Farm-Management-Notes-Sudhakar-Tripathy-6th-Semester-2
Farm-Management-Notes-Sudhakar-Tripathy-6th-Semester-2
Farm-Management-Notes-Sudhakar-Tripathy-6th-Semester-2
(Farm Management)
Credit Hours:1 + 1=2
Semester:VI
Prepared by
Dr Sudhakar Tripathy
Department of Agricultural Economics, MSSOA, CUTM, PKD, ODISHA.INDIA
Lecture 1
Production Economics-Meaning & Definition, Nature and
Scope of Agricultural Production Economics
Agricultural Economics
As a separate discipline, agricultural economics started only in the beginning of 20th
century when economic issues pertaining to agriculture aroused interest at several
educational centres. The depression of 1890s that wrecked havoc in agriculture at many
places forced organized farmers groups to take keen interest in farm management
problems. The study and teaching of agricultural economics was started at Harvard
University (USA) in 1903 by Professor Thomas Nixon Carver. Agricultural economics
may be defined as the application of principles and methods of economics to study the
problems of agriculture to get maximum output and profits from the use of resources that
are limited for the well being of the society in general and farming industry in particular.
Agriculture sector has undergone a sea change over time from being subsistence in
nature in early stages to the present day online high-tech agribusiness. It is no more
confined to production at the farm level. The storage, processing and distribution of
agricultural products involve an array of agribusiness industries. Initially, agricultural
economics studied the cost and returns for farm enterprises and emphasized the study of
management problems on farms. But now it encompasses a host of activities related to
farm management, agricultural marketing, agricultural finance and accounting,
agricultural trade and laws, contract farming, etc.
Objectives
1. To determine and outline the conditions that give the optimum use of capital,
labour, land and management resources in the production of crops, livestock and
allied enterprises.
2. To determine the extent to which the existing use of resources deviates from the
optimum use.
3. To analyse the forces which condition the existing production pattern and
resource use.
4. To explain the means and methods in getting from the existing use to optimum
use of resources.
Lecture 2
Agricultural Production Economics: Basic Concepts
1. Production: The process through which some goods and services called inputs are
transformed into other goods called products or output.
2. Production function: A systematic and mathematical expression of the
relationship among various quantities of inputs or input services used in the
production of a commodity and the corresponding quantities of output is called a
production function.
3. Continuous production function: This function arises for those inputs which can
be divided into smaller doses. Continuous variables can be known from
measurement, for example, seeds and fertilizers, etc.
4. Discontinuous or discrete production function: This function arises for those
inputs or work units which cannot be divided into smaller units and hence are
used in whole numbers. For example, number of ploughings, weedings and
harvestings, etc.
5. Short run production period: The planning period during which one or more of
the resources are fixed while others are variable resources. The output can be
varied only by intensive use of fixed resources. It is written as
Y=f (X1, X2 / X3…..Xn) where Y is output, X1, X2 are variable
inputs and X3…..Xn are fixed inputs.
6. Long run production period: The planning period during which all the resources
can be varied. It is written as
Y=f (X1, X2 ,…..Xn)
7. Technical coefficient: The amount of input per unit of output is called technical
coefficient.
8. Resources: Anything that aids in production is called a resource. The resources
physically enter the production process.
9. Resource services: The work done by a person, machine or livestock is called a
resource service. Resources do not enter the production process physically.
10. Fixed resources: The resources that remain unchanged irrespective of the level of
production are called fixed resources. For example, land , building, machinery.
These resources exist only in short run. The costs associated with these resources
are called fixed costs.
11. Variable resources: The resources that vary with the level of production are
called variable resources. These resources exist both in short run and long run.
For example, seeds, fertilizers, chemicals, etc. The costs associated with these
resources are called variable costs.
12. Flow resources: The resources that cannot be stored and should be used as and
when these are available. For example, services of a labourer on a particular day.
13. Stock resources: The resources that can be stored for use later on. For example,
seeds. Defining an input as a flow or stock depends on the length of time under
consideration. For example, tractor with 10 years life is a stock resources if we
take the services of tractor for its entire useful life of 10 years. But it also
provides its service every day, therefore it is a flow resources.
14. Production period: It is the time period required for the transformation of
resources or inputs into products.
15. Farm entrepreneur: Farm entrepreneur is the person who organizes and operates
the farm business and bears the responsibility of the outcome of the business.
16. Farm business manager: Person appointed by the entrepreneur to manage and
supervise the farm business and is paid for the services rendered. He/she carries
out the instructions of the entrepreneur.
17. Productivity: Output per unit of inputs is called the productivity.
18. Technical efficiency: It is the ratio of the physical output to inputs used. It
implies the using of resources as effectively as possible without any wastages.
19. Economic efficiency: It is the expression of technical efficiency in monetary
terms through the prices. In other words, the ratio of value of output to value of
inputs is termed as economic efficiency. It implies maximization of profits per
unit of input.
20. Allocative efficiency: It occurs when no possible reorganization of
resources/production can make any combination higher yielding without making
other combination less yielding. It refers to resource use efficiency.
21. Optimality: It is an ideal condition or situation in which costs are minimum
and/or profits maximum.
22. Cost of cultivation: The expenditure incurred on all inputs and input services in
raising a crop on a unit area is called cost of cultivation. It is expressed as rupees
per hectare or rupees per acre.
23. Cost of production: The expenditure incurred in producing a unit quantity of
output is known as cost of production, for example, Rs./kg of Rs./quintal.
24. Independent variable: Variable whose value does not depend on other variables
and which influences the dependent variable, is termed as independent variable,
for example, land, labour and capital.
25. Dependent variable: Variable whose value depends on other variables is termed
as dependent variable, for example, crop output.
26. Slope of a line: It represents the rate of change in one variable that occurs when
another variable changes. Slope varies at different points on a curve but remains
same on all points on a given line. It is the rate of change in the variable on
vertical axis per unit change in the variable on horizontal axis and is expressed as
a number.
27. Total physical product: Total amount of output obtained by using different units
of inputs measured in physical units, for example, kg, tonnes, etc.
28. Average physical product (APP): Output per unit of input on an average is termed
as APP and is given by Y/X.
29. Marginal physical product: Addition to total output obtained by using the
marginal unit of input and is measured as ΔY/ΔX.
Lecture 3
Production Functions: Meaning and Types
The production function portrays an input-output relationship. It describes the rate at which
resources are transformed into products. There are numerous input-output relationships in
agriculture because the rates at which the inputs are transformed into outputs will vary among
soil types, animals, technologies, rainfall amount and so forth.
Definition: Production function is a technical and mathematical relationship describing the
manner and extent to which a particular product depends upon the quantities of inputs or services
of inputs, used at a given level of technology and in a given period of time. It shows the quantity
of output that can be produced using different levels of inputs.
A production function can be expressed in different ways: in written form, enumerating and
describing the inputs that have a bearing on the output; by listing inputs and the resulting outputs
numerically in a table; depicting in the form of a graph or a diagram; and in the form of an
algebraic equation. Symbolically, a production function can be written as
Y=f (X1, X2 , X3 ,…….., Xn) where Y is output, X1, X2 , X3….. Xn are inputs. It,
however, does not tell which inputs are fixed and which are the variable ones. Since in
production, fixed inputs play an important role, these are expressed as: Y=f (X1, X2 / X3…..Xn)
where Y is output, X1, X2 are variable inputs and X3…..Xn are fixed inputs.
ii) Quadratic PF: Also known as second degree polynomial. This type of PF allows both
declining & negative marginal productivity thus embracing the second and third stage of
production simultaneously.
y b b x b x2 where b0, b1 , & b2, are the parameters. Such PFs are quite common in
0 1 1 21
iii) Cobb-Douglas PF: It is also known as power production function. It is most widely used PF.
It accounts for only our stage of production at a time & cannot represent constant, increasing or
decreasing marginal productivity simultaneously.
Y = b0 x1b1 where b0 is efficiency parameters & b1 is elasticity of production
Lecture 4
Laws of Returns: Increasing, Constant and Decreasing
In production one or a combination of the following relationships are commonly
observed:
1. Law of constant marginal returns (productivity),
2. Law of increasing marginal returns (productivity) and
3. Law of decreasing marginal returns (productivity)
1. Law of constant marginal returns (productivity): It is said to operate when each marginal
unit of variable input adds equal quantity of output to the total output. It is applicable over
limited range, e.g. one tractor (plus driver) will almost give same output, other things remaining
constant.
2. Law of increasing marginal returns (productivity): It is said to operate when each marginal
unit of variable input adds more and more quantity of output to the total output. It is not common
in agriculture, e.g. small increase in seed input given the fixed inputs.
The law of diminishing returns describes the relationship between output and the variable input
when other inputs are held constant.
Definition: If increasing amounts of one input are added to a production process while all other
inputs are held constant, the amount of output added per unit of variable input will eventually
decrease. It is also known as law of diminishing productivity or the law of variable proportions.
Application of the law of diminishing returns to the production concept can result in a production
function of classical type. It displays increasing marginal returns first and then decreasing
marginal returns.
Ep 1
Y
Ep 0
Ep 1
Output
TPP
Inflection point
I II III
Input Congestion
APP
X
0 MPP
Input
Three stages of production
The classical production function can be divided into three regions or stages, each being
important from the standpoint of efficient resources use.
Stage-I occurs when marginal physical product (MPP) > average physical product (APP). APP
is increasing throughout this stage, indicating that the average rate at which X is transformed into
Y, increases until APP reaches its maximum at the end of Stage-I.
Stage-II occurs when MPP is decreasing and is less than APP but greater than zero. The physical
efficiency of the variable input reaches a peak at the beginning of Stage–II. On the other hand
physical efficiency of fixed input is greatest at the end of Stage-II. This is because the number of
fixed input is constant and therefore the output/ unit of fixed input must be the largest when the
total output from the production process is maximum.
Stage-III occurs when MPP is negative. Stage III occurs when excessive quantities of variable
input are combined with the fixed input, so much, that total physical product (TPP) begins to
decrease.
1. If the product has any value at all, input use once begun, should be continued until Stage
–II is reached. That is because physical efficiency of variable resources, measured by
APP, increases throughout stage –I.
2. Even if input is free, it will not be used in stage III. Maximum output occurs when Stage
II closes. It is of no use applying variable input when TPP starts coming down.
3. Stage II defines the area of economic relevance. Variable input use must be somewhere
in stage-II, but exact input amount can be determined when choice indicators (input &
output prices) are known.
1. When MPP is increasing, APP is also increasing. So long as MPP is above APP, the APP
keeps increasing.
2. When MPP curve goes below APP curve, APP starts declining, that is, when AP is decreasing
the MP is always less than APP.
3. When MP = AP, AP will be at maximum. Here MP curve must intersect AP curve from
above at its highest point.
MP < AP AP↓
MP = AP AP is at maximum.
Elasticity of production: The elasticity of production is a concept that measures the degree of
responsiveness between output and input. It is independent of the units of measurement.
% change in output
E p
% change in input
Y / Y Y / X MPP
Ep
X / X Y/X APP
Ep > 1 in Stage I
0 Ep 1 stage II
is based on exact MPPs
E p is negative stage III
The point of diminishing returns can be defined to occur when MPP =APP that is Ep= 1 (lower
boundary of stage II) & this is the minimum amount of variable input that will be used & it
occurs when the efficiency of variable input is at its maximum. At the other end, MPP is zero,
therefore Ep= 0. Thus the relevant production zone is when O ≤ Ep ≤ 1.
Isoquant (Iso-product curve): It is defined as the locus of various combinations of two inputs
yielding the same level of output. Each point on an isoquant represents the maximum output that
can be attained with these input combinations. Isoquant is a convenient device for compressing
the 3-dimension picture of a production process into two dimensions. X1 = f (X2, Y0).
Isoquant map
X2
X1
Properties of isoquants
1. Isoquants have a negative slope,
2. Isoquants to right indicate higher output level,
3. Isoquants do not interest each other,
4. Isoquant are convex to origin showing diminishing MRTS.
Types of Factor-Factor Relationship: Many types of production surfaces are possible
depending upon the underlying production function. The shapes of the isoquants and production
surfaces will depend on the manner in which the variable inputs are combined to produce a
particular level of output. Broadly, these are three categories of such combinations of inputs.
X2
y3
y2
y1
o
X1
Substitutes: Two resources are said to be substitutes when change in price of one leads to a
change in demand for another (MRTS is –ve).
Complements: Resources used together in production. When Price of X1 increases the demand
for X2 decrease. (MRTS is zero).
2. Constant rate of substitution: Such type of a factor-factor relationship gives linear isoquants.
The substitution occurs at constant rate i.e. the amount of one input replaced by the other input
does not change as the added input increases.
X21 X 22 X 2n
= = ----------- =
X11 X 12 X 1n
X2
O
1
Assumes perfect substitutbility
Constant Substitution
X2 X1 ∆X2 ΔX1 X2 MRTS
X1 X1X2
Female labour Male labour
10 1 2 1 2/1=2
8 2 2 1 2/1=2
6 3 2 1 2/1=2
4 4 2 1 2/1=2
2 5 2 1 2/1=2
e.g. Two labourers. Decision rule use either of the two depending on the relative prices.
3. Varying Rate of substitution: In this there can either be increasing rate or decreasing rate of
substitution. In this MRTSX1X2 varies over iso-product curve. It means that the amount of one
input (X1) required to substitute for one unit of another input (X2) at a given level of production
increases or decreases as the amount of X1 used increases. Substitution at decreasing rate is
common in agriculture (N& P or K & L)
X 21 X 22 X 2n
> > ----------- >
X11 X 12 X 1n
23 0
16 1 7 1 7
10 2 6 1 6
5 3 5 1 5
1 4 4 1 4
0 5 1 1 1
X2
Y1
0 X1
These convex isoquants represent continuous substitution between the two inputs. These are easy
to handle mathematically (using calculus).
X 2
MRTSX1X2 =
X 1
Marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS or MRS): MRTS is defined as the negative of
the slope of the isoquant at any point. It is the rate at which two factors of production can be
exchanged at a particular level of output and consequently that of the levels of inputs used.
Dy Dy
dy = .dx1+ .dX2
DX1 DX 2
dy =0 on an isoquant
Dy
dX 2 DX1 = MP1
- =
dX1 Dy MP2
DX 2
Iso-cost line: Locus of all possible combination of two inputs which can be purchased with a
given outlay or budget.
P x 2 (X 2 )
T=PX1 .X1+Px .X2 or X1= ( T -
P x1) P x1
2
X2
X2
X1
X2
X2
PX2 becomes
Costlier &
PX1 decreases
X1
X1
(i) It prices are same and only outlay changes then iso-cost lines will be parallel to each
other.
(ii) Changes in prices of inputs will change the slope of iso-cost line.
Computing Least cost combination: Three methods
1 8 2 24 16 32
2 6 3 18 12 30
3 5 4 15 16 31
X2
0
2
q1
O 0
1 1
Iso-cline: A line or curve connecting the least cost combinations of inputs for all output levels is
known as isocline. Isocline passes through all isoquants at points where they have same slope. It
shows how the relative proportion of the factors changes as the output is increased. It shows that
resources should be used along this line as long as MVP> MC of resources used.
Ridge lines: Represent the points of maximum output from each input, given a fixed amount of
the other input. On the ridge lines MPP is zero. Ridge lines represent the economic relevance
within the ridge lines MPPs of both the inputs is positive but decreasing.
For X2 A
X2
B
(Ridge line
For X1)
X1
Expansion Path: - There can be numerous isoclines for different possible combinations of input
prices. All these sets of prices of inputs do not prevail at any particular given time. A farm
manager has to be consider only one set of input prices that is most appropriate for the planning
period. The isoclines depending upon this set of prices (most appropriate) is called expansion
path. At any particular time there is only our expansion path possible.
Thus, the line or curve connecting the points of least cost combination for different levels of
output is called expansion path. Expansion path is an isocline on which slope of isoquant
(MRTS) equals the slopes of isocost line (price ratio). The expansion path indicates the best way
of producing the different levels of output given the input prices & the technology. If expansion
path is a straight line through origin, it means inputs will be used in the same proportion at all
output levels and hence it is called scale line. It is curved; it implies the inputs will be used in
various proportions.
X2
X1
Lecture 7
Product-Product Relationship
Product-product relationship: The farmers have limited resources and have a number of
enterprises/or enterprise combinations of crops and livestock to choose from. So the question is:
How much of what to produce and with what technology. In other words, what combination of
enterprises should be produced?
Algebraically, y1 = f (y2)
(i) Joint Products: Joint products result from the same production process and the
production of one without the other is not possible. For instance, cotton lint & seed,
wheat & straw. In such cases the quantity of one product produced decides the
quantity of other product. For production decisions, joint products can be treated as
one product. Changes in product combinations are possible in long run only (through
research).
Y2
·K
O H Y1
(iii) Supplementary products: Exists when increase or decrease in one product does not
affect the production level of the other product. All supplementary relationships
should be taken advantage of by producing both products to the point where the
products become competitive.
O D Y2
(iv) Competitiveness: This relationship holds when increase or decrease in the production
of one product affects the production of other commodity inversely. Competitive
enterprises compete for farm resources & substitute for each other. When two
products are competitive, some amount of one product must be given up to increase
the level of other product. MRPS between products is negative. When two products
are competitive, they may substitute at constant rate, increasing rate or decreasing
rate.
(a) Constant Rate of Substitution: It means that a unit change in one product is
throughout accompanied by the same unit opposite change in the other product
e.g. wheat & gram for land.
Y2
y1 y12 = ------= y1N . This is normally a short run relationship. When this relationship
=
y2 y22 y2N
exists it will be economical to produce only one of the products depending upon the relative
prices.
(b) Increasing Rate of Substitution: In this each unit increase in the level of one
product is accompanied by larger and larger decrease in the level of other product.
e.g. wheat & gram will substitute at increasing rate for capital and labour.
y21 y22 y2n
< < ---- <
y11 y12 y1n
Y2
ΔY2
ΔY1 Y1
Here profit is maximum when physical rate of substitution is equal to product price ratio.
Definitions
Farm management is defined as the science that deals with organization and operation of
the farm in the context of efficiency and continuous profits (J.N. Efferson).
Farm management is defined as the science of organization and management of the farm
enterprises for the purpose of securing greatest continuous profits (G.F. Warren).
Farm management is defined as the art of managing a farm successfully as measured by
the test of profitableness (Gray).
Farm management is defined as the art of applying business and scientific principles to
the organization and operation of the farm (Andrew Boss).
Farm management is the decision-making process whereby limited resources are
allocated to a number of production alternatives to organize and operate the business in
such a way to attain some objectives (Ronald D. Kay).
Farm management is a branch of agricultural economics, which deals with wealth earning
and wealth spending activities of farmer in relation to the organization and operation of
the individual farm unit for securing the maximum possible net income (Bradford and
Johnson).
Farm management, as the sub-division of economics, which considers the allocation of
limited resources within the individual farm, is a science of choice and decision-making
and thus a field requiring studied judgment (Heady and Jensen).
Thus in simple words, farm management can be defined as a science which deals with
judicious decisions on the use of scarce farm resources, having alternative uses to obtain the
maximum profit and family satisfaction on a continuous basis from the farm as a whole and
under sound farming programmes. In other words, farm management seeks to help the farmer
in deciding problems like what to produce, how much to produce, how to produce and when to
buy and sell and in organization and managerial problems relating to these decisions.
It covers aspects of farm business which have a bearing on the economic efficiency of the farm.
thus, the types of enterprises to be combined, the kind of crops and varieties to be grown, the
dosage of fertilizers to be applied, the implements to be used, the way the farm functions are to
be performed, all these fall within the purview of the subject of farm management. The subject of
farm management includes; farm management research, training and extension.
Following are the differences between agricultural production economics and farm management.
Fixed cost (FC): Fixed costs are those costs which do not change in magnitude as the amount of
output produced changes and are incurred even when production is not undertaken. These are
also called sunk costs. These could be fixed cash costs such as land taxes, interest, insurance
premiums, permanently hired labour, etc. Non-cash fixed costs include depreciation on
buildings, machinery interest on capital investment, cost of family labour & management, etc.
Variable costs (VC): The costs that are incurred on variable inputs and hence vary with the level
of production are called variable costs. Higher the production more will be VC and vice-versa.
Expenses on fertilizer, seed, chemical fuel consumption, etc.
NR = TR-TC
Opportunity cost: Farm resources are limited but these can be put to different uses. When these
are used in our product, some alternative usage is always forgone. The opportunity cost is the
value of best alternative forgone.
Cost Function: Cost function (or TC curves) represents the functional relationship between
output and total cost. That is what happens to cost structure when different quantities of a
commodity are produced. The cost function can be represented by (i) arithmetically (tabular
form), (ii) Geometrically or (iii) Algebraically. Exact nature (curvature) of cost function depends
on the corresponding production function provided the prices for inputs do not change with the
quality of inputs purchased.
y
TP
30 TP1
25
20
15
10
O 5 10 15 20 25 X
TVC
Output
1. Total fixed cost (TFC): The costs incurred on all fixed inputs used in production are known
as TFC. These do not change with the output levels & hence represented by a straight line
parallel to X axis.
2. Total variable cost (TVC): Refers to the costs of variable input used in production & is
computed by multiplying the amount of variable input by the price/ unit of input.
TVC = Px·X
ATC
AVC MC
Cost
AFC
Output
4. Average fixed cost (AFC): It is the fixed cost per unit of output & is computed by dividing
TFC by the amount of output at that particular level of output. AFC varies for each level of
output and as the output increases, AFC decreases. When output is zero, AFC = TFC. AFC
always slopes downward regardless of production function. AFC curve declines continuously &
never shows upward movement because after maximum product is achieved, input use beyond
this becomes irrational.
TVC P .X Px
5. Average variable cost (AVC): AVC is given by AVC x
Y Y Y/X
AVC varies with the levels of production & its shape depends on production function. The
height of AVC depends upon the unit cost of the variable input. Like AFC, AVC cannot be
computed when output is zero. AVC is inversely related to APP. AVC falls first due to
economies of large scale production & then rises due to diseconomies of scale in production.
AVC (like APP) measures the efficiency of variable input: when AVC is decreasing, efficiency
of variable input is increasing; it is at maximum when AVC is at minimum & it is decreasing
when AVC is increasing. As the production expands, the AVC declines initially, reaches a
lowest point & then bends upwards.
TC
6. Average Total Cost (ATC) = Y or AFC +AVC; shape of ATC depends upon shape of
production function. ATC decreases as output increases, attains a minimum and increases
thereafter. ATC is often referred to as ‗unit cost‘ of production – the cost of producing the unit of
output. The initial decrease in ATC is caused by the spreading of FC among an increasing
number of units of output and the increasing efficiency with which the variable input is used. As
output increases further, ATC attains a minimum & begins to increase, as increase in AVC can
no longer be offset by decrease in AFC. ATC curve has the same slope as AVC. Difference is
that the lowest point in case of AVC reaches earlier as compared to ATC.
7. Marginal Cost (MC): May be defined as the change in TC in response to a unit change in
TC
output. That is it is the cost of producing an additional unit of output & is given by .
Y
Actually a change in TC is always equal to change in VC at a given level of FC. So MC must be
worked out by dividing the change in VC by the change in output.
Lectures 10 & 11
Economic Principles applied to the Organization of Farm Business
1. Cost Principle
TC = VC+ FC
(A) In the short run: Gross revenue (GR) must cover the VC. Maximum net revenue is
obtained when MC = MR. If GR < TC but > VC, guiding principle should be to keep
increasing production as long as MR > MC.
In the short run, MC = MR point may be at a level of input use that may involve a loss
instead of profit. Yet at this point loss will be minimized. This situation of operating the
farms when MR is > AVC but < ATC is common in agriculture. This explains why
farmers keep on doing farming even when they run into losses.
(B) In the long Run: GR should be > VC + FC=TC. For taking production decision in such a
situation, one should go on using resources as long as added returns remain greater than
added total costs. Here, the object is to maximize profits instead of minimizing the losses.
2. Law of Equi- Marginal Returns (Special case of substitution)
When resources are unlimited, farmer can produce all products under the rule,
But resources are limited, expansion of one enterprise requires contraction of other. The big
question is which enterprise combination will give the greatest income? Such an optimum choice
of enterprises is made based on the principle of equi-marginal return or the opportunity cost
principle. Profit will be the greatest if each unit of labour, capital and land is used where it adds
the most to the returns. In other words, this principle lays down: the best combination of
enterprises or practices will be where limited resources are allocated in a manner that one cannot
change the use of a simple unit without reducing the income. Thus, the resources should be used
where they give not the highest average returns but the greatest marginal returns. Thus, the best
combination of enterprises is obtained not when we select profitable crops but most profitable
crops. The profitability of an enterprise depends on the price of the product, the direct costs
attached to it & the amount of product sacrificed as one enterprise gets replaced with other.
Budgeting & programming techniques take this principle into account for working out an
optimum plan.
Example: A farmer has Rs 5000 to invest on crops, dairy or poultry. What amount of capital he
should invest on each enterprise to get highest profit?
There are two types of investments: (1) Investments on operating inputs & (2) Investment on
capital assets (land, farm building, machinery, equipment, etc). Analysis of these investments
involves not only the comparison of costs and returns associated with it, but also the timings of
occurrence of costs & returns. The costs & returns from investments in operating resources occur
with a production period of a year or less. The marginal principles are used to determine the
optimum level of operating resources & there is no need to bring in time element here. But in
case of capital assets where the costs & returns are in different time periods and also capital
expenditure involves costs & returns over time (orchards). Some expenditure may be recurring &
some non- recurring. To examine the profitability of these investments it requires the recognition
of time value of money. Money has time value for the following reasons.
(1) Earning power of money: represented by opportunity cost of money (rate of interest )
(2) Inflation – purchasing power of money varies inversely with the price level. A rupee
earned a year from now is less valuable than a rupee earned today.
(3) Uncertainty: Investment deals with future & future is uncertain. Investments are made
with the expectation of receiving a stream of benefits in the future.
Thus, farm management involves dynamic adjustments in the organization & operation of farm
business by taking into account (a) time element in the valuation of present value of future
incomes by discounting future returns.
For discounting one needs to know the future & the capital position of the farmer. This implies
the exact future income / cost should be known. Capital position of the farmer affects the interest
rate to be used for discounting and the (b) risks & uncertainties in farm operations over time
(natural calamities, price fluctuations, technical changes). Two aspects of the problem are
considered under such situations: (a) Growth of a cash outlay over time i.e. compounding & (b)
Discounting of future incomes.
(1) Compounding: Compounding is the procedure to find the future value of a present sum,
given the earning power (interest rate) of money & the frequency of compounding. e.g.
Rs 100 @ 10% interest rate after 4 years.
1st year – 100+10 =110; 2nd – 110@10% = 110+11=121; 3rd year- 121@10@ = 121+12.10 =
133.10 4th: 133.10@ 10% = 133.10+13.31 = 146.41
(2) Discounting: is the procedure where the present value of the future income is determined.
P
PV ; P is the amount to be received in future, PV is the present value e.g. Rs 5000 to
(1 i)n
be received after 3 years i =10%
For unlimited capital use market rate of interest. And for limited capital use the r that capital may
fetch for the farmer. Law of diminishing returns applies to agriculture in general but its operation
can be postponed under the following conditions: (i) Improved technology (2) New soils & (3)
Scarcity of Capital (as on stage I) – all lead to the produce of increasing returns.
Reasons for law of diminishing returns in agriculture: (1) Excessive dependence on weather, (2)
less scope for division of labour, farmer is the labour manager & capitalist (3) Less scope of
machinery (4) cultivation of inferior/ marginal lands (5) Continuous cultivation leading to
fertility loss.
Example: Analysis of time value of money in purchasing a tractor: A farmer wants to purchase a
tractor he has two options (1) purchase a new tractor 2,50,000 that will last 10 years & (2)
purchase an old tractor worth 1,50,000 & replace it after 5 years with another old tractor worth
1,50,000.
(A) Farmer with unlimited capital : Has the opportunity of lending money @ 5%
150000
PV 1,17,600
(1.05)5
So 2, 50,000 V/S D 15000 + 117600 = 2, 67,600
(B) With limited capital: Has on opportunity of investing in poultry & earning 15% a year.
The opportunity cost of not using money for poultry is
1,50000
PV 74550
(1.15)5
Farming
Types
2. Specialised
3. Mixed
4. Ranching
5. Dry
A. Types of farming
Natural, economic and to some extent social factors determine the type of farming in an
area. Within the restraining influence of natural factors, economic factors- relative prices of farm
products, resources of the farmer, transport facility, farm size, land value and technological
developments influence the type of farming practiced in a region and set the proportion of area
under each enterprises. Religious beliefs and social background also play some part in following
the type of farming on the farm.
A farm on which no single product or source of income equals as much as 50% of the
total receipt is called a diversified or general farm. On such a farm, the farmer depends on
several sources of income.
Cash
Sources of Income grain
Dairy
Farming
Poultry
Sheep
Rearing
1. Marketable produce is insufficient unless the producers arrange for the sale of their
produce on co-operative basis.
2. Because of varied jobs in diversified farming, a farmer can effectively supervise only
limited number of workers.
3. Better equipping of the farm is not possible because it is not economical to have
expensive implements and machinery for each enterprise.
4. There are chances when some of the leaks in farm business may remain undetected
due to diversity of operations.
Under Indian conditions, the advantages of diversified farming far outweigh any
consideration for specialized farming. As a rule, crop-dairy type of diversified
farming is followed, because it offers more economical use of land, labour and capital
and permits safest possible way to withstand adverse weather conditions or violent
price fluctuations. Very often complementary relationships are observed among
enterprises, which contribute to increased farm production and profitability.
(2) Specialised farming
A specialized farm is one on which 50% or more receipts are derived from one enterprise.
Income is sale plus produce used at home.
3. Select appropriate enterprise combinations that results in the better use of resources.
4. Timing various jobs and operations for smooth conduct of operations without competition.
6. Provide guidance and flexibility for ensuring better use and growth of the farm business.
7. Provide allocation of resources for producing the requisite products for marketing and
household consumption.
Thus farm planning may be deemed as an educational tool to bring about desirable
organizational changes on the farm to increase the farm income of the farming family.
Farm plans are categorized into two sub-groups viz., simple farm plan and complete farm plan.
Simple farm plan implies planning for minor changes or for a particular enterprise. Complete
farm planning envisages more number of changes in the existing organization. It is adopted for
the farm as a whole.
Characteristics of good farm plan
The following are the characteristics of a good farm plan:
1. Plans should aim at efficient utilization of all the available resources on the farm.
2. Plans should be flexible i.e., they should be adaptable to changing environmental conditions.
3. Farm plans should be simple and easily understood.
4. Considering the available resources, farm plans should ensure balanced production
programme consisting of food crops, commercial crops and fodder crops.
5. The production programme included in the farm plan should aim at improving soil fertility.
6. Farm plans should facilitate efficient marketing of farm products.
7. It should take into account up-to-date technology.
8. Farm plans should consider the goals, knowledge, training and experience of the farmers, and
their attitude towards risk.
9. Farm plans should avoid too risky enterprises.
10. Farm plans should provide for borrowing, using and repaying the credit.
B) Farm budgeting
Farm plan is a programme of total farm activity drawn up by the farmer in advance. It should
show the crops to be grown; farm practices to be followed; combination of other enterprises; use
of labour, investments to be made on the farm, etc. The expression of farm plan in monetary
terms i.e. by the estimation of receipts, expenses and net income, is called farm budgeting. In
other words, farm budgeting is a process of estimating costs, returns and net profit of a farm or a
particular enterprise. Farm budgets are classified into enterprise budget, partial budget and
complete budget or whole farm budget. Farm budgeting is a method of examining the
profitability of alternative farm plans.
1. Farm enterprise budget
Commodity production on the farm is called farm enterprise. Farm budgets can be developed for
each potential enterprise. Enterprise budgets are prepared in terms of a common unit i.e., acre,
hectare, for a crop, one head of livestock, etc. This facilitates easy comparison among the
enterprises. Enterprise budget is the estimation of expected income, costs and profit for an
enterprise.
Organization of enterprise budget
It consists of three elements viz., income, costs and profitability. Income is computed by
estimating the expected output and expected price. The estimated output is based on the average
price expected in future. In order to estimate the variable costs we need information on quantity
of inputs used and the prices at which they are purchased. Fixed costs to be included in enterprise
budget are land revenue, depreciation, interest on fixed capital and rental value of owned land.
Table: Enterprise Budget for Pea
Sr. No Particulars Per bigha Per ha
Quantity Rate(`) Value(`) Quantity Value (`)
A Variable cost
1 Seed (kg) 22 33 726 275 9075
2 Seed treatment 18 225
3 FYM (q) 7.50 162 1215 93.75 15187.5
4 Fertilizers
i) IFFCO mixture (kg) 13 10.70 139.10 162.50 1738.75
ii) Urea (kg) 6 6 36 75 450
5 Plant protection 418 5225
6 Bullock labour (days) 2 500 1000 25 12500
7 Human Labour (man days)
i) Field preparation 3 150 450 37.50 5625
ii) Seed preparation & sowing 3 150 450 37.50 5625
iii) Manuring 3 150 450 37.50 5625
iv) Interculture 11 150 1650 137.50 20625
v) Irrigation 4 150 600 50 7500
vi) Spraying 3 150 450 37.50 5625
vii) Harvesting/Picking, 7 150 1050 87.50 13125
packing & transportation
viii) Total human labour of which 34 5100 425 63750
i) Family labour 22 150 3300 275 41250
ii) Hired Labour 12 150 1800 150 22500
8 Sub total (1 to 7) 8652.10 108151.3
9 Interest on working capital 115.36 1442.02
10 Total variable cost(A=8+9) 8767.46 109593.3
B Fixed cost
i) Rental value of land 5000 62500
ii) Interest on fixed capital 648 8100
iii) Depreciation 810 10125
Total fixed cost 6458 80725
C Total cost (A+B) 15225.46 190318.3
D Production and Returns
1 Production (q) 10.75 134.375
2 Average price (`/kg) 22 22
3 By product (q) 1.02 12.75
4 Average price (`/kg) 15 15
5 Gross Returns 25180 314750
6 Net Returns (`) 9954.54 124431.70
2. Partial budgeting
Partial budgeting refers to the estimating the outcome or returns for a part of the business, i.e.
one or a few activities. Partial budgeting is a statement of anticipated changes in costs, returns
and profitability for such a minor modification on the farm. When a farmer contemplates few
modifications or minor changes in the existing organization of the farm business, partial
budgeting technique is employed. It is similar to that of marginal analysis, wherein the changes
in costs and returns resulting from proposed modifications are alone considered. It consists of
four important elements viz., added costs, added returns, reduced returns and reduced costs.
Partial budgeting technique is generally used to evaluate the profitability of input substitution,
enterprise substitution and scale of operation.
1. Added costs: Additional costs are incurred, if the proposed modification is the introduction of
a new enterprise or increase in the size of the existing enterprise.
2. Added returns: Additional returns could be received when the proposed modification is the
addition of a new enterprise, or increase in the size of the existing enterprise or adoption of
technology that results in higher productivity.
3. Reduced returns: Decrease in the returns is observed when the proposed modification
involves the elimination of an existing enterprise or reduction in the size of the existing
enterprise.
4. Reduced costs: Decrease in the costs is found when the proposed modification involves the
elimination of existing enterprise or reduction in the size of the enterprise or adoption of a
technology that uses fewer amounts of resources.
3. Complete Budgeting
It is a method of estimating expected income, expense and profits for the farm as whole.
Complete budgeting is employed when farmers want to overhaul the entire farm business.
Steps in farm planning and budgeting: The sound farm plan should be generally feasible,
acceptable, and adaptable. To make the farm plan successful, the following steps should be
adopted with relevance to given farm and its resources.
1. Statement of objective.
2. Diagnosis of the existing organization
3. Assessment of resource endowments on the farm.
4. Identification of enterprises to be included.
5. Preparation of enterprise budgets.
6. Identification of risks, and
7. Preparation of a plan.
1. Statement of objective: The objective of the farmer may be profit maximization or cost
minimization. In selecting enterprises and their combinations, the farmer aims at maximization
of profits. On the other hand, while choosing resources and their combinations, he aims at cost
minimization.
2. Diagnosis of the existing organization: Diagnosis and prescription are the two important
components of planning. The planner has to examine the existing organization of farm business
carefully and identify the weaknesses or defects or loopholes in the current plan. Once mistakes
are identified, corrective steps can be taken in future. Farm plans primarily prescribe remedies
for the defects of the existing plan.
3. Assessment of resource endowment on the farm:
a) Land: Here there is a need to spell out the land holding area, type of land i.e. wet land or dry
land, crops grown, type of soils available, topography, texture, fertility status, drainage, soil and
water development, soil and water conservation methods, etc.
b) Labour: The extent of family labour available with the farmer viz., women, men and children
along with their age, household work and farm work done by them should be indicated.
Permanent labourers if any engaged by the farmer, type of work done and amount of
remuneration paid should be indicated. Labour supply, in the village and demand for labour for
different crops in different seasons should be assessed. The supply position with reference to
livestock should be assessed correctly.
c) Capital: Working capital required for raising crops should be indicated. Owned funds
available and the amount of funds borrowed, from different sources, interest paid, etc., need to be
clearly specified. Specification of repayment dates, terms and conditions, etc., is also required.
Fixed capital relates to information on farm buildings, farm equipment, farm machinery, etc.
d) Organization: The farmer‘s knowledge in farming, his expertise, his experience in farming
and confidence in adapting new potential technology should be assessed. Based on this
information relevant farm plan should be devised. If the farmer is risk-averse, farm plans, which
provide stable income under risk, should be generated.
e) Irrigation sources: Availability of different sources of irrigation, area covered under different
sources, period of availability of irrigation, quantity of irrigation water available, crop demands
for irrigation water, accessibility of land to the irrigation sources such as canal and tank, etc.,
should also be indicated. In addition to this cost of irrigation needs to be mentioned.
4. Identification of enterprises to be included: List of enterprises not only grown by the
farmer but also enterprises grown in that area and also crop rotations are identified. Estimate the
input-output coefficients in terms of acre or hectare or head of livestock for all the enterprises,
which we propose to include. Information on input and output prices should be collected so as to
work out the costs and returns.
5. Preparation of enterprise budgets: Estimate the income, cost and profitability of each
enterprise to be included in the plan. The preparation of enterprise budgets facilitates comparison
of profitability of different enterprises.
6. Identification of risks: List out all types of risks viz., production risk, weather risk,
technological risk, institutional risk, marketing risk, etc., faced by the farmers. Particularly the
incidence of pests, rodents and diseases, frequency of drought occurrence over time, cyclones,
floods and their havoc caused to farm plans. Marketing risks comprising of risk emanating from
price fluctuations and failure of markets to arrest the malpractices of middlemen should be
indicated.
7. Preparation of a plan: The first step is indentifying the scarcest resources and selecting that
enterprise which yields maximum returns per unit of scarcest resource. This process is repeated
till all the scarce resources are put to the best use which results in optimum combination of the
enterprises.
Lecture 15
Risk and Uncertainty
Following Frank Knight, the knowledge situation can be classified into the following logical
possibilities:
Knowledge
situation
Risk
Perfect Imperfect
knowledge Knowledge
A priori Statistical
Uncertainty
Perfect knowledge: There would be no need for farm management experts if knowledge was
perfect. If these were so, technology, prices and institutional behaviour would be known with
certainty for any period of time in the future. But the concept of perfect knowledge is a fallacious
one and does not represent the real world situation.
From the economic point of view, uncertainty is undoubtedly the most important. The
occurrence of an event cannot be quantified with the help of probability. Thus future occurrence
of an event cannot be predicted. A farmer often finds himself confronted with such a situation
where the knowledge is incomplete, yet the decision has to be taken. It becomes, therefore,
essential to formulate some estimates however wild, of the most likely outcomes. In practice,
however, farmers are unable to draw a clear distinction between risk and uncertainty though the
reaction in each situation is markedly different. Mostly the terms risk and uncertainty are used
interchangeably.
Types of Risks and Uncertainties: They are classified into five categories:
1. The economic uncertainties are markedly reduced in many economies where input and
product prices are announced before sowing a crop. Economic uncertainties of this nature are
usually caused by national and international policies which are beyond the approach of an
individual farmer.
4. Institutional uncertainties: Institutions like government, banks, etc., may also cause
uncertainties for an individual farmer. Crop cess, credit squeeze, price supports, subsidies, etc.
may be enforced or withdrawn without taking an individual farmer into confidence. This type of
uncertainty may also result in non-availability of resources in appropriate quantities and at the
appropriate time and place.
5. Personal uncertainties
The farm plan may not be executed because of some mishap in the farmer‘s household or in his
permanent labour force.
Some farmers take more risk than others. However, all farmers use one or more measures of
different types of safeguard themselves against risks and uncertainties on their farms. The
various measures generally used to counter risks and uncertainties in agriculture are as follows:
2. Discounting returns
At this stage we refer to discounting only as a function of risk and uncertainty, and not time.
Planning based on single value expectations of input-output coefficients may invariably be
misleading as it assumes a perfect knowledge situation. It amounts to deducting a safety margin
from the expected prices, yields or incomes.
3. Insurance
Insurance is another well-accepted method to safeguard against risk and uncertainty. However,
insurance in agriculture is not common in many countries including India. It helps the farmer,
whenever used, to lessen the variability in income and minimize the chances of the farm income
dropping below a minimum level.
4. Forward contracts
They reduce the future prices, both of the factors of production and of the products, into
certainty. Contracts may either be in money or in kind. Employment of a labourer on the farm for
a period of one, two or twelve months on some agreed amount is an example of forward contract
in money. Similarly, pre-harvest apple contract in Himachal Pradesh or Jammu and Kashmir is
another example. On the other hand, share cropping is a good example of forward contracts in
kind. Contracts in kind reduce income variability where contracts in money do extract the
opposite.
5. Flexibility
This refers to the convenience with which the organization of production on a farm can be
changed. Some organizations are obviously more flexible than others and flexibility in an
organization through change in production helps obtaining advantages and improvements in the
economic and technological environment of a farmer. As an uncertainty safeguard, flexibility
may be built into farm plan for stabilization of incomes from year to year and to maximize the
expected stream of total income over a longer period of time. It differs from diversification in the
sense that it aims at preventing the sacrifice of large gains as compared to the prevention of large
losses through diversification.
Due to technological and economic changes certain enterprises may suddenly gain or lose
importance over time. Thus, quick changes may be required which can only be brought about at
a low cost if the plans are not rigid but flexible. Flexibility can be of the following types:
i) Time flexibility: Time flexibility may be introduced either through proper selection of
products or production methods or partly by both. Orchard plantation is a relatively more rigid
enterprise than annual crops like wheat, maize, paddy, etc. A short lived farm structure or
equipment is more flexible than one which durable.
ii) Cost flexibility: whenever time flexibility is of limited use, cost flexibility becomes
important. Cost flexibility refers to variations in output within the structure of a plant with a
longer life. Extension or contraction of output, whenever desired by favourable prices or yields,
can be brought about at lower costs for a given plant. through a farmer may find that owning a
potato digger on his farm would result in lower costs than those which have to be paid for
custom hiring a similar one, yet he may keep on hiring machine in order to have more cost
flexibility on his farm.
iii) Product Flexibility: product flexibility, like any type of flexibility, aims at changes in
production in response to price signals. In this category we consider the form of physical
resources, e.g. machines, farm structure, etc., which can be switched readily from one product to
another.
7. Diversification
Diversification is a very important, useful and popular method to safeguard against risk and
uncertainty in agriculture. Here we refer to diversification as a means of stabilizing incomes
rather than profit maximizing related to reaping gains of complementarity and supplementarity.
Lecture 16
Linear Programming
Linear programming (LP) is a budgeting technique that is more refined and systematic than the
conventional budgeting in determining the optimum combination of enterprises or inputs so as to
maximize the income or minimize the cost within the limits of available resources. It may be
defined as ―the analysis of the problems in which a linear function of a number of variables is to
be maximized or minimized when those variables are subject to a number of restraints in the
form of linear inequalities‖. In linear programming models, the objective of the typical farm i.e.,
maximization of net profit or cost minimization is achieved through optimal plan generated from
its solution. The objective function specified, i.e., profit maximization or cost minimization, is
linear in form and constraints on resource restrictions are specified in linear form. LP has been
used in agriculture since 1950s. As a normative tool, it provides prudent solutions to farm
planning problems.
Components of LP problem
There are three quantitative components in LP model. They are
Assumptions of LP problem
There are seven basic assumptions:
The term ―natural resource‖ means anything that we use from our environment to achieve our
objective. For example, we require bricks, cement, iron, wood etc. to construct a building. All these
items are called resources for construction of building.
A resource can be defined as ‘any natural or artificial substance, energy or organism, which is
used by human being for its welfare.
All that nature has provided such as soil, air, water, minerals, coal, sunshine (sunlight), animals and
plants, etc., are known as natural resources. The resources, which have been developed by human
beings during the growth of civilization, are called artificial resources. For example, biogas, thermal
electricity, plastics. These man-made resources are generally derived from some other natural
resources. For example, plastics from the natural resource, petroleum.
The natural resources include, air, water, soil, minerals, along with the climate and solar energy,
which form the non-living or ‗abiotic‘ part of nature. Interactions between the abiotic aspects of
nature and specific living organisms together form ecosystems of various types. Many of these living
organisms are used as our food resources. Others are linked to our food less directly, such as
pollinators and dispersers of plants, soil animals like worms, which recycle nutrients for plant growth,
and fungi and termites that break up dead plant material so that micro-organisms can act on the
detritus to reform soil nutrients.
Classification of Natural Resources
- BIOTIC RESOURCES are resources which come from biosphere and have a life example. human beings,
flora and fauna, fisheries, livestock etc. The materials obtained from them are also considered biotic,
example fossil fuels, coal, petroleum, because these are formed from decayed organic matter.
- ABIOTIC RESOURCES are those resources which come from non-living, non-organic material.
Example, rocks, minerals, air, water, metals etc.
- PERPETUAL RESOURCES – these are resources which exist irrespective of the amount of their usage.
With adequate technology, they provide a vast potential for use. Example. Sun, wind and water
- RENEWABLE RESOURCES - the resources which can be renewed and reproduced by physical,
chemical or mechanical processes are known as renewable or replenishable resources. These resources are
able to increase their abundance through reproduction and utilization of simple substances. Examples of
such resources are water, forests and wildlife, plants etc. we can further divide into continuous or flow and
biological.
Renewable Resources can be further classified as Living Renewable Resources and Non-Living Renewable
Resources: Some examples of renewable resources though they do not have life cycle but can be recycled
are wood and wood-products, pulp products, natural rubber, fibers (e.g. cotton, jute, animalwool, silk and
synthetic fibers) and leather.
Living Renewable (biological) resources are those renewable resources which come from living (biotic)
sources – like forests, plants
Non-Living Renewable resources are those that renewable resources which come from non-living
(abiotic) sources like land, water, air. Example, metals, minerals, wind, sun etc.
Continuous/ Flow Renewable resources are resources which do not need regeneration. Similar to that
of perpetual resources, example wind, tides etc.
- NON-RENEWABLE RESOURCES - this process takes place over a long geological time. Examples of
such resources are minerals and fossil fuels. This may take millions of years in their formation. Some of the
resources like metals are recyclable and some like fossils fuels cannot be recycled and as such they get
exhausted with their use.
Recyclable resources are those which can be processed to be used again and again. These are non-
renewable resources, which can be collected after they are used and can be recycled. These are
mainly the non-energy mineral resources, which occur in the earth's crust (e.g. ores of aluminium,
copper, mercury etc.) and deposits of fertilizer nutrients (e.g. phosphate sock and potassium and
minerals used in their natural state like asbestos, clay, mica etc)
Non- Recyclable resources are those which once used perish, example coal. These are non-
renewable resources, which cannot be recycled in any way. Examples of these are fossil fuels and
uranium, which provide 90 per cent of our energy requirements.
There are a few substances too which can be recycled a few times, before they completely perish or turn
non-renewable resources.
(iii) Classification based on ownership: Individual vs. Community vs. National vs. International
- This classification is inspired from socio-economic demarcation or classification of resources and natural
wealth. Interestingly, the resources (metals/ minerals) found on these pieces of land ownership also belong
to the concerned owner.
- INDIVIDUAL RESOURCES - these are resources owned by individuals privately. Example, land owned
by a farmer allotted to them by government against the payment of revenue. Urban people own plots,
houses and other property. Some other examples include plantation, pasture lands, ponds, water in wells
etc.
- COMMUNITY RESOURCES- these include resources that are accessible to all the members of the
community like the village grazing grounds, burial grounds, village ponds, public parks, picnic spots,
playgrounds in urban areas are accessible to all the people living there.
- NATIONAL RESOURCES- technically speaking all the resources belong to the nation because the
country has legal powers to acquire even private property for public good. This we may have seen many
times when government take fields owned by private individuals to construct roads, canals, railways. All
minerals, water resources, forests, wildlife, land within the political boundaries and oceanic area upto 12
nautical miles from the coast termed as territorial water and resources therein belong to the nation.
- INTERNATIONAL RESOURCES - there are also international resources regulating resources. The
oceanic resources beyond 200km of the Exclusive Economic Zone belong to open ocean and no individual
country can utilize these without the consensus of international institutions.
(iv) Classification based on the stage of development of the resource: Potential vs. Developed vs.
Stock Reserves
- POTENTIAL RESOURCES are those which can be found in a particular region but are yet to be put to
use. Example. Regions in states like Rajasthan and Gujarat have huge potential for development of solar,
wind and tidal energy, which us yet to be used.
- DEVELOPED/ACTUAL RESOURCES includes are resources which have been/ are surveyed and their
quality and quantity have been determined for utilization. The development of resources however depends
on technology and level of their feasibility
- STOCK - the materials in the environment which have the potential to satisfy human needs but human
beings do not have the appropriate technology to access these, are included among stock. Water for
example is a compound of two inflammable gases; hydrogen and oxygen which can be used as a source of
energy. But we do not know how to use them for this purpose. Therefore it is considered as stock.
- RESERVES - they are the subset of stock/ actual which are/ can be used with the help of existing
technical knowledge. Reserves can be used for meeting future requirements. For example water in lakes,
dams, forests etc is a reserve which can be used in the future.
-LOCALIZED RESOURCES are found only in certain parts of the world (e.g., copper and iron ore,
geothermal power).
Environment-Economy Interaction
How does NRE help in agriculture?
Resource economists provide science-based information to help agriculture producers balance
production demands with elements central to agricultural sustainability, including:
Its focus is how to operate an economy within the It focuses on maximizing the crop yield while
ecological constraints of earth's natural resources. maintaining a good soil ecosystem.
We study how the environment and natural We study the interactions between farming and
resources can be managed to provide the greatest the environment.
net benefits.
Our research covers terrestrial and marine Our research covers climate change impacts on
biodiversity conservation, pollution, bio- agriculture, land degradation, carbon storage on
economic modelling of invasive pests, bushfire farms, perennial farming systems, salinity
management, adoption of new conservation management and more.
practices by landholders and more.
Resource economics brings together and connects Agricultural economics today includes a variety
different disciplines within the natural and social of applied areas, having considerable overlap
sciences connected to broad areas of earth with conventional economics with substantial
science, human economics, and natural contributions to research in economics,
ecosystems econometrics, development economics, and
environmental economics. Agricultural
economics influences food policy, agricultural
policy, and environmental policy.
Unique Properties/Characteristics of Natural Resources
Resources have three main characteristics namely:
1) Utility,
2) Limited availability,
Scarcity: Scarcity is the fundamental economic problem of having humans who have unlimited
wants and needs in a world of limited resources. It states that society has insufficient productive
resources to fulfil all human wants and needs.
Resource depletion: Resource depletion is an economic term referring to the exhaustion of raw
materials within a region. Resource depletion is most commonly used in reference to farming,
fishing, mining, and fossil fuels.
..........................................................xxxxxxx.................................................................
Lecture- 18
Natural Resource Economics
Externalities
What Is an Externality?
An externality is an economic term referring to a cost or benefit incurred or received by a third party.
However, the third party has no control over the creation of that cost or benefit.
An externality can be either positive or negative and can stem from either the production or
consumption of a good or service. The costs and benefits can be both private—to an individual or an
organization—or social, meaning it can affect society as a whole.
Pollution emitted by a factory that muddies the surrounding environment and affects the health of
nearby residents is a negative externality. The effect of a well-educated labour force on the
productivity of a company is an example of a positive externality.
Externalities in Agriculture
Cultural
Environmental
Others
Based on those two criteria, we can classify all physical products into four different types of goods:
private goods, public goods, common resources/ common property resources and club goods. We will
look at each of them in more detail below
Private Goods
Private Goods are products that are excludable and rival. They have to be purchased before they can
be consumed. Thus, anyone who cannot afford private goods is excluded from their consumption.
Likewise, the consumption of private goods by an individual prevents other individuals from
consuming the same goods. Therefore, private goods are also considered rival goods. Examples of
private goods include ice cream, cheese, houses, cars, etc.
Public Goods
Public goods describe products that are non-excludable and non-rival. That means, no one can be
prevented from consuming them, and they can be used by individuals without reducing their
availability to other individuals. Examples of public goods include fresh air, knowledge, national
defence, street lighting, etc.
Common resources are defined as products or resources that are non-excludable but rival. That means
they can be used by virtually anyone. However, if one individual consumes common resources, their
availability to other individuals is reduced. The combination of those two characteristics often results
in an overuse of common resources (see also the tragedy of the commons). Examples of common
resources include freshwater, fish, timber, pasture, etc.
Club goods are products that are excludable but non-rival. Thus, individuals can be prevented from
consuming them, but their consumption does not reduce their availability to other individuals (at least
until a point of overuse or congestion is reached). Club goods are sometimes also referred to as
artificially scarce resources. They are often provided by natural monopolies. Examples of club goods
include cable television, cinemas, wireless internet, toll roads, etc.
In a Nutshell
There are four different types of goods in economics which can be classified based on excludability
and rivalrousness: private goods, public goods, common resources, and club goods. Private Goods are
products that are excludable and rival. Public goods describe products that are non-excludable and
non-rival. Common resources are defined as products or resources that are non-excludable but rival.
And last but not least, club goods are products that are excludable but non-rival.
Importance
of Common property Resources
Within the field of economics, common resources are generally referred to as common pool
resources, common property resources, or common access resources—a type of good whose
characteristics or size make them costly or difficult to regulate and exclude potential users from
obtaining benefits from their use. Common pool resources typically contain a core resource (e.g.,
timber in a forest) from which a limited quantity of units can be extracted when the natural systems
replenishing this resource are properly maintained and the resource is not degraded.
Unlike pure public goods, common pool resources face problems of congestion or overuse, because
they are subtractable. A common-pool resource typically consists of a core resource (e.g. water or
fish), which defines the stock variable, while providing a limited quantity of extractable fringe units,
which defines the flow variable. While the core resource is to be protected or nurtured in order to
allow for its continuous exploitation, the fringe units can be harvested or consumed.
We can list a large number of CPRs, which can be brought under the broad headings like land
resources, forest resources, water resources, and fishery resources. These resources are being
degraded overtime due to overuse or lack of proper management.
Land Resources
Common property land resource refers to lands identified with a specific type of property rights. The
common lands covered in the National Sample Survey (NSS) enquiry are panchayat lands,
government revenue lands, village common lands, village thrashing lands, unclassified forest lands,
woodlands and wastelands, river banks, and lands belonging to other households used as commons.
Forest Resources
Another category of land for which common property rights may exist is land under forests.
Unclassified forests, with very low productivity, are always open to use by local communities:
Accordingly, both protected and unclassified forests are treated as forming a part of common
property forest resources. It is, therefore, the subset of total forest area minus reserve forests to which
common property rights are assumed to exist.
Water Resources
There are a variety of resources of water, which are in the public domain, and a significant part of
these are included in the category of commons. Examples are flows of rivers, tanks and natural lakes,
groundwater, wetland and mangrove areas, and such other water bodies. Man-made water resources
such as dams and canals, tube wells, other wells, and supply of all types of potable water also fall in
the category of CPRs depending upon their property rights. Unfortunately, even after many debates
about property rights (such as traditional rights, community rights, and basic need human rights),
water has not yet been declared as CPR in India, though references are made in the water policy
document indirectly.
By and large, water resources in India are in common property regimes only. Irrigation canals are
managed jointly by the government and communities. Traditionally, tanks, village ponds, and lakes -
all of which are treated as CPRs-are sources of water for drinking, livestock rearing, washing, fishing
and bathing, and several sanitary-related activities.
(i) Definition,
(ii) Accountability,
(iii) Depletion
(iv) Shrinkage, and
(v) Policy and management.
A common property resource is potentially subject to congestion, depletion or degradation when its
use is pushed beyond the limit of sustainable yield. Hardin (1968) called the problem of CPR as the
'tragedy of the commons'.
He brought out the problem by illustrating it through the metaphor of shepherds and the size of their
herds. It is in the self-interest of individual shepherds that they increase the size of their herds, as it
will generate more profits. Eventually the overall sheep population will exceed the pasture's (the
common's) regeneration capacity. As a result, the pasture area will shrink and degenerate. While
Hardin explained the problem through a lucid example, it holds true for all natural resources which
do not have well-defined property rights.
There are three variables involved: i) the quantity of the resource (let us call it C for commons), ii)
the rate of replenishment of the resource (Rr), and iii) the rate of use of the resource (RU). Whenever
RI, exceeds Rr we have a tragedy. If C is too large and Rl1 is too small the depletion of the resource
is so slow that it is not noticed and it is not viewed as a tragedy.
However, with the passage of time as population size increases, there is an increase in R,, and the
depletion is perceptible.
The tragedy of the commons can be represented by the formal framework of the 'prisoner's dilemma'
(PD) game. This game has a peculiar characteristic, which makes it an excellent representation of an
important class of social phenomena. It brings out that the problem of social aggregation is not so
simple.
There are situations when everyone may suffer loss even if every individual acts rationally. Let us
consider the case of two herdsmen who must decide on the number of animals to let pasture on a
common land (belonging to both).
To further simplify the presentation, let us assume that the choice facing each herdsman is between
letting one or two animals on the common land. If both herdsmen choose to have one animal each,
each of them gains Rs. 5.
If, however, both choose to have two animals each on the common land, these animals will be
underfed and will lose much of their economic value. As a result, the total gain each, herdsman may
expect for having two animals pasturing is Rs. 4. Finally, if one herdsman has only one animal on the
common land, and the other has two, their gains are Rs. 3 and Rs. 6 respectively. This situation can
be summarised by entering the different gains, called payoffs, in a double entry matrix, as shown in
Table 11.1, where the first number in each cell is the payoff accruing to herdsman 1, while the second
number refers to herdsman 2.
It is easy to see that each herdsman will choose the strategy 'put two animals'. Such a strategy is
called a dominant strategy (maximising own benefit), since the optimal action for one player does not
depend on the strategy followed by the other player.
Here each player has a dominant strategy so that the Nash equilibrium of the game comes out
naturally as the one where each player chooses to put two animals on the common land. Here lies the
tragedy of the commons: even though it would be better for both herdsmen to put only one animal on
the commons (Pareto-superior outcome), it is individually rational for each of them to put two
animals, and the Pareto-inferior outcome obtains.
Here 'the rational individual cannot obtain the collective output and maximising individual benefit
will lead to collective ruin, where societal benefit will not be maximised. Hardin, however, fails to
make the distinction between situations of no property (open access) and situations of common
property.
His model is best fit for the situations of no property or open access and not the situations of common
property. Therefore, the tragedy of the commons is a pessimist conclusion posed by Hardin. T
he two key assumptions of prisoner's dilemma model - players choose in ignorance of each other's
choices, and each player chooses only once before the payoffs are received - become responsible for
such pessimist conclusion.
In economics approaches to resource management, the common denominator is typically some form
of measurement that can be related to individual welfare. Economics provides a comprehensive
framework for analysing most aspects of natural resource and environmental issues. Optimal
extraction and use of non-renewable resources, in particular as analysed by the Hotelling‘s rule.
Economic indicators of sustainability derived from the weak sustainability view that the total amount
of capital must be maintained. The basic Hotelling Rule is based on a number of simplifying
assumptions. The total stock of resources is assumed to be known and of equal quality, and all the
market players are assumed to have full knowledge. The concept of management of non-renewable
resources is mainly concerned with how a resource stock should be used optimally and not concerned
with sustainability.
Sustainability:
The word sustainability is derived from the Latin sustinere (tenere, to hold; sus,up). The most widely
quoted definition of sustainability and sustainable development, that of the Brundtland Commission
of the United Nations on March 20, 1987: ―sustainable development is development that meets the
needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs.
Environmental, social and economic demands - the "three pillars" of sustainability. The word
sustainability is applied not only to human sustainability on earth, but too many situations and
contexts over many scales of space and time, from small local ones to the global balance of
production and consumption. Sustainability is the capacity to endure. In ecology, sustainability
describes how biological systems remain diverse and productive over time, a necessary precondition
for human well-being. Long-lived and healthy wetlands and forests are examples of sustainable
biological systems.
Sustainability farming: It is the system that in which NRS are managed so that the potential yield
and stock of NRS do not decline over time
Measurement
Sustainability measurement is a term that denotes the measurements used as the quantitative basis for
the informed management of sustainability. The metrics used for the measurement of sustainability
(involving the sustainability of environmental, social and economic domains are evolving: they
include indicators, benchmarks, audits, sustainability standards and certification systems.
Resource productivity:
Resource productivity is the quantity of good or service (outcome) that is obtained through the
expenditure of unit resource. This can be expressed in monetary terms as the monetary yield per unit
resource. Resource productivity and resource intensity are key concepts used in sustainability
measurement. The sustainability objective is to maximize resource productivity while minimizing
resource intensity
Intra-generational equity
Equity can also be applied across communities and nations within one generation. The reason that
intra-generational equity is a key principle of sustainable development is that inequities are a cause of
environmental degradation. Poverty deprives people of the choice about whether or not to be
environmentally sound in their activities.
First, the majority of people would be deprived in terms of low welfare level despite their hard work
(equity failure),
Second, unfair access to public infrastructure, facilities and services could occur (equity failure). i.e .
Failure to guarantee intra- and inter-generational equity would cause deep inequality and un
sustainability
Third, natural resources may be so exploited that threaten their sustainability of use.
Fourth, negative externalities of economic activities could create serious threat to the environment
Equity issues: