Nonlinearities in Economics: An Interdisciplinary Approach To Economic Dynamics, Growth and Cycles 1st Edition Giuseppe Orlando (Editor)
Nonlinearities in Economics: An Interdisciplinary Approach To Economic Dynamics, Growth and Cycles 1st Edition Giuseppe Orlando (Editor)
Nonlinearities in Economics: An Interdisciplinary Approach To Economic Dynamics, Growth and Cycles 1st Edition Giuseppe Orlando (Editor)
https://ebookmeta.com/product/cancer-treatment-an-
interdisciplinary-approach-an-interdisciplinary-approach-
jan-1-2024_3031439821_springer-1st-edition-nima-rezaei/
https://ebookmeta.com/product/an-introduction-to-economic-
dynamics-modelling-analysis-and-simulation-1st-edition-srinivas-
raghavendra/
https://ebookmeta.com/product/principles-of-environmental-
economics-and-sustainability-an-integrated-economic-and-
ecological-approach-4th-edition-ahmed-hussen/
https://ebookmeta.com/product/modelling-trends-and-cycles-in-
economic-time-series-2nd-edition-terence-c-mills/
Science Technology and Modernity An Interdisciplinary
Approach 1st Edition Kavita S Jerath
https://ebookmeta.com/product/science-technology-and-modernity-
an-interdisciplinary-approach-1st-edition-kavita-s-jerath/
https://ebookmeta.com/product/science-technology-and-modernity-
an-interdisciplinary-approach-1st-edition-kavita-s-jerath-2/
https://ebookmeta.com/product/an-impulse-and-earthquake-energy-
balance-approach-in-nonlinear-structural-dynamics-1st-edition-
takewaki/
https://ebookmeta.com/product/cultures-of-stone-an-
interdisciplinary-approach-to-the-materiality-of-stone-1st-
edition-gabriel-cooney/
https://ebookmeta.com/product/network-algorithmics-an-
interdisciplinary-approach-to-designing-fast-networked-
devices-2nd-edition-george-varghese/
Dynamic Modeling and Econometrics in
Economics and Finance 29
Giuseppe Orlando
Alexander N. Pisarchik
Ruedi Stoop Editors
Nonlinearities
in Economics
An Interdisciplinary Approach
to Economic Dynamics, Growth and
Cycles
Dynamic Modeling and Econometrics
in Economics and Finance
Volume 29
Series Editors
Stefan Mittnik, Department of Statistics, Ludwig Maximilian University of Munich,
München, Germany
Willi Semmler, New School for Social Research, New York, NY, USA and Bielefeld
University, Germany
In recent years there has been a rapidly growing interest in the study of dynamic
nonlinear phenomena in economic and financial theory, while at the same time
econometricians and statisticians have been developing methods for modeling such
phenomena. Despite the common focus of theorists and econometricians, both lines
of research have had their own publication outlets. The new book series is designed
to further the understanding of dynamic phenomena in economics and finance
by bridging the gap between dynamic theory and empirics and to provide cross-
fertilization between the two strands. The series will place particular focus on
monographs, surveys, edited volumes, conference proceedings and handbooks on:
• Nonlinear dynamic phenomena in economics and finance, including equilibrium,
disequilibrium, optimizing and adaptive evolutionary points of view; nonlin-
ear and complex dynamics in microeconomics, finance, macroeconomics and
applied fields of economics.
• Econometric and statistical methods for analysis of nonlinear processes in
economics and finance, including computational methods, numerical tools and
software to study nonlinear dependence, asymmetries, persistence of fluctua-
tions, multiple equilibria, chaotic and bifurcation phenomena.
• Applications linking theory and empirical analysis in areas such as macrody-
namics, microdynamics, asset pricing, financial analysis and portfolio analysis,
international economics, resource dynamics and environment, industrial orga-
nization and dynamics of technical change, labor economics, demographics,
population dynamics, and game theory.
The target audience of this series includes researchers at universities and research
and policy institutions, students at graduate institutions, and practitioners in eco-
nomics, finance and international economics in private or government institutions.
Nonlinearities in Economics
An Interdisciplinary Approach to Economic
Dynamics, Growth and Cycles
Editors
Giuseppe Orlando Alexander N. Pisarchik
Department of Economics & Finance Technical University of Madrid
University of Bari Aldo Moro Center for Biomedical Technology, Campus
Bari, Italy Montegancedo
Pozuelo de Alarcón, Madrid, Spain
Ruedi Stoop
Institute of Neuroinformatics
Swiss Federal Institute of Technology
Zürich, Switzerland
© The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland
AG 2021
This work is subject to copyright. All rights are solely and exclusively licensed by the Publisher, whether
the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse
of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and
transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar
or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication
does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant
protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
The publisher, the authors, and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book
are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or
the editors give a warranty, expressed or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any
errors or omissions that may have been made. The publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional
claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
This Springer imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature Switzerland AG.
The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland
Reviews
Finally, a volume is coming out in our Springer Series Dynamic Modeling and
Econometrics in Economics and Finance that will be of great service to the
community of nonlinear modelers in economics—with very comprehensive surveys
on history, theory, and econometrics of complex systems.
Arnhold Professor of International Cooperation and Development at The New
School for Social Research
v
Preface
Dear Reader,
vii
viii Preface
Without him, many exciting developments and events (not least the mentioned
NDES conferences) would not have been achieved.
We hope that you will find the text inspiring and useful. Let even the parts that
you might like less sharpen your view and become beneficial to you in this way as
well.
This book was a long trip with great companions that strengthened both academic
and human ties between authors and co-editors. To some extent, this was at the
expense of our families, and of friends not engaged in this endeavour.
Giuseppe Orlando, in particular, would like to ask the indulgence of his children
Niccolò Libero and Gaia Carmela Francesca who have many good reasons to
complain about their father during this period. He would also like to express his
sincere gratitude and appreciation to Carlo Lucheroni at the University of Camerino
for numerous helpful comments, to Nicola Basile at the University of Bari for
valuable suggestions provided, to Luigi Fortuna and his colleagues at the University
of Catania for having organized the NDES2019—Nonlinear Dynamics of Electronic
Systems Conference and to Edward Bace at the Middlesex University for his help in
polishing some of the chapters. Sincere special thanks go to Michele Mininni at the
University of Bari who has been a firm point of reference from G.O.’s early study
days on. Last but not least, he expresses his profound obligation to his parents, as
without support and love by the parents, not much can be accomplished during one’s
lifetime.
ix
Contents
1 Introduction .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
Giuseppe Orlando, Alexander N. Pisarchik, and Ruedi Stoop
xi
xii Contents
Appendix A .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 337
Back Cover . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 361
Contributors
xiii
xiv Contributors
G. Orlando ()
University of Bari, Department of Economics and Finance, Bari, Italy
University of Camerino, School of Sciences and Technology, Camerino, Italy
e-mail: [email protected]; [email protected]
A. N. Pisarchik
Technical University of Madrid, Center for Biomedical Technology, Campus Montegancedo,
Pozuelo de Alarcón, Madrid, Spain
e-mail: [email protected]
R. Stoop
ETHZ and University of Zurich, Institute of Neuroinformatics, Zurich, Switzerland
Technical University of Xi’an, Xi’an, Shaanxi, China
e-mail: [email protected]; [email protected]
in a general equilibrium theory (see, for example, Debreu [6], Arrow and Hann [1],
etc.). Only at the beginning of the twentieth century, to describe market dynamics
in economic models of business cycles, economists did start using difference and
differential equations. Ragnar Frisch [10], for example, suggested to study the
evolution of economics in time from a dynamical systems viewpoint. The future
state of such a system depends only on its past and present. Such a slush in economic
theory is largely due to outstanding discoveries of mathematicians in the field of
nonlinear dynamics made at the end of the nineteenth century. The most prominent
achievements were the development of stability theory by Aleksandr Lyapunov and
the solution of three-body problem by Henri Poincaré [32].
Three centuries later, Birkhoff showed that Poincaré’s geometric intuition can
be cast within a mathematically precise description. This could have been the early
official birthday of chaos theory, if aspects of irregular, unpredictable dynamics were
recognised as relevant for real-world experimental systems as well. If appropriately
perceived, Van der Pol, who presented almost simultaneously with Birkhoff his
electronic heart pacemaker circuit (showing, in addition to period “heartbeats” also
chaotic behaviour), would have provided this experimental connection.
Originally, the term “chaos” was generally used for dynamical processes that
lacked aspects of order that would render their dynamics easily seizable in the
sense of predictability. As a consequence, the main understanding was, for a long
time, that we would never be able to arrive at a thorough understanding of such
phenomena. A chaotic system has specific properties that differ from a stochastic or
noisy system. First of all, a chaotic motion is deterministic (in the sense that every
event is physically determined by an unbroken chain of earlier events) and crucially
depends on initial conditions.
The reason why this more precise notion of chaos took so long to penetrate
into the standard science was twofold. First, apart from the mentioned more global
approaches, the preferred mathematical analysis methods were linearisation around
fixed points of the motion, from which the asymptotic dynamics were extracted.
This local approach, however, is sufficient only for linear systems. Nonlinearity
provides fixed-objects that are not present in linear systems, such as limit cycles,
that are not captured by linearization methods.
Edward Norton Lorenz was among the first to discover in the 1960s a so-called
strange attractor in a three-dimensional continuous-time dynamical system, when
carrying out numerical experiments on convection flows [15]. Indeed, the advent of
direct numerical simulations of differential equations on computers made it finally
possible to access and to explore the chaos phenomenology, to anyone for whom
computational power was available. Initially, Lorenz was able to publish his work
in marginal journals only. Until well into the late 1970s, several physics scholars
in the western world, in particular, Mitchell Feigenbaum [2, 7] established the
breakthrough of the new view on dynamics. He drew the attention of the scientific
society to the ubiquitousness of this phenomenon, and offered new pathways of
how to characterise and to predict such phenomena. It would, however, be unfair to
withhold the great contributions to this area by scientists of the former Soviet Union,
such as Andrey Kolmogorov, Vladimir Arnold, Aleksandr Andronov, Oleksandr
1 Introduction 3
Sharkovsky, and others. In fact, Feigenbaum’s findings aroused interest and finally
got accepted only after a presentation of Feigenbaum given to Soviet scientists.
Through the research conducted by many scholars not following the scientific
mainstream, and their collaborative efforts, it was finally shown that, seen on a
higher level, chaotic dynamics is not only ordered [9] and therefore intelligible but
also that it is deterministic and controllable [30, 33, 34].
It took some time to work out the fundamentals of chaotic dynamics and
then, the analysis proceeded towards the description and the exploitation of chaos
for applications. A field that seems particularly attractive and suitable for this is
economics that, from its statistical description, can be expected to be organised
along the fundamental principles of symmetry breaking and self-organisation as
well, and manifests a behaviour that could, with an appropriate permitting analysis,
be associated with chaotic processes. Economic dynamics is obviously nonlinear. In
particular, it is characterised by cyclical fluctuations called “business cycles”. Burns
and Mitchell [4] define business cycles as a type of fluctuation which “consists of
expansions occurring at about the same time in many economic activities, followed
by similarly general recessions, contractions, and revivals which merge into the
expansion phase of the next cycle” (where a recession is a negative variation of
the economy for two consecutive quarters cf. Fig. 1.1).
Fig. 1.1 Changes in US real disposable personal income (i.e., the personal income net of income
taxes) (blue—DSPIC96) and Real personal consumption expenditures (red—PCECC96) 1959
(Q1)—2014 (Q2). Source: Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), St. Louis Fed. Greyed vertical
areas correspond to periods of economic recessions (i.e., economic contraction) as reckoned by
FRED (Table A.1)
4 G. Orlando et al.
The emergence of these very robust cycles is one strong motivation for our pro-
posed change of paradigm. In contrast to the stochastic models focusing exclusively
on external and random shocks (like the so-called real business cycle (RBC)), we
propose to—alternatively or synergetically—consider structural system character-
istics that are endogenous (in contrast to the exogenous influences considered in
the traditional approaches). In that regard, by comparing an Ornstein–Uhlenbeck
stochastic process [22, 23] with a Kaldor–Kalecki [17, 18] deterministic chaotic
model, Orlando et al. [28] exhibited that nonlinearity in the latter model permits to
represent reality at least as well as the stochastic model. Furthermore, the Kaldor–
Kalecki model was able to reproduce an extreme event (black swan [28, 35]). A
further confirmation can be found in Orlando et al. [29], where it was shown that real
and simulated business cycle dynamics have similar characteristics, thus validating
the chaotic model as a suitable tool to simulate reality. Notwithstanding economic
dynamics is not purely deterministic, a strong stochastic component always exists
and should be included in economic models. Therefore, statistical analysis of
economic data is important to reveal the presence of determinism in the behaviour
and to forecast future evolution. However, the effect of random fluctuations is
unpredictable although probabilistic analysis in financial modelling can provide
us with some information about possible scenarios. For example, increasing noise
could indicate an impending financial crisis, because the dynamical systems are
known [8, 14] to amplify random fluctuations when approaching a critical point.
Another promising application of nonlinear analysis methods to economy would
be the possibility to predict sudden jumps or drops in stock prices that occur
for no apparent reason. By considering these jumps as extreme events, the same
approach as for forecasting sudden weather changes [3], giant laser pulses [31], or
forthcoming epileptic seizures [11] could be used. Such a research (not included in
this book) is still under development.
The whole endeavour taken by this work embraces (i) finding suitable models of
business cycles, (ii) searching for indicators for structural changes in economic
signals, and (iii) comparing time series generated by the studied models versus
real-world time series [27–29]. Our book consists of four parts. Focusing on
a particularly attractive class of economic nonlinear models related to growth
and business cycles, we explore chaotic behaviour of these models by means
of numerical analysis, recurrence quantification, and statistical techniques, and
demonstrate that the results are consistent with those obtained by applying the
same techniques to time series of real-world macroeconomic data. This implies
that with the help of these methods we are able to (i) identify common features
between data and model whenever they exist, (ii) to discover features that guide
economic dynamics, and (iii) to extract indicators of structural changes in the
signal (e.g., precursors of crashes and more general catastrophes). We emphasise the
1 Introduction 5
explain how this method can be applied to detect spatio-temporal recurrent patterns
underlying different dynamical regimes in economic time series. Such analysis
allows us to reveal the nature of business cycles and corresponding macroeconomic
variables, i.e., whether their character is deterministic or stochastic. Furthermore we
show how RQA provides an indicator of structural changes in chaotic time series
[25, 26].
As a book on economic dynamics, Part III focuses more on economics itself,
providing more specifically economics-related background and literature. While
in economics the phenomenon of chaos may be expected to contribute many
fascinating aspects, to go beyond purely intellectual constructions with limited
real-world explanatory strength, we provide the reader the background information
regarding theories on growth and business cycles. In particular, Chap. 11 focuses on
the ties between real-world economics and nonlinear dynamics. Chapter 12 provides
a sketch of the Keynesian multiplier and of the multiplier-accelerator model by
Hansen and Samuelson, and of the Kaldor model. Chapter 13 explains Domar’s
and the Harrod’s model separately. In contrast to standard economic literature that
glues those models together, in our view Harrod instability (tested in Chap. 18)
has nothing to do with the mathematical notion of the instability characterising the
Domar model. Chapter 14 is about the interpretation of cycles as a struggle between
capitalists and workers. This is introduced by the Phillips curve (which statistically
relates unemployment with the rate of change of nominal wages), followed by the
Lotka–Volterra model which is the basic framework of the Goodwin model. The
latter reinterprets, in economic terms, the dynamics of prey-predator of biological
systems. Chapter 15 explains how control over a system that becomes unstable
or highly noisy can be achieved. The objective is to calm down and optimise the
system’s behaviour. We show that such measures lead to stable cycles in any generic
nonlinear system and that hard-limiter control follows a nongeneric dynamical
system behaviour with a bifurcation cascade to chaos that is fundamentally distinct
from the Feigenbaum case.
Part IV consists of Chaps. 16–20 that are devoted to new perspectives in under-
standing economics. A reality check on the theories discussed in earlier parts by the
means described in Parts I–III is provided. Chapter 16 introduces the experimental
Part of the book, following Goodwin’s opinion that nonlinearities are the origin of
oscillations in economics [12]. We use this approach to study cycles with Kaldor’s
framework, as is detailed in Chap. 12. The model presented is an alternative to the
usual models available in literature [17, 18]. Additional features, such as a full set
of parameters and the ability to embed randomness, open the way to a mixture of
stochastic and deterministic chaos. Chapter 17 describes an indicator that exhibits
structural changes in a signal/time series related to chaos [25]. To achieve that, RQA
and statistical techniques are applied, to both real time series and model-generated
time series [26]. Our aim is to (i) find common properties if and where they do exist,
(ii) discover some hidden features of economic dynamics and (iii) highlight some
1 Introduction 7
indicators of structural changes in the signal (i.e., in our case to look for precursors
of a crash). In Chap. 18 we focus on the Harrod’s model detailed in Chap. 13.
We present a specification of Harrod’s model where chaos is a consequence of
the gaps between actual, warranted and natural rates of growth. For this model,
we prove that real-world economic dynamics can be replicated by a suitable
calibration of the parameters of the model. Moreover, we prove that opening the
economy to foreign trade can lead to reducing cyclical instability, thus confirming
Harrod’s conjecture [19]. Chapter 19 presents an extension of the Goodwin growth-
cycle model that considers the rate of capacity utilisation as a new variable in an
adapted Lotka–Volterra system of differential equations, where capacity utilisation
is proportional to the difference between the output expansion function and capital
accumulation. With this approach, connections between demand, labour market, and
capital accumulation are established in a model that generates a cyclical pattern
amongst the employment rate, the profit share, and capacity utilisation. The model
is then tested against the US economy, using quarterly data from 1970 to 2019
and the Vector Auto-Regression (VAR). The latter is a stochastic process model
widely used in econometrics to capture the linear interdependencies between time
series. The conclusion is that positive profit share innovation affects positively both
the employment rate and the rate of capacity utilisation, suggesting a profit-led
pattern supporting the theoretical model presented (especially to the profit-squeeze
mechanism).
Lastly, Chap. 20 summarises advances in nonlinear model predictive control
(NMPC) through multi-regime cointegrated VAR (MRCIVAR). The study exhibits
the impact of financial stress shocks and monetary policy at macroeconomic level
in different countries. The chapter illustrates the vector error correction model
(VECM), that is commonly used to model macroeconomic time series, because
VECM is able to connect the economic theory around equilibrium and the dynamic
process towards the equilibrium into a set of empirically testable relations. The said
feature has been exploited to study business cycles during different phases by many
(e.g., see Mittnik and Semmler [16], Chen et al. [5] and Hamilton [13]). MRCIVAR
is used to examine the impact of real activities on the financial stress. The outcome
is that financial shocks have asymmetric effects on the short term interest rate,
depending on the regime the economy is in. More precisely, in the rate-cut regime
a financial stress shock will decrease the short term rate while, in the non-rate-cut
regime, the shock will increase the short term rate (even though in some cases the
effects are not statistically significant).
We hope that, with this book we provide some food for thought to a wide
audience and stimulate curiosity in approaching economics unconventionally by
hybridisation with physics, engineering, and economics. We have left out our
research on financial mathematics [20, 21, 23, 24] intentionally, as this matter runs
parallel to the presented material as long as market stability, solvency, and resilience
of financial institutions are concerned.
8 G. Orlando et al.
References
25. Orlando, G., Zimatore, G.: RQA correlations on real business cycles time series. In: Indian
Academy of Sciences Conference Series—Proceedings of the Conference on Perspectives
in Nonlinear Dynamics—2016, vol. 1, pp. 35–41. Springer, Berlin (2017). https://doi.org/10.
29195/iascs.01.01.0009
26. Orlando, G., Zimatore, G.: Recurrence quantification analysis of business cycles. Chaos
Solitons Fractals 110, 82–94 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chaos.2018.02.032
27. Orlando, G., Zimatore, G.: RQA correlations on business cycles: a comparison between real
and simulated data. Adv. Nonlinear Dyn. Electron. Syst. 17, 62–68 (2019). https://doi.org/10.
1142/9789811201523_0012
28. Orlando, G., Zimatore, G.: Business cycle modeling between financial crises and black swans:
Ornstein–Uhlenbeck stochastic process vs Kaldor deterministic chaotic model. Chaos 30(8),
083129 (2020)
29. Orlando, G., Zimatore, G.: Recurrence quantification analysis on a Kaldorian business cycle
model. Nonlinear Dyn. (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11071-020-05511-y
30. Ott, E., Grebogi, C., Yorke, J.A.: Controlling chaos. Phys. Rev. Lett. 64(11), 1196 (1990)
31. Pisarchik, A.N., Jaimes-Reátegui, R., Sevilla-Escoboza, R., Huerta-Cuellar, G., Taki, M.:
Rogue waves in a multistable system. Phys. Rev. Lett. 107(27), 274101 (2011)
32. Poincaré, H.: New Methods of Celestial Mechanics, vol. 13. Springer, Berlin (1992)
33. Romeiras, F.J., Grebogi, C., Ott, E., Dayawansa, W.: Controlling chaotic dynamical systems.
Phys. D: Nonlinear Phenom. 58(1–4), 165–192 (1992)
34. Schuster, H.: Handbook of Chaos Control. Wiley, London (1999)
35. Taleb, N.N.: The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable, vol. 2. Random House
(2007)
Part I
Mathematical Background
Chapter 2
Dynamical Systems
The concept of dynamical system that we will use here is taken from R.E. Kalman
[1] who introduced it in the 1960s while studying the problem of linear filtering and
prediction.
Roughly speaking, a system consists of a set of the so-called states (generally
vectors of real numbers), where the adjective dynamics emphasizes the fact that
these states vary in time according to a suitable dynamical law. This concept
of dynamical system is cast in the following definition.
Definition 2.1 (Dynamical System) A dynamical system is an entity defined by
the following axioms:
1. There exist an ordered set T of times, a set X of states and a function φ from T ×
T × X to X. φ is called a state transition function.
2. For all t, τ ∈ T and for all x ∈ X one has that φ(t, τ, x) represents the state at
time t of a system whose initial state at time τ is x.
3. The function φ satisfies the following properties:
Consistency: φ(τ, τ, x) = x for all τ ∈ T , and for all x ∈ X.
G. Orlando ()
University of Bari, Department of Economics and Finance, Bari, Italy
University of Camerino, School of Sciences and Technology, Camerino, Italy
e-mail: [email protected]; [email protected]
G. Taglialatela
University of Bari, Department of Economics and Finance, Bari, Italy
e-mail: [email protected]
Composition: φ(t3 , t1 , x) = φ t3 , t2 , φ(t2 , t1 , x) , for all x ∈ X and for all
t1 , t2 , t3 ∈ T with t1 < t2 < t3 .
In the following we always consider X = Rn .
Definition 2.2 (Reversibility) If the state transition function φ defined for any
(t, τ ) in T × T , once assigned the initial time τ and the initial state x, the state
of the system is uniquely determined for the future (i.e. for all t > τ ), as well as for
the past (i.e. for t < τ ), the system is said to be reversible.
If the state transition function φ is defined only for t ≥ τ , then the system is said
to be irreversible.
Definition 2.3 (Event, Orbit and Flow) For all t ∈ T , x ∈ X, the pair (t, x) is
called an event. Moreover, for τ and x fixed, the function t ∈ T → φ(t, τ, x) ∈ X
is called a movement of the system. The set of all movements is called a flow. The
image of the movement, i.e. the set
φ(t, τ, x) t ∈ T ,
is called an orbit (or a trajectory) of the system, i.e. the orbit passing through the
state x at time τ .
It is not always possible to find a closed formula for the orbits of dynamical
systems, but it is possible to study the behaviour of the orbits for long time
nonetheless.
Definition 2.4 (Fixed or Equilibrium Point) A state x ∗ ∈ X is called a fixed point
(or an equilibrium point) of the dynamics, if there exist t1 , t2 ∈ T , with t2 > t1 , such
that
x ∗ is said to be a fixed point in an infinite time if there exists t1 > T such that
The fixed point x ∗ is asymptotically stable if it is stable and there exists a δ > 0
such that for all x ∈ X with |x − x ∗ | ≤ δ it holds that
lim φ(t, τ, x) − x ∗ = 0 holds.
t →∞
φ(t, τ, x) =
φ (t − τ, x) (2.1)
ẋ = f (t, x) (2.4)
defines a continuous reversible dynamic system. In fact the time set is T = I , the
state set is X = R and the state transition function φ is the function from I × I × R
to R such that for all t, τ ∈ I , ξ ∈ R one has that
φ(t, τ, ξ ) = x(t) ,
where x(t) is the unique solution of the Cauchy problem (2.3). In this case the
movements are the solutions to Eq. (2.4) and, for any solution x, the corresponding
orbit is on the interval x(t) t ∈ I .
The system is autonomous if, and only if, the function f does not depend
explicitly on t, that is we have
ẋ(t) = f x(t)
The discussion contained in the previous Sect. 2.2.1 for a single equation can be
extended to systems of ordinary differential equations.
In fact, if x = (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) ∈ Rn , let f = f (t, x) be a vector function
from I × Rn to Rn , and let f1 , f2 , . . . , fn be the components of f .
2 Dynamical Systems 17
Obviously, the state of the system at time t will only depend on the initial time τ ,
the initial state x and the restriction of the input function u to the interval of extremes
t and τ . Hence, we have to assume that the state transition function φ satisfies the
following properties.
Consistency: φ(τ, τ, x, u) = x(t) ∀ (τ, x, u(·)) ∈ T × X × Ω.
Composition: φ(t3 , t1 , x, u) = φ (t3 , t2 , φ (t2 , t1 , x, u) , u) for each (x, u) ∈ X ×
Ω, and for each t1 < t2 < t3 .
Causality: If u, v ∈ Ω and u|[τ,t ] = v|[τ,t ] , then φ(t, τ, x, u) = φ(t, τ, x, v).
This framework can be used for theoretical approaches in continuous-time
systems.
+∞
1 j 1 1 1
exp(A) = A = I + A + A2 + A3 + · · · + Aj + · · · .
j! 2 6 j!
j =0
−1
exp(A) = exp(−A) .
• exp(A T ) = exp(A)T .
• det exp(A) = etr(A) , where tr(A) denotes the trace of A.
• If B = P AP −1 , where P is an invertible matrix, then
exp(B) = P exp(A) P −1 .
• If A is diagonal
⎛ ⎞
λ1 0 ... 0
⎜ 0 λ2 0 ⎟
⎜ ⎟
A=⎜. . . ⎟,
⎝.. . . .⎠
.
0 ... 0 λn
2 Dynamical Systems 19
then
⎛ ⎞
e λ1 0 ... 0
⎜ 0 e λ2 0 ⎟
⎜ ⎟
exp(A) = ⎜ . .. . ⎟.
⎝ .. . .. ⎠
0 ... 0 e λn
ẋ = Ax ,
A being a fixed matrix, the solution for the initial point x 0 at t = 0 is given by
x(t) = exp(tA) x 0 .
Indeed, as
+∞ j
t
x(t) = Aj x 0
j!
j =0
we have
+∞ +∞ j
t j −1 t
ẋ(t) = Aj x 0 = Aj +1 x 0
(j − 1)! j!
j =1 j =0
+∞ j
t
=A Aj x 0 = A x(t) .
j!
j =0
We can obtain the behaviour of the solution x(t) by studying the eigenvalues
of the matrix A. Indeed, assume for example that A is diagonalizable and all the
eigenvalues λj , j = 1, . . . , n, have negative real part. We then have
⎛ λ1 t ⎞
e 0 ... 0
⎜ 0 e λ2 t 0 ⎟
⎜ ⎟ −1
x(t) = exp(tA) x 0 = P ⎜ . . . ⎟ P x0 ,
⎝ .. .. .. ⎠
0 ... 0 e λn t
for some invertible matrix P . As eλn t → 0 for t → +∞, we see that the solution
x(t) = 0 is stable.
The Hartman–Grobman Theorem 2.2 given below will elucidate the behaviour
around the fixed points of nonlinear systems by a linearization in a neighbourhood
20 G. Orlando and G. Taglialatela
ẋ = f (x),
a hyperbolic fixed point is a fixed point x ∗ for which all the eigenvalues of the
Jacobian matrix
⎛ ⎞
∂x1 f1 ∂x1 f2 . . . ∂x1 fn
⎜∂x f1 ∂x f2 . . . ∂x fn ⎟
⎜ 2 2 2 ⎟
Df = ⎜ . ⎟
⎝ .. ⎠
∂xn f1 ∂xn f2 . . . ∂xn fn
holds. Thus, the flow of the nonlinear system is homeomorphic to et A (i.e. to the flow
of the linearized system).
A sufficient condition for an equilibrium x a to be stable is given by the following
theorem.
Theorem 2.3 (Lyapunov [8]) Let Ω be an open subset of Rn , and f : Ω → Rn be
a C 1 function. Let x a ∈ Ω be a zero of f .
Consider the dynamical system
ẋ(t) = f x(t) , x ∈ Rn .
The equilibrium x(t) = x a is stable if all the eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix
of f at x a have a negative real part.
We end this section recalling a useful tool to prove the stability of equilibria.
Definition 2.16 (Lyapunov Function) Let f : Rn → Rn , with f (x 0 ) = 0, and
consider the autonomous dynamical system
ẋ(t) = f x(t) ,
1
2
0 0
–1 –2
–3 –2
–1 0 1 2 –4
3
where we have
(a) (b)
Fig. 2.2 Convergence to the limit cycle. On the boundary of D, the vector field points inwards the
set. Therefore, once a trajectory enters in D, it will stay on it forever. (a) A system with a stable
limit cycle in a vector field. (b) Limit cycle in a compact set D [7]
2
−1
0
−2
0 −2
Fig. 2.3 In R3 Poincaré–Bendixson is invalid
∂x f (x, y) + ∂y g(x, y)
In this case, a movement is a sequence {xn }n∈N such that xn+1 = f (xn ) for all
n, whereas an orbit is a set of the form {x0 , x1 , x2 , . . . , xn , . . . } with xn+1 = f (xn )
for all n ∈ N.
In the following we focus on 1-dimensional dynamical systems.
Example 2.1 If d = 1, and f (x) = x 2 , the orbit of f with initial point x0 = 2 is
n
the set {2, 4, 16, 256, . . . } = {22 }n∈N .
Remark 2.4 Note that the dynamical system defined by Eq. (2.9) is autonomous
(cfr. Eq. (2.1)). Moreover it is reversible if and only if the function f is bijective.
Indeed, if f −1 is the inverse of f , we can extend the definition of f ◦n also
to negative n by
g(xn )
xn+1 = xn − . (2.13)
g (xn )
P1
P3
P5
P7
P6
P4
P2
x
x1 x3 x5 x7 x6 x4 x2
Fig. 2.5 Different examples of critical points. From top left clockwise: a centre denoting a stable
but not asymptotically stable point, an asymptotically stable node and an asymptotically stable
spiral both denoted as a sink. Then an unstable spiral and an unstable node, i.e. source. Last figure
shows a saddle node where some orbits converge and some others diverge
after some n∗ . A point is asymptotically stable if it is stable and the orbit approaches
the critical point as n → ∞. If a critical point is not stable, then it is unstable (see
Fig. 2.5). In some instances these critical points could have mixed characteristics
(see Fig. 2.6).
Definition 2.23 (Limit Set) Given x ∈ X, the limit set of x is the set A of points
ω ∈ X for which there is an increasing sequence of natural numbers {nj }j ∈N such
that
and since there exists δ > 0 such that for all x ∈]xa − δ, xa + δ[, one has
f (x) − f (a)
<K.
x − xa
Hence
f (x) − xa < K|x − xa | < Kδ . (2.14)
as xn+1 = f (xn ). Thus it follows by induction that for all x0 ∈ ]xa − δ, xa + δ[ and
for all n ∈ N one has that
|xn − xa < K n |x0 − xa | < K n δ .
g(x)
f (x) = x − , (2.15)
g (x)
and hence
g (x) g(x)g (x) g(x)g (x)
f (x) = 1 −
+
= . (2.16)
g (x) g (x) 2 g (x)2
are also periodic, and by the chain rule, the derivative of f ◦n in those points is the
same and equal to
y y
P0
P2
P4 P3 P1 P2
x x
x0 x2 x4 x3 x1 x0 x1 x2
P1
P0
(a) (b)
Fig. 2.7 Convergence to the attractor. Panel (a) represents f (x) = −x 3 that is a mirror image
of f (x) = x 3 and panel (b) corresponds to the graph of f ◦2 (x) = x 9
32 G. Orlando and G. Taglialatela
f ◦2 (x) for which −1 and +1 are fixed repeller points, and since neither is fixed for
f , then they will be cyclic repellers (see Fig. 2.7b).
We end this section with the n-dimensional version of Theorem 2.7.
Theorem 2.8 Consider the discrete-time dynamical system
x n+1 = f (x n ) ,
f (x a ) = x a ,
In this section we present some definitions that will be used in Sect. 3.1.
or, equivalently, by
2
f (x) 3 f (x)
f (x) =
S
− . (2.21)
f (x) 2 f (x)
2 Dynamical Systems 33
The relevant property of the Schwarz derivative is to preserve the sign with the
composition, in the sense that if f S (x) > 0, then it is also (f ◦n )S (x) > 0 ∀n ∈
N. To prove this statement we first prove a “chain rule” formula for the Schwarz
derivative.
Lemma 2.1 Let f, g be three times derivable, and then
2
(f ◦ g)S (x) = f S g(x) g (x) + g S (x) . (2.22)
Hence,
3
f g(x) g (x) + 3f g(x) g (x)g (x) + f g(x) g (x)
(f ◦ g)S (x) =
f g(x) g (x)
2 2
3 f g(x) g (x) + f g(x) g (x)
−
2 f (x)
⎡ 2 ⎤
f g(x) 3 f g(x) 2
= ⎣ −
⎦ g (x)
f g(x) 2 f g(x)
g (x) 3 g (x) 2
+ −
g (x) 2 g (x)
2
= f S g(x) g (x) + g S (x) .
Then
n !n n
− ai )
i=1 (x Q (x)
Q (x) = = . (2.24)
x − aj x − aj
j =1 j =1
Therefore, by (2.20),
⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞2
n n
d 1 1 1
QS (x) = ⎝ ⎠− ⎝ ⎠
dx x − aj 2 x − aj
j =1 j =1
⎛ ⎞2
n n
1 1⎝ 1 ⎠
=− − < 0.
(x − aj )2 2 x − aj
j =1 j =1
As mentioned before , the Schwarz derivative preserves the sign under composition
that is useful in the following theorem.
Theorem 2.10 (Singer [7]) Let f be a map from a closed interval I ⊆ [0, b] onto
itself; then the dynamical system xn+1 = f (xn ) has at most one periodic orbit in
the interval I if the following conditions are met:
1. f is a function C 3 ;
2. There exists a critical point xc ∈ I such that
⎧
⎪
⎪
⎨f (x) > 0 , for x < xc ,
f (x) = 0 , for x = xc ,
⎪
⎪
⎩f (x) < 0 , for x > x .
c
These trifling contributions, all but one, which Mr. C. has with
unnecessary scrupulosity recorded, slipped out of his mind, as they
well might.’
If the contributions themselves were characteristic, so certainly is
the manner of speaking of them. These men, and the men who were
more or less their associates, believed much in each other. In no
different spirit from Wordsworth’s did Coleridge himself write, in his
introduction to Poems on Various Subjects, these words about
Charles Lamb: ‘The effusions signed C. L. were written by Mr.
Charles Lamb, of the India House; independently of the signature,
their superior merit would have sufficiently distinguished them.’ And
in no different spirit did Coleridge write of Wordsworth, years
afterwards, in the Biographia Literaria, when their ways had parted.
He could explain generously then ‘what Mr. Wordsworth really
intended’ by the theories put forward in that famous preface which
was too much for Coleridge.
But to return to the book—or rather, for the moment, to
Wordsworth’s account of it. As the friends endeavoured to proceed
conjointly in the construction of the ‘Ancient Mariner’—it was still that
same evening in which the poem was conceived—their respective
manners proved so widely different that it would have been, to
Wordsworth’s mind, ‘quite presumptuous in me to do anything but
separate from an undertaking upon which I could only have been a
clog.’ ‘The “Ancient Mariner” grew and grew,’ he adds, ‘till it became
too important for our first object, which was limited to our expectation
of five pounds; and we began to think of a volume, which was to
consist, as Mr. Coleridge has told the world, of poems chiefly on
supernatural subjects taken from common life, but looked at, as
much as might be, through an imaginative medium.’ That
‘imaginative medium’ was to distinguish these poems, we have been
told elsewhere, from the rhymed stories of Crabbe. Poetic realism
and prosaic realism, and what a world between them!
In April 1798 Wordsworth wrote to his friend, the Bristol
bookseller: ‘You will be pleased to hear that I have gone on adding
very rapidly to my stock of poetry. Do come and let me read it to you
under the old trees in the park.’ Definite proposals, too, were to be
made; and it was written to Cottle—this time, I think, by Coleridge
—‘We deem that the volumes offered to you are, to a certain degree,
one work in kind.’ That same spring, but later on, Cottle did visit
Nether Stowey, and he writes of it in his own book of interesting if
sometimes illegitimate gossip: ‘At this interview it was determined
that the volume should be published under the title of Lyrical Ballads,
on the terms stipulated.’ Thirty guineas seems to have been
Wordsworth’s share. And, furthermore, it was settled that it should
not contain the poem of ‘Salisbury Plain,’ but only an extract from it
—Cottle himself, nevertheless, thought that poem the finest
Wordsworth had written; that it should not contain the poem of ‘Peter
Bell,’ but consist rather of shorter poems, and for the most part of
pieces more recently written. ‘I had recommended two volumes,’
Cottle tells us, ‘but one was fixed on, and that to be published
anonymously.’ All which speedily came about. Cottle further says,
‘The volume of the Lyrical Ballads was published about midsummer,
1798.’ But it was not really till some while after midsummer, for not
only were the Tintern Abbey lines, which close the little volume with
so august a calm, not written till the 13th of July, but it is said
expressly in Wordsworth’s Life that as late as September the 13th
the book was ‘printed, not published.’ Some weeks before,
Wordsworth and his sister took up temporary abode in Bristol, that
they might be near the printer. Then, at length, in the early part of
autumn, the Lyrical Ballads appeared, and Wordsworth and his
sister, and Coleridge, left England for Germany.
To the first edition of Lyrical Ballads is prefixed four pages of
‘Advertisement,’ or preface. About it two or three points are
noticeable. First, it gives no hint that two poets have been engaged
upon the volume: ‘the author,’ who speaks of himself in the third
person, is responsible alike for the ‘Ancient Mariner’ and for ‘Goody
Blake and Harry Gill.’ Secondly, it is written in that familiar language
—just our daily speech a little chastened and braced—which
Wordsworth employed at the beginning, and employed to the end.
Again, it utters, thus early in Wordsworth’s life, that note of warning
as to mistaken notions of what Poetry demands, which the writer
repeated afterwards with infinite elaboration. ‘It is the honourable
characteristic of Poetry that its materials are to be found in every
subject which can interest the human mind’—that is, by implication,
his first apology for the choice of humble theme. ‘Readers of superior
judgment may disapprove of the style in which many of these pieces
are executed: it must be expected that many lines and phrases will
not exactly suit their taste.’ Expressions may seem too familiar—may
seem lacking in dignity. But, ‘it is apprehended that the more
conversant the reader is with our elder writers, and with those in
modern times who have been most successful in painting manners
and passions, the fewer complaints of this kind will he have to make.’
Here is the apology for the fashion of presentation—the germ of that
which was afterwards so fully developed in famous writings which
borrowed here and there a neat and significant phrase from this first
‘Advertisement.’
The title of the ‘Ancient Mariner’ begins the table of contents,
and the poem runs on to the fifty-first page of the volume—nearly a
quarter of all that the volume holds. But Coleridge’s remaining
contributions were small and few, consisting of ‘The Nightingale,’ and
of but one other. That he made even these contributions has
sometimes escaped people’s notice. He had intended to do more, for
he tells us in the Biographia Literaria that, having written the ‘Ancient
Mariner,’ he was preparing, among other poems, ‘The Dark Ladie’
and the ‘Christabel.’ ‘But Mr. Wordsworth’s industry has proved much
more successful, and the number of his poems so much greater, that
my compositions, instead of forming a balance, appeared rather an
interpolation of heterogeneous matter.’ When the ‘Ancient Mariner’
came to be reprinted—under Coleridge’s banner alone—some minor
changes were made. Some of them were gains, but some were
losses. And there was added then, what the Lyrical Ballads does not
contain, the ‘Gloss’—that wonderful telling of the story and yet
departing from it—which is set forth in grave and inspired prose. ‘It
was an afterthought,’ Wordsworth tells us, in speaking of his friend’s
poem.
Of Wordsworth’s own share—that far greater share of his—in the
poems, it is interesting to notice how the general title, Lyrical Ballads
with a few other Poems, is required to cover the whole of it. For they
are of two kinds—Wordsworth’s poems in the volume—the simple
stories of humble life, which may or may not be dramatic, in which
the ‘I’ of the poet is not necessarily himself, and the poems which
record unmistakably his personal feeling and experience, such as
‘The Tables Turned, an Evening Scene,’ the noble lines written near
Tintern Abbey, and the small poem which rejoices in perhaps the
longest title ever bestowed upon verse, ‘Lines written at a small
distance from my house, and sent by my little boy to the person to
whom they are addressed.’ These, and one or two others, are the
contributions to which Coleridge refers when he says that ‘Mr.
Wordsworth added two or three poems written in his own character,
in the impassioned, lofty, and sustained diction which is
characteristic of his genius.’
Many of Wordsworth’s verses, whether of the one class or the
other, in the Lyrical Ballads, bear reference to the circumstances of
the moment and the place—are stamped with the mark of his
Alfoxden sojourn. ‘The Thorn’ arose out of his observing on the ridge
of Quantock Hill a thorn on a stormy day. He had often passed it
unnoticed in calm. ‘I said to myself, Cannot I by some invention do
as much to make this Thorn prominently an impressive object as the
storm has made it to my eyes at this moment? I began the poem
accordingly, and composed it with great rapidity.’ He adds that Sir
George Beaumont painted a picture from it, which Wilkie thought his
best. Wilkie—sagacious Scotsman!—did not commit himself too
much by such praise. But Wordsworth thought the picture nobly
done. The only fault of any consequence, he said, was the woman’s
figure—too old and decrepit ‘for one likely to frequent an eminence
on such a call.’ ‘Expostulation and Reply,’ which Wordsworth learned
was a favourite among the Quakers, was composed in front of the
house at Alfoxden, in the spring of 1798. ‘The Tables Turned’ was
composed at the same time, in praise of the
And of ‘The Last of the Flock,’ the author says that the incident
occurred in the village of Holford, close by Alfoxden.
But I think the most interesting of the records is the record of ‘We
are Seven.’ This was composed while walking in the favourite grove.
In Wordsworth’s confession that he composed the last stanza first,
we get at the secret of how entirely the subject had struck him from
the spiritual side.
1
Since moved to the Corratorie.
2
Feodora, the evil genius, one may say, of the
Peau de Chagrin.
3
If this was Madame de Castries, the intention
did not always hold good, since more than
touches of that charmer there are supposed to
be in the Duchesse de Langeais.
What Balzac seems to have been struck with, from the first, in
Evelina de Hanska, was her sincerity and oneness of purpose, the
truth of her devotion to his work, and a certain similarity, an
immediate sympathy, between his nature and hers. Much of his
work, as he avows, has been done to strike the public—to provide
the public with that without which it could scarcely accord him the
attention he asked. But ‘certainly there are books in which I have
loved to be myself; and you will know well which they are, for they
are those in which my heart has spoken.’ When at length the two
came together, at Neuchâtel in 1833—as in Vienna, and in Russian
Poland itself, in later years—there was nothing, it seems, in either to
diminish the interest or to break the spell. And the fascination
continued. I have for my own part a little theory that the sympathy of