Does Party Polarization Affect the Electoral Prospects of a New Centrist Candidate? †
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Related Literature
3. Experimental Design
4. Experimental Results
4.1. Aggregate Election Outcomes
4.2. Individual Voting Behavior
5. Conclusions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Instructions
Appendix A.1. General Rules
- The experiment will last approximately 90 min.
- You will receive a 5-dollar show-up fee for arriving on time. In addition, you will receive additional earnings, which will depend on decisions you and other participants make during the experiment.
- Your total earnings will be paid out to you privately and in cash at the end of the experiment. No other participant will be told how much money you have earned during the experiment.
- It is important to remain quiet and not talk to other participants during the experiment. If you have a question at any time, please quietly raise your hand, and someone will come to you. Participants who do not respect the silence requirement will be asked to leave.
Appendix A.2. Experiment Instructions
Appendix A.2.1. Experimental Rounds and Groups
Appendix A.2.2. Group Choice and Individual Earnings
Appendix A.2.3. Voting Rule
- If one alternative has received the largest number of votes, this alternative will be the one chosen by your group.
- If two or more alternatives receive the same largest number of votes, then the computer will randomly select one of those alternatives; this will be the one chosen by your group.
Appendix A.2.4. Information at the End of a Round
Appendix B. Screenshots
Appendix C. First Series of Elections
Average Max Vote Share | Average Winning Margin | Frequency of Ties | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
All 8 periods | Extreme | 62.9% | 25.9% | 7.3% |
Moderate | 60.8% | 21.7% | 10.4% | |
p-value | 0.399 | 0.394 | 0.374 | |
Periods 1–4 | Extreme | 64.6% | 29.1% | 4.2% |
Moderate | 61.7% | 23.3% | 6.2% | |
p-value | 0.234 | 0.234 | 0.5 | |
Periods 5–8 | Extreme | 61.3% | 22.7% | 10.4% |
Moderate | 60.0% | 20.0% | 14.6% | |
p-value | 0.261 | 0.261 | 0.411 |
Appendix D. Participants’ Voting Behavior
Own Side Candidate | Centrist Candidate | Opposite Side Candidate | Abstain | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Extreme treatment | Extreme left | 70.3% | 26.6% | 2.08% | 1.04% |
Extreme right | 67.7% | 29.7% | 1.56% | 1.04% | |
p-value | 0.494 | 0.483 | 0.5 | 1 (2-sided test) | |
Center left | 59.9% | 31.2% | 8.85% | 0% | |
Center right | 52.6% | 43.2% | 3.12% | 1.04% | |
p-value | 0.339 | 0.268 | 0.5 | 0.239 | |
Moderate left | 65.6% | 30.2% | 4.2% | 0% | |
Moderate right | 51% | 24% | 16.7% | 8.3% | |
p-value | 0.124 | 0.388 | 0.171 | 0.5 | |
Moderate treatment | Extreme left | 63.5% | 27.1% | 7.3% | 2.1% |
Extreme right | 74.5% | 20.8% | 3.7% | 1% | |
p-value | 0.25 | 0.382 | 0.327 | 0.295 | |
Center left | 75.5% | 18.8% | 5.7% | 0% | |
Center right | 76% | 19.8% | 3.7% | 0.5% | |
p-value | 0.308 | 0.28 | 0.428 | 0.5 | |
Moderate left | 63.5% | 34.4% | 2.1% | 0% | |
Moderate right | 86.5% | 13.5% | 0% | 0% | |
p-value | 0.048 | 0.049 | 0.239 | 1 (2-sided test) |
Appendix E. Ranking of the Centrist Candidate
Top | Second | Last | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
All 8 Periods | Extreme | 43.2% | 33.9% | 22.9% |
Moderate | 21.9% | 28.6% | 49.5% | |
p-value | 0.133 | 0.34 | 0.038 | |
Periods 9–12 | Extreme | 40.6% | 33.3% | 26% |
Moderate | 10.4% | 28.1% | 61.5% | |
p-value | 0.027 | 0.317 | 0.023 | |
Periods 13–16 | Extreme | 45.8% | 34.4% | 19.8% |
Moderate | 33.3% | 29.2% | 37.5% | |
p-value | 0.239 | 0.462 | 0.067 |
1 | The literature has offered several explanations for the rise in polarization. In the case of the US, Theriault (2008) [3] argues that it follows from the interaction of several factors, which include (1) congressional institutional changes, which have restricted congressmen’s prerogatives and given more power to polarized leaders, and (2) the geographical sorting of voters, which leads to the election of more ideological representatives. Abramowitz (2010; 5) [4] proposes another explanation that relies on candidates paying special attention to the views of their partisans, who tend to be among the most ideologically polarized in the population: “⋯ polarization at the elite level is largely a reflection of polarization among the politically engaged segment of the American public.” Others, such as McCarty (2019; 99) [2], argue that there are many plausible causes for the rise in polarization: “⋯ strong cases can be made for a wide variety of causes ranging from the Southern Realignment to increasing economic inequality and racial/ethnic diversity to the reemergence of strong party competition for the control of the federal government.” At a more general level, see Osborne (1995) [5] or Bol, Dellis and Oak (2017) [6], among others, for a review of explanations for party polarization, which have been identified in the theoretical literature on electoral competition. |
2 | Bol, Blais and Labbé St-Vincent (2018) [19] is a rare laboratory experiment with both strategic candidacy and strategic voting. However, it does not look at polarization, contrasting with the present paper. |
3 | |
4 | The experimental instructions use neutral language, designating candidates as alternatives and referring to them by colors, as is common practice in the experimental voting literature (e.g., Forsythe, Myerson, Rietz and Weber, 1993) [8]. For each group, colors (Blue, Green, Orange, Purple and Red) are assigned randomly to candidates. Appendix A, Appendix B, Appendix C, Appendix D and Appendix E provides the experimental instructions. |
5 | As Figure 1 indicates, there is one voter with each of the following ideal points: 4, 5, 7, 10, 13, 15 and 16. There are two voters with an ideal point of 6 and two other voters with an ideal point of 14. The two voters at 6 (respectively 14) obtain the same payoff from the left moderate as from the left extremist (respectively, from the right moderate as from the right extremist). The two voters at 4 and 5 (respectively, 15 and 16) prefer the left extremist to the left moderate (respectively, the right extremist to the right moderate). Finally, the voter at 7 (respectively, 13) prefers the left moderate to the left extremist (respectively, the right moderate to the right extremist). |
6 | These two series of elections were followed by two other series that addressed a different research question and are discussed in a separate paper; see Dellis and Vanberg (2021) [30] for details. |
7 | Having only two candidates in the first series of elections is meant to be consistent with Duverger’s law (Duverger, 1954 [31]), which states that Plurality Voting tends to favor a two-party system. |
8 | It is worth mentioning that the centrist is the Condorcet winner, that is, the candidate who would defeat any of the other two candidates in a pairwise contest. |
9 | Virtually everybody who registered was able to participate in the experiment; only a small number of late-comers were not able to participate as the sessions were already fully booked. Almost all people who registered and participated in the experiment were students with a mix of undergraduate and graduate students. Students were registered in many programs, with a greater proportion of participants studying economics. |
10 | Instructions appear in the Appendix A. The experiment was computerized using the software Z-tree (Fischbacher, 2007 [32]). |
11 | Screenshots of the vote and result screens are included in the Appendix A, Appendix B, Appendix C, Appendix D and Appendix E. |
12 | I thank a referee for the suggestion to add this table. |
13 | It is worth mentioning that among the left and right candidates, the one leading at period 9 (that is, the one who obtains the maximum Left-Right vote share) is almost always the one who was leading at period 8 (that is, the period just before the addition of the centrist candidate) with the same frequencies in both treatments. Specifically, out of the 24 groups, 20 (10 in each treatment) have a leading candidate at period 8, and 4 (2 in each treatment) have a tie between the two candidates. Out of the 20 groups with a leading candidate at period 8, 16 (8 in each treatment) have at period 9 the same candidate with the highest vote share among the left and right candidates. |
14 | Consistent with Duverger’s law, participants tend to desert the trailing candidate (i.e., the candidate with the lowest vote share). In the extreme treatment, the average lowest vote share among the three candidates drops from 17.7% in period 9 to 8.6% in period 16. Similarly, in the moderate treatment, the average lowest vote share among the three candidates drops from 23% in period 9 to 13.6% in period 16. I shall return to this observation below when looking at participants’ voting behavior. |
15 | In case of a tie, I assign the higher rank. For example, if the centrist ties for first place, I categorize him as having received the highest vote share. Alternatively, if the centrist ties with another candidate for the second-highest and lowest positions, I categorize the centrist as having received the second-highest vote share. It is worth mentioning that the conclusions are robust to breaking ties equiprobably (rather than in favor of the highest rank). For example, if the centrist ties for first place with another candidate, then with equiprobable tie-breaking, the centrist is categorized as having received the highest and the second-highest vote shares, each with frequency 1/2. Table A3 in the Appendix E reports the frequencies of the centrist candidate at the three vote ranks (highest, second-highest, and lowest) when ties are broken equiprobably. |
16 | No three-way tie occurred in any of the 192 elections of the second series. |
17 | Ties are primarily attributable to a setting with a small number of voters; they are rare in elections involving thousands or millions of voters. The above experimental results suggest that the election outcome is more uncertain for the centrist candidate when there is less party polarization. |
18 | It is worth mentioning that in the static game, voting for the centrist candidate is a weakly dominant strategy for a participant located at 10. |
19 | Voting for the candidate on the opposite side (i.e., one’s least-preferred candidate) and abstaining from voting are, in the static game, weakly dominated strategies. The latter follows from costless voting, which explains why we observe in the experimental data (1) a low level of vote abstention and (2) no (statistically significant) treatment difference in vote abstention. However, the literature has found empirical evidence of a relationship between party polarization and voter turnout. The evidence is somewhat mixed. In the US, Abramowitz (2010) [4] finds a positive relationship and Rogowski (2014) [33] finds a negative one (particularly among citizens with lower levels of education). Lee (2013) [34] finds that the sign of the relationship depends on voters’ level of education: negative for the least educated people (as in Rogowski’s study) and positive for the most educated ones. In Latin America, Béjar, Moraes and López-Cariboni (2020) [35] find a positive relationship. In France, Munõz and Meguid (2021) [36] find that the effect of party polarization on voter turnout depends on the position of the voter relative to party positions. Future experiments might introduce some costs of voting. This could add a channel through which party polarization affects a centrist’s electoral prospects. In the present experiment, the whole effect passes through strategic voting behavior. Making voting costly might add an effect that passes through voters’ turnout decisions. |
20 | For simplicity, I exclude elections where the left and right candidates tie. It is worth mentioning that the results are similar if we include those elections and consider both sides as leading. |
References
- Fiorina, M.; Samuel, A. Political polarization in the American public. Annu. Rev. Political Sci. 2008, 11, 563–588. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McCarty, N. Polarization. What Everyone Needs to Know; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Theriault, S. Party Polarization in Congress; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Abramowitz, A. The Disappearing Center. Engaged Citizens, Polarization, and American Democracy; Yale University Press: London, UK, 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Osborne, M. Spatial models of political competition under plurality rule: A survey of some explanations of the number of candidates and the positions they take. Can. J. Econ. D’Economique 1995, 28, 261–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bol, D.; Arnaud, D.; Mandar, O. Candidatures endogènes dans les élections pluralitaires: Quelques explications du nombre de candidats et de leur polarisation. L’Actualité Econ. 2017, 93, 141–171. (In French) [Google Scholar]
- Nagel, J.; Christopher, W. Centre-party strength and major-party divergence in Britain, 1945–2005. Br. J. Political Sci. 2010, 40, 279–304. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Forsythe, R.; Roger, M.; Thomas, R.; Robert, W. An experiment on coordination in multi-candidate elections: The importance of polls and election histories. Soc. Choice Welf. 1993, 10, 223–247. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Granic, D.-G. The problem of the divided majority: Preference aggregation under uncertainty. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2017, 133, 21–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bouton, L.; Aniol, L.-S.; Frédéric, M. Unanimous rules in the laboratory. Games Econ. Behav. 2017, 102, 179–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Forsythe, R.; Roger, M.; Thomas, R.; Robert, W. An experimental study of voting rules and polls in three-candidate elections. Int. J. Game Theory 1996, 25, 355–383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Van der Straeten, K.; Jean-François, L.; Nicolas, S.; André, B. Strategic, sincere, and heuristic voting under four election rules: An experimental study. Soc. Choice Welf. 2010, 35, 435–472. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dellis, A.; Sean, D.; Katerina, S. Multiple votes, ballot truncation and the two-party system: An experiment. Soc. Choice Welf. 2011, 37, 171–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bassi, A. Voting systems and strategic manipulation: An experimental study. J. Theor. Politics 2015, 27, 58–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aragones, E.; Thomas, P. The effect of candidate quality on electoral equilibrium: An experimental study. Am. Political Sci. Rev. 2004, 98, 77–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cadigan, J. The citizen candidate model: An experimental analysis. Public Choice 2005, 123, 197–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tsakas, N.; Dimitrios, X. Electoral competition with third party entry in the lab. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2018, 148, 121–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grosser, J.; Thomas, P. Candidate entry and political polarization: An experimental study. Am. Political Sci. 2019, 113, 209–225. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bol, D.; André, B.; Simon, L. Which matters most: Party strategic exit or voter strategic voting? A laboratory experiment. Political Sci. Res. Methods 2018, 6, 229–244. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bol, D.; Arnaud, D.; Mandar, O. Comparison of voting procedures using models of electoral competition with endogenous candidacy. In The Political Economy of Social Choices; Gallego, M., Schofield, N., Eds.; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- Palfrey, T. Spatial equilibrium with entry. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1984, 51, 139–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Weber, S. On hierarchical spatial competition. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1992, 59, 407–425. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Weber, S. Entry deterrence in electoral spatial competition. Soc. Choice Welf. 1997, 15, 31–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Osborne, M. Candidate positioning and entry in a political competition. Games Econ. Behav. 1993, 5, 133–151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Osborne, M.; Slivinski, A. A model of political competition with citizen-candidates. Q. J. Econ. 1996, 111, 65–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Besley, T.; Stephen, C. An economic model of representative democracy. Q. J. Econ. 1997, 112, 85–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dellis, A. Would letting people vote for multiple candidates yield policy moderation? J. Econ. Theory 2009, 144, 772–801. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dellis, A.; Mandar, O. Multiple votes, multiple candidacies and polarization. Soc. Choice Welf. 2016, 46, 1–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xefteris, D. Stability in electoral competition: A case for multiple votes. J. Econ. Theory 2016, 161, 76–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dellis, A.; Christoph, V. Rank Voting and Polarization: An Experiment. Mimeo 2021. [Google Scholar]
- Duverger, M. Political Parties; Wiley: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 1954. [Google Scholar]
- Fischbacher, U. Z-tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-made Economic Experiment. Exp. Econ. 2007, 10, 171–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rogowski, J. Electoral choice, ideological conflict, and political participation. Am. J. Political Sci. 2014, 58, 479–494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lee, J.M. Elite polarization and mass political engagement: Information, alienation, and mobilization. J. Int. Area Studies 2013, 20, 89–109. [Google Scholar]
- Béjar, S.; Juan, M.; Santiago, L.-C. Elite polarization and voting turnout in Latin America, 1993–2010. J. Elect. Public Opin. Parties 2020, 30, 1–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Murias, M.M.; Bonnie, M. Does party polarization mobilize or de-mobilize voters? The answer depends on where voters stand. Elect. Stud. 2021, 70, 102279. [Google Scholar]
Centrist | Maximum Left-Right | Minimum Left-Right | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
All 8 periods | Extreme | 37.0% | 45.8% | 17.2% |
Moderate | 28.5% | 44.7% | 26.9% | |
p-value | 0.082 | 0.473 | 0.006 | |
Periods 9–12 | Extreme | 37.0% | 43.9% | 19.1% |
Moderate | 25.2% | 45.4% | 29.4% | |
p-value | 0.049 | 0.233 | 0.008 | |
Periods 13–16 | Extreme | 36.9% | 47.7% | 15.4% |
Moderate | 31.8% | 43.9% | 24.3% | |
p-value | 0.217 | 0.162 | 0.019 |
Top | Second | Last | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
All 8 periods | Extreme | 46.9% | 33.3% | 19.8% |
Moderate | 27.1% | 29.2% | 43.8% | |
p-value | 0.132 | 0.416 | 0.038 | |
Periods 9–12 | Extreme | 45.8% | 33.3% | 20.8% |
Moderate | 14.6% | 29.2% | 56.2% | |
p-value | 0.043 | 0.419 | 0.017 | |
Periods 13–16 | Extreme | 47.9% | 33.3% | 18.8% |
Moderate | 39.6% | 29.2% | 31.2% | |
p-value | 0.345 | 0.475 | 0.173 |
Outright Wins | Two-Way Ties | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
, | , | ||||
All 8 periods | Extreme | 38 | 47 | 4 | 7 |
Moderate | 16 | 58 | 12 | 10 | |
Periods 9–12 | Extreme | 17 | 24 | 2 | 5 |
Moderate | 3 | 31 | 10 | 4 | |
Periods 13–16 | Extreme | 21 | 23 | 2 | 2 |
Moderate | 13 | 27 | 2 | 6 |
Own-Side Candidate | Centrist Candidate | Opposite-Side Candidate | Abstain | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
All 8 periods | Extreme | 61.8% | 31.6% | 5.2% | 1.4% |
Moderate | 72.9% | 22.1% | 4.3% | 0.7% | |
p-value | 0.035 | 0.052 | 0.54 | 0.327 | |
Periods 9–12 | Extreme | 61.9% | 31.5% | 5% | 1.7% |
Moderate | 76.5% | 18.3% | 4.6% | 0.6% | |
p-value | 0.042 | 0.037 | 0.495 | 0.239 | |
Periods 13–16 | Extreme | 61.7% | 31.7% | 5.4% | 1.2% |
Moderate | 69.4% | 25.8% | 4% | 0.8% | |
p-value | 0.091 | 0.162 | 0.479 | 0.5 |
Trailing Side | Leading Side | ||
---|---|---|---|
All 8 Periods | Extreme | 2.7 | 0.59 |
Moderate | 1.8 | 0.54 | |
p-value | 0.027 | 0.517 | |
Periods 9–12 | Extreme | 2.6 | 0.72 |
Moderate | 1.5 | 0.53 | |
p-value | 0.006 | 0.273 | |
Periods 13–16 | Extreme | 2.85 | 0.46 |
Moderate | 2.05 | 0.55 | |
p-value | 0.058 | 0.336 |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Dellis, A. Does Party Polarization Affect the Electoral Prospects of a New Centrist Candidate? Games 2022, 13, 53. https://doi.org/10.3390/g13040053
Dellis A. Does Party Polarization Affect the Electoral Prospects of a New Centrist Candidate? Games. 2022; 13(4):53. https://doi.org/10.3390/g13040053
Chicago/Turabian StyleDellis, Arnaud. 2022. "Does Party Polarization Affect the Electoral Prospects of a New Centrist Candidate?" Games 13, no. 4: 53. https://doi.org/10.3390/g13040053
APA StyleDellis, A. (2022). Does Party Polarization Affect the Electoral Prospects of a New Centrist Candidate? Games, 13(4), 53. https://doi.org/10.3390/g13040053