Final Structural Change and Trade Openness Revised THESE
Final Structural Change and Trade Openness Revised THESE
Final Structural Change and Trade Openness Revised THESE
African Countries
Kabinet Kaba, Justin Yifu, Mary-Françoise Renard
Abstract
In this paper, we study the role of trade openness in the economic reallocation from the agri-
culture to the manufacturing sector in 34 sub-Saharan African countries between 1970-2016. The
results show that the long term evolution of trade openness negatively impacts the long-run and
the short-run dynamics of structural change. Moreover, this impact goes through aggregate ex-
ports not aggregate imports. By breaking down global exports, we find that commodities exports
have a negative impact while manufacturing exports positively impact structural change. These
results are explained by the fact that, contrary to Asian countries, African countries have failed
to put trade at the service of industrialization by following the logic of comparative advantage.
More precisely, they have failed to invest the revenues from commodities exports to improve the
quality of infrastructure in order to remove the constraints on the relocation to labor-intensive
manufacturing activities. Unlike previous studies, we address the endogeneity problem by using
a dynamic ordinary least squares method after a pooled mean group method.
Acknowledgment: We thank Annie Krautkraemer and Muhammad Naseem for the proofreading
and valuable suggestions that are contributed to improve the paper. This work was supported by the
Agence Nationale de la Recherche of the French government through the program "Investissements
d’avenir "ANR-10-LABX-14-01".
* Corresponding author: [email protected]; CNRS, IRD, CERDI, F-63000 CLERMONT FERRAND, France.
† [email protected]; Institute of New Structural Economics, Institute of South-South Cooperation and Develop-
ment, National School of Development, Peking University.
‡ [email protected]; School of Economics, CERDI-IDREC, University Clermont Auvergne.
1
1 Introduction
Most research on economic development began with questions on structural change (SC) from agri-
culture to industry (Atolia et al. 2020; Murphy et al. 1989b; Kuznets & Murphy, 1966; Lewis, 1954).
Indeed, SC means reallocation of economic activity from the low productivity sector (agriculture)
to the high productivity sector (industry).1 Thus, it is an industrialization process that leads to
total factor productivity growth even if productivity has not increased within sectors (McMillan &
Rodrik, 2011). For example, if workers move from agriculture to industry, total factor productivity
will increase because the labor force moved from the low productivity sector to the high productiv-
ity sector (Lewis, 1954). So, the magnitude of the SC’s effect on economic development will depend
on its direction and the speed at which economic reallocation to industry occurs. In addition, eco-
nomic development is a conditional process of continuous industrial and technological upgrading
(Lin, 2012).
The main determinants of the nature of SC are the industrial and trade policies implemented by
the states. These policies can lead to a SC involving either industrialization or de-industrialization
depending on how they are implemented. During the nineteenth century, the countries of Asia,
Africa, and Latin America underwent a process of de-industrialization. Their total share in the
world manufacturing output fell from 60.5% in 1830 to 7.5% in 1913 (Nayyar, 2019). This period
being the colonial era, it was marked by a massive global investment in their natural resources sec-
tors and a concentration of the global manufacturing investment in the United States and Europe,
which were the colonizers. Although this de-industrialization was a common phenomenon to all
the previously mentioned three regions during colonization, the period of 1970-2016 was marked
by some divergences among them in terms of industrialization. Between 1970-2016, the share of
manufacturing value-added in GDP increased from 10% to 23% in Asia while that of East Asia in
the global manufacturing value-added increased from 4% to 41% (Nayyar, 2019). In sub-Saharan
Africa (SSA), the manufacturing value-added share in GDP fell from about 13% in 1980 to 10%
in 2016, its share in the global manufacturing production fell from 3% in 1970 to less than 2% in
2010 (Page et al. 2016). As a result, SC has been growth-enhancing in Asia while it has been
growth-reducing in SSA (McMillan et al. 2014). However, the de-industrialization in SSA is puz-
zling because this region has the lowest average wage in the world so it should benefit more from
economic reallocation to labor-intensive manufacturing industries compared with other regions.
Another difference between Asian and SSA countries lies in the industrial and trade policies
as a support for industrialization. During the 1950s and 1960s, some Asian countries, like many
developing countries in other parts of the world, opted for trade protection policies because of the
de-industrialization of the colonial period. On the one hand, these trade strategies took the form
of import substitution policies aimed at protecting the local manufacturing sector development.
1 In this paper, the term industry and industrialization refer only to manufacturing sector according to the literature
about industrialization (Rodrik, 2016b; Gui-Diby & Renard, 2015; Kang & Lee, 2011).
2
On the other hand, it took the form of state intervention in order to guide the firms in the labor-
intensive primary manufacturing industries following their comparative advantage (Lin, 2009).
Although a large majority of these countries opened up to international trade during the 1980’s,
their particularity lies in the progressive modification of the content of their exports. In some cases,
they began to export agricultural raw materials, and then a significant share of these exports was
gradually made up of labor-intensive manufacturing goods and later of capital-intensive manufac-
turing products. After their independence, some SSA leaders had the ambition to industrialize
their countries to no longer depend on their former colonial power. Thus, their idea was to create
the same capital-intensive industries as in developed countries. These policies were initially accom-
panied by an industrial dynamism in some SSA countries. In 1960, the shares of the manufacturing
value-added in GDP were 9%, 10%, 14%, 16% and 20%, in Kenya, Senegal, Congo, Zimbabwe and
South Africa, respectively (Austin et al. 2016). For many SSA countries, the end of the 1980s was
marked by a trade openness that allowed them to export sizeable natural resources with a low rate
of diversification. As a result, the annual growth rate of the manufacturing sector, which was 8%
between 1961-1970 in SSA, was reduced to 5.1%, 1.9% and 1.1%, between 1971-1980, 1981-1990,
and 1991-2000, respectively.
At some points in their history, Asia and SSA have implemented first trade protection and then
trade openness policies. However, the trade measures taken by the governments of these two re-
gions have been different as the nature of their SC. Thus, the purpose of this paper is to understand
how trade openness and industrial policies explain the nature or the direction of SC in 34 SSA coun-
tries between 1970-2016.2 Our interest in this period is determined by the fact that it includes both
a large part of trade protection (1970- the end of the 1980s) and trade liberalization periods (after
the end of the 1980s) in Africa. Due to data constraints, we do not consider the periods before 1970
and after 2016.
Given the importance of SC in the process of economic growth and development, it is the subject
of many research papers. The first half of this literature studies the nature of SC and its implica-
tions in terms of growth and poverty reduction in Africa (McMillan & Rodrik, 2011; De Brauw et al.
2014; Christiaensen & Todo, 2014). The second half is based on the constraints related to the SC
(Bräutigam & Tang, 2014; Collier & Dercon, 2014; Harrison et al. 2014).3 According to McMillan &
Headey (2014), the research on this issue remains poor in terms of empirical analysis in the case of
Africa which implies that our knowledge about this question in SSA is very limited. Indeed, some
of these papers are based on descriptive statistics, which are correlation and not causality analyses
(De Brauw et al. 2014; Dorosh & Thurlow, 2014; McMillan & Headey, 2014; Collier & Dercon, 2014;
Bräutigam & Tang, 2014). In addition, the papers that perform econometric analyses use ordinary
least squares as estimate method (Christiaensen & Todo, 2014; Harrison et al. 2014; McMillan &
Rodrik, 2011), which does not consider endogeneity bias. Also, these papers study a limited num-
2 See 10 for the list of countries studied.
3 McMillan & Headey (2014) provide an overview about the literature of structural change in Africa.
3
ber of African countries due to a lack of data related to manufacturing employment for most of SSA
countries.
In order to fill the methodological gap, we perform pooled mean group (PMG) and dynamic ordi-
nary least squares (DOLS) to model the long-run and short-run relationships between SC and trade
openness. The relevance of the empirical methods lies in the fact that SC is a dynamic process dur-
ing which there is a reallocation of economic activity from agriculture to industry. In addition, they
also make it possible to take into account endogeneity bias (DOLS) and the fallacious regression.4
Concerning the measurement gap, we measure SC by the ratio between the manufacturing value-
added and the agriculture value-added; the availability of these data allows to study an important
number of countries in SSA. In addition, we contribute to the literature through a theoretical and
historical discussion on trade and industrial policies in Asia and SSA. This allows us to examine
how differences in industrial and trade policies have led to different patterns of structural transfor-
mation between these two regions.
The empirical results show that trade openness is a barrier to SC and thus to industrialization in
SSA. Indeed, the long-term evolution of trade openness negatively affects the long-run and short-
run dynamics of SC and this negative impact goes through aggregate exports, but not aggregate
imports. By breaking down global exports, we find that commodities exports have a negative impact
while manufacturing exports have a positive impact on SC. This surprising result can be explained
mainly by bad decisions in industrial and trade policies. First, the post-independence industrial
policies focused on the creation of capital-intensive industries while the comparative advantage of
African countries is in labor-intensive industries. Second, the trade policies of the end of the 1980s
were based on a deep specialization in the exports of raw materials without investing exports’
resources in the development of a competitive domestic industrial sector. Indeed, SSA countries
suffer from significant infrastructure constraints, which represent a significant transaction cost for
the industrial activities. Consequently, the return on investment in manufacturing activities will be
low and may be lower than that in imports activities. Still, as a result of infrastructure constraints
and the poor business environment, the risk associated with the creation of a new industry will be
high relative to the risk associated with import activities. In this context, even with a comparative
advantage in low-skilled labor-intensive industries, the entrepreneurs in SSA will prefer to import
rather than invest in manufacturing sector. Therefore, a trade openness based on commodities
exports without a resources-investment policy will crowd out the manufacturing sector. This effect
will be amplified by the rise of GDP per capita due to commodities exports, which will increase the
domestic demand, but with a weak industrial base, the rise of the domestic demand will lead to an
increase in the demand for foreign products.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows: we present in Section 2 the history, debate and
the measures of SC; the literature review will be presented in Section 3; stylized facts, variables
4 The endogeneity bias in this case arises because there may be reverse causality between SC and trade openness. In
addition, we study a macroeconomic model in which the variables can be explained by each other.
4
and data description are presented in Section 4; empirical strategy will be discussed in the Section
5; the results will be presented in Section 6 and Section 7 will be the concluding remarks.
2.1 Structural change and trade policies: Asia versus sub-Saharan Africa
Although industrialization was an important objective of the independence period in Asia and SSA,
the policies to achieve this goal led to two different results in terms of SC. The aim of this sub-
section is to present how trade measures and state intervention have explained the nature of SC in
the two regions.
The SC performance in Asia has been accepted as the result of its trade and industrial policies.
State intervention had built the bases of industrialization in this region (Wade, 2004). Indeed,
the industrial policies in the post-colonial period can be understood in the context of colonization.
According to Nayyar (2019), the colonial era has been marked by trade openness which was ac-
companied by de-industrialization. Hence, after their independence, the purpose of the industrial
policies was to protect the local manufacturing sector. Although some individual particularities
can be noted, the industrial strategies were threefold. First, the manufacturing firms in the labor-
intensive activities have benefited from the import substitution policies. In some economies like
Korea and Taiwan, the aim of trade policies was to protect the export manufacturing sector by an
undervaluation of the exchange rate and a restriction of trade to other sectors. Second, there have
been strategies for guiding and coordinating firms. This has taken shape in public investments in
hard and soft infrastructure and an incentive for banks to provide long-term credit for investments
that are oriented towards the industrial sector.5 For example, in Korea, banks have been encour-
aged to charge differentiated interest rates depending whether investments are oriented towards
the sector of comparative advantage or not; while in Taiwan, there were credit taxes. Given the
scarcity of resources, these policies aimed at allocating them to well identified sectors. Third, in
some economies like China, South Korea, Taiwan, and Vietnam, some agrarian and land redistri-
bution reforms have been implemented. As a result of these reforms, the exports of agricultural
5 Hard infrastructure: energy, transport, telecommunication. Soft infrastructure: finance
5
products increased in these countries. (Wade, 2004). According to Rodrik (1995), the plausible ex-
planation of the Asian miracle can be understood through the previous measures mentioned above.
Indeed, given the high return on physical capital in Taiwan and Korea, the interventionist policies
of their governments were to coordinate the investment decisions of the economic agents. Thus, the
trade openness of the 1960s was the result of a strong import-demand for inputs in order to support
the investment demand.
Trade openness in most Asian countries was marked by an increasing share of the world trade
and an upgrade of their exports content (Lin, 2012; Nayyar, 2019). The eight best performing
economies in East Asia recorded a growth in their share of world exports, from 7.9% in 1965 to
13.1% in 1980, and 18.2% in 1990 (Page, 1994). The contribution of manufacturing exports was the
main reason for this trade performance. Between 1965-1990, Japan became the leading exporter
of manufacturing products in the world, its share increasing from 8% to 12%, between 1970-1980
(Page, 1994). In the same time, the world share of manufactured exports from the four tigers
has grown almost four times faster than that of Japan.6 According to Lin (2012), in the 1990s,
China was a major exporter of raw materials but in the 2000s, it moved from this type of export
to sophisticated goods exports. India also is following this path. In Malaysia, the Philippines and
Thailand, the share of primary commodities in total exports was 80% in 1980 and then about 20%-
30% in 2016; their shares of medium and high-technology industrial products have been 50%, 75%
and 50% in 2016 (Nayyar, 2019). In Indonesia, the share of primary commodities in total exports
was 80% in 1980 and then about 30% in 2016 while it decreased from 60% to 20% in Sri Lanka.
Concerning resource-based and low-technology industrial products, their share in total exports for
the same years increased from 18% to 50% in Indonesia and from 35% to 70% in Sri Lanka.
After their independence, the leaders of SSA countries were convinced that the economic devel-
opment of African nations should go through industrialization. «Industry...is the means by which
rapid improvement in Africa’s living standards is possible...» Kwame Nkrumah (1965).7
To achieve this goal, they have put in place two strategies of industrialization. On the one hand,
the state was the initiator of industrialization, which motivated it to create and invest heavily in
state-owned industries. On the other hand, to ensure a balance between domestic demand and pro-
duction, trade protection policies have been implemented through very high customs tariffs. These
import substitution policies were implemented both by the “ socialist states like Ghana under
Kwame Nkrumah; Guinea under Sekou Touré; Tanzania under Julius Nyerere; and the “ capitalist
states like Côte dIvoire under Houphouët-Boigny and Kenya under Jomo Kenyatta (Austin et al.
2016). Unlike Asian countries, the objective of these policies was that the local industrial produc-
tion should serve domestic consumption instead of export. In line with these measures, there has
6 The four tigers: South Korea, Hong Kong, Singapour and Taïwan
7 Kwame Nkrumah is the first president of Ghana and the hero of this country’s independence.
6
been an industrial development in some SSA countries. In fact, the industrial sector has grown
by 14.6% per year in SSA between 1965-1973, and this was more than double the GDP growth
which was 6.6% per year over the same period (Newman et al. 2016). From 1965 to 1970, manu-
facturing production increased by more than 7% in 7 SSA countries (Newman et al. 2016).8 This
manufacturing growth was about 8% in Ethiopia and Ghana, 10% in Tanzania and Uganda. Al-
though the interventionist strategy led to growth in the manufacturing sector, the success of trade
protection policies and the massive investment in state-owned enterprises quickly became short-
lived. These industrialization programs were based on the production of capital-intensive goods,
while SSA is characterized by a scarcity of capital and an abundance of less skilled labor. For ex-
ample, in the 1970s, one of the industrial ambition of the Democratic Republic of Congo was the
construction of an automobile factory while its main competitor was the United States with a large
gap in terms of income per capita and capital availability (Lin, 2012). Over the same period, the
capital intensity doubled in Senegal as industrial production declined (Meier et al. 1989). After
their independence, the government of Ghana invested in the electronic and machinery industries
in order to produce domestically the production inputs. Although import substitution policies have
been implemented by most SSA countries, there have been some differences in their application.
Indeed, a large majority of the French colonies remained in the colonial monetary zone at the time
called " franc des Colonies Fançaises d’Afrique ", while most British colonies together with Guinea
opted for monetary independence. In the case of the second group of countries, exchange rate over-
valuation policies were put in place. Theoretically, exchange rate overvaluation would act as an
indirect subsidy to manufacturing firms, allowing them to import intermediate inputs and capital
goods below world prices. This strategy reduced the incentive to invest in the agricultural export
activities, which in turn led to a shortage of foreign exchange reserves for imports of intermediate
inputs. Moreover, the industrial development strategy was based on a massive public investment
in state-owned enterprises, rather than on the improvement of their productivity. This resulted in
public expenditures far greater than the tax-raising capacity of governments. As a result of these
measures, the high level of customs duties contributed to reducing the efficiency of the domestic
production of nished goods. In fact, the cost of importing intermediate inputs exceeded the import
price of finished manufactured goods (Newman et al. 2016). The ineffectiveness of public spend-
ing and trade measures forced SSA governments to consolidate their public finances. Thus, the
1980s marked the end of public intervention in favor of economic liberalization advocated by the
international institutions.
In the context of debt unsustainability, the international institutions including the World Bank
(WB) and the International Monetary fund (IMF) advocated for some reforms. Known as " Struc-
tural Adjustment Programs ", these reforms were followed by de-industrialization in SSA. Over the
mid-1990s, the manufacturing growth rate was lower than that of the period 1985-1990 in eight
8 The 7 SSA countries: Ethiopia, Ghana, Kenya, Nigeria, Senegal, Tanzania and Uganda.
7
SSA countries (Newman et al. 2016).9 From 1980 to 1985, the manufacturing growth became nega-
tive in Ghana, Nigeria, and Tanzania, it remained at 4% in Ethiopia, Kenya, Senegal and Uganda.
The average growth rate of manufacturing in Ghana fell from 7.5% at the end of the 1980s to
-7.4% at the beginning of the 1990s. Furthermore, the manufacturing value-added per worker de-
creased for many SSA countries between 1995-2010: from 100 to 64; 56; 36; 66, in Ethiopia, Kenya,
Mozambique, and Senegal, respectively (Page et al. 2016). Although in the case of other developing
countries the manufacturing share in the global exports was from 10% in 1980 to 29.6% in 2011,
it was from 3% to 2.8% in Africa (Newman et al. 2016). One characteristic of this period was that
most SSA countries exported sizeable natural resources with a high level of concentration.
Clearly, at some points in their history, Asia and SSA have implemented industrialization poli-
cies, based sometimes on trade protection and sometimes on trade liberalization while the nature
of their SC has been different. The explanation of the results of these policies can be understood
through the role of states in the implementation of industrial strategy. The post-independence in-
dustrial policies have failed to generate sustainable growth in SSA because they were not based on
countries comparative advantages. In most SSA countries, the state has been unable to guide and
coordinate the local entrepreneurs towards the comparative advantage sector. Indeed, countries
with a relative natural resources abundance or unskilled labor force and scarcity of human and
physical capital must create labor-intensive and natural resource-intensive industries. The liber-
alization policies have also failed because most African governments didn’t use the commodities
exports’ revenues to reduce the constraints related to soft and hard infrastructure deficits that lead
to high transaction costs, inhibiting the development of a local manufacturing sector.
According to Gui-Diby & Renard (2015), at least 26 African countries had an industrialization strat-
egy in 2017. In July 2016, the United Nations General Assembly adopted a resolution announcing
the third decade of the industrial development in Africa. Although it is an important issue for
African policy-makers, some observers argue that SSA can experience a growth miracle with SC
between agriculture and services (McMillan & Harttgen, 2014). In fact, a reallocation of economic
activity from agriculture to manufacturing can be a real driver of poverty reduction and employ-
ment (Rodrik, 2016a). However, SC between agriculture and services is less likely to impact the
total factor productivity in SSA. Indeed, the type of services - for example information technology -
that impacts the overall productivity requires a very skilled labor force. As an illustration, it takes
several years of study and institutional quality improvement to transform a farmer into a program-
mer or into a call center operator. However, it only takes manual dexterity and physical capital
to transform a farmer into a worker in a labor-intensive manufacturing industry multiplying his
productivity by two or three (Rodrik, 2016a). It is the case of China, people moving from agriculture
9 The 8 countries: Ethiopia, Ghana, Kenya, Mozambique, Nigeria, Senegal, Tanzania, and Uganda.
8
to industry and from industry to services. However, it should be noted that these services represent
inputs for the primary sector in some developing countries. For instance, the introduction of mo-
bile phones in the city of Kerala in India would have allowed fishermen to make price arbitration
between different markets increasing their profit by 8% (Jensen, 2007). The Kenyan mobile bank-
ing system (M-Pesa) has reportedly allowed some very poor women to leave the agricultural to the
non-agricultural activities (Suri & Jack, 2016). Thus, these examples show that high-tech services
could facilitate structural transformation from agriculture to industry but they are not a driver of
overall productivity growth and unemployment reduction (Rodrik, 2018).
The manufacturing sector in Africa has both advantages and disadvantages. One undeniable
advantage is its competitiveness in terms of labor costs. As labor costs are increasing in Asian
countries, SSA could be the future area of relocation of labor-intensive production and/or assembly
activities (Lin, 2012). In this context, SSA could benefit from the global value chains (GVCs) by
integrating it more fully into global markets. The other advantage of the African manufacturing
industry is the high young population growth on this continent. According to the African Devel-
opment Bank (AfDB) Groups report - Strategy of the Bank Group for Youth Employment in Africa
2016-2025 -, the young African population will double in 2050 reaching 830 million. This demo-
graphic growth is a boon to industrialization both in terms of labor availability and in terms of
demand for African manufacturing goods.
Despite the previous advantages, this sector is still undermined by several problems related to
the business environment. In SSA, most companies recognized business environment constraints
such as power outages and regulatory burden as a major problem. For example, the losses associ-
ated with power outages can reach 10% of firms sales in some countries (Gelb et al. 2014). About 1/3
of the enterprises report poor conditions of transport networks as a major constraint. On average,
40% of firms in SSA report that bribery practices are common.
According to Rodrik (2016b), Gui-Diby & Renard (2015), Kang & Lee (2011), industrialization is
measured by the manufacturing value-added share in GDP or by the manufacturing employment
share in total employment. From the new structural economics perspective, it is equally important
to measure the employment and the value-added share of manufacturing industries with different
capital intensities (Lin, 2011). SC is defined as a reallocation of economic activity between agri-
culture, manufacturing and services (Herrendorf et al. 2014). Starting from this definition, the
authors stipulate that SC from the production perspective is measured either by the evolution of
the sectoral value-added shares in GDP or by the evolution of the sectoral employment shares in
total employment. According to them, the main limitation of using employment as a SC proxy is
that the change in employment may not reflect the real changes in labor as input. Indeed, employ-
ment is determined either by the number of workers or by the number of hours worked. However,
9
there may be differences between the number of hours worked and human capital between sectors
due to countries’ level of development (Herrendorf et al. 2014). In addition, data for manufactur-
ing employment exist for few SSA countries. Hence, SC between agriculture and manufacturing
is measured in this paper by the ratio of their value-added. This measure typically corresponds
to a reallocation of economic activity between these two sectors. The ratio between manufacturing
and agriculture reflects the way in which the value-added of manufacturing increases (decreases)
over time compared to that of agriculture. Thus, the variations in such a ratio show how the man-
ufacturing sector contributes to GDP relative to agriculture, reflecting a reallocation of economic
activity between the two sectors.
3 Literature review
Many papers have studied the determinants and the impacts of SC but few of them focus on the case
of Africa. The literature that has studied SC in Africa can be organized into two main categories.
The first focuses on the characteristics and the nature of economic reallocation and the second
studies the constraints related to the SC.
According to the Lewis dual economy model, developing countries are characterized by a traditional
sector with low productivity level and a modern sector with high level of productivity. Thus, SC that
leads to economic development is defined by a reallocation of economic activity from the traditional
to the modern sector. Nevertheless, the evolution has been different in Africa (McMillan & Headey,
2014; McMillan & Rodrik, 2011). Based on disaggregated data on sectoral employments, McMil-
lan & Rodrik (2011) show that SC has been growth-reducing from 1990 to 1999 in the case of Latin
America and Africa. According to the authors, one of the factors that helps to understand this result
is the natural resources endowment. Indeed, in countries with a high share of natural resources in
total exports, SC is a source of reduced economic growth and productivity. One of the main reasons
is that the natural resources sector - mineral resources - is a highly productive sector that cannot
10
absorb a significant amount of unskilled labor. Another explanation about the reduction of growth
by SC could be the type of urban migration that SSA countries have experienced (Rodrik, 2016b;
De Brauw et al. 2014). In the case of many developing countries, rural areas are composed of
low-productive agricultural activities while urban areas are characterized by the existence of non-
agricultural activities particularly industrial activities. Thus, labor migration from rural to urban
areas should take the form of a SC involving industrialization. However, De Brauw et al. (2014)
show that a significant proportion of African population resides in rural places. Although cities
abound in activities that can provide better returns than agricultural sector, the migration rate
towards them is still very low in several African countries. Specifically, the annual migration rate
in these countries was estimated at 1% from 1990 to 2000 (De Brauw et al. 2014). In many SSA
countries, the experience of labor migration from rural to urban areas has resulted in a concentra-
tion of labor in traditional services instead of industrial sector (Rodrik, 2016b). Moreover, in some
countries, there has been a movement of labor from the manufacturing sector to the traditional
sector, particularly agriculture (McMillan & Headey, 2014). In this section, one conclusion can be
summarized: in the case of most SSA countries, SC was in the wrong direction and its impact on
economic growth and the living standard depends on its nature.
Although manufacturing industries are more productive than agriculture, SSA has not experienced
a real reallocation of economic activity from the traditional to the modern sector to allow a sig-
nificant improvement in the standard of living. For example, a large part of the labor force is
concentrated in the agricultural sector in Africa. More precisely, the share of agricultural employ-
ment reaches 80% of the active population in some African countries (McMillan & Headey, 2014). If
manufacturing is more productive than agriculture, why does Africa not experience an economic re-
allocation towards manufacturing? Using samples including African and non-African cross-country
firm level data, Harrison et al. (2014) show that manufacturing industries in Africa perform less
than those elsewhere. According to the authors, manufacturing firms in Africa have a low level of
productivity; they sell, export, and invest less than others. However, when they control for infras-
tructure and the quality of institutions, it appears that African firms perform better than others.
The business environment - especially the quality of infrastructure and institutions - needs to be
improved so as to increase the competitiveness and the labor absorption capacity of the manufac-
turing sector in Africa. In this context, Bräutigam & Tang (2014) have done a qualitative analysis
of how foreign direct investment - especially Chinese investments - may result in SC in Africa. Ac-
cording to the authors, foreign investments in Africa can lead to a SC if they are attracted in special
economic zones (SEZs). In addition, Harrison et al. (2014) find that the impact of foreign ownership
is higher in Africa than in other developing economies. The papers by Harrison et al. (2014) and
Bräutigam & Tang (2014) highlight the constraints related to manufacturing industry in Africa to
11
explain why a real SC does not occur. In this sense, Collier & Dercon (2014) study the constraints re-
lated to the African agricultural sector. They show that a real SC can occur if productivity increases
in agriculture; this would lead to a movement of labor from agriculture to manufacturing. So, the
policymakers in Africa should make the agricultural sector more marketable. Finally, Dorosh &
Thurlow (2014) highlighted the role of state in the process of SC in Ethiopia and Uganda. They
wonder in which sector state must invest more to force a real structural transformation. Develop-
ing dynamic economy-wide models, they conclude that public investment in cities is an important
determinant of SC in the long term, because the modern sectors are located in cities. However, in
the short term, for an imperative of poverty reduction, they suggest further public investment in
agriculture.
This sub-section presents different stylized facts about SC and trade in our sample. Between 1970-
2016, SSA experienced on average two periods of SC between agriculture and manufacturing (see
the first graph of Figure 1). First, a slight increase appears in the share of manufacturing value-
added in GDP and and a decrease appears in the agriculture share from 1970 to the end of the
1980s (the first graph of Figure 1). This can be interpreted as a structural transformation leading
to industrialization even if the increase of manufacturing and the decrease of agriculture are very
weak. However, at the end of the 1980s, we can see a slight SC involving de-industrialization be-
cause manufacturing decreased while agriculture increased. Although the above graphs are simple
correlations, these two types of SC correspond to two different periods of trade policy. On the one
hand, the period of SC involving industrialization corresponds to that of protectionist policies in
SSA. On the other hand, the period of SC leading to de-industrialization corresponds on average
to the period of trade liberalization of the SSA countries. Also, it appears that the share of agri-
culture in GDP is still on average higher than that of manufacturing which in the case of SSA
reflects a poor performance of SC. Although it is the key sector of economic development, the share
of manufacturing in GDP was still very low in SSA from 1970 to 2016 (about 10% in 2016).
The first graph of Figure 1 does not provide information about the productivity difference be-
tween agriculture and manufacturing. To address this, we collect data for 11 SSA countries on
the sectoral shares in GDP and in total employment from the Groningen Growth and Development
Centre database. This database is relevant because it provides sectoral employment for 11 SSA
countries in addition to the sectoral value-added.10 Hence, the second graph of Figure 1 shows
10 The 11 SSA countries for which data on manufacturing employment exist are: Botswana, Ethiopia, Ghana, Kenya,
12
the average shares of manufacturing and agriculture in GDP and in total employment between
1970-2000 and 2000-2011.11 It appears that from 1970 to 2000, the share of agriculture in total em-
ployment was higher than its share in GDP and it was the opposite for the manufacturing sector.
Arithmetically, this reflects the higher productivity in manufacturing sector. The important fact
that emerges from Figure 1 is that manufacturing is more productive than agriculture in SSA but
its share in total employment is still very small. Consequently, a reallocation of economic activity
from agriculture to manufacturing should be an important source of economic growth in Africa.
Indeed, a significant number of workers would leave the low productivity (agriculture) to the high
productivity sector (manufacturing). This will lead to an increase in overall productivity in SSA
even if productivity within sectors does not increase. A more precise analysis clearly shows the
low technological level of African industries (Table 9). From 2000 to 2015, 87% of employment was
in manufacturing industries with low level of technology and only 1.47% was in manufacturing
industries with high level of technology.12
Over the period of trade openness policies (1995-2000), the exports from SSA remained highly
concentrated in a small number of products compared with other regions in the world (with a con-
centration index of about 0.25).13 Over the period 2001-2018, the exports were still more concen-
trated with 0.37 as the average concentration index (see the first graph of Figure 2).14 With an
average concentration index of just over 0.06 and 0.08 between 1995-2000 and 2001-2018, respec-
tively the imports in SSA are less concentrated than those in Asia and North America (see the
second graph of Figure 2).
Table 1 presents the variables of our econometric models. The ratio between the manufacturing
and agriculture value-added is the SC measure. The de facto trade openness index is the variable
of interest while aggregate exports and imports are its transmission channels. In order to study
the transmission channels of aggregate exports, they are broken down into commodities and man-
ufacturing exports. Our variables of control are: exchange rate overvaluation, market size, public
investment, private investment, the quality of institutions and the financial globalization.
11 We look at the period before and after 2000 because McMillan & Rodrik (2011) show that the contribution of SC to
economic growth is different in the two periods. Also, 2011 is the end of period because of data constraint.
12 The data come from the United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO) database. The average number
of people employed in each sector is calculated for our countries where data are available. The period 2000-2015 is considered
because of the availability of data. Finally, South Africa is excluded because of its industrial weight relative to other SSA
countries.
13 The concentration index provides information on whether exports are concentrated on a small number of products or are
homogeneously distributed over several products. This index ranges from 0 (exports are homogeneously distributed among
products) to 1 (exports are highly concentrated in a small number of products). No data are available on export and import
concentration indexes before 1995.
14 The export concentration index is represented over the period 2001-2018 in order to understand how the degree of export
13
Table 1: Data and variables description
14
5 Empirical strategy
We use PMG and DOLS estimation methods in our analysis. These techniques allow for modeling
the long-run and the short-run relationships between SC and trade openness. However, we are only
interested in the long-term effects of the explanatory variables, although these effects are studied
on both the short-run and the long-run evolution of the dependent variable. The PMG and the
DOLS also make it possible to consider the endogeneity issue and the fallacious regression. The
endogeneity bias in this case is manifested by the fact that there could be a causal relationship
between the explanatory variables and the error term. Thus, the PMG method is used first as es-
timation method and then the DOLS method is applied in robustness. However, before performing
these two methods, it is necessary to verify the stationarity of the individual variables and the coin-
tegration of their combinations. Thus, some unit root and cointegration tests are carried out prior
to the PMG and the DOLS.
According to Mignon & Hurlin (2005), there are mainly two generations of panel unit root tests.
The first one (Bai & Ng, 2004; Levin & Lin, 1993; Hadri 1999; Harris & Tzavalis, 1999; Maddala &
Wu, 1999; Choi; 2001; Levin et al. 2002; Im et al. 2003) is based on an absence of inter-individual
correlation in any form (Mignon & Hurlin, 2005) . The second generation ( Phillips & Sul, 2003;
Moon & Perron, 2004; Choi, 2002; Pesaran, 2007) attempts to control all inter-dependencies that
could exist between the individuals.
In this paper, we apply three unit root tests from the aforementioned generations. We first
perform two tests from the first generation (Im et al., 2003 and Choi, 2001) and then one test
from the second generation (Pesaran, 2007). The choice of Im et al. (2003) and Choi (2001) is
explained by the following reasons. Indeed, Im et al. (2003) and Choi (2001) consider the unit
roots as heterogeneous across individuals, which is relevant in a macroeconomic study such as this
one (see Hurlin & Mignon, 2005). Moreover, Im et al. (2003), postulate a heterogeneity of in the
existence of unit roots across individuals. These assumptions are realistic and plausible in our study
because some heterogeneous characteristics between countries can generate different unit roots and
can imply the occurrence of the unit root in some countries and not in other countries. The test from
Choi (2001) applies a fisher-type test on each panel separately (meta-analysis) while considering
the combination of the p-values from the individual tests as an overall test. Such an approach is
consistent with the time series approach, which is different from the rest of the first generation
tests. The test of Pesaran (2007) is performed because its approach remains substantially close to
the DOLS which is the robustness estimation method in this paper.15 Indeed, unlike some second-
generation tests that transform the series to be tested, Pesaran (2007) keeps the raw variable to be
15 The similarity between the Pesaran (2007) method and the DOLS approach is based on the fact that the latter also
stores the raw data of the variables while adding the first advanced and delayed difference (Mignon & Hurlin, 2007).
15
tested. The authors introduce into the Augmented-Dicker-Fuller model (ADF) the individual means
of the variable that is delayed by period and the first differences of the latter in instantaneous
(Mignon & Hurlin, 2005). For the sake of consistency, we will consider a variable as stationary if
all the three tests simultaneously reject the null hypothesis of non stationarity.
Similar to the unit root tests, two generations of cointegration tests exist. The first one concerns
the assumption of homogeneous cointegration relationships between individuals. It postulates that
the cointegration relationship cannot exist between some individuals in the panel without existing
between other individuals in the same panel. (Kao; 1999; Pedroni, 1999). The second generation
of tests stipulates the existence of heterogeneous cointegration relations (Westerlund, 2005). More
precisely, it considers that a cointegration can exist between one group of individuals without being
the case for other individuals in the same panel. Thus, to consider a combination of variables as
cointegrated, all the three tests must simultaneously reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration.
The PMG method is an econometric technique applied to cointegrated panels. According to Black-
burne III & Frank (2007), the main characteristic of cointegrated variables is their reactivity to
any deviation from the long-run equilibrium. This feature allows using an error-correction model
for cointegrated panels that links the long-run and short-run dynamics. In this type of model,
the short-run dynamics will be influenced by any deviation from the long-term equilibrium (Black-
burne III & Frank, 2007). Thus, the PMG allows estimating an error-correction model by the
maximum likelihood method:
∑
p−1 ∑
q−1
∆yi,t = ϕi (yi,t−1 − θi Xi,t ) + λi,j ∆yi,t−1 + σi,j ∆Xi,t−j + µi + ϵi,t (2)
j=1 j=0
where i=1,2,N represents the group number and t represents the time period. The first term (yi,t−1 −
θi′ Xi,t ) in equation (2) represents the long-term dynamics while the first difference variables reflect
the short-term dynamics. ϕi is the error correction term that reflects the speed at which there is a
return to the long-term equilibrium. Then, the long-term relationship exists if ϕi is different from
zero; there is a return to the long-term equilibrium if ϕi is negative and significant. Thus, it is not
necessary to test the cointegration of the model if ϕi is negative and significant (Blackburne III &
Frank, 2007). Hence, the condition for using an error correction model is that the error correcting
coefficient becomes negative and significant. ∆yi,t represents the dependent variable (SC). The
first difference of SC is the dependent variable in the PMG models because the error correction
coefficients show that we cannot apply the PMG on the models in which the SC, as a dependent
variable, is in level form. However, this is relevant as it allows for studying the long run dynamics’
effects of the explanatory variables on the short-run dynamics of SC in the PMG while the effects
on the long term dynamics of SC will be studied in the DOLS models.
16
Xi,t represents the vector of explanatory variables. It should be noted that only the first-order
integrated explanatory variables are included in both the long-run and short-run dynamics. The
variables that will eventually be stationary in level form will be in the short term dynamics, there-
fore they will be only in first difference. To understand the transmission channels of trade openness’
effect, we will replace it by the variables named ńExports and Importsż. Then, in order to explain
the sign of Exports, we replace it by the variables named ńCommodities exports and Manufactur-
ing exportsż. θi is the vector of the long-term coefficients and σi,j is the vector of the short-term
coefficients. λi,j is a scalar corresponding to the coefficients of the delay of the first difference of
the dependent variable. µi corresponds to the country fixed effects and ϵi,t is the identically and
independently distributed error term.
Before estimates, the Hausman test is applied. It allows for a comparison between the estimator
of the mean group (MG) and that of the PMG in order to choose the best model. The difference
between these two methods comes from the fact that the long term dynamics is supposed to be
homogeneous in all groups of the panel for PMG while it is heterogeneous in MG (Blackburne III
& Frank, 2007). The null hypothesis of this test corresponds to the efficiency of the PMG estimator
compared to the MG estimator.
Although the PMG introduces the lagged values of the variables in first difference, this is insuf-
ficient to fully address the endogeneity problem between the explanatory variables and the error
term. To overcome this, another cointegrated panel estimation method which takes this issue well
into account is performed for robustness.
In this study, we test the robustness of the PMG results by performing the DOLS method in order
to correct for endogeneity. DOLS is a cointegrated panel estimation technique that consists of
introducing into a cointegrating relationship the advanced and delayed values of the first difference
of the explanatory variables. The introduction of the two previous terms consists of controlling
the possible endogeneity of the explanatory variables by eliminating the correlation between them
and the error term. Kao & Chiang (2000) studied the finite-sample properties of estimators from
homogeneous cointegrated panel estimation methods. Their investigation concerned the Ordinary
Least Squares (OLS) method, Fully Modified Ordinary Least Squares and DOLS. They concluded
that DOLS substantially improved the estimators from the other two methods.
∞
∑
yi,t = αi + βXi,t + δi,k ∆Xi,t+k + ϵ∗i,t (3)
k=− ∞
Where Xi,t represents a vector grouping all of explanatory variables. The first-order integrated
explanatory variables will be in level form and in first difference while the variables stationary in
level form will be in the short-term dynamics, so in first difference.
17
yi,t corresponds to the structural change measure noted SC. β represents the vector of the long
∑∞
run coefficients along the explanatory variables. The introduction of the term δi,k ∆Xi,t+k in
k=− ∞
equation (3) allows for controlling the correlation between the explanatory variables and the error
term. The DOLS estimators are obtained by estimating equation (3) using the OLS.
6 Results
This section presents all the results obtained from the empirical strategy. The results of the unit
root and cointegration tests are presented initially, followed by those of the PMG and the DOLS.
Tables 2, 3 and 4 report the results of the unit root tests from Im et al. (2003), Choi (2001) and
Pesaran (2007), respectively. The null hypothesis of non stationarity (in level form) is simultane-
ously rejected by the three tests in the case of four variables (Overvalue, Private investment, Public
investment and Institutions). Thus, these variables are considered as stationary and they will only
be introduced in the short run part of the PMG and the DOLS. Therefore, the variables: Structural
change, Trade openness, Market size, Services, Financial flows, Exports, Imports, Commodities ex-
ports and Manufacturing exports are considered as first-order integrated variables. It should be
noted that the threshold of significance considered in the present tests is 1%. More precisely, we
reject the null hypothesis of non stationarity only if the p-value is less than or equal to 1%.
Table 5 presents the results of the three cointegration tests related to the combinations of vari-
ables estimated by the DOLS. The combinations of variables considered are all cointegrated because
the null hypothesis of non cointegration is rejected in all cases.16
Table 6 presents the results of the PMG estimates. The variables that are stationary in first differ-
ence are simultaneously in the long-run dynamics and in the short-run dynamics (Trade openness,
Market size, Services, Financial flows, Exports and Imports). The variables that are stationary in
level form are only in the short-run dynamics (Private investment, Public investment, Institutions,
Overvalue). In all combinations of variables, the error correction coefficients (Speed adjustment)
are negative and significant (column 1-4). Therefore, the long term relationships exist and there is a
return of variables to the long-run equilibrium.17 From columns 1 to 4, the results of the Hausman
tests are reported. Note that the Hausman test could not be applied on the complete models includ-
ing all the explanatory variables. This is because the number of iterations of MG exceeded what
our data allowed due to the high number of explanatory variables. To perform the Hausman test,
16 The Stata command (xtcointtest) that allows to run the three cointegration tests does not support more than seven
explanatory variables.
17 Note that we are only interested in the effect of the long-run dynamics of the variables of interest.
18
we applied the estimates of the PMG and the MG on two different models. The first is the model
without the share of services’ value-added in GDP and the second without the variable of financial
flows. The choice to gradually remove these two variables - in order to perform the Hausman test
- is explained by the following reason. They are the only control variables that are in both the
long-run and short-run dynamics, thus, by gradually removing them, the number of explanatory
variables is reduced so that the MG and therefore the Hausman test can be applied. From columns
1 to 4, in the two models, the p-values of the Hausman test do not reject the null hypothesis which
states that the PMG estimator is more efficient compared to the MG one. Based on the previous
conclusion, we apply the PMG on the complete model with all explanatory variables.
The first column reports the combination of variables in which trade openness is the variable of
interest. In column 1, the indicator of trade openness (in level form) negatively and significantly im-
pacts the first difference of SC. Thus, the long-term evolution of trade openness negatively impacts
the short-run dynamics of SC.
To understand the transmission channels of trade openness’ effect, we replace it by the share of
exports and that of imports in GDP. Hence, the columns 2, 3 and 4 present these effects when the
share of exports and that of imports in GDP replace the trade openness index. Column 2 considers
the combination of variables in which the share of exports in GDP is the variable of interest while
column 3 reports the combination in which the share of imports in GDP is the variable of interest.
Finally, the column 4 presents the set of variables with the share of exports and that of imports in
GDP as variables of interest. The long run dynamics of exports negatively and significantly affects
the short run dynamics of SC - columns 2 & 4 - while the long term dynamics of imports positively
and significantly impacts SC (in first difference; column 4). The coefficient of trade openness (-
.0021107) is considerably lower than those of exports (-.1527709 & -.1518654) and that of imports
(.057296). This could be explained by the fact that the trade openness indicator encompasses many
things including diversity of trading partners and trade in services in addition to trade in goods.
Moreover, the effects of exports are larger and more significant than those of imports. Therefore,
exports could be the single variable through which the negative impact of trade openness passes.
From the previous findings, it appears that trade openness negatively affects the short run
dynamics of SC and that this negative effect is driven by exports. As the PMG method allows for
studying the long run dynamic effects of trade on the short run dynamics of SC, it is important to
understand the long term dynamics of trade on the long term dynamics of SC. In this sense, the
DOLS method is applied, which also allows for good control of the endogeneity issue compared to
the PMG method.
The present subsection considers the combinations of variables estimated by the DOLS method,
these results are reported in Table 7. As in PMG, the variables that are stationary in first differ-
19
ence are simultaneously in the long term dynamics and in the short term dynamics while those
stationary in level form are only in the short run dynamics. Hence, the dependent variable is in
level form allowing to study the long run dynamics’ effects of the variables of interest on the long
term dynamics of SC. However, the short term effects of the variables in level form are automati-
cally considered in the DOLS estimates, so their coefficients will not appear in Table 7.
In the DOLS estimates, we consider the default lag (2) and the default lead (1) as well as the
default level (95). Column 1 is the combination of variables in which the trade openness indicator
corresponds to the variable of interest. From this column, it appears that the long-term evolution
of trade openness negatively and significantly affects the long-run dynamics of SC.
The transmission channels are studied in columns 2, 3 and 4. The share of exports in GDP (in
level form) negatively and significantly impacts the long term evolution of SC (columns 2 & 4) while
the share of imports in GDP has no significant effect. As explained previously, the coefficients of
exports are higher than that of trade openness.
In addition, the long term coefficients of trade openness and exports in the DOLS estimates
are higher than their long run coefficients in the PMG models. This may be explained by the fact
that the two methods have two different measures of the dependent variable. In the PMG, the first
difference of SC is the dependent variable while it is considered in level in the DOLS. Hence, this
shows that the long run dynamics of trade openness and that of exports influence more the long
term dynamics of SC than its short run evolution.
From the PMG and the DOLS estimates, the share of exports in GDP is the channel through
which trade openness affects SC. Therefore, the exports are disaggregated into commodities exports
and manufacturing exports. Table 8 presents the results of DOLS estimates when the exports of
commodities and manufacturing products are considered as variables of interest while controlling
the effects of imports. From column 2 to column 9, the commodities exports (in level form) nega-
tively and significantly affect the long run dynamics of SC while manufacturing exports positively
impact it. However, the effect of commodities exports (column 9) is more significant than that of
manufacturing exports. This could be explained by the weak industrial base of African countries.
In addition, it could explain why the overall effects of exports - the effects of total exports in GDP
- are negative. Moreover, the coefficients of manufacturing exports are higher that those of com-
modities exports showing that the magnitude of manufacturing exports is more important. In the
first column, the effect of commodities exports is positive but it becomes negative when the effect of
market size is controlled, this may be explained through the spending effect discussed in the next
subsection.
From the previous results, it appears that the negative effect of the long-run dynamics of trade
openness passes through commodities exports.
20
6.4 Theoretical discussion
Our results show that the long-run effect of trade openness on the long-term and the short-run
dynamics of SC is negative and passes through commodities exports. Therefore, trade openness is
a barrier to SC and then to industrialization in SSA. This surprising conclusion can be mainly ex-
plained by two mistakes in the industrial and trade policies. First, the post-independence industrial
policies focused on the creation of capital-intensive industries while the comparative advantage of
African countries is in labor-intensive industries. Second, trade policies of the end of the 1980s were
based on a deep specialization in the exports of raw materials without investing exports’ resources
in the development of a competitive domestic industrial sector. Indeed, SSA countries suffer from
significant infrastructure constraints, which represent significant transaction costs for the indus-
trial activities. Consequently, the return on investment in manufacturing activities will be low and
may be lower than that in import activities. Still, as a result of infrastructure constraints and the
poor business environment, the risk associated with the creation of a new industry will be high
relative to the risk associated with import activities. In this context, even with a comparative ad-
vantage in low-skilled labor-intensive industries, the entrepreneurs in SSA will prefer to import
rather than invest in the manufacturing sector. Therefore, a trade openness based on commodities
exports without a resources-investment policy will crowd out the manufacturing sector. This effect
will be amplified by the rise of GDP per capita due to commodities exports, which will increase the
domestic demand, but with a weak industrial base, the rise of the domestic demand will lead to an
increase in the demand for foreign products.
7 Concluding remarks
Economic openness has been considered by the main international institutions and many economists
as the best way for African countries to develop. Nevertheless, the situation in most of these coun-
tries does not confirm this idea. Economic development may be approximated by structural change
which illustrates a country’s ability to move from agriculture to industry. Considering the im-
portance of this subject and its consequences in terms of political economy, we studied how trade
openness has impacted the structural change. We find in this paper that trade openness has nega-
tively affected structural change in 34 SSA countries between 1970-2016, and this negative impact
goes through exports and not imports. This is explained by the fact that states in Africa have
failed to put trade policy at the service of industrialization by following the logic of comparative
advantage. More precisely, they have failed to invest the exports revenues to improve hard and soft
infrastructure in order to remove the constraints on relocation to labor-intensive manufacturing
activity.
Therefore, industrial and trade policies are the roots of this mechanism. As argued in the New
Structural Economics (Lin, 2011), the comparative advantages based on factorendowment only
21
determine the factor costs of production for an industry. The competitiveness of an industry in
domestic and international markets also depends on transaction costs, which are determined by
infrastructure and business environment, in addition to the factor costs of production. If African
governments can help reduce the transaction costs with good infrastructure and business envi-
ronment for the labor-intensive industries, African countries will be able to produce and export
labor-intensive manufacturing goods as East Asian countries have done.
References
Atolia, M., Loungani, P., Marquis, M. & Papageorgiou, C. (2020), ‘Rethinking development policy:
What remains of structural transformation?’, World Development 128, 104834.
Austin, G., Frankema, E. & Jerven, M. (2016), ‘Patterns of manufacturing growth in sub-saharan
africa: from colonization to the present’.
Bai, J. & Ng, S. (2004), ‘A panic attack on unit roots and cointegration’, Econometrica 72(4), 1127–
1177.
Bräutigam, D. & Tang, X. (2014), ‘going global in groups: Structural transformation and chinas
special economic zones overseas’, World Development 63, 78–91.
Choi, I. (2001), ‘Unit root tests for panel data’, Journal of international money and Finance
20(2), 249–272.
Choi, I. (2002), ‘Combination unit root tests for cross-sectionally correlated pannels’.
Christiaensen, L. & Todo, Y. (2014), ‘Poverty reduction during the rural–urban transformation–the
role of the missing middle’, World Development 63, 43–58.
Collier, P. & Dercon, S. (2014), ‘African agriculture in 50 years: smallholders in a rapidly changing
world?’, World development 63, 92–101.
De Brauw, A., Mueller, V. & Lee, H. L. (2014), ‘The role of rural–urban migration in the structural
transformation of sub-saharan africa’, World Development 63, 33–42.
Dorosh, P. & Thurlow, J. (2014), ‘Can cities or towns drive african development? economywide
analysis for ethiopia and uganda’, World Development 63, 113–123.
Dreher, A. (2006), ‘Does globalization affect growth? evidence from a new index of globalization’,
Applied economics 38(10), 1091–1110.
22
Gelb, A., Meyer, C. J. & Ramachandran, V. (2014), Development as diffusion: Manufacturing pro-
ductivity and sub-saharan africa’s missing middle, Technical report, World Institute for Develop-
ment Economic Research (UNU-WIDER).
Gui-Diby, S. L. & Renard, M.-F. (2015), ‘Foreign direct investment inflows and the industrialization
of african countries’, World Development 74, 43–57.
Gygli, S., Haelg, F., Potrafke, N. & Sturm, J.-E. (2019), ‘The kof globalisation index–revisited’, The
Review of International Organizations 14(3), 543–574.
Hadri, K. (1999), Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root in
panel data with serially correlated errors, Technical report, University of Liverpool, Department
of Economics.
Harris, R. D. & Tzavalis, E. (1999), ‘Inference for unit roots in dynamic panels where the time
dimension is fixed’, Journal of econometrics 91(2), 201–226.
Harrison, A. E., Lin, J. Y. & Xu, L. C. (2014), ‘Explaining africas (dis) advantage’, World Develop-
ment 63, 59–77.
Herrendorf, B., Rogerson, R. & Valentinyi, Á. (2014), Growth and structural transformation, in
‘Handbook of economic growth’, Vol. 2, Elsevier, pp. 855–941.
Hurlin, C. & Mignon, V. (2005), ‘Une synthèse des tests de racine unitaire sur données de panel’,
Economie prevision 169(3), 253–294.
Im, K. S., Pesaran, M. H. & Shin, Y. (2003), ‘Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels’, Journal
of econometrics 115(1), 53–74.
Jensen, R. (2007), ‘The digital provide: Information (technology), market performance, and welfare
in the south indian fisheries sector’, The quarterly journal of economics 122(3), 879–924.
Kang, S. J. & Lee, H. (2011), ‘Foreign direct investment and de-industrialisation’, The World Econ-
omy 34(2), 313–329.
Kao, C. (1999), ‘Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel data’, Jour-
nal of econometrics 90(1), 1–44.
Kao, C. & Chiang, M. (2000), ‘On the inference of a cointegrating regression in panel data’, Advances
in econometrics 15(1), 179–222.
Kose, M. A., Prasad, E. S. & Terrones, M. E. (2009), ‘Does openness to international financial flows
raise productivity growth?’, Journal of International Money and Finance 28(4), 554–580.
23
Kuznets, S. & Murphy, J. T. (1966), Modern economic growth: Rate, structure, and spread, Vol. 2,
Yale University Press New Haven.
Levin, A. & Lin, C.-F. (1993), ‘Unit root tests in panel data’, Dept. of Economics, University of
California-San Diego .
Levin, A., Lin, C.-F. & Chu, C.-S. J. (2002), ‘Unit root tests in panel data: asymptotic and finite-
sample properties’, Journal of econometrics 108(1), 1–24.
Lewis, W. A. (1954), ‘Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour’, The manchester
school 22(2), 139–191.
Lin, J. Y. (2009), Economic development and transition: thought, strategy, and viability, Cambridge
university press.
Lin, J. Y. (2011), ‘New structural economics: A framework for rethinking development’, The World
Bank Research Observer 26(2), 193–221.
Lin, J. Y. (2012), ‘From flying geese to leading dragons: New opportunities and strategies for struc-
tural transformation in developing countries 1’, Global Policy 3(4), 397–409.
Maddala, G. S. & Wu, S. (1999), ‘A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and a new
simple test’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and statistics 61(S1), 631–652.
McMillan, M., Rodrik, D. & Verduzco-Gallo, Í. (2014), ‘Globalization, structural change, and pro-
ductivity growth, with an update on africa’, World Development 63(63), 11–32.
McMillan, M. S. & Harttgen, K. (2014), What is driving the’african growth miracle’?, Technical
report, National Bureau of Economic Research.
McMillan, M. S. & Rodrik, D. (2011), Globalization, structural change and productivity growth,
Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Mehlum, H., Moene, K. & Torvik, R. (2006), ‘Cursed by resources or institutions?’, World Economy
29(8), 1117–1131.
Meier, G. M., Steel, W. F. & Carroll, R. J. (1989), Industrial Adjustment in Sub-Saharan Africa,
World Bank.
Mignon, V. & Hurlin, C. (2005), ‘Une synthèse des tests de racine unitaire sur données de panel’,
Economie & prévision 169(3), 253–294.
Mignon, V. & Hurlin, C. (2007), ‘Une synthèse des tests de cointégration sur données de panel’,
Économie & prévision 180(4), 241–265.
24
Moon, H. R. & Perron, B. (2004), ‘Testing for a unit root in panels with dynamic factors’, Journal of
econometrics 122(1), 81–126.
Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A. & Vishny, R. (1989a), ‘Income distribution, market size, and industrial-
ization’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 104(3), 537–564.
Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A. & Vishny, R. W. (1989b), ‘Industrialization and the big push’, Journal of
political economy 97(5), 1003–1026.
Newman, C., Page, J., Rand, J., Shimeles, A., Söderbom, M. & Tarp, F. (2016), Made in Africa:
Learning to compete in industry, Brookings Institution Press.
Page, J. (1994), ‘The east asian miracle: four lessons for development policy’, NBER macroeconomics
annual 9, 219–269.
Page, J., Tarp, F., Rand, J., Shimeles, A., Newman, C. & Söderbom, M. (2016), Manufacturing trans-
formation: comparative studies of industrial development in Africa and emerging Asia, Oxford
University Press.
Pedroni, P. (1999), ‘Critical values for cointegration tests in heterogeneous panels with multiple
regressors’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and statistics 61(S1), 653–670.
Pesaran, M. H. (2007), ‘A simple panel unit root test in the presence of cross-section dependence’,
Journal of applied econometrics 22(2), 265–312.
Phillips, P. C. & Sul, D. (2003), ‘Dynamic panel estimation and homogeneity testing under cross
section dependence’, The Econometrics Journal 6(1), 217–259.
Rodrik, D. (1995), ‘Getting interventions right: how south korea and taiwan grew rich’, Economic
policy 10(20), 53–107.
Rodrik, D. (2008), ‘The real exchange rate and economic growth’, Brookings papers on economic
activity 2008(2), 365–412.
Rodrik, D. (2016a), ‘An african growth miracle?’, Journal of African Economies 27(1), 10–27.
Rodrik, D. (2018), New technologies, global value chains, and developing economies, Technical re-
port, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Rowthorn, R. & Ramaswamy, R. (1999), ‘Growth, trade, and deindustrialization’, IMF Staff papers
46(1), 18–41.
25
Suri, T. & Jack, W. (2016), ‘The long-run poverty and gender impacts of mobile money’, Science
354(6317), 1288–1292.
Wade, R. (2004), Governing the market: Economic theory and the role of government in East Asian
industrialization, Princeton University Press.
Westerlund, J. (2005), ‘New simple tests for panel cointegration’, Econometric Reviews 24(3), 297–
316.
Level Difference
W-t-bar P-value W-t-bar P-value
Structural change -2.6254 0.0043 -23.6074 0.0000
Trade openness -2.9560 0.0016 -34.6986 0.0000
Market size 0.9099 0.8186 -25.5303 0.0000
Overvalue -3.2581 0.0006 -28.8503 0.0000
Private investment -6.0642 0.0000 -32.6232 0.0000
Public investment -5.0098 0.0000 -36.0397 0.0000
Financial flows -0.2749 0.3917 -33.2385 0.0000
Institutions -3.9899 0.0000 -30.2068 0.0000
Exports -1.3713 0.0851 -37.5976 0.0000
Imports -1.7427 0.0407 -31.7554 0.0000
Commodities exports 3.6320 0.9999 -18.1607 0.0000
Manufacturing exports 1.4972 0.9328 -20.1674 0.0000
Services -1.4104 0.0792 -34.1483 0.0000
Cross-sectional means removed; Trend: included; ADF regressions: lags average (chosen by AIC)
26
Table 3: Unit root tests of Choi (2001)
Level Difference
Inverse chi-squared(68) P-value Inverse chi-squared(68) P-value
Structural change 89.6186 0.0407 459.7901 0.0000
Trade openness 83.3658 0.0992 720.5550 0.0000
Market size 59.3147 0.7646 420.8672 0.0000
Overvalue 119.8320 0.0001 656.7123 0.0000
Private investment 172.0334 0.0000 768.7588 0.0000
Public investment 120.9433 0.0001 687.9636 0.0000
Financial flows 63.0972 0.6456 626.8327 0.0000
Institutions 125.4033 0.0000 622.5646 0.0000
Exports 55.4213 0.8633 594.8207 0.0000
Imports 93.7159 0.0211 684.0933 0.0000
Commodities exports 27.7861 1.0000 204.5625 0.0000
Manufacturing exports 52.2547 0.9211 272.6022 0.0000
Services 74.8380 0.2661 651.9471 0.0000
Cross-sectional means removed; Trend: included; ADF regressions: lags average (1)
Level Difference
Z[t-bar] P-value Z[t-bar] P-value
Structural change -0.120 0.452 -16.820 0.000
Trade openness -0.698 0.242 -16.924 0.000
Market size -3.294 0.000 -15.310 0.000
Overvalue -3.753 0.000 -17.835 0.000
Private investment -5.889 0.000 -18.776 0.000
Public investment -2.356 0.009 -17.386 0.000
Financial flows -1.366 0.086 -17.598 0.000
Institutions -4.534 0.000 -18.936 0.000
Exports -0.976 0.165 -16.934 0.000
Imports -1.914 0.028 -17.236 0.000
Commodities exports -0.213 0.416 -6.822 0.000
Manufacturing exports -0.829 0.203 -8.304 0.000
Services -1.234 0.109 -17.197 0.000
27
Table 5: Cointegration tests
Statistic P-value
Cointegration tests of Table 7 (Kao. 1999)
Column 1 -8.1157 0.0000
28
Table 6: Results of pooled mean group regression (Trade, Exports and Imports=variables of inter-
est). Dependent variable=Structural Change (SC) in first difference
Long term
Trade openness -0.0021107***
(0.0004399)
Market size 0.0001805*** 0.0001462*** 0.0002058*** 0.0001472***
(0.0000181) (0.0000145) (0.0000201) (0.0000147)
Services 0.0844419*** 0.0475774 0.1138835** 0.0800284**
(0.0295534) (0.037624) (0.0538892) (0.0383079)
Financial flows -0.0005264 -0.0009145***-0.0021849***-0.0011364***
(0.0004532) (0.0003329) (0.0004745) (0.0003395)
Exports -0.1527709*** -0.1518654***
(0.0502625) (0.0520921)
Imports 0.0532131 0.057296*
(0.0484063) (0.0337941)
Short term
D.Trade openness 0.0009553
(0.0007692)
D.Market Size -0.0000439 -0.0000289 -0.0000521 -0.0000292
(0.0001249) (0.0001065) (0.0000988) (0.0000961)
D.Private investment 0.0058382 0.0065547 0.0041486 0.005646
(0.0056816) (0.0055025) (0.0063938) (0.0071945)
D.Public investment 0.0538132 0.052118 0.0535493 0.0520154
(0.0537545) (0.0531388) (0.0533028) (0.0529558)
D.Institutions 0.0183557 0.0186742 0.0163783 0.0150417
(0.0149779) (0.0171489) (0.0150384) (0.0167394)
D.Overvalue 0.4233416 0.3820578 0.5339482 0.438734
(0.6543199) (0.6740034) (0.5998952) (0.6139992)
D.Services 1.342541 1.529346 1.382024 1.588423
(1.016762) (1.179363) (1.146947) (1.310509)
D.Financial flows 0.0012726 0.000986 0.0022509* 0.0014937*
(0.0011705) (0.0008384) (0.0013581) (0.0009013)
D.Exports 0.4697152 0.480681*
(0.298485) (0.2713108)
D.Imports 0.4010649 0.3225534
(0.2662685) (0.2508033)
Long term
Trade openness -0.0076458**
(.0032351)
Market size 0.0006705*** 0.0006917*** 0.0006687*** 0.0006995***
(0.0000275) (0.0000275) (0.0000274) (0.0000272)
Services 1.974076*** 1.56599*** 1.871118*** 1.440138
(0.4477717) (0.4603088) (0.4448313) (0.4569518)
Financial flows 0.0001524 0.0003297 -0.006175** -0.0003084
(0.0034178) (0.0032161) (0.0031567) (0.0031748)
Exports -0.8502828** -0.9987805***
(0.3342852) (0.3491011)
Imports 0.2654616 0.416993
(0.2630464) (0.2771208)
Short term
D.Private investment -0.0077444 -0.0099882* -0.0076349 -0.010517
(0.0057618) (0.0057713) (0.0057411) (0.005726)
D.Public investment -0.0032855 -0.0055682 -0.0068059 -0.0059569
(0.0077747) (0.0077907) (0.0077212) 0.0076903
D.Institutions -0.0143746 -0.0181957 -0.0087786 -0.0161653
(0.0114702) (0.0115031) 0.0113962 (0.0113553)
D.Overvalue -0.481386 -0.3757975 -0.5972287 -0.4780664
(0.4713986) (0.4722814) (0.4683098) (0.4664018)
30
Table 8: Results of dynamic ordinary least squares (Commodities exports and Manufacturing exports=variables of interest). Dependent vari-
able=Structural Change (SC)
Long term
Commodities exports 7.461784*** -2.500147*** -2.356291** -2.330151** -2.350349** -2.342119** -2.886397*** -2.673329*** -3.104344**
(1.300944) (0.7617856) (0.9779092) (0.977993) (0.9787037) (0.9850031) (0.9675338) (0.9611609) (0.9951719)
Manufacturing exports 8.92155* 5.646871** 5.698859** 5.737565** 5.71137** 5.581255** 6.169063** 6.790427** 4.967643*
(4.874452) (2.272052) (2.691295) (2.702651) (2.7028) (2.73495) (2.686608) (2.666392) (2.680079)
Market size 0.0007507*** 0.0007586*** 0.0007589*** 0.000759*** 0.000768 0.0007868*** 0.0007846*** 0.000799
(0.0000472) (0.0000617) (0.0000617) (0.0000617) (0.0000622) (0.0000614) (0.0000618) (0.0000622)
Services -1.103008 -1.061427 -1.352422
(1.224092) (1.213779) (1.221038)
Financial flows -0.0047392 -0.0078099
31
(0.0079871) (0.0080082)
Imports 1.163895*
(0.6892334)
Short term
D.Private investment -0.0229423* -0.0186855 -0.020132 -0.019114 -0.0103941 -0.0072953 -0.0240858*
(0.0131471) (0.0133312) (0.013382) (0.0134687) (0.0133931) (0.0132792) (0.0133311)
D.Public investment -0.0103331 -0.0104343 -0.009962 -0.011885 -0.0162152 -0.0114526
(0.0187076) (0.0187109) (0.0188322) (0.0184968) (0.0183593) (0.0183615)
D.Institutions -0.0620709* -0.055355* -0.0548493* -0.055315* -0.0547462*
(0.0321339) (0.0323455) (0.0318085) (0.0315354) (0.0315467)
D.Overvalue 0.7724858 0.7832072 0.5960143 0.0008766
(1.007958) (0.9899629) (0.9882157) (0.9887854)
32
Table 9: The Structure of Manufacturing Employment 2000-2015
Paper and paper products 2.00 Wood products (excl. furniture) 5.78
Tobacco products 3.49 Fabricated metal products 11.29
Leather. leather products and footwear 3.64 Rubber and plastics products 13.95
Fabricated metal products 5.11 Paper and paper products 20.95
Furniture; manufacturing n.e.c. 6.16 Food and beverages 22.60
Wood products (excl. furniture) 6.86 Furniture; manufacturing n.e.c. 23.41
Rubber and plastics products 8.05 Leather. leather products and footwear 31.05
Wearing apparel. fur 10.54 Tobacco products 38.92
Textiles 10.68 Textiles 48.05
Food and beverages 30.85 Wearing apparel. fur 89.11
Medical. precision and optical instruments .10 Coke.refined petroleum products.nuclear fuel 6.50
Office. accounting and computing machinery .12 Medical. precision and optical instruments 10.92
Radio.television and communication equipment.12 Electrical machinery and apparatus 18.79
Coke.refined petroleum products.nuclear fuel .39 Office. accounting and computing machinery 33.64
Electrical machinery and apparatus .74 Radio.television and communication equipment76.22
33
Figure 2: Trade Concentration in the world regions
34
Table 10: List of Country
Country Country
Benin Guinea-Bissau
Botswana Kenya
Burkina Faso Lesotho
Burundi Malawi
Cabo Verde Mali
Cameroon Mauritania
Central African Republic Mozambique
Chad Niger
Congo. Rep. Nigeria
Cote d’Ivoire Rwanda
Equatorial Guinea Senegal
Eswatini Sierra Leone
Ethiopia South Africa
Gabon Tanzania
Gambia. The Togo
Ghana Zambia
Guinea Zimbabwe
35