Rpi 0605

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

Working Papers in Economics

Department of Economics, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, 110 8th Street, Troy, NY, 12180-3590, USA. Tel: +1518-276-6387; Fax: +1-518-276-2235; URL: http://www.rpi.edu/dept/economics/; E-Mail: [email protected]

Corporate Social Responsibility and Economic Performance


Catherine J. Morrison-Paul
University of California, Davis
Donald S. Siegel
Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute

Number 0605
March 2006

______________________________________________________________________________
For more information and to browse and download further Rensselaer Working Papers in
Economics, please visit: http://www.rpi.edu/dept/economics/www/workingpapers/

Corporate Social Responsibility and Economic Performance

Catherine J. Morrison Paul


Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics
University of California, Davis
One Shields Ave.
Davis, CA 95616-8512
Tel: (530) 752-0469
Fax: (916) 752-5614
Email: [email protected]
Donald S. Siegel
Department of Economics
Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute
Sage Building-Room 3506
110 8th Street
Troy, NY 12180-3590
Tel: (518) 276-2049
Fax: (518) 276-2035
Email: [email protected]
January, 2006

We thank participants at the October 2004 International Centre for Corporate Social
Responsibility Workshop on Corporate Social Responsibility at the University of Nottingham for
their insightful comments on a previous version of this paper. The second author also gratefully
acknowledges financial support from the School of Humanities and Social Sciences at
Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute and the International Centre for Corporate Social Responsibility
at the University of Nottingham.

Corporate Social Responsibility and Economic Performance


Abstract
We describe some perspectives on corporate social responsibility (CSR), in order to
provide a context for considering the strategic motivations and implications of CSR. Based on
this framework, which is based on characterizing optimal firm decision making and underlies
most existing work on CSR, we propose an agenda for further theoretical and empirical research
on CSR. We then summarize and relate the articles in this special issue to the proposed agenda.
Keywords: Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR), Total Factor Productivity (TFP),
Environmental Performance
JEL Classification: L15, L21, M14

Introduction
In recent years, academics in fields of several business administration have studied the
economic and managerial implications of corporate social responsibility (CSR). CSR may be
defined, consistent with McWilliams and Siegel (2001), as actions on the part of a firm that
appear to advance the promotion of some social good beyond the immediate interests of the
firm/shareholders and beyond legal requirements. That is, CSR activities of companies are those
that exceed compliance with respect to, e.g., environmental or social regulations, in order to
create the perception or reality that these firms are advancing a social goal.
It is not surprising that some firms choose to be socially responsible in this sense. Most
large multi-national companies encounter extensive pressure from consumers, employees,
suppliers, community groups, government, non-governmental organizations (NGOs), and
institutional shareholders to engage in CSR. Such CSR activities might include incorporating
social characteristics or features into products and manufacturing processes (e.g., producing
aerosol products with no fluorocarbons or making greater use of environmentally-friendly
technologies), striving to reach higher levels of environmental performance via recycling or
pollution abatement (e.g., adopting an aggressive stance towards reducing emissions), or
promoting the goals of community organizations or NGOs (e.g., United Way or Greenpeace).
From an economics perspective, companies would be expected to engage in such activities if the
perceived (measured or unmeasured) benefits exceeded the associated costs in the view of the
decision-making entity.
Recent theories of CSR (Baron, 2001, McWilliams and Siegel, 2001, Bagnoli and Watts,
2003) thus conjecture that companies engage in profit-maximizing CSR, based on anticipated
benefits from these actions. Examples of such benefits might include reputation enhancement,
3

the potential to charge a premium price for its product(s), or the enhanced ability to recruit and
retain high quality workers. For a CSR action to be undertaken by a company, the benefits of
engaging in this activity must offset the higher costs associated with the additional resources that
must presumably be allocated for the firm to achieve CSR status. Due to rising pressures for and
visibility of CSR activities in the increasingly socially aware climate of developed countries, the
end result has been a substantial increase in investment in such activities in all OECD nations.
Based on the profit-maximization CSR hypothesis, most academic studies of CSR have
focused on a narrowly-defined business-oriented research question: do socially responsible firms
achieve higher, lower, or similar levels of financial performance than comparable firms that do
not meet the same CSR criteria (Griffin and Mahon, 1997, Dowell, Hart, and Yeung, 2000,
McWilliams and Siegel, 2000, and Orlitzky, Schmidt, and Rynes, 2003)? Financial performance
is typically defined in such studies in terms of either (short- or long-run) stock prices or
accounting profitability (e.g., return on equity, return on investment, or operating profit). Such
studies also tend to use the firm rather than the establishment or sector as the unit of observation
for empirical analysis, both because they are advancing a business case for CSR and due to the
ready availability of company-level financial data (e.g., accounting data from Standard and
Poors Compustat or stock price data from the Center for Research in Security Prices).
Although the business administration perspective of this body of research justifies an
exclusive focus on financial measures of performance, from an economic perspective this is
unfortunate. A more salient issue in this context is the relationship between economic
performance and CSR activities, where economic performance involves technological and
economic relationships between output production and input demand, recognizing opportunity
costs of inputs and capital accumulation. For example, economic performance may be defined as
4

the amount of (good or marketable) output producible from a given amount of inputs
(productivity), the deviation of output produced from that implied by best practice production
(technical efficiency), or the input/resource use required to produce a given amount of output
(cost effectiveness). Because such measures are based on evaluating marketed outputs and
inputs, this raises questions about whether conventional productivity/performance estimates are
biased from not recognizing environmental or other social externalities, and how economic
performance might be affected by reducing such externalities.
For public policy makers, clarifying such relationships helps to identify the resource costs
of CSR, or market failures with respect to CSR (Siegel, 2001). Such information in turn
provides guidance on optimal levels of social responsibility regulation. For managers,
information on such relationships is useful because it helps to inform resource allocation
decisions regarding CSR activities. That is, empirical evidence on the magnitude of the tradeoff
between cost or productivity and CSR facilitates determining the amount of CSR expenditure
that is economically justifiable.
Our objective in this special issue is to explore this economic perspective to CSR, and
thus address some of these gaps in the literature on CSR. After identifying some of the leading
contributors to the literature on environmental externalities and economic performance, we
solicited manuscripts on the economics of CSR and held a workshop in Nottingham, England,
jointly sponsored by the School of Humanities and Social Sciences at Rensselaer Polytechnic
Institute and the International Centre for Corporate Social Responsibility (ICCSR) at the
University of Nottingham. Among the authors and discussants at the workshop were scholars
from several academic disciplines (economics, political science, accounting, finance, and
management), including many international contributors and junior scholars.
5

The best economics-oriented papers generated from this workshop were selected for this
special issue, after an additional round of reviews. These studies address two critical themes of
the economics of CSR: (1) methodological issues relating to productivity measurement when
bad outputs that impose social costs are jointly produced with good or marketable outputs; and
(2) empirical relationships between environmental and social regulation/performance and
economic performance/productivity. In addition, all but one of the articles in this special issue
are based on establishment-level data, which is generally regarded as more appropriate for
productivity measurement than firm-level data. In the remainder of our introduction to this
special issue, we provide a brief summary of each of these studies in the context of the
economics of CSR and CSR impacts on productivity and costs.
Ronald Shadbegian and Wayne Gray analyze the relationships among environmental
performance, productivity, and regulatory activity. The authors link confidential U.S. databases
from the Census Bureau (the Longitudinal Research Database, which contains detailed
production data, and the Pollution Abatement Costs and Expenditures survey) and the EPA (the
National Emissions Inventory, the Permit Compliance System, the Toxic Release Inventory, and
the Compliance Data System).
The authors estimate a stochastic frontier production function model, based on
establishment-level data from the pulp and paper, oil, and steel industries. The results show fairly
substantial deviations of production from the efficient frontier, which depend on actions
affecting environmental degradation. In particular, technical efficiency is lower for older than
younger establishments, although both have roughly the same level of environmental
performance as proxied by emissions. Efficiency is also lower for establishments that spend
more on pollution abatement. However, negligible production efficiency effects appear to result
6

from additional regulatory inspections, which imply somewhat lower emissions. They also
report that regulatory actions, such as local stringency of air pollution limits, are associated with
higher levels of efficiency. The latter result suggests that such activities could be stressed by
policy with limited productivity consequences.
Donald Vitaliano and Gregory Stella provide direct empirical evidence on the
productivity impact of CSR, based on assessment of a key piece of social legislation in the
banking industry. The Community Reinvestment Act of 1977 established an elaborate, on-going
system of social rating for banks. The data allow the authors to identify whether a bank achieves
a social rating of outstanding with respect to their lending practices, which is defined as an act
of voluntary CSR since such companies are deemed to be going beyond compliance, consistent
with McWilliams and Siegel (2001).
The authors estimate a data envelopment analysis (DEA) cost minimization model to
analyze the relationship between such CSR ratings and productivity. Interestingly, they report no
difference in technical efficiency between banks that receive an outstanding rating and those that
receive a satisfactory rating. However, cost efficiency does differ between CSR and non-CSR
banks. An outstanding rating involves annual extra costs of $7.4 million, or 1.3% of total costs,
which the authors interpret as the shadow price of CSR since it is not based on measured output
production or input use. Further, firms appear to recoup the additional cost of being socially
responsible. That is, the findings suggest that pre- and after-tax rates of return are equivalent for
banks receiving outstanding and satisfactory ratings.
Wendy Chapple, Catherine Morrison Paul, and Richard Harris empirically analyze the
cost and input use impacts of voluntary waste minimization, which is viewed as a form of
environmental CSR. Their empirical analysis is based on the Annual Business Inquiry
7

Respondents Database (ARD), which contains longitudinal data for thousands of U.K.
manufacturing establishments. In their framework, plants product bad outputs such as waste,
which have negative environmental externalities, jointly with their good outputs. Although firms
have tax and reputation-enhancement incentives to reduce waste, doing so can result in less
output for a given input base (lower productivity), or more input use for a given production level
(higher costs).
To assess such tradeoffs, the authors estimate a generalized Leontief cost function, with
shift factors and output levels in quadratic form, following Paul (2001). This functional form
allows the authors to generate detailed evidence on substitution patterns involving output and
waste production and capital, labor, and materials input use. They find that reducing waste is
materials using (implying increased intermediate materials demand or outsourcing), but capital
and labor input saving (implying reduced investment and employment). These patterns vary
significantly, however, by county, region, and industry, suggesting substantial differences in the
costs of limiting waste generation/disposal that depends on various internal and external factors.
Our special issue concludes with a paper by Rolf Fre, Shawna Grosskopf, and Carl
Pasurka, who introduce an index number approach based on Malmquist quantity indexes to deal
with the measurement of productivity when there are good and bad outputs: an Environmental
Performance Index (EPI). The authors show that the EPI has highly desirable index number
properties, and that with only one good and one bad output it simplifies to an index of the good
to bad output ratio over time.
The authors apply this model to longitudinal data on U.S. coal-fired power plants, for
which a natural experiment on the production impacts of environmental CSR actions arose when
the Phase I Acid Rain program of the U.S. Clean Air Act, designed to reduce sulfur dioxide
8

emissions in power plants, was implemented in 1995. The authors find that plants taking part in
this program experienced a substantial improvement in their environmental performance, as
measured by the EPI, during the sample period. This suggests that encouragement for CSR can
have beneficial social impacts as it motivates firms to adapt their production practices and thus
their good to bad output balance.
Gerald Granderson addresses the effects on productivity measures when there is a bad
output that contributes to environmental damage. He conducts a decomposition of total factor
productivity growth for firms that are subject to regulation due to their production of such a bad
output. As a basis for this decomposition, CSR is framed within a production function context, in
which the production of good and bad outputs yields social benefits and costs that are recognized
by socially responsible firms.
The author decomposes total factor productivity growth into scale economies, technical
change, and efficiency change, based on longitudinal data from 34 U.S. investor-owned electric
utilities and using the Bauer (1990) method combined with techniques developed by Denny,
Fuss, and Waverman (1981) and Granderson (1997). He identifies the productive contribution of
the bad output using methods developed by Ball, Fare, Grosskopf, and Zaim (2005) and Chapple,
Morrison Paul, and Harris (2005). He finds that improvements in scale, efficiency, and technical
change contributed to productivity growth in this sector, but that failure to account for
production of the bad output results in overestimation of the overall rate of productivity growth
and its scale economy and technical change components. This suggests that CSR activities limit
the productive effects of technical change and scale economies.
In sum, these articles provide an important foundation for economic CSR analysis by
showing how one might evaluate the costs and benefits of CSR activities in the context of
9

productivity and cost efficiency. They document that CSR activities may affect the productive
impacts of efficiency, technical change and scale economies, as well as increase input costs and
composition (potentially increasing outsourcing and reducing investment and employment). The
findings also indicate that these impacts are dependent on firm characteristics such as the
motivations for socially responsible actions, tax laws, location, and plant age and innovation
activities. These results provide provocative insights, therefore, regarding how CSR must be
balanced by benefits or regulations (implied social benefits) to motivate firms to carry out such
activities.

10

REFERENCES
Bagnoli, M. and S. Watts. 2003. Selling to Socially Responsible Consumers: Competition and
the Private Provision of Public Goods, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy,
12:419-445.
Ball, E., Fare, R., Grosskopf, S. and O. Zaim. 2005. Accounting for Externalities in the
Meaurement of Productivity Growth: The Malmquist Cost Productivity Measure, Structural
Change and Economic Dynamics, 16(3): 374-394.
Baron, D. 2001. Private politics, corporate social responsibility and integrated strategy,
Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 10:7-45.
Bauer, P.W. 1990. Decomposing TFP Growth in the Presence of Cost Inefficiency,
Nonconstant Returns to Scale, and Technological Progress, Journal of Productivity
Analysis, 1:287-301.
Chapple, W., Morrison Paul, C. J., and R. Harris. 2005. Manufacturing and Corporate
Environmental Responsibility: Cost Implications of Voluntary Waste Minimisation, Structural
Change and Economic Dynamics, 16(3):347-373.
Cornwell, C., Schmidt, P. and R.C. Sickles. 1990. Production Frontiers With CrossSectionaland Time-Series Variation in Efficiency Levels, Journal of Econometrics, 46:185-200.
Denny, M., Fuss, M., and L. Waverman. 1981, The Measurement and Interpretation of Total
Factor Productivity in Regulated Industries, with an Application to Canadian
Telecommunications, in Productivity Measurement in Regulated Industries, 179-218.
Dowell, G., Hart, S. and B. Yeung. 2000. Do Corporate Global Environmental Standards Create
or Destroy Market Value? Management Science, 46(8):1059-1074.
Griffin, J.J. and J.F Mahon. 1997. The Corporate Social Performance and Corporate Financial
Performance Debate: Twenty-five years of Incomparable Research. Business and Society,
36(1):5-31.
McWilliams, A. and D. Siegel. 2000. Corporate Social Responsibility and Financial
Performance: Correlation or Misspecification? Strategic Management Journal, 21(5):603-609.
McWilliams, A. and D. Siegel. 2001. Corporate Social Responsibility: A Theory of the Firm
Perspective. Academy of Management Review, 26(1):117-127.
Orlitzky, M., Schmidt, F.L., and S.L Rynes. 2003. Corporate Social and Financial Performance:
A Meta-Analysis. Organization Studies, 24(3):403-441.

11

Paul, C. J. M. 2001. Market and Cost Structure in the U.S. Beef Packing Industry : A Plant-Level
Analysis, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83(1):64-76.
Siegel, D. 2001. Do British companies really need a minister to make them socially responsible?,
Parliamentary Brief, 7:7-8, (special supplement on Business and the Community).

12

You might also like