred to as ‘GARCH-X’.
The estimates of di may quantify the extent that this model explains the
relationship between disequilibrium and conditional volatility not explained by
GARCH(l, 1). This parameterization guarantees H, to be positive definite and it
allows the conditional covariances to change signs over time.2 In the empirical
study in the next section we suppose that A and B are diagonal matrices with
al, a2 and bi, b2 in the diagonals, respectively.
Dollars for one unit of foreign currency. The notation s, and ft is used for the
logarithms of the spot and forward series, respectively, so that X,=(s,f$.
Baillie and Bollerslev (1989a) present the results that the unit root hypothesis
cannot be rejected for all the series. They also report the results of the cointegration
tests of Phillips (1987) between s, + 22and ft, which are found strongly cointegrated.
However, if X, =(s t+22 ft)‘, the ECM (1) includes variables not available at time
t. As we are interested in prediction using the conditional expectations given
information at time t, we instead use X, =(st ft)’ so that the right-hand side of
equation (1) should not include the variables unknown at time t. s, and ft are
found strongly cointegrated in all currencies at less than one per cent level. We
use z, =ft -s,, which is found stationary. To save space the estimated statistics
are not reported.
The lag lengths (p) in ECM (l), chosen by the use of the Schwarz information
criterion (SIC), are 4 (BP), 4 (DM), 5 (JY), 5 (CD), 0 (FF), 0 (IL) and 4 (SF).
In Table 1, the asymptotic probability values for various specification tests for
the ECM (1) estimated by least squares assuming conditional homoscedasticity
are presented. These tests are: (a) the Ljung-Box test and the McLeod-Li (1983)
test for up to the twentieth order serial correlation in the residuals and in the
squared residuals; (b) Wooldridge’s (1990) robust regression based LM test for
autocorrelations (AR);(c) the LM test for ARCH; (d) White’s (1989) neural network
test for neglected non-linearity in conditional mean; and (e) the LM test for
GARCH-X. Using the lag lengths (p) in ECM (1) chosen by the SIC, the residuals
are not serially correlated, while the McLeod-Li statistics and the LM test
statistics for ARCH are very significant.
We estimate the model with formulations of the conditional mean E(AX, I%- ,)
as in (1) and the conditional variance H,_=E(& ( &__ 1) as in (2). Let 8 be the
vector of all the parameters in the conditional mean and conditional variance.
The parameter estimates are obtained by maximizing the quasi (normal) log-
likelihood function over 8 using scoring methods with only first numerical
derivatives being used (ci la Bollerslev and Wooldridge, 1992). At the maximizing
value of 8 (the QMLE), the asymptotic robust standard errors are obtained (d la
White, 1982; White and Domowitz, 1984; Weiss, 1986; Bollerslev and Wooldridge,
1992). In Table 2 the estimated parameters of the conditional variances are
reported for five currencies. To save space the results for the conditional means
are not reported. The asymptotic robust standard errors are in parentheses. BP
and JY are not included as we cannot find a step of increasing likelihood from
many different initial values of 8. The estimates of D are generally significant.
Nelson (1990) and Bougerol and Picard (1992) establish conditions for the
stationarity and ergodicity of the (integrated) GARCH(l, 1) process. Bollerslev
and Wooldridge (1992) provide regularity conditions under which the QMLE
will be consistent and asymptotically normal, some of which are verified by
Lumsdaine (1991). She also proves that the QMLE is consistent and asymptotically
normal without assuming a finite fourth moment of errors (which is assumed in
Weiss, 1986). Lee and Hansen (1992) show that these may hold when the
GARCH(l, 1) process is integrated or even when it is mildly explosive provided
that the conditional fourth moment of standardized error is bounded (which is a
fairly weak condition).
Based on the asymptotic normality of the QMLE we test the GARCH-X using
Lagrange multiplier (LM) test, Wald tests, and likelihood ratio (LR) tests.3 Our
TABLE 1. Specification tests for the ECM (1) estimated by OLS.
DM CD FF IL SF
Ljung-Box(20) 0.660 0.823 0.108 0.110 0.242 0.109 0.091 0.186 0.351 0.342
McLeod-Li(20) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.085 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
Neural(3) 0.139 0.321 0.020 0.273 0.080 0.007 0.483 0.171 0.290 0.341
AR(l) 0.992 0.677 0.464 0.280 0.037 0.040 0.075 0.053 0.848 0.530 _1
AR(2) 0.953 0.970 0.504 0.572 0.999 0.987 0.993 0.865 0.955 0.991 $
AR(5) 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.999 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.889 0.874 2
ARCH( 1) 0.003 0.003 0.000 0.001 0.161 0.026 0.000 0.000 0.09 1 0.163 ;
ARCH( 5) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 w
ARCH( 10) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.013 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
ARCH[O]-X 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.053 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
ARCHLI J-X 0.025 0.027 0.001 0.003 0.143 0.017 0.239 0.929 0.013 0.013
ARCH[S]-X 0.128 0.133 0.016 0.028 0.160 0.057 0.315 0.852 0.088 0.090
ARCH[lO]-X 0.106 0.106 0.049 0.071 0.159 0.077 0.379 0.947 0.101 0.108
GARCH[l,l]-X 0.038 0.005 0.004 0.552 0.985 0.027 0.020 0.163 0.003 0.012
Nofe: The number in parentheses is the degree of freedom. The number in square brackets is the order of GARCH fitted under the null hypothesis to test for GARCH-X.
All the values are asymptotic p-values. For the neural network test we use 10 phantom hidden units, 3 principal components of them, and 5 draws of the test in
computing the Hochberg Bonferroni based (see Lee et al., 1993). We do not report results for BP and JY as we could not find a step of increasing likelihood for
the ECM model with GARCH-X specification from many different initial values of f3.
380 Spread and volatility in spot and forward exchange rates
DM CD FF IL SF
Cl 0.003 (3e-4) 5e-4 (5e-5) 0.003 (4e-4) 0.005 (2e-4) 0.001 (6e-4)
c2 9e-5 (6e-5) 4e-5 (le-5) < le-5 (0.7 15) 6e-4 (le-4) 6e-5 (8e-5)
c3 0.003 (3e-4) 5e-4 (5e-5) 0.003 (4e-4) 0.005 (2e-4) 0.001 (6e-4)
a, 0.627 (0.075) 0.441 (0.016) 0.516 (0.039) 0.409 (0.029) 0.483 (0.053)
a2 0.607 (0.072) 0.447 (0.017) 0.547 (0.044) 0.424 (0.028) 0.473 (0.052)
b, 0.758 (0.013) 0.870 (0.004) 0.782 (0.017) 0.635 (0.015) 0.880 (0.011)
bz 0.760 (0.011) 0.870 (0.005) 0.767 (0.019) 0.602 (0.025) 0.882 (0.012)
dl 0.444 (0.077) 0.312 (0.039) 0.206 (0.096) 0.076 (0.067) 0.195 (0.079)
d2 0.030 (0.009) 0.023 (0.005) 0.107 (0.036) 0.092 (0.016) 0.018 (0.005)
d3 0.450 (0.069) 0.301 (0.040) 0.136 (0.099) 0.076 (0.080) 0.202 (0.076)
Nope: Asymptoticrobust standard errors are in parentheses. For BP and JY we could not find a step of
increasing likelihood using many different parameter values.
Note: * denotes the minimum of AIC or SIC. Model 1 is the ECM estimated by least squares assuming
the conditional homoscedasticity; Model 2 is the ECM with GARCH specification; and Model 3
is the ECM with GARCH-X specification. Model 2 and Model 3 are estimated by maximizing the
normal likelihood function (QMLE) using the method of scoring. The number of parameters in
Model 1 is 4(p+ l)+ 3 where p is the number of lags in ECM (1). Model 2 has four more parameters
than Model 1 and Model 3 has three more parameters than Model 2. For BP and JY we could
not find a step ofincreasinglikelihood for Model 3 from many different initial values ofparameters.
more volatile and uncertainty increases. If $_I has additional predictive power
for the changing variances of the spot and forward exchange rate changes, this
may be exploited to obtain more precise time varying confidence intervals for
point forecasts of exchange rate changes.
Notes
1. See Hansen and Hodrick (1983) or Mark (1985) for more details. They also derive more
explicit relationship between the first and second conditional moments under additional
assumptions on the joint distribution of Q and z and consumer preferences.
2. In order to allow z:_ 1 to have negative coefficients in (2) we also used a symmetric matrix
G instead of D’D.As the diagonal elements of G turn out to be positive for our data, we
use D’D which guarantees If, to be positive definite. The off-diagonal element of D’D may
be negative.
3. It may be noted that our LM and LR tests are not robust to departures from normality
or information equality while our Wald tests are. Robust LM tests are available in literature
(Wooldridge, 1990; Bollerslev and Wooldridge, 1992), which we do not pursue here. LR
tests do not follow an asymptotic chi-square distribution in the presence of ARCH (White,
1984, p. 76).
References
ATTANASIO,ORAZIO P., ‘Risk, Time Varying Second Moments and Market Efficiency,’ Review
of Economic Studies, May 1991,58: 479-494.
BABA,YOSHIHISA,ROBERTF. ENGLE, DENNIS F. KRAFT, AND KENNETH F. KRONER, ‘Multivariate
Simultaneous Generalized ARCH,’ UCSD Working Paper, 1991.
BAILLIE,RICHARDT., AND TIM BOLLERSLEV, ‘Common Stochastic Trends in a System of Exchange
Rates,’ The Journal of Finance, March 1984, 44: 167-181 (1989a).
BAILLIE,RICHARDT., AND TIM BOLLERSLEV, ‘The Message in Daily Exchange Rates: A Conditional
Variance Tale,‘Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, July 1989,7: 297-305 (1989b).
BOLLERSLEV,TIM, ‘Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity,’ Journal of
Econometrics, April 1986, 31: 307-327.
BOLLERSLEV,TIM, AND JEFFREYM. WOOLDRIDGE‘Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimation and
Inference in Dynamic Models with Time Varying Covariances.’ Econometric Reviews,
1992, ll(2): 143-172.
TAE-HWY LEE 383