FreeEconHelp.com, Learning Economics... Solved!: algebra
Showing posts with label algebra. Show all posts
Showing posts with label algebra. Show all posts

8/7/18

How to find equilibrium price and quantity mathematically

10:05
How to find equilibrium price and quantity mathematically
Edit: Updated August 2018 with more examples and links to relevant topics.

Summary:  To solve for equilibrium price and quantity you should perform the following steps:

1) Solve for the demand function and the supply function in terms of Q (quantity).

2) Set Qs (quantity supplied) equal to Qd (quantity demanded). The equations will be in terms of price (P)

3) Solve for P, this is going to be your equilibrium Price for the problem.

4) Plug your equilibrium price into either your demand or supply function (or both--but most times it will be easier to plug into supply) and solve for Q, which will give you equilibrium quantity.


When solving for equilibrium price and quantity, you need to have a demand function, and a supply function.  Sometimes you will be given an inverse demand function (ie. P = 5 –Q) in this case you need to solve for Q as a function of P.  Once you have both your supply and demand function, you simply need to set quantity demanded equal to quantity supplied, and solve.

This is best explained by using an example...

Suppose your monthly quantity demand function for a product is Qd = 10,000-80P, and your monthly quantity supply function for a product is Qs=20P, then we need to follow the first step outlined above and set Qd=Qs and solve for price.

1)    Qd=Qs   which is also equal to--
2)    10,000 – 80P = 20P

We then must add 80P to both sides, then divide by 100 to get:

7/30/18

Price elasticity of demand example

10:07
Price elasticity of demand example

Price elasticity of demand example question where you have to solve for the percent change in quantity or price instead of the elasticity measure. Imagine an elasticity question that gives you the elasticity and then asks you to calculate the percent change in either quantity or price given the percent change in the other term. For example, you are told that the price elasticity of demand for apples is -2 and that  quantity demanded of applies increases from 100 apples to 250 apples. What would the corresponding change in price have to be to accommodate this change in quantity demanded?

First we have to set up our standard price elasticity of demand formula or equation:

10/1/15

What is present value?

13:12
What is present value?
The present value is the value in today's dollars of an asset, benefit, or cost that will occur in the future. Perhaps the easiest way to think of a present value is to ask yourself how much you would be willing to accept to sell your rights to a future asset.

For example, is you were to plant an orange tree today you make expect to get $50 worth of oranges in the future. Since you have to wait for the oranges (and their $50 value), the value in today's dollars will be less. If someone is patient and the time they have to wait for the oranges is small, then their willingness to accept amount (the present value) may be $45 or $40. If the person is impatient or has to wait a long period of time, then the willingness to accept amount (the present value) may be much lower approaching $5 or so.

The present value of a future payoff should never be larger than the face value of the payoff. This is a result of the idea of "discounting" which means that people tend to prefer having resources now rather than in the future. For example, imagine you were given the choice between:

9/7/15

What is a price function?

14:49
What is a price function?
Sometimes you will be asked to define a price function. When you receive such a question, it is probably in regards to a supply and demand graph, and you will be asked to graph said price function. The three components of a price function include: price (as you probably expected), an intercept, and quantity. It is also possible for a price function to include many other variables such as preferences, prices of related goods, income, number of buyers, etc. but this is for more complicated price functions (and upper division style classes).

A price function generally looks like:

6/4/15

Price discriminating monopoly, solving for profit maximization

13:28
Price discriminating monopoly, solving for profit maximization
This post goes over the math required to solve for the profit maximizing price and quantity of a price discriminating monopoly operating in two markets. Consider the following problem:


A cable company sells subscriptions in San Francisco and Boston. The demand function for each of the two groups, which are separate and do not have the ability to re-sell to members of the other community, are Psf = 480 - 4Qsf and Pb = 400 -2 Qb. The cost of providing the cable service for the firm is TC = 500 + 4Q, where Q = Qsf + Qb. If the company can price discriminate between the two markets, what are the profit maximizing prices and quantities for the San Francisco and Boston markets?

To solve this problem, we need to review the steps for finding the profit maximizing price and quantity for a monopoly. We find that we need to find the price and quantity where marginal revenue (MR) is equal to marginal cost (MC).

Solving for equilibrium with Qs and Qd

12:45
Solving for equilibrium with Qs and Qd
This post goes over an example of solving for equilibrium price and quantity using the method detailed in the prior equilibrium solving method post. In this example we are given a Qs equation as shown:

Qs= -7909.88 + 79.0988P

Note that this gives us a positive sloping supply curve and that price has to be at least 100 in order for the supplier to produce anything at all (we can figure this out by dividing the intercept 7909.88 by the coefficient on the price 79.0988).

The next step is exploring the demand equation. In this example we are given a demand function as follows:

Qd= 38650 - 40P

Here we have a downward sloping demand curve and the quantity demanded at a price of 0 will be 38650. Once the price reaches 966.25 we will see a quantity demanded of 0 (found by dividing 38650 by 40).

6/27/14

Expected Value vs. Expected Utility, what is the difference?

11:53
Expected Value vs. Expected Utility, what is the difference?
This post highlights the differences between expected value and expected utility and demonstrates how the difference between the two is in how they are calculated. Expected value shows us the value that is to be expected from engaging in a lottery (or risky situation) where there are 2 or more possible outcomes. Likewise, Expected utility shows us the utility that is expected out of a lottery with two or more possibilities. Remember that utility shows the satisfaction or happiness derived from a good/service/money while value simply shows us the monetary value. That is why the two terms are measured differently and show us different things. The rest of this post will describe how to calculate expected value and expected utility and has solved examples demonstrating the importance of the difference between them.

A good rule of thumb is to read the problem, and identify all of the key information. You need to know 4 things:
1) what is the probability of outcome 1?
2) what is the monetary value of outcome 1?, these go into the first term of your equations.
3) what is the probability of outcome 2? This can either be stated explicitly in the problem, or calculated from the probability given for outcome 1.
4) what is the monetary value of outcome 2?, these go into the second term of your equations.

Equations:

2/26/13

How to find a cross price elasticity of demand from a demand equation

16:19
How to find a cross price elasticity of demand from a demand equation


Finding the price elasticity of demand, and the cross price elasticity of demand from a demand function is something that most intermediate microeconomics will require you to know.  This idea is related to finding the point price elasticity of demand covered in a previous post.  For more information on the process you should review that post.  This posting is going to go over an example of calculate both the price elasticity of demand and the cross price elasticity of demand for two related goods from the following demand function to demonstrate how the process is done.

9/16/12

Economics notes on market equilibrium

23:48
Economics notes on market equilibrium


Finding the market equilibrium:

Graphically  -- check out this prior post on finding market equilibrium graphically.

Mathematically – information with examples about finding market equilibrium mathematically.
Here is another example:

Begin with the implicit demand function for bacon: Qd=D(p, pb, pc, Y)
Then you are given the explicit demand function for bacon: Qd=171-20p+20pb+3pc+2Y

5/15/12

Comparing perfectly competitive markets with monopolistically competitive markets, the change in surplus and deadweight loss

22:24
Comparing perfectly competitive markets with monopolistically competitive markets, the change in surplus and deadweight loss

This post goes over the math required to show the difference between surplus and equilibrium in a perfectly competitive and monopolistically competitive market. Note that a monopolistically competitive market's math and graph will be the same for a monopoly or an oligopoly.  Here are the equations to work with:

P = 40 - 8Q
MC = 8

4/13/12

How to aggregate demand functions

00:18
How to aggregate demand functions

We will go over the economics of demand functions for different consumers and how to add them together to get aggregated demand functions.  At the end we will simulate multiple identical consumers and how this will change the associated demand functions, first let’s begin with two types of consumers.  Consumer type 1 has a demand function of:

Q1 = 20 – 2P

And consumer type 2 has a demand function of:

4/12/12

Monopoly math problem with a tax

23:46
Monopoly math problem with a tax

This post goes over the algebraic methods necessary to solve common economics monopoly problems.  We assume that you are given a basic demand function and marginal cost function, and are asked to derive marginal revenue function and find out what the monopoly price and quantity will end up being.

First we are probably given either a demand function (solved for Q) or an inverse demand function (solved for P).  We need the inverse demand function because this gives us the slope of the demand curve (since P is on the Y axis).  Once we have the inverse demand function we can solve for the marginal revenue function by doubling the slope (making it steeper).  A past post goes over the math behind calculating monopoly equilibrium price and quantity, so I will go over another example really quickly then introduce the idea of combining demand curves and adding a tax into the mix.

4/4/12

Mathematically solving for equilibrium Y and I after a shift in the IS/LM model

07:33
Mathematically solving for equilibrium Y and I after a shift in the IS/LM model
This post goes over some mathematical manipulations of the IS/LM model.  It also briefly discusses some of the economic intuition behind the equilibrium and possible shifts:

Suppose the economy can be summarized by the following set of equations:
C = 20 + 0.9Yd – 10(i - 0.1); I = 20 – 10(i - 0.1); G = 20; T = 10 + 0.2Y
Yd = Y - T
Md/P = 0.6Y – 200i
Ms =10,000

We are going to solve the IS and LM equations in terms of Y (and i) and then solve for the equilibrium price, consumption and investment level as well.  After this we will change an exogenous variable simulating expansionary fiscal policy and go through the implications.

3/28/12

Solving for equilibrium price and quantity after a shift in supply and demand

02:07
Solving for equilibrium price and quantity after a shift in supply and demand
 This economics post goes over the tricky problem of determining the change in equilibrium price and quantity after a shift occurs.  This changes both the supply and demand function.  The trick is to know how to enter the shift into the supply and demand equations.  Generally you need to solve the functions for quantity (Q) and change the intercept.

The question in this post is:

Assuming Pd = 250 - 0.5Q and Ps = 100 + 0.25Q, then
What if quantity demanded at every price level increases by 10 and quantity supplied also rises by 5 at every price level?

3/16/12

How to find monopoly price and quantity

22:30
How to find monopoly price and quantity

In this post we go over the economics of monopoly pricing.  We start with a demand function and a total cost function, and are able to figure out the necessary calculations to get to equilibrium quantity and price.

Summary:
1)  We need to equate marginal revenue (MR) to marginal cost (MC) and in order to do this we need to figure out what the MR and MC functions are.  If these are known already, skip to step 4.

3/4/12

Solving for quantity demanded using price elasticity of demand

23:32
Solving for quantity demanded using price elasticity of demand

The price elasticity of demand measure can be used for predicting consumer response to price changes.  One of the most powerful tools in economics is using knowledge of consumer behavior to predict what will happen before the change actually takes place.  The following question considers the consumer response to a price increase in gasoline.  It is always a good thing to study behavior before making a change, otherwise you could potentially not only lose customers, but also go out of business.

2/17/12

Calculating equilibrium and surplus with a tax, a question and answer

06:23
Calculating equilibrium and surplus with a tax, a question and answer

This intensive economics question goes over calculating equilibrium price and quantity, then using those numbers to get consumer and producer surplus, and finally implementing a tax to see how that will change the previous results:

1. The inverse demand curve (or average revenue curve) for the product of a perfectly competitive industry is give by p=80-0.5Q where p is the price and Q is the quantity. The short-run industry marginal cost function is MC=50+0.25Q

a) Calculate the equilibrium price and quantity assuming perfect competition and profit maximization and hence calculate the consumer and producers' surplus.

2/7/12

Per capita production functions, math and graphs

10:34
Per capita production functions, math and graphs

Most of the time in economics’ classes you are given the production function and asked to convert it into a per capita production function for further manipulation.  This article is going to go over the economics of production functions and per capita production functions with 5 different examples including graphs showing what the functions look like.  Check out this other post for information on the math behind getting a production function to a per capita or per person production function, using a generic form and some other specific examples. 

Here is the actual question being looked at:

2/3/12

How to solve dominant firm problems, a question and answer

18:54
How to solve dominant firm problems, a question and answer
This post is going over the economics of a dominant firm problem using algebra and math.  For more information on the economic theory of a dominant firm or price leader model go here.  The actual question being solved is:

In the model of a dominant firm, assume that the fringe supply curve is given by Q= -1+0.2P, where P is market price and Q is output. Demand is given by Q=11 –P. What will price and output be if there is no dominant firm? Now assume that there is a dominant firm, whose marginal cost is constant at $6. Derive the residual demand curve that it faces and calculate its profit-maximizing output and price.

In order to solve this you need to follow these steps:

1/17/12

Perfect competition and profit maximization

16:08
Perfect competition and profit maximization
This economics post will go over the profit maximization behavoir of a perfectly competitive firm.

For a related numerical example look here, for a graphical example look here, and finally for a word problem based example look here.

Remember that when calculating the profit maximizaing point for any firm, it is imperative that we set marginal revenue equal to marginal cost (MR=MC).  If we are at any other point, then there are potential gains to be made.  Imagine if MR<MC, at this point we are losing money on the margin.  We are selling too many goods or services, and need to scale back.  If MR>MC, then we are selling too few, and we could sell more goods or services because our marginal gain is greater than our marginal cost.  Below is a graphic showing this relationship for a perfectly competitive firm: