M. APPLE Ideology, Reproduction...
M. APPLE Ideology, Reproduction...
M. APPLE Ideology, Reproduction...
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Comparative and International Education Society and University of Chicago Press are collaborating with JSTOR to
digitize, preserve and extend access to Comparative Education Review.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Introduction
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
367
MICHAEL W. APPLE
Many economists and not a few sociologists and historians of education have a peculiar way of looking at schools. They envision the
institution of schooling as something like a black box. One measures
input before students enter schools and then measures output along the
way or when "adults" enter the labor force. What actually goes on within
the black box-what is taught, the concrete experience of children and
teachers-is
less important in this view than the more global and
macroeconomic considerations of rate of return on investment or, more
radically, the reproduction of the division of labor. While these are
important considerations, perhaps especially that dealing with the role of
the school as a reproductive force in an unequal society, by the very
nature of a vision of school as black box they cannot demonstrate how
these effects are built within schools. Therefore, these individuals are less
precise than they could be in explaining part of the role of cultural
institutions in the reproduction they want to describe. Yet, as I shall
argue here, such cultural explanations need to be gotten at; but it
requires a different but often complementary orientation than the ones
these and other scholars employ.
There is a unique combination of elite and popular culture in schools.
As institutions, they provide exceptionally interesting, and politically and
economically potent, areas for the investigation of mechanisms of cultural distribution in a society. Thinking of schools as mechanisms of
cultural distribution is important since, as the late Italian Marxist Antonio
Gramsci noted, a critical element in enhancing the ideological dominance
of certain classes is the control of the knowledge preserving and producing institutions of a particular society.' Thus, the "reality" that schools
and other cultural institutions select, preserve, and distribute may need
to be particularized, in Mannheim's words,2 so' that it can be seen as a
particular "social construction" which may not serve the interests of every
individual and group in society.
1 Thomas R. Bates, "Gramsci and the Theory of Hegemony," Journal of the History of Ideas 36
(April-June 1975): 36.
2
Karl Mannheim, Ideologyand Utopia (New York: Harcourt, Brace & World, 1936).
368
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IDEOLOGYAND EDUCATIONALREFORM
Paul, 1975).
4 Geoff Whitty, "Sociologyand the Problem of Radical EducationalChange," in Educability,
SchoolsandIdeology,ed. MichaelFlude and John Ahier (London: Halstead, 1974), p. 125.
Comparative Education Review
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
369
MICHAEL W. APPLE
education, as the key to change, ignores the fact that the form and content of
education are affected, and in some cases determined, by the actual systems of
[political] decision and [economic] maintenance.5
Both Whitty and Williams are raising quite difficult issues about what
might be called the relationship between ideology and school knowledge,
yet the context is generally British. It should not surprise us that there is a
rather extensive history of dealing with issues concerning the connections
between culture and control on the Continent and in England. For one
thing, they have had a less hidden set of class antagonisms than the
United States. That the tradition of ideological analysis is less visible in
American educational and cultural scholarship speaks to two other
concerns though: the ahistorical nature of most educational activity and
the dominance of an ethic of amelioration through technical models in
most curriculum discourse.6 The ahistorical nature of the field of
curriculum is rather interesting here. Anyone familiar with the intense
argumentation both within and on the fringes of the Progressive Education Association during its history soon realizes that one of the major
points of contention among progressive educators was the problem of
indoctrination. Should schools, guided by a vision of a more just society,
teach a particular set of social meanings to their students? Should they
concern themselves only with progressive pedagogical techniques, rather
than espouse a particular social and economic cause? Questions of this
type "plagued" democratically minded educators in the past, and the
controversy continues, though in a different vocabulary, to this day.
In fact, as Stanwood Cobb, one of the early organizers of the
Progressive Education Association, stated in a recent interview, many
progressive educators throughout the early decades of this century were
quite cautious about even raising the question of what actual content
should be taught and evaluated in schools. They often preferred to
concern themselves primarily with teaching methods, in part because the
determination of curriculum was perceived as inherently a political issue
which could split the movement.7 Cobb's estimation of the larger structural causes behind these educators' choice of arenas in which to act may
or may not be historically accurate. The fact remains though that, at least
phenomenologically, many educators recognized that the culture pre5 RaymondWilliams,TheLongRevolution(London:Chatto& Windus, 1961), pp.
119-20.
Herbert M. Kliebard,"PersistentCurriculumIssues in HistoricalPerspective,"in Curriculum
TheReconceptualists,
ed. WilliamPinar(Berkeley:McCutchan,1975), pp. 39-50.
Theorizing:
7 Taped interviewgiven at the Universityof Wisconsin--Madison.The necessityfor large-scale
educationalreform movementsto have this cautious penumbraof vagueness is analyzedfurther in
B. Paul KomisarandJames McClellan,"The Logic of Slogans,"in LanguageandConcepts
in Education,
ed. B. Othanel Smith and RobertEnnis (Chicago:Rand McNally,1961), pp. 195-214.
6
370
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
371
MICHAEL W. APPLE
372
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IDEOLOGYAND EDUCATIONALREFORM
and Ireland, ed. R. Bell (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1973), p. 201.
"14Wexler, p.
21.
For further examination of the roots of this tradition, see Michael W. Apple, "Power and
School Knowledge," Review of Education 3 (January/February 1977): 26-49; and Michael W.
Apple
and Philip Wexler, "Cultural Capital and Educational Transmissions," Educational
Theory27 (Winter
1978): 34-43.
'5
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
373
MICHAELW. APPLE
374
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IDEOLOGYAND EDUCATIONALREFORM
Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, Schoolingin CapitalistAmerica (New York: Basic, 1975).
MacDonald, p. 309. This piece also provides a number of interesting criticisms of Bowles and
Gintis's reliance on a correspondence theory.
22
John W. Meyer, "The Effects of Education as an Institution," AmericanJournal of Sociology53
(July 1977): 64.
23
MacDonald, pp. 34-47; see also, Apple and King (n. 10 above); and Bourdieu and Passeron
(n. 8 above).
24
Roger Dale, Geoff Esland, and Madeleine MacDonald, eds., Schooling and Capitalism: A
SociologicalReader (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1976), p. 4.
21
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
375
MICHAELW. APPLE
society at large. These theorists maintain that the rules which govern social
behavior,attitudes,morals and beliefs are filtered down from the macrolevel of
economic and political structuresto the individualvia work experience, education processes and family socialization. The individual acquires a particular
awareness and perception of the society in which he lives. And it is this
understanding and attitude towards the social order which [in large part]
constitutehis consciousness.27
Ibid.
26
R. W. Connell, Ruling Class, Ruling Culture (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1977), p.
27
MacDonald,p. 60.
219.
376
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IDEOLOGYAND EDUCATIONALREFORM
Let me pause here to clarify one thing: This is not to maintain that
either culture or consciousness is mechanistically determined (in the
strong sense of that term) by economic structure. Rather, it seeks both to
bring to a level of awareness and to make historically and empirically
problematic the dialectical relationship between cultural control and
distribution and economic and political stratification.28 Our ordinary
taken from the achievement and socialization
perceptions-ones
are bracketed. The "cognitive interest" underlying the
models-hence,
research program is to look relationally, if you will, to think about school
knowledge as being generated out of ideological and economic conflicts
"outside" as well as "inside" education. These conflicts and forces set
limits on (not mechanistically determine) cultural responses. This requires subtlety, not appraisals which argue for a one-to-one correspondence between institutional life and cultural forms. Neither all curricula
nor all culture are "mere products" of simple economic forces.29
In fact, I want to note a critical caveat at this point. There is an
obvious danger here, one that should not go unrecognized. To make the
actual "stuff' of curriculum problematic, to hold what currently counts as
legitimate knowledge up to ideological scrutiny, can lead to a rather
vulgar brand of relativism. That is, to see overt and hidden curricular
knowledge as social and historical products ultimately tends to raise
questions about the criteria of validity and truth we employ.30 The
epistemological issues that might be raised here are not uninteresting, to
say the least. However, the point behind these investigations is not to
relativize totally either our knowledge or our criteria for warranting its
truth or falsity (though the Marxist tradition has a long history of just this
debate, as the controversy between, say, Adorno and Popper documents;
we have much to learn from the epistemological and political issues raised
by this debate, by the way).3 Rather, as I just mentioned, the
methodological dictum is to think relationally or structurally. In clearer
culture and economics interpenetrate and act
"28The two-way nature of this relationship-how
on each other in a dynamic fashion-is best examined in Raymond Williams, "Base and Superstructure in Marxist Cultural Theory," New Left Review 83 (November/December 1973): 3-16.
29 Ibid.; see also the final
chapter, "Aspects of the Relations between Education and Production,"
Bernstein (n. 8 above).
30 Michael F. D. Young, "Taking Sides against the Probable," Rationality,Education and the Social
Organizationof Knowledge,ed. Chris Jenks (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1977), pp. 86-96; and
Michael W. Apple, "Curriculum as Ideological Selection," ComparativeEducation Review 20
(June
1976): 209-15.
31 See,
e.g., Albrecht Wellmer, CriticalTheoryof Society(New York: Herder & Herder, 1971), esp.
chap. 1; see also the discussion of the position taken by the French Marxist philosopher of science,
Louis Althusser, in Miriam Glucksmann, StructuralistAnalysisin
ContemporarySocial Thought(London:
Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1974). Though it may be difficult to deal with "proving" critically oriented
social assertions using the positivist tradition, this does not mean that empirical documentaion of
aspects of the problem is inconsequential. This is nicely argued in Connell (n. 26 above).
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
377
MICHAEL W. APPLE
terms, one should look for the subtle connections between educational
phenomena, such as curriculum, and the latent social and economic
outcomes of the institution.
These points are obviously similar to those often associated with the
critical theorists of the Frankfurt school, who have argued that the
context in which we perceive social facts, the general way we conceptually
organize our world, may hide the fact that these seemingly commonsensical appearances serve particular interests.32 But these interests cannot
merely be assumed; they need to be documented. In order to lay some of
the foundation of this documentation, we shall need to turn to some of
the hypotheses that I mentioned earlier, I would suggest. We shall need to
explore how cultural distribution and economic power are intimately
intertwined, not just in the teaching of "moral knowledge" as in some of
the reproduction theorists, but in the formal corpus of school knowledge
itself.
On the Problem of High-Status Knowledge
378
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IDEOLOGYAND EDUCATIONALREFORM
information, cultural attributes, etc., but rather they also transform (and
sometimes reject) these expected dispositions, propensities, skills, and
facts into biographically significant meanings.33 Thus, while the act of
treating knowledge as a thing makes for ease of discussion, a methodological simplification if you will, it needs to be understood as just such a
simplifying act. (The fact that it is usually considered a thing in our
society does, of course, point to its reification as a commodity in advanced
industrial societies.)34
Once again, one of Michael F. D. Young's arguments is helpful as a
beginning here. He states that "those in positions of power will attempt to
define what is taken as knowledge, how accessible to different groups any
knowledge is, and what are accepted relationships between different
knowledge areas and between those who have access to them and make
them available."35 Though this is not always or even necessarily a
conscious process of manipulation and control, and hence may be a bit
overstated, it does raise the issue of the relative status of knowledge and
its accessibility. For within this statement is a proposition that might entail
something like the following. The possession of high-status knowledge,
knowledge that is considered of exceptional import and is connected to
the structure of corporate economies, is related to and in fact seems to
entail the nonpossession by others. In essence, high-status knowledge "is
by definition scarce, and its scarcity is inextricably linked to its instrumentality."36
This is an exceptionally critical point and needs to be gone into a bit
further. I have argued that schools do not merely "process" people but
that they "process" knowledge as well. They enhance and give
legitimacy
to particular types of cultural resources which are related to
unequal
economic forms. In order to understand this, we want to think about the
kinds of knowledge that schools take as the most important, that
they
want to maximize. I shall define this as technical knowledge, not to
denigrate it, but to differentiate it from, say, aesthetics, physical grace,
and so on. The conception of the maximization of technical
knowledge is
See the articles by Hugh Mehan and Robert MacKay in Childhoodand Socialization, ed. Hans
"33
Peter Dreitzel (New York: Macmillan, 1973), and Linda M. McNeil, "Economic Dimensions of Social
Studies Curricula: Curriculum as Institutionalized
Knowledge" (doctoral thesis, University of
Wisconsin-Madison,
1977).
34 Whitty (n. 4 above).
35 Michael F. D. Young, "An Approach to the Study of Curricula as Socially
Organized
Knowledge," in Young, Knowledgeand Control.There are interesting parallels here between the work
of Young and Huebner in their joint focus on curricular
accessibility (cf. Dwayne Huebner,
"Curriculum as the Accessibility of Knowledge," mimeographed
[paper presented at the Curriculum
Theory Study Group, Minneapolis, March 2, 1970]).
36 Bernice Fischer, "Conceptual Masks: An
Essay Review of Fred Inglis, Ideology and the
Imagination,"Review of Education 1 (November 1975): 526; see also Hextall and Sarup, pp. 151-71.
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
379
MICHAEL W. APPLE
" The principle that schools serve to maximize the production of technical knowledge was first
noted by Walter Feinberg in his provocative chapter, "A Critical
Analysis of the Social and Economic
Limits to the Humanizing of Education," in HumanisticEducation: Visionsand Realities, ed. Richard H.
Weller (Berkeley: McCutchan, 1977), pp. 249-69. My analysis here is indebted to his own.
38 Andrew Hacker, "Cutting Classes," New YorkReview
of Books 23 (May 1976): 15. Hacker notes
that at full employment our economy can usefully
employ only about 43% of the work-age
population. It is not profitable to employ more than that. "Some of the unnecessary 57% become
housewives, college students, or retire on moderate pension. Others, however, must settle for a
lifetime of poverty because the economic system offers them no alternatives."
380
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IDEOLOGYAND EDUCATIONALREFORM
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
381
MICHAEL W. APPLE
382
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
383
MICHAELW. APPLE
384
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IDEOLOGYAND EDUCATIONALREFORM
I want to stop here, knowing full well that much more could be and
needs to be said about the topics I have raised. For example, in order to
go further with the relationship between high-status knowledge and an
"external" social order, one would have to inquire into the history of the
concomitant rise of new classes of social personnel and the growth of
new types of "legitimate" knowledge." These issues obviously require
Williams, The Long Revolution (n. 5), pp. 298-99.
Henry M. Levin, "A Radical Critique of Educational Policy," Occasional Paper of the Stanford
University Evaluation Consortium, March 1977, mimeographed (Stanford, Calif.).
49 Basil Bernstein has made some intriguing inroads into this area in his "Aspects of the
Relations between Education and Production" in Bernstein (n. 8) (see also, Nicos Poulantzas, Classes
in ContemporaryCapitalism[London: New Left Books, 1975]).
47
48
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
385
MICHAELW. APPLE
386
October 1978
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IDEOLOGYAND EDUCATIONALREFORM
"53
Walter Feinberg, Reason and Rhetoric: The Intellectual Foundations of TwentiethCenturyLiberal
Educational Policy (New York: Wiley, 1975).
This content downloaded from 200.52.254.249 on Fri, 20 Nov 2015 13:36:32 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
387