1. Introduction
In 2015, the exchange rate became a hot issue for Vietnam’s economy with regard to concerns about China’s devaluation of the Yuan, the increase of the federal fund rate of Fed, and the US dollar appreciation against many currencies in the world. Due to being pegged to the USD, the Vietnam Dong (VND) became more expensive against many foreign currencies, thus, the competitiveness of Vietnamese goods and the trade balance was affected negatively. The debatable policy question is whether a dong-pegged-to-the-dollar policy over the years remains appropriate. From a corporate perspective, does the stability of the VND against USD support enterprises to avoid risk in international business because the US dollar is the main payment currency, or enterprises may be adversely impacted by the uncertainty of bilateral exchange rates for currencies of different countries around the world? In the period of integrating into the world’s economy, Vietnam could be seriously challenged by the increase in such risks, therefore, it is necessary to find a suitable exchange rate arrangement. Under that situation, on 31 December 2015, the State Bank of Vietnam issued Decision No. 2730/QD-NHNN to announce the way to determine the central rate of the VND against the USD, which would be used by financial institutions authorized to trade in foreign currencies. The rate is calculated based on three benchmarks: demand and supply of the Vietnam Dong, the movement of eight currencies of the countries having the largest weights for trading and investment with Vietnam, including the USD, the Euro, the Chinese Yuan, the Japanese Yen, the Singapore Dollar, the South Korean Won, the Thai Baht, and the Taiwan Dollar, and macroeconomic balance.
However, whether the exchange rate stability based on the eight major currencies really brings advantages to international trade or not is still a significant question because of the mixed results of theoretical, as well as empirical, studies on the impact of exchange rate volatility on international trade, although many studies also propose that mitigating exchange rate risk is very important to ensuring that the exports of a country achieve sustained stable growth. Moreover, in Vietnam, economists often study the impact of exchange rate movement on the trade balance, inflation, and economic growth, while studies concentrating on measuring and assessing the influence of exchange rate volatility are still limited, especially in regards to the macro approach. Therefore, it is worthwhile to investigate the effect of exchange rate volatility on exports in the Vietnam context.
For all of the above reasons, this paper investigates the impact of exchange rate volatility between VND and the basket of eight foreign currencies referred to in the central rate benchmark on exports of the Vietnamese economy using quarterly data from the first quarter of 2000 to the fourth quarter of 2014 and the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) method of
Pesaran et al. (
2001). Pesaran’s ARDL method shows having comparatively superior forecasting performance compared to the other techniques based on co-integration (
Iqbal and Uddin 2013;
Adom and Bekoe 2012). The result shows that export performance will be impacted by exchange rate volatility in the long run. A one percent increase in exchange rate volatility will reduce export volume significantly by about 0.11 percent. However, an appreciation of the domestic currency can adversely affect the competitiveness of Vietnamese exports in the international market in the short run, while the Vietnam Dong’s devaluation will have positive impacts and improve exports in the long run. A surprising finding is that real foreign income has a negative impact on export volume of Vietnam in both the long run and the short run. The findings provide some implications for managers, policymakers, and entrepreneurs. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows:
Section 2 reviews the theoretical background and econometric techniques for examining the effect of exchange rate volatility on exports. Next,
Section 3 describes the model, methodology and relevant data used for quantitative assessment in the case of Vietnam. Then, the estimation results are discussed in
Section 4. Finally,
Section 5 concludes with a summary of findings and policy recommendations.
2. Theoretical Framework and Literature Review
Different theories exist in the literature regarding the impact of exchange rate volatility on exporter behavior. An increase in exchange rate volatility may be associated with either an increase or a decrease in the volume of exports, given plausible alternative assumptions.
Traditionally, it has been argued that exchange rate volatility will have a negative influence on exports.
Clark (
1973) analyses a very early example, in which a firm produces a homogenous commodity and exports its products entirely to one foreign market. In this basic model, the market is considered as perfectly competitive and imported inputs are not required. The firm receives payments for its exports in foreign currency and hedging possibilities are extremely limited. Owing to adjustment costs, the firm cannot change its output over the planning horizon. The unpredictable variation of the exchange rate, therefore, is solely blame for uncertainty about future export sales as well as future profits in domestic currency. For the sake of maximizing the expected value of utility, which depends on both the expected value and the variance of profits, the risk-averse firm would reduce its exposure to risk in response to higher volatility in the exchange rate. That is, the volume of production, and hence exports would be cut down in this circumstance. This simple model is also developed by a number of authors, for example,
Baron (
1976b);
Hooper and Kohlhagen (
1978), indicated the same conclusion that exchange rate volatility has a negative effect on exports.
However, all of those conclusions result from several restrictive assumptions. One obvious criticism of the traditional models is that the exporter’s risk exposure is attributed solely to the exchange rate volatility, whereas it may depend on the availability of hedging techniques, diversification possibilities, the existence of imported inputs, and other factors. The rationale of this assumption is that forward exchange markets are just in infancy or even not appear in developing economies. In addition, transaction hedging may prove relatively expensive and challenging for some manufacturing firms with a long time between order and delivery. However, this is not the case with advanced countries, in which such markets are well-developed. For risk-adverse entrepreneurs who can hedge their contracts, a higher exchange rate volatility would not always deter exports, as noted by
Ethier (
1973) and
Baron (
1976a). Furthermore, the companies can minimize exchange rate risk in other ways; take multinational cooperation to be a good case in point. Being involved in a wide range of trade and financial transactions over numerous countries, it would see an abundance of diverse opportunities to offset the movement of a bilateral exchange rate, such as the variability of other exchange rates or interest rates. Relaxing the assumption of no imported intermediate inputs,
Clark (
1973) finds that the loss from the depreciation in a foreign currency to the exporter will be partly alleviated by lowering input cost. Likewise, if inventories are possible and firms can allocate their sales between abroad and home markets, a declining effect on export earnings will also be compensated. More generally, from a finance perspective,
Makin (
1978) argues that a diversified firm holding a portfolio of assets and liabilities determined in various currencies will be able to protect itself from exchange rate risks related to exports and imports. Finally, recent studies suggest that exchange rate volatility does not just embody a risk, but profit opportunities. For instance, as examined by
Canzoneri et al. (
1984), if a firm has ability to alter its factor inputs to benefit from changes in exchange rate without adjustment costs, a higher volatility may create greater probability to make profit.
Gros (
1987) derives a further version of model with the presence of adjustment costs, in which exporting can be seen as an option depending on capacity, taking advantage of favorable conditions (e.g., high prices) and to minimizing the influence otherwise. The value of the option rises as result of higher variability of the exchange rate, creating a positive effect on exports. Therefore, the effect of volatility remains ambiguous because the dominant direction depends on a case-by-case basis.
In the early models, the negative association between exchange rate volatility and expected export increases is supported in terms of risk aversion. The uncertainty of the exchange rate seems to not affect a risk-neutral firm’s decision. Nonetheless,
De Grauwe (
1988) argues that the assumption of risk-averse agents is not adequate to ensure the direction of this link. What is relevant is the degree of risk aversion. An increase in risk, in general, has both a substitution and an income effect that work in opposite directions (
Goldstein and Khan 1985). The substitution effect discourages risk-averse agents to export because it lowers the expected utility representing the attractiveness of the risky activity, while the income effects urges very risk-averse agents to increase their exports to avoid the possibility of a severe decline in the revenues. Taken together, these studies support the notion that even though firms are worse off with an increase in exchange rate risk, their response may be to export more rather than less.
All of the theoretical studies reviewed here support the notion that the net effect of exchange rate volatility on exports is ambiguous, as differing results can arise from plausible alternative assumptions and modelling strategies. Increased exchange rate volatility can have no significant effect on exports, or where significant, no systematic effect in one direction or the other.
Numerous empirical studies have been conducted in many countries and areas around the world to evaluate the impact of exchange rate volatility on exports. Again, the implications of the results of those studies confirm that, although exchange rate volatility has an impact on exports, the effect can be either positive or negative depending on the endowment of each country; whether empirical studies use aggregate data, sectoral data or bilateral data; and the econometric techniques applied.
The empirical literature using aggregate data tends to find weak evidence in favor of a negative impact of exchange rate uncertainty on the trade flows of a country to the rest of the world. Using the Engel-Granger method,
Doroodian (
1999) approximated volatility with both Autoregressive Integrated Moving Average (ARIMA) and Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (GARCH) techniques to study the exports of India, Malaysia, and South Korea from the second quarter of 1973 to the third quarter of 1996. The results reveal significantly negative effects of exchange rate volatility on exports. Meanwhile, employing the Johansen approach of co-integration and using Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (ARCH) method to calculate volatility,
Arize and Malindretos (
1998) found mixed results for two Pacific-Basin countries: volatility is shown to depress New Zealand exports, while its impact is positive in the case of Australia.
To sum up, the majority of empirical studies indicate that the relationship between a single country’s exports and exchange rate volatility is statistically significantly negative in the long run, especially in developing countries, while others consider that there is the positive relationship in the short run or long run. The basis for empirical model development is mostly based on simple demand functions of exports. Relative prices, income, and volatility are often employed as determinants. There are two major problems facing the applied econometrics in these studies. Firstly, there has not yet been a standard exchange rate volatility proxy (
Bahmani-Oskooee and Hegerty 2007). Some measure of variance has dominated this field, but the precise calculation of this measure differs from study to study. Later estimates have involved using the standard deviation of a rate of change or the level of a variable.
Kenen and Rodrik (
1986) draw attention to the moving standard deviation of the monthly change in the exchange rate, which has the advantage of being stationary. Utilizing newer time-series methods,
Engle and Granger (
1987) developed Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (ARCH) as a measure of volatility in time-series errors, which is a widespread measure of exchange rate volatility in the literature. A broader perspective is adopted by (
Pattichis 2003) who develops Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (GARCH), which incorporates moving-average processes. These authors’ estimates also have the desirable property of stationarity. Some measures are more popular than others, however, none stands out as the standard volatility proxy (
Bahmani-Oskooee and Hegerty 2007). The second problem is the type of method used in estimating the empirical model. While the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) was commonly used in the early papers, newer and more sophisticated techniques, including time-series and panel data methods, in recent studies have facilitated investigation of the sensitivity of exports to a measure of exchange rate volatility. The main goal of modern time-series analysis is to take into consideration integrating properties of the variables so that spurious results can be avoided. Some popular methods of time-series analysis in recent years are the Engle-Granger method, the Johansen method, and the bounds testing approach.
3. Exchange Rate Volatility Measurement
Exchange rate volatility denotes the amount of uncertainty or risk about the size of changes in the exchange rate. If the exchange rate can potentially be spread out over a larger range of values in a short time span, it is termed to have high volatility. If the exchange rate does not fluctuate dramatically, and tends to be steadier, it is termed to have low volatility. Additionally, real and nominal exchange rate volatilities are different for practical purposes. The properties of the method used to estimate volatility have also received lots of attention.
Bahmani-Oskooee and Hegerty (
2007) emphasizes the fact that a clearly dominant approximation for uncertainty has not yet emerged up to now.
In this paper, the exchange rate volatility is measured by the moving average of the standard deviation of exchange rates, which is typically used by a number of scholars such as
Chowdhury (
1993);
Arize and Malindretos (
1998);
Kasman and Kasman (
2005). This equation is as follows:
where m is the number of periods; and t is time and ER refers to the exchange rate index. In our study, m = 2.
Bagella et al. (
2006) show advantages of effective exchange rate volatility comparing with bilateral exchange rate volatility and find that this variable performs much better than the bilateral exchange rate volatility measure. An important advantage is that the effective exchange rate reflects more sufficiently the stability of a country which might have low bilateral exchange rate volatility with a leading currency but absorb instability via variability of economic policies of its trade partners. Therefore, we use the nominal effective exchange rate between the VND and a foreign currency basket (NEER) to compute the exchange rate volatility. This selected basket consists of eight foreign currencies used by the SBV to refer to the central exchange rate from the beginning of 2016, including: USD (United States), EUR (EU), CNY (China), THB (Thailand), JPY (Japan), SGD (Singapore) KRW (Korea), and TWD (Taiwan). This option aims to assess the validity of the new exchange rate policy for export purposes. Following the splicing procedure proposed by
Ellis (
2001), this index is computed as:
where
is the real effective exchange rate of Vietnam at time
;
is the nominal bilateral exchange rate relative to currency of country
, measured as the number of units of the domestic currency per unit of currency of country
and expressed as an index;
is the weight assigned to the currency of country
at time
, reflecting the contribution of the country
to Vietnam’s foreign trade,
In Equation (2), the nominal effective exchange rate is calculated as the ratio of geometrically weighted bilateral nominal exchange rates in the current period and in the preceding period, using current weights, spliced onto the preceding level of nominal effective exchange rate. There are two main advantages associated with the use of this approach. Firstly, the weights are allowed to vary over time in order to account for the possibility that some countries may become more important trading partners. Otherwise, if actual trade shares move significantly and this is not taken into consideration, the effective exchange rate would give a misleading picture of the net effect of movements in particular bilateral exchange rates. Secondly, as changing weights are updated, it is important that the exchange rate index should be spliced together with the previous observation. Otherwise, in periods in which the weights change, it would not be clear whether a change in the
is reflecting changes in the weights or in the bilateral exchange rates, as we can see from a common calculation:
. There are some prior studies using this approach, such as
Moccero and Winograd (
2006);
Chinn (
2006);
Betliy (
2002);
Dullien (
2005).
Data for bilateral exchange rates and trade weights are computed from International Financial Statistics (IFS) and Direction of Trade Statistics (DOTS) of IMF.
Figure 1 describes the volatility of NEER of the Vietnam Dong versus the eight currency basket for the period from the first quarter of 2000 to the fourth quarter of 2014. The degree of this volatility depends on the exchange rate policy and the fluctuation of foreign currencies in the world market. As can be seen from
Figure 1, the NEER volatility fluctuated gradually from 2000 to 2007, dramatically increased during the following four years and decreased between 2012 and 2014.
After introducing a new principle for setting the exchange rate in 1999, the volatility from 2000 to 2008 was relatively small as the official exchange rate was almost unchanged. During the period from 2008 to 2011, the State Bank of Vietnam had devalued three times the Vietnam Dong by approximately 10% and adjusted the trading band in commercial banks continuously (widened the band five times from ±0.5% to ±5% and then narrowed it back to 1%). These actions increased the exchange rate fluctuation. From 2012 to 2014, the official exchange rate remained stable except for a devaluation in June 2013 and the trading band was fixed at ±1%, therefore, the volatility was small.
5. Conclusions
This paper aims to examine the impact of exchange rate volatility on Vietnamese exports performance during the period from the first quarter of 2000 to the fourth quarter of 2014. We use the Moving Average of Standard Deviation (MASD) model and nominal effective exchange rates computed by a weighted average of the nominal bilateral exchange rate of the Vietnam Dong against the basket of eight foreign currencies to measure exchange rate volatility. This paper also applies an approach called the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) to investigate the existence of a level relationship among variables in the model and implements it using EVIEWS software offered by IHS Markit (London, UK). The advantage of this approach is that it is suitable for small sample size and regressors which are a mixture of I(0) and I(1).
It is found that there exists a co-integration relationship between real exports, real foreign income, real effective exchange rate, and nominal exchange rate volatility. In addition, the speed of adjustment to the long run equilibrium is fairly high.
The result shows that export performance will be impacted by exchange rate volatility in the long run. A one percent increase in exchange rate volatility will reduce export volume significantly by about 0.11 percent. One anticipated finding is that real foreign income has a negative impact on export volume of Vietnam in both the long run and the short run. As the income of trading partners increases, they tend to import fewer Vietnamese goods, which reflects that the position of Vietnamese goods in the international market remains low-grade. Finally, an appreciation of the domestic currency can adversely affect the competitiveness of Vietnamese exports in the international market in the short run, while the Vietnam Dong’s devaluation will have positive impacts and improve exports in the long run. Since the inflation rate of Vietnam is unstable, it may impact the exporters’ expectations of movement of real exchange rate. We will deal with this issue for our future empirical research.
These findings have some important policy implications. Firstly, for the State Bank of Vietnam, the conversion of the exchange rate regime from announcing a solid exchange rate between the VND and the US to announcing a central rate and cross rates with eight strong currencies is the right direction to promote export performance. The weighting for these currencies in the basket may be calculated based on stabilizing the nominal effective exchange rate with these eight currencies to reduce exchange rate uncertainty.
Secondly, besides considering exchange rate policy, it is essential for the government to adapt synchronous implementation solutions to overcome the bottlenecks in Vietnamese exports. Production cost, brand value, product quality, and technology content are key factors which threaten to decrease export competitiveness.
Finally, in the context of Vietnam, as the foreign currency derivatives market has not fully developed and there are potential risks in international business, enterprises needs a proper international trade strategy, including a long-term vision for risk analysis and forecasting, combined with the flexible use of risk hedging tools such as futures, options, swap contracts. In addition, exporters wishing to promote their international trade should not rely solely on the devaluation of the domestic currency, but on the long-term strategy in building their brand, defining their comparative advantages and increasing market access.