Powell 20240823 A
Powell 20240823 A
Powell 20240823 A
Remarks by
Jerome H. Powell
Chair
at
economic distortions are fading. Inflation has declined significantly. The labor market is
no longer overheated, and conditions are now less tight than those that prevailed before
the pandemic. Supply constraints have normalized. And the balance of the risks to our
two mandates has changed. Our objective has been to restore price stability while
maintaining a strong labor market, avoiding the sharp increases in unemployment that
characterized earlier disinflationary episodes when inflation expectations were less well
anchored. While the task is not complete, we have made a good deal of progress toward
that outcome.
Today, I will begin by addressing the current economic situation and the path
ahead for monetary policy. I will then turn to a discussion of economic events since the
pandemic arrived, exploring why inflation rose to levels not seen in a generation, and
Let’s begin with the current situation and the near-term outlook for policy.
For much of the past three years, inflation ran well above our 2 percent goal, and
labor market conditions were extremely tight. The Federal Open Market Committee’s
(FOMC) primary focus has been on bringing down inflation, and appropriately so. Prior
to this episode, most Americans alive today had not experienced the pain of high inflation
for a sustained period. Inflation brought substantial hardship, especially for those least
-2-
able to meet the higher costs of essentials like food, housing, and transportation. High
Our restrictive monetary policy helped restore balance between aggregate supply
and demand, easing inflationary pressures and ensuring that inflation expectations
remained well anchored. Inflation is now much closer to our objective, with prices
having risen 2.5 percent over the past 12 months (figure 1). 2 After a pause earlier this
year, progress toward our 2 percent objective has resumed. My confidence has grown
Turning to employment, in the years just prior to the pandemic, we saw the
significant benefits to society that can come from a long period of strong labor market
gaps, and, with inflation low and stable, healthy real wage gains that were increasingly
Today, the labor market has cooled considerably from its formerly overheated
state. The unemployment rate began to rise over a year ago and is now at 4.3 percent—
still low by historical standards, but almost a full percentage point above its level in early
2023 (figure 2). Most of that increase has come over the past six months. So far, rising
1
Shiller (1997) and Stantcheva (2024) study why people dislike inflation. Pfafjar and Winkler (2024)
study households’ attitudes toward inflation and unemployment. Binetti, Nuzzi, and Stantcheva (2024)
investigate households’ attitudes toward, and understanding of, inflation. Kaplan and Schulhofer-Wohl
(2017) and Jaravel (2021) document heterogeneity in the inflation rate experienced by households across
the income distribution.
2
The data for the personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index is available for June 2024. Over
the 12 months to June 2024, the PCE price index increased 2.5 percent. Data for the consumer price index
and producer price index are available through July 2024 and can be used to estimate the level of the PCE
price index through July. While such an estimate is subject to uncertainty, it suggests that inflation
remained near 2.5 percent through July.
3
Research documenting such benefits include Aaronson and others (2019), who discuss the experience in
the 2010s and review related historical evidence.
-3-
unemployment has not been the result of elevated layoffs, as is typically the case in an
economic downturn. Rather, the increase mainly reflects a substantial increase in the
supply of workers and a slowdown from the previously frantic pace of hiring. Even so,
the cooling in labor market conditions is unmistakable. Job gains remain solid but have
slowed this year. 4 Job vacancies have fallen, and the ratio of vacancies to unemployment
has returned to its pre-pandemic range. The hiring and quits rates are now below the
levels that prevailed in 2018 and 2019. Nominal wage gains have moderated. All told,
labor market conditions are now less tight than just before the pandemic in 2019—a year
when inflation ran below 2 percent. It seems unlikely that the labor market will be a
Overall, the economy continues to grow at a solid pace. But the inflation and
labor market data show an evolving situation. The upside risks to inflation have
in our last FOMC statement, we are attentive to the risks to both sides of our dual
mandate.
The time has come for policy to adjust. The direction of travel is clear, and the
timing and pace of rate cuts will depend on incoming data, the evolving outlook, and the
balance of risks.
4
Payroll employment grew by an average of 170,000 per month over the three months ending in July. On
August 21, the Bureau of Labor Statistics released the preliminary estimate of the upcoming annual
benchmark revision to the establishment survey data, which will be issued in February 2025. The
preliminary estimate indicates a downward adjustment to March 2024 total nonfarm employment of
818,000.
-4-
progress toward price stability. With an appropriate dialing back of policy restraint, there
is good reason to think that the economy will get back to 2 percent inflation while
maintaining a strong labor market. The current level of our policy rate gives us ample
room to respond to any risks we may face, including the risk of unwelcome further
Let’s now turn to the questions of why inflation rose, and why it has fallen so
research on these questions, and this is a good time for this discussion. 5 It is, of course,
too soon to make definitive assessments. This period will be analyzed and debated long
around the world. It was a time of radical uncertainty and severe downside risks. As so
responded with extraordinary force, especially in the U.S. Congress unanimously passed
the CARES Act. At the Fed, we used our powers to an unprecedented extent to stabilize
After a historically deep but brief recession, in mid-2020 the economy began to
grow again. As the risks of a severe, extended downturn receded, and as the economy
5
Early examples include Ball, Leigh, and Mishra (2022) and di Giovanni and others (2022). More recent
work includes Benigno and Eggertsson (2023, 2024), Blanchard and Bernanke (2023, 2024), Crump and
others (2024), Bai and others (2024), and Dao and others (forthcoming).
-5-
reopened, we faced the risk of replaying the painfully slow recovery that followed the
Congress delivered substantial additional fiscal support in late 2020 and again in
early 2021. Spending recovered strongly in the first half of 2021. The ongoing pandemic
shaped the pattern of the recovery. Lingering concerns over COVID weighed on
changes in work and leisure practices, and the additional savings associated with
goods.
The pandemic also wreaked havoc on supply conditions. Eight million people left
the workforce at its onset, and the size of the labor force was still 4 million below its pre-
pandemic level in early 2021. The labor force would not return to its pre-pandemic trend
until mid-2023 (figure 3). 6 Supply chains were snarled by a combination of lost workers,
disrupted international trade linkages, and tectonic shifts in the composition and level of
demand (figure 4). Clearly, this was nothing like the slow recovery after the Global
Financial Crisis.
Enter inflation. After running below target through 2020, inflation spiked in
March and April 2021. The initial burst of inflation was concentrated rather than broad
based, with extremely large price increases for goods in short supply, such as motor
6
The Federal Reserve Board staff’s estimate of the labor force makes two adjustments to the Bureau of
Labor Statistics’ published estimates: (i) reweighing Current Population Survey respondents such that the
labor force estimates in all years reflect the Census Bureau’s latest vintage of population estimates; and (ii)
accounting for net immigration that is likely not fully reflected in the Census Bureau’s latest population
estimates, as detailed in the CBO’s 2024 Demographic Outlook (see
https://www.cbo.gov/publication/59899). The pre-pandemic trend described here is calculated by
appending the CBO’s January 2020 projected labor force growth from the start of the pandemic through
2024:Q2 onto the level of the labor force just before the start of the pandemic. (See Congressional Budget
Office (2020), The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2020 to 2030; https://www.cbo.gov/publication/56073.)
-6-
vehicles. My colleagues and I judged at the outset that these pandemic-related factors
would not be persistent and, thus, that the sudden rise in inflation was likely to pass
through fairly quickly without the need for a monetary policy response—in short, that the
inflation would be transitory. Standard thinking has long been that, as long as inflation
expectations remain well anchored, it can be appropriate for central banks to look through
The good ship Transitory was a crowded one, with most mainstream analysts and
advanced-economy central bankers on board. 8 The common expectation was that supply
conditions would improve reasonably quickly, that the rapid recovery in demand would
run its course, and that demand would rotate back from goods to services, bringing
inflation down.
For a time, the data were consistent with the transitory hypothesis. Monthly
readings for core inflation declined every month from April to September 2021, although
progress came slower than expected (figure 5). The case began to weaken around
midyear, as was reflected in our communications. Beginning in October, the data turned
hard against the transitory hypothesis. 9 Inflation rose and broadened out from goods into
7
For example, former Chair Ben Bernanke and Olivier Blanchard summarize the standard approach in their
work on inflation the following way: “Standard central banking doctrine holds that, so long as inflation
expectations are reasonably well anchored, there is a case for ‘looking through’ temporary supply shocks
rather than responding to the short-run increase in inflation” (Blanchard and Bernanke, 2024, p. 2). Clarida
(forthcoming) notes how central banks around the world faced a sharp rise in the relative price of goods
and chose, at least initially, to accommodate the price pressures with an expected transitory increase in
inflation.
8
In the September 2021 Summary of Economic Projections (SEP), the median projection for headline
inflation in 2022 was 2.2 percent. In the August 2021 Survey of Professional Forecasters (the closest
survey to the September SEP), the median projection for headline inflation in 2022 was also 2.2 percent.
Projections from the Blue Chip survey were similar around this time.
9
Beginning with the data for October, readings for monthly core PCE jumped to 0.4 percent or higher and
inflationary pressures broadened out across goods and services categories. And monthly job gains, already
strong, were consistently revised higher over the second half of 2021. Measures of wage inflation also
accelerated.
-7-
services. It became clear that the high inflation was not transitory, and that it would
require a strong policy response if inflation expectations were to remain well anchored.
tighten. After phasing out our asset purchases, we lifted off in March 2022.
By early 2022, headline inflation exceeded 6 percent, with core inflation above
5 percent. New supply shocks appeared. Russia’s invasion of Ukraine led to a sharp
increase in energy and commodity prices. The improvements in supply conditions and
rotation in demand from goods to services were taking much longer than expected, in part
due to further COVID waves in the U.S. 10 And COVID continued to disrupt production
experiences: rapid increases in the demand for goods, strained supply chains, tight labor
markets, and sharp hikes in commodity prices. 12 The global nature of inflation was
unlike any period since the 1970s. Back then, high inflation became entrenched—an
By mid-2022, the labor market was extremely tight, with employment increasing
by over 6½ million from the middle of 2021. This increase in labor demand was met, in
part, by workers rejoining the labor force as health concerns began to fade. But labor
supply remained constrained, and, in the summer of 2022, labor force participation
10
For example, labor supply continued to be materially affected by COVID even after vaccines became
broadly available in the U.S. By late 2021, anticipated increases in labor force participation had not yet
materialized, likely owing, in part, to the rise of the Delta and Omicron COVID variants.
11
For example, in March 2022, lockdowns were imposed in the Jilin province, the largest center for auto
production. Authorities also ramped up or extended restrictions in manufacturing hubs in the southeast and
in Shanghai, where lockdowns had initially been scheduled to end in April 2022.
12
The global nature of this inflationary episode is emphasized in Cascaldi-Garcia and others (2024) and
Clarida (forthcoming), among others.
-8-
remained well below pre-pandemic levels. There were nearly twice as many job
openings as unemployed persons from March 2022 through the end of the year, signaling
a severe labor shortage (figure 6). 13 Inflation peaked at 7.1 percent in June 2022.
At this podium two years ago, I discussed the possibility that addressing inflation
could bring some pain in the form of higher unemployment and slower growth. Some
argued that getting inflation under control would require a recession and a lengthy period
The FOMC did not flinch from carrying out our responsibilities, and our actions
policy rate by 425 basis points in 2022 and another 100 basis points in 2023. We have
held our policy rate at its current restrictive level since July 2023 (figure 7).
The summer of 2022 proved to be the peak of inflation. The 4-1/2 percentage
point decline in inflation from its peak two years ago has occurred in a context of low
How did inflation fall without a sharp rise in unemployment above its estimated
natural rate?
energy and commodity markets, were important drivers of high inflation, and their
13
It has been argued that the natural rate of unemployment had risen, and that the unemployment rate was
less informative about tightness in labor market than other measures such as those involving vacancies. For
example, see Crump and others (2024). More generally, research has emphasized that the unemployment
rate and the ratio of vacancies to unemployment often provide similar signals, but the signals differed in the
pandemic period, and the ratio of vacancies to unemployment is a better overall indicator. For example,
see Ball, Leigh, and Mishra (2022) and Benigno and Eggertsson (2023, 2024).
14
For example, Ball, Leigh, and Mishra (2022) and Cecchetti and others (2023) present analyses
emphasizing that disinflation would require economic slack.
-9-
reversal has been a key part of the story of its decline. The unwinding of these factors
took much longer than expected but ultimately played a large role in the subsequent
pressures while allowing growth to continue at a healthy pace. As labor demand also
layoffs, bringing the labor market to a state where it is no longer a source of inflationary
pressures.
models have long reflected the view that inflation will return to its objective when
product and labor markets are balanced—without the need for economic slack—so long
as inflation expectations are anchored at our objective. That’s what the models said, but
the stability of longer-run inflation expectations since the 2000s had not been tested by a
persistent burst of high inflation. It was far from assured that the inflation anchor would
hold. Concerns over de-anchoring contributed to the view that disinflation would require
slack in the economy and specifically in the labor market. An important takeaway from
bank actions, can facilitate disinflation without the need for slack.
collision between overheated and temporarily distorted demand and constrained supply.
While researchers differ in their approaches and, to some extent, in their conclusions, a
consensus seems to be emerging, which I see as attributing most of the rise in inflation to
- 10 -
this collision. 15 All told, the healing from pandemic distortions, our efforts to moderate
aggregate demand, and the anchoring of expectations have worked together to put
Disinflation while preserving labor market strength is only possible with anchored
inflation expectations, which reflect the public’s confidence that the central bank will
bring about 2 percent inflation over time. That confidence has been built over decades
Conclusion
unlike any other, and that there remains much to be learned from this extraordinary
period. Our Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy emphasizes
our commitment to reviewing our principles and making appropriate adjustments through
a thorough public review every five years. As we begin this process later this year, we
will be open to criticism and new ideas, while preserving the strengths of our framework.
The limits of our knowledge—so clearly evident during the pandemic—demand humility
and a questioning spirit focused on learning lessons from the past and applying them
15
Blanchard and Bernanke (2023) use a traditional (flexible) Phillips curve approach to reach this
conclusion for the U.S. Blanchard and Bernanke (2024) and Dao and others (forthcoming) examine a
broader set of countries using similar approaches. Di Giovanni and others (2022) and Bai and others
(2024) use different techniques and emphasize supply constraints and shocks in the increase in inflation
over 2021 and 2022.
- 11 -
References
Aaronson, Stephanie R., Mary C. Daly, William L. Wascher, and David W. Wilcox
(2019). “Okun Revisited: Who Benefits Most from a Strong Economy,” Finance
and Economics Discussion Series 2019-072. Washington: Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, September,
http://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2019.072.
Bai, Xiwen, Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde, Yiliang Li, and Francesco Zanetti (2024). “The
Causal Effects of Global Supply Chain Disruptions on Macroeconomic
Outcomes: Evidence and Theory,” NBER Working Paper Series 32098.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, February,
https://www.nber.org/papers/w32098.
Ball, Laurence, Daniel Leigh, and Prachi Mishra (2022). “Understanding US Inflation
during the COVID-19 Era,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall, pp. 1–
54, https://www.brookings.edu/articles/understanding-u-s-inflation-during-the-
covid-era.
Benigno, Pierpaolo, and Gauti B. Eggertsson (2023). “It’s Baaack: The Surge in
Inflation in the 2020s and the Return of the Non-Linear Phillips Curve,” NBER
Working Paper Series 31197. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research, April, https://www.nber.org/papers/w31197.
——— (2024). “Insights from the 2020s Inflation Surge: A Tale of Two Curves,” paper
presented at “Reassessing the Effectiveness and Transmission of Monetary
Policy,” a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
held in Jackson Hole, Wyo., August 22–24.
Blanchard, Olivier. J., and Ben S. Bernanke (2023). “What Caused the US Pandemic-Era
Inflation?” NBER Working Paper Series 31417. Cambridge, Mass.: National
Bureau of Economic Research, June, http://www.nber.org/papers/w31417.
Cecchetti, Stephen G., Michael E. Feroli, Peter Hooper, Frederic S. Mishkin, and Kermit
L. Schoenholtz (2023). “Managing Disinflations,” paper presented at the U.S.
Monetary Policy Forum, New York, February 24.
Crump, Richard K., Stefano Eusepi, Marc Giannoni, and Ayşegül Şahin, (2024). “The
Unemployment–Inflation Trade-Off Revisited: The Phillips Curve in COVID
Times,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 145, Supplement (July), 103580.
Dao, Mai Chi, Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, Daniel Leigh, and Prachi Mishra
(forthcoming). “Understanding the International Rise and Fall of Inflation since
2020,” Journal of Monetary Economics.
Kaplan, Greg, and Sam Schulhofer-Wohl (2017). “Inflation at the Household Level,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 91 (November), pp. 19–38.
Pfajfar, Damjan, and Fabian Winkler (2024). “Households’ Preferences over Inflation
and Monetary Policy Tradeoffs,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series
2024-036. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
May, https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2024.036.
Shiller, Robert J. (1997). “Why Do People Dislike Inflation?” in Christina D. Romer and
David H. Romer, eds., Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, pp. 13–65.
7 7
6 6
5 5
4 4
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Note: The data are monthly and extend through July 2024. The data for July 2024 are estimates based on consumer price index
and producer price index data. The outlined shaded bar indicates a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau
of Economic Research: February 2020-April 2020. PCE is personal consumption expenditures. The dashed line is at the 2 percent
longer-run inflation target.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, PCE, via Haver Analytics.
Figure 2
8 8 6 6
7 7 5 5
6 6 4 4
5 5 3 3
4 4 2 2
3 3 1 1
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Note: The data are monthly and extend through July 2024. The outlined Note: The data are monthly and extend through June 2024. Rates are
shaded bar indicates a period of business recession as defined by the measured as percent of private employment. The outlined shaded bar
National Bureau of Economic Research: February 2020-April 2020. The indicates a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of
unemployment rate peaked at 14.8 percent in April 2020. Unemployment Economic Research: February 2020-April 2020.
rates for April-July 2020 are omitted for readability. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
Figure 3
Millions
172 172
Staff estimate
Pre-pandemic trend
170 170
168 168
166 166
164 164
162 162
160 160
158 158
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Note: Quarterly and seasonally adjusted data extending through 2024:Q2. The black line is a Federal Reserve Board staff
estimate of the labor force, making two adjustments to the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ published estimates: (i) reweighing Current
Population Survey respondents such that the labor force estimates in all years reflect the Census Bureau’s latest population
estimates; and (ii) accounting for net immigration that is likely not fully reflected in the Census Bureau’s latest population estimates,
as detailed in the Congressional Budget Office’s (CBO) The Demographic Outlook: 2024 to 2054, https://www.cbo.gov/publication/59899.
The pre-pandemic trend is calculated by appending the CBO’s January 2020 projected labor force growth from the start of the
pandemic through 2024:Q2 onto the level of the labor force just before the start of the pandemic. The outlined shaded bar indicates
a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research: February 2020-April 2020.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics; CBO; Federal Reserve Board staff calculations.
Figure 4
4 4
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0
-1 -1
-2 -2
0.7 0.7
0.6 0.6
0.5 0.5
0.4 0.4
0.3 0.3
0.2 0.2
0.1 0.1
-0.0 -0.0
-0.1 -0.1
-0.2 -0.2
-0.3 -0.3
-0.4 -0.4
2020 2021
Note: The data are monthly and extend through December 2021. PCE is personal consumption expenditures. The gray outlined
shaded bar indicates a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research: February 2020-
April 2020. The light-green outlined shaded region highlights the period from April 2021 to September 2021.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, PCE, via Haver Analytics.
Figure 6
Ratio
2.5 2.5
2.0 2.0
1.5 1.5
1.0 1.0
0.5 0.5
0.0 0.0
Percent
6 6
5 5
4 4
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0