Henry Hazlitt and The Failure of Keynesian Economics: by Richard M. Ebeling
Henry Hazlitt and The Failure of Keynesian Economics: by Richard M. Ebeling
NOVEMBER 2004
or four decades, from the mid-1930s to the 1970s, Keynesian economics almost monopolized economic policy in the United States and around the world. The new economics, as it was called, was going to assure mankind economic stability, full employment, and material prosperity all through wise government management of monetary and scal policy. So dominant was this view that only in 1959 did the rst book-length refutation of the ideas of John Maynard Keynes appear: Henry Hazlitts The Failure of the New Economics: An Analysis of the Keynesian Fallacies.1 Keynes (18831946)2 had a acquired an international reputation shortly after World War I, when he published The Economic Consequences of the Peace, a biting criticism of the Treaty of Versailles that formally ended the war.3 In the 1920s he was a leading critic of the gold standard and a vocal proponent of a government-managed currency to maintain full employment. In his 1924 book, A Tract on Monetary Reform, Keynes declared that gold was a barbarous relic and that governments should use their control over the money supply to maintain a stable domestic price level even if this required abandoning a stable foreign exchange rate between the British pound and the other currencies of the world.4 In 1930 Keynes published A Treatise on Money, a two-volume work that he expected
Richard Ebeling is the president of FEE.
would establish his reputation as the leading monetary theorist of his time.5 Instead, the book was savaged by reviewers, including many of the most prominent economists in Great Britain and the United States. The most devastating criticisms were made by a young Austrian economist named Friedrich A. Hayek, who in a lengthy two-part review demonstrated the logical confusions and theoretical misunderstandings that ran through the entire work.6 For the next ve years Keynes devoted his time to devising a new theory for his argument that a free-market economy was inherently unstable and that only the guiding hand of government could assure full employment in the face of the economic disaster being experienced during the Great Depression of the early 1930s. This work nally appeared in February 1936 under the title The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money.7 Except for some of Keyness young protgs at Cambridge University, most of the reviewers of the book were highly critical of many of its theoretical innovations, as well as its inationary prescriptions for unemployment.8 Even some economists who later became proponents of Keyness new economics were initially highly critical of his work. For example, Alvin Hansen, who was one of the leading advocates of Keynesian economics in the United States in the 1950s and 1960s, wrote in late 1936 that The General Theory is not a landmark in the sense 15
The Freeman: Ideas on Liberty November 2004 that it lays the foundation for a new economics. . . . The book is more a symptom of economic trends than a foundation stone upon which a science can be built.9 Yet within a few years, and most certainly by the end of World War II, Keyness ideas had virtually pushed aside every other explanation of the causes and cures of economic depressions.10 Keyness book became the foundation stone for the new macroeconomics. His face even appeared on the cover of the December 31, 1965, issue of Time magazine. The feature article, titled We Are All Keynesians Now, stated: Today, some 20 years after his death, his theories are a prime inuence on the worlds free economies, especially Americas. . . . Now Keynes and his ideas, though they still make some people nervous, have been so widely accepted that they constitute both the new orthodoxy in the universities and the touchstone of economic management in Washington. . . . Now even businessmen, traditionally hostile to Governments role in the economy, have been won over. . . . They have begun to take for granted that the Government will intervene to head off recession or choke off ination, [and] no longer think that decit spending is immoral.11 Keynes argued in The General Theory that the free-market economy contained no builtin mechanism to assure full employment. The crucial weakness, he said, lies in the relationship between savings and investment. People tend to consume more as their incomes go up, but the increase is not as great as the increase in income. In other words, they also save a portion of their higher income. The problem, he insisted, is that saving is non-spending and if people do not spend all the extra income they earn, businessmen may not have the incentive to invest enough to employ all those who want to work at prevailing wages. As a result, a large portion of the labor force may be left unemployed because the private sector has failed to create enough jobs. The economy, therefore, may be stuck 16 for a prolonged period in what Keynes called an unemployment equilibrium. Couldnt workers improve their prospects by accepting lower money wages? No, Keynes insisted, because workers suffer from a money illusioneven if prices were falling and a cut in wages would make them no worse off in real buying-power terms, workers would refuse to accept less money. Rather than demand that workers accept lower pay, Keynes favored raising the general level of prices so employers could make profits without cutting wages. In other words, Keyness solution to unemployment was price ination.
Decit Spending
Government decit spending would provide additional market demand, pushing prices up and stimulating more hiring. Public-works projects would prime the pump. This policy would continue until full employment was attained. But since, in Keyness view, businessmen were usually shortsighted and irrational in their fears about investment prospects, the private sector would always lag behind in creating jobs. The government would have to be constantly at the monetary and scal controls, injecting spending into the economy to prevent it from sinking back into unacceptable levels of unemployment. In Keyness conception of the world, governments guided by his ideas would be wise and farseeing, assuring that the mass unemployment of the 1930s never happened again. Government would manipulate interest rates, the level of prices, and the amount and direction of investment to assure that society had high employment, socially beneficial investment, and general economic stability. There were critics of Keynesian economics in the 1940s and 1950s, but they were virtually ignored by academic economists and policymakers.12 Some mainstream macroeconomists also took Keynes to task. But many of their criticisms were couched in terms clearly meant not to antagonize their Keynesian colleagues.
Henry Hazlitt and the Failure of Keynesian Economics Then in 1959 came Henry Hazlitts The Failure of the New Economics.13 What was unique about Hazlitts exposition was his chapter-by-chapter dissection of the arguments in Keyness General Theory.14 Central to Keyness theory was his insistence that Says Law was wrong in claiming that supply creates its own demand. Just because people supply goods on the market does not mean they will demand what others are selling. They may abstain from spending by holding idle cash balances. Thus there could be a general glut of goods on the market. money supply in the early 1930s increased the degree to which prices and wages had to fall to re-establish full employment.) Hazlitt considered Keyness inationary x crude and dangerous. First, Hazlitt pointed out that Keyness focus on macroeconomic aggregates concealed the microeconomic relationships among a multitude of individual prices and wages. The price level, wage level, total output, aggregate demand, and aggregate supply were all statistical ctions that had no reality in the actual market. Thus the wage level could not be too high relative to the general price level. But in the 1930s many wages for different types of labor were out of balance with the prices of individual goods sold on the market. What was needed to restore full employment was an adjustment of numerous individual wages and resource prices to the lower prices of many consumer goods. The extent to which any individual money wage or resource price might have to adjust downwards depended on the distinct supply and demand conditions in each of the individual markets. An inationary policy attempts to bring some individual price-wage relationships back into balance by pushing prices up throughout the economy, Hazlitt explained. Because Keynes, with his lump, aggregate thinking, is opposed to restoring employment or equilibrium by small, gradual, piecemeal adjustments . . . we must achieve the same result by inating the money supply and raising the price level, so everybodys real wages are slashed by the same percentage. . . . The Keynesian remedy, in short, is like changing the lock to avoid changing to the right key, or like adjusting the piano to the stool instead of the stool to the piano.16 Second, Hazlitt pointed out that workers and labor unions are aware of how rising prices affect the real value of money wages. There is certainly no money illusion in an upward direction. An increasing cost of living due to rising prices soon brings worker and union demands for higher pay to make 17
Says Law
Hazlitt showed that Keynes had misunderstood what the Jean-Baptiste Say and other nineteenth-century economists meant. Goods can virtually always nd buyers if prices are sufciently attractive. The preKeynesian classical economists never denied that goods can go unsold and labor unemployed if suppliers fail to adjust their prices and wages to match existing market demand. Furthermore, Hazlitt explained, many of the classical economists, especially John Stuart Mill, understood that individuals could hoard money rather than immediately spend it. But this was most frequently due to the temporary uncertainties of an economic crisis, usually caused by a prior, unstable inationary boom.15 The central aw in Keyness thinking, Hazlitt insisted, was his unwillingness to acknowledge that the high unemployment in Great Britain in the 1920s and the United States in the 1930s was caused by government intervention, including the empowering of labor unions, that made many prices and wages virtually rigid. Political and special-interest power prevented markets from competitively re-establishing a balance between supply and demand for various goods. Hence, the market was trapped in wage and price distortions that destroyed employment and production opportunities, resulting in the Great Depression. (Hazlitt did not deny that the contraction of the
The Freeman: Ideas on Liberty November 2004 up for lost purchasing power. But if workers and unions demand the same real wages they had before the ination, then the Keynes solution to unemployment must fail. Finally, Keyness macroeconomic approach also concealed the fact that beneath the aggregate rising price level, ination distorts many of the relative price relationships, including the rate of interest. This inevitably brings about misdirection of resources, capital, and labor across different sectors of the market that will eventually require a reshufing of supply and demand once the ination ends. Thus the inationary cure for unemployment brings in its wake an eventual new bout of unemployment when workers have to shift jobs and readjust their wage demands in the post-inationary period. Indeed, in a series of chapters, Hazlitt clearly showed that Keynes was confused about the actual relationships among savings, investment, and the rate of interest. The core of his theory was founded on a bundle of errors and mistakes. This resulted in Keyness failure to comprehend that saving, investment, and capital formationnot government-stimulated increases in aggregate consumer demandare the foundations of sustainable employment and rising standards of living.17 Hazlitt also took Keynes to task for advocating increasing government control and direction of investment decision-making. Keynes clearly believed, Hazlitt sarcastically observed, that there exists a class of people (perhaps economists very much resembling Lord Keynes) who are completely informed, rational, balanced, wise, who have means of knowing at all times exactly how much investment is needed and in exactly what amounts it should be allocated to exactly which industries and projects, and that these managers are above corruption and above any interest in the outcome of the next election.18 If The General Theory had so many fundamental aws, how did it become, in the words of one of his most enthusiastic followers, the Keynesian bible?19 Hazlitt offered some possible reasons in his introduction to his edited volume, The Critics of 18 Keynesian Economics, which appeared a year after his own book. He suggested that Keyness theories rationalized the politics of special-interest groups that desired to reap the benets of an ination. Also, while much of The General Theory is written in difcult language, Keynes could dazzle the reader with literary imagery and wit that hid his central logical aws. Keynes used the technique of obscure arguments followed by clear and triumphant conclusions, Hazlitt said. And nally, Hazlitt conjectured that the success of the book may have had a lot to do with its appearing to overthrow the existing orthodoxy in favor of radical and fashionable ideas about social engineering. But whatever the full explanation of the Keynesian cult, Hazlitt concluded, its existence is one of the great intellectual scandals of our age.20 The monolithic domination that Keynesian economics once had over all macroeconomic policy has been broken for more than two decades. While too many of Keyness misconceptions still underlie how economists think about ination, recession, and unemployment, the original and primitive Keynesian thinking has been more or less overthrown. To a great extent this is because of the thorough and brilliant demolition that Henry Hazlitt performed more than 40 years ago.
1. Henry Hazlitt, The Failure of the New Economics: An Analysis of the Keynesian Fallacies (Princeton: D. Van Nostrand, 1959), reprinted by the Foundation for Economic Education in 1995. 2. The most comprehensive biography of Keynes is Robert Skidelsky, John Maynard Keynes: Hopes Betrayed, 18831920 (London: Macmillan, 1983), John Maynard Keynes: The Economist as Saviour, 19201937 (London: Macmillan, 1992), and John Maynard Keynes: Fighting for Britain, 19371946 (London: Macmillan, 2000); in addition, see, Roy H. Harrod, The Life of John Maynard Keynes (London: Macmillan, 1951), and D. E. Moggridge, Maynard Keynes: An Economists Biography (London: Routledge, 1992). All of them are highly sympathetic to Keynes as an economist and policy advocate. 3. John Maynard Keynes, The Economic Consequences of the Peace (New York: Harcourt, Brace, 1920); see the critical analysis of Keyness arguments about the peace treaty by Etienne Mantoux, The Carthaginian Peace, or The Economic Consequences of Mr. Keynes (New York: Charles Scribners Sons, 1952). 4. John Maynard Keynes, A Tract on Monetary Reform (New York: Harcourt, Brace, 1924); see the critical analysis of Keyness arguments by Benjamin M. Anderson, The Gold Standard vs. A Managed Currency, Chase Economic Bulletin, March 23, 1925, p. 39. 5. John Maynard Keynes, A Treatise on Money, 2 vols. (New York: Harcourt Brace, 1930).
19