How American Health Care Killed My Father

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

POLICY SEPTEMBER 2009

After the needless death of his father, the author, a business executive, began a personal exploration of a health-care
industry that for years has delivered poor service and irregular quality at astonishingly high cost. It is a system, he
argues, that is not worth preserving in anything like its current form. And the health-care reform now being
contemplated will not fix it. Here’s a radical solution to an agonizing problem.
by David Goldhill

How American Health Care


Killed My Father

A
LMOST TWO YEARS ago, my father was killed by a hospital-borne infection in
the intensive-care unit of a well-regarded nonprofit hospital in New York City.
Dad had just turned 83, and he had a variety of the ailments common to men of
his age. But he was still working on the day he walked into the hospital with
pneumonia. Within 36 hours, he had developed sepsis. Over the next five weeks in the ICU,
a wave of secondary infections, also acquired in the hospital, overwhelmed his defenses. My
dad became a statistic—merely one of the roughly 100,000 Americans whose deaths are
caused or influenced by infections picked up in hospitals. One hundred thousand deaths:
more than double the number of people killed in car crashes, five times the number killed in
homicides, 20 times the total number of our armed forces killed in Iraq and Afghanistan.
Another victim in a building American tragedy.
Illustration by Mark Hooper

About a week after my father’s death, The New Yorker ran an article by Atul Gawande
profiling the efforts of Dr. Peter Pronovost to reduce the incidence of fatal hospital-borne infections. Pronovost’s solution?
A simple checklist of ICU protocols governing physician hand-washing and other basic sterilization procedures. Hospitals
implementing Pronovost’s checklist had enjoyed almost instantaneous success, reducing hospital-infection rates by two-
thirds within the first three months of its adoption. But many physicians rejected the checklist as an unnecessary and
belittling bureaucratic intrusion, and many hospital executives were reluctant to push it on them. The story chronicled
Pronovost’s travels around the country as he struggled to persuade hospitals to embrace his reform.

It was a heroic story, but to me, it was also deeply unsettling. How was it possible that Pronovost needed to beg hospitals to
adopt an essentially cost-free idea that saved so many lives? Here’s an industry that loudly protests the high cost of liability
insurance and the injustice of our tort system and yet needs extensive lobbying to embrace a simple technique to save up to
100,000 people.
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 1 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

100,000 people.

And what about us—the patients? How does a nation that might close down a business for a single illness from a suspicious
hamburger tolerate the carnage inflicted by our hospitals? And not just those 100,000 deaths. In April, a Wall Street
Journal story suggested that blood clots following surgery or illness, the leading cause of preventable hospital deaths in the
U.S., may kill nearly 200,000 patients per year. How did Americans learn to accept hundreds of thousands of deaths from
minor medical mistakes as an inevitability?

My survivor’s grief has taken the form of an obsession with our health-care system. For more than a year, I’ve been reading
as much as I can get my hands on, talking to doctors and patients, and asking a lot of questions.

Keeping Dad company in the hospital for five weeks had left me befuddled. How can a facility featuring state-of-the-art
diagnostic equipment use less-sophisticated information technology than my local sushi bar? How can the ICU stress the
importance of sterility when its trash is picked up once daily, and only after flowing onto the floor of a patient’s room?
Considering the importance of a patient’s frame of mind to recovery, why are the rooms so cheerless and uncomfortable? In
whose interest is the bizarre scheduling of hospital shifts, so that a five-week stay brings an endless string of new personnel
assigned to a patient’s care? Why, in other words, has this technologically advanced hospital missed out on the revolution in
quality control and customer service that has swept all other consumer-facing industries in the past two generations?

I’m a businessman, and in no sense a health-care expert. But the persistence of bad industry practices—from long lines at
the doctor’s office to ever-rising prices to astonishing numbers of preventable deaths—seems beyond all normal logic, and
must have an underlying cause. There needs to be a business reason why an industry, year in and year out, would be able to
get away with poor customer service, unaffordable prices, and uneven results—a reason my father and so many others are
unnecessarily killed.

Like every grieving family member, I looked for someone to blame for my father’s death. But my dad’s doctors weren’t
incompetent—on the contrary, his hospital physicians were smart, thoughtful, and hard-working. Nor is he dead because of
indifferent nursing—without exception, his nurses were dedicated and compassionate. Nor from financial limitations—he
was a Medicare patient, and the issue of expense was never once raised. There were no greedy pharmaceutical companies,
evil health insurers, or other popular villains in his particular tragedy.

Indeed, I suspect that our collective search for villains—for someone to blame—has distracted us and our political leaders
from addressing the fundamental causes of our nation’s health-care crisis. All of the actors in health care—from doctors to
insurers to pharmaceutical companies—work in a heavily regulated, massively subsidized industry full of structural
distortions. They all want to serve patients well. But they also all behave rationally in response to the economic incentives
those distortions create. Accidentally, but relentlessly, America has built a health-care system with incentives that
inexorably generate terrible and perverse results. Incentives that emphasize health care over any other aspect of health and
well-being. That emphasize treatment over prevention. That disguise true costs. That favor complexity, and discourage
transparent competition based on price or quality. That result in a generational pyramid scheme rather than sustainable
financing. And that—most important—remove consumers from our irreplaceable role as the ultimate ensurer of value.

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 2 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

These are the impersonal forces, I’ve come to believe, that explain why things have gone so badly wrong in health care,
producing the national dilemma of runaway costs and poorly covered millions. The problems I’ve explored in the past year
hardly count as breakthrough discoveries—health-care experts undoubtedly view all of them as old news. But some experts,
it seems, have come to see many of these problems as inevitable in any health-care system—as conditions to be patched up,
papered over, or worked around, but not problems to be solved.

That’s the premise behind today’s incremental approach to health-care reform. Though details of the legislation are still
being negotiated, its principles are a reprise of previous reforms—addressing access to health care by expanding government
aid to those without adequate insurance, while attempting to control rising costs through centrally administered initiatives.
Some of the ideas now on the table may well be sensible in the context of our current system. But fundamentally, the
“comprehensive” reform being contemplated merely cements in place the current system—insurance-based, employment-
centered, administratively complex. It addresses the underlying causes of our health-care crisis only obliquely, if at all;
indeed, by extending the current system to more people, it will likely increase the ultimate cost of true reform.

I’m a Democrat, and have long been concerned about America’s lack of a health safety net. But based on my own work
experience, I also believe that unless we fix the problems at the foundation of our health system—largely problems of
incentives—our reforms won’t do much good, and may do harm. To achieve maximum coverage at acceptable cost with
acceptable quality, health care will need to become subject to the same forces that have boosted efficiency and value
throughout the economy. We will need to reduce, rather than expand, the role of insurance; focus the government’s role
exclusively on things that only government can do (protect the poor, cover us against true catastrophe, enforce safety
standards, and ensure provider competition); overcome our addiction to Ponzi-scheme financing, hidden subsidies,
manipulated prices, and undisclosed results; and rely more on ourselves, the consumers, as the ultimate guarantors of good
service, reasonable prices, and sensible trade-offs between health-care spending and spending on all the other good things
money can buy.

These ideas stand well outside the emerging political consensus about reform. So before exploring alternative policies, let’s
reexamine our basic assumptions about health care—what it actually is, how it’s financed, its accountability to patients, and
finally its relationship to the eternal laws of supply and demand. Everyone I know has at least one personal story about how
screwed up our health-care system is; before spending (another) $1trillion or so on reform, we need a much clearer
understanding of the causes of the problems we all experience.

HEALTH CARE ISN’T HEALTH (OR HAPPINESS)

“Money is honey,” my grandmother used to tell me, “but health is wealth.” She said
“health,” not “health care.” Listening to debates over health-care reform, it is sometimes
difficult to remember that there is a difference.

Medical care, of course, is merely one component of our overall health. Nutrition, exercise,
education, emotional security, our natural environment, and public safety may now be
more important than care in producing further advances in longevity and quality of life. (In Illustration by Stephen Savage

2005, almost half of all deaths in the U.S. resulted from heart disease, diabetes, lung cancer,
homicide, suicide, and accidents—all of which are arguably influenced as much by lifestyle choices and living environment
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 3 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

homicide, suicide, and accidents—all of which are arguably influenced as much by lifestyle choices and living environment
as by health care.) And of course even health itself is only one aspect of personal fulfillment, alongside family and friends,
travel, recreation, the pursuit of knowledge and experience, and more.

Yet spending on health care, by families and by the government, is crowding out spending on almost everything else. As a
nation, we now spend almost 18 percent of our GDP on health care. In 1966, Medicare and Medicaid made up 1 percent of
total government spending; now that figure is 20 percent, and quickly rising. Already, the federal government spends eight
times as much on health care as it does on education, 12 times what it spends on food aid to children and families, 30 times
what it spends on law enforcement, 78 times what it spends on land management and conservation, 87 times the spending
on water supply, and 830 times the spending on energy conservation. Education, public safety, environment, infrastructure
—all other public priorities are being slowly devoured by the health-care beast.

It’s no different for families. From 2000 to 2008, the U.S. economy grew by $4.4 trillion; of that growth, roughly one out of
every four dollars was spent on health care. Household expenditures on health care already exceed those on housing. And
health care’s share is growing.

By what mechanism does society determine that an extra, say, $100 billion for health care will make us healthier than even
$10 billion for cleaner air or water, or $25 billion for better nutrition, or $5 billion for parks, or $10 billion for recreation, or
$50 billion in additional vacation time—or all of those alternatives combined?

The answer is, no mechanism at all. Health care simply keeps gobbling up national resources, seemingly without regard to
other societal needs; it’s treated as an island that doesn’t touch or affect the rest of the economy. As new tests and
treatments are developed, they are, for the most part, added to our Medicare or commercial insurance policies, no matter
what they cost. But of course the money must come from somewhere. If the amount we spend on care had grown only at the
general rate of inflation since 1970, annual health-care costs now would be roughly $5,000 less per American—that’s about
10 percent of today’s median income, to invest for the future or to spend on all the other things that contribute to our well-
being. To be sure, our society has become wealthier over the years, and we’d naturally want to spend some of this new
wealth on more and better health care; but how did we choose to spend this much?

The housing bubble offers some important lessons for health-care policy. The claim that something—whether housing or
health care—is an undersupplied social good is commonly used to justify government intervention, and policy makers have
long striven to make housing more affordable. But by making housing investments eligible for special tax benefits and
subsidized borrowing rates, the government has stimulated not only the construction of more houses but also the
willingness of people to borrow and spend more on houses than they otherwise would have. The result is now tragically
clear.

As with housing, directing so much of society’s resources to health care is stimulating the provision of vastly more care.
Along the way, it’s also distorting demand, raising prices, and making us all poorer by crowding out other, possibly more
beneficial, uses for the resources now air-dropped onto the island of health care. Why do we view health care as
disconnected from everything else? Why do we spend so much on it? And why, ultimately, do we get such inconsistent
results? Any discussion of the ills within the system must begin with a hard look at the tax-advantaged comprehensive-
insurance industry at its center.
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 4 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

insurance industry at its center.

HEALTH INSURANCE ISN’T HEALTH CARE

How often have you heard a politician say that millions of Americans “have no health care,” when he or she meant they have
no health insurance? How has a method of financing health care become synonymous with care itself?

The reason for financing at least some of our health care with an insurance system is obvious. We all worry that a serious
illness or an accident might one day require urgent, extensive care, imposing an extreme financial burden on us. In this
sense, health-care insurance is just like all other forms of insurance—life, property, liability—where the many who face a
risk share the cost incurred by the few who actually suffer a loss.

But health insurance is different from every other type of insurance. Health insurance is the primary payment mechanism
not just for expenses that are unexpected and large, but for nearly all health-care expenses. We’ve become so used to health
insurance that we don’t realize how absurd that is. We can’t imagine paying for gas with our auto-insurance policy, or for
our electric bills with our homeowners insurance, but we all assume that our regular checkups and dental cleanings will be
covered at least partially by insurance. Most pregnancies are planned, and deliveries are predictable many months in
advance, yet they’re financed the same way we finance fixing a car after a wreck—through an insurance claim.

Comprehensive health insurance is such an ingrained element of our thinking, we forget that its rise to dominance is
relatively recent. Modern group health insurance was introduced in 1929, and employer-based insurance began to blossom
during World War II, when wage freezes prompted employers to expand other benefits as a way of attracting workers. Still,
as late as 1954, only a minority of Americans had health insurance. That’s when Congress passed a law making employer
contributions to employee health plans tax-deductible without making the resulting benefits taxable to employees. This
seemingly minor tax benefit not only encouraged the spread of catastrophic insurance, but had the accidental effect of
making employer-funded health insurance the most affordable option (after taxes) for financing pretty much any type of
health care. There was nothing natural or inevitable about the way our system developed: employer-based, comprehensive
insurance crowded out alternative methods of paying for health-care expenses only because of a poorly considered tax
benefit passed half a century ago.

In designing Medicare and Medicaid in 1965, the government essentially adopted this comprehensive-insurance model for
its own spending, and by the next year had enrolled nearly 12 percent of the population. And it is no coincidence that the
great inflation in health-care costs began soon after. We all believe we need comprehensive health insurance because the
cost of care—even routine care—appears too high to bear on our own. But the use of insurance to fund virtually all care is
itself a major cause of health care’s high expense.

Insurance is probably the most complex, costly, and distortional method of financing any activity; that’s why it is otherwise
used to fund only rare, unexpected, and large costs. Imagine sending your weekly grocery bill to an insurance clerk for
review, and having the grocer reimbursed by the insurer to whom you’ve paid your share. An expensive and wasteful
absurdity, no?

Is this really a big problem for our health-care system? Well, for every two doctors in the U.S., there is now one health-
insurance employee—more than 470,000 in total. In 2006, it cost almost $500 per person just to administer health
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 5 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

insurance employee—more than 470,000 in total. In 2006, it cost almost $500 per person just to administer health
insurance. Much of this enormous cost would simply disappear if we paid routine and predictable health-care expenditures
the way we pay for everything else—by ourselves.

THE MORAL -HAZARD ECONOMY

Society’s excess cost from health insurance’s administrative expense pales next to the
damage caused by “moral hazard”—the tendency we all have to change our behavior,
becoming spendthrifts and otherwise taking less care with our decisions, when someone
else is covering the costs. Needless to say, much medical care is unavoidable; we don’t
choose to become sick, nor do we seek more treatment than we think we need. Still,
hospitals, drug companies, health insurers, and medical-device manufacturers now spend
roughly $6 billion a year on advertising. If the demand for health care is purely a response
to unavoidable medical need, why do these companies do so much advertising?

Medical ads on TV typically inform the viewer that a specific treatment—a drug, device,
surgical procedure—is available for a chronic condition. Many also note that the product or
treatment is eligible for Medicare or private-insurance reimbursement. In some cases, the
advertiser will offer to help the patient obtain that reimbursement. The key message: you Illustration by Stephen Savage

can benefit from this product and pass the bill on to someone else.

Every time you walk into a doctor’s office, it’s implicit that someone else will be paying most or all of your bill; for most of
us, that means we give less attention to prices for medical services than we do to prices for anything else. Most physicians,
meanwhile, benefit financially from ordering diagnostic tests, doing procedures, and scheduling follow-up appointments.
Combine these two features of the system with a third—the informational advantage that extensive training has given
physicians over their patients, and the authority that advantage confers—and you have a system where physicians can, to
some extent, generate demand at will.

Do they? Well, Medicare spends almost twice as much per patient in Dallas, where there are more doctors and care facilities
per resident, as it does in Salem, Oregon, where supply is tighter. Why? Because doctors (particularly specialists) in surplus
areas order more tests and treatments per capita, and keep their practices busy. Many studies have shown that the patients
in areas like Dallas do not benefit in any measurable way from all this extra care. All of the physicians I know are genuinely
dedicated to their patients. But at the margin, all of us are at least subconsciously influenced by our own economic interests.
The data are clear: in our current system, physician supply often begets patient demand.

Moral hazard has fostered an accidental collusion between providers benefiting from higher costs and patients who don’t
fully bear them. In this environment, trying to control costs is awfully tough. When Medicare cut reimbursement rates in
2005 on chemotherapy and anemia drugs, for instance, it saved almost 20 percent of the previously billed costs. But
Medicare’s total cancer-treatment costs actually rose almost immediately. As The New York Times reported, some
physicians believed their colleagues simply performed more treatments, particularly higher-profit ones.

Want further evidence of moral hazard? The average insured American and the average uninsured American spend very
similar amounts of their own money on health care each year—$654 and $583, respectively. But they spend wildly different
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 6 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

similar amounts of their own money on health care each year—$654 and $583, respectively. But they spend wildly different
amounts of other people’s money—$3,809 and $1,103, respectively. Sometimes the uninsured do not get highly beneficial
treatments because they cannot afford them at today’s prices—something any reform must address. But likewise, insured
patients often get only marginally beneficial (or even outright unnecessary) care at mind-boggling cost. If it’s true that the
insurance system leads us to focus on only our direct share of costs—rather than the total cost to society—it’s not surprising
that insured families and uninsured ones would make similar decisions as to how much of their own money to spend on
care, but very different decisions on the total amount to consume.

The unfortunate fact is, health-care demand has no natural limit. Our society will always keep creating new treatments to
cure previously incurable problems. Some of these will save lives or add productive years to them; many will simply make us
more comfortable. That’s all to the good. But the cost of this comfort, and whether it’s really worthwhile, is never calculated
—by anyone. For almost all our health-care needs, the current system allows us as consumers to ask providers, “What’s my
share?” instead of “How much does this cost?”—a question we ask before buying any other good or service. And the subtle
difference between those two questions is costing us all a fortune.

THERE’S NO ONE ELSE TO PAY THE BILL

Perhaps the greatest problem posed by our health-insurance-driven regime is the sense it creates that someone else is
actually paying for most of our health care—and that the costs of new benefits can also be borne by someone else.
Unfortunately, there is no one else.

For fun, let’s imagine confiscating all the profits of all the famously greedy health-insurance companies. That would pay for
four days of health care for all Americans. Let’s add in the profits of the 10 biggest rapacious U.S. drug companies. Another 7
days. Indeed, confiscating all the profits of all American companies, in every industry, wouldn’t cover even five months of
our health-care expenses.

Somebody else always seems to be paying for at least part of our health care. But that’s just an illusion. At $2.4 trillion and
growing, our nation’s health-care bill is too big to be paid by anyone other than all of us.

In 2007, employer-based health insurance cost, on average, more than $12,000 per family, up 78 percent since 2001. I’ve
run several companies and company divisions of various sizes over the course of my career, so I can confidently tell you that
raises (and even entry-level hiring) are tightly limited by rising health-care costs. You may think your employer is paying for
your health care, but in fact your company’s share of the insurance premium comes out of your potential wage increase.
Where else could it come from?

Let’s say you’re a 22-year-old single employee at my company today, starting out at a $30,000 annual salary. Let’s assume
you’ll get married in six years, support two children for 20 years, retire at 65, and die at 80. Now let’s make a crazy
assumption: insurance premiums, Medicare taxes and premiums, and out-of-pocket costs will grow no faster than your
earnings—say, 3 percent a year. By the end of your working days, your annual salary will be up to $107,000. And over your
lifetime, you and your employer together will have paid $1.77 million for your family’s health care. $1.77 million! And that’s
only after assuming the taming of costs! In recent years, health-care costs have actually grown 2 to 3 percent faster than the
economy. If that continues, your 22-year-old self is looking at an additional $2 million or so in expenses over your lifetime

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 7 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

—roughly $4 million in total.

Would you have guessed these numbers were so large? If not, you have good cause: only a quarter would be paid by you
directly (and much of that after retirement). The rest would be spent by others on your behalf, deducted from your earnings
before you received your paycheck. And that’s a big reason why our health-care system is so expensive.

THE GOVERNMENT IS NOT GOOD AT COST REDUCTION

Every proposal for health-care reform has featured some element of cost control to “balance” the inflationary impact of
expanding access. Yet it goes without saying that in the big picture, all government efforts to control costs have failed.

Why? One reason is a fixation on prices rather than costs. The government regularly tries to cap costs by limiting the
reimbursement rates paid to providers by Medicare and Medicaid, and generally pays much less for each service than private
insurers. But as we’ve seen, that can lead providers to perform more services, and to steer patients toward higher-priced,
more lightly regulated treatments. The government’s efforts to expand “access” to care while limiting costs are like blowing
up a balloon while simultaneously squeezing it. The balloon continues to inflate, but in misshapen form.

Cost control is a feature of decentralized, competitive markets, not of centralized bureaucracy—a matter of incentives, not
mandates. What’s more, cost control is dynamic. Even the simplest business faces constant variation in its costs for labor,
facilities, and capital; to compete, management must react quickly, efficiently, and, most often, prospectively. By contrast,
government bureaucracies set regulations and reimbursement rates through carefully evaluated and broadly applied rules.
These bureaucracies first must notice market changes and resource misallocations, and then (sometimes subject to political
considerations) issue additional regulations or change reimbursement rates to address each problem retrospectively.

As a result, strange distortions crop up constantly in health care. For example, although the population is rapidly aging, we
have few geriatricians—physicians who address the cluster of common patient issues related to aging, often crossing
traditional specialty lines. Why? Because under Medicare’s current reimbursement system (which generally pays more to
physicians who do lots of tests and procedures), geriatricians typically don’t make much money. If seniors were the true
customers, they would likely flock to geriatricians, bidding up their rates—and sending a useful signal to medical-school
students. But Medicare is the real customer, and it pays more to specialists in established fields. And so, seniors often end
up overusing specialists who are not focused on their specific health needs.

Many reformers believe if we could only adopt a single-payer system, we could deliver health care more cheaply than we do
today. The experience of other developed countries suggests that’s true: the government as single payer would have lower
administrative costs than private insurers, as well as enormous market clout and the ability to bring down prices, although
at the cost of explicitly rationing care.

But even leaving aside the effects of price controls on innovation and customer service, today’s Medicare system should leave
us skeptical about the long-term viability of that approach. From 2000 to 2007, despite its market power, Medicare’s
hospital and physician reimbursements per enrollee rose by 5.4 percent and 8.5 percent, respectively, per year. As currently
structured, Medicare is a Ponzi scheme. The Medicare tax rate has been raised seven times since its enactment, and almost
certainly will need to be raised again in the next decade. The Medicare tax contributions and premiums that today’s
beneficiaries have paid into the system don’t come close to fully funding their care, which today’s workers subsidize. The
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 8 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

beneficiaries have paid into the system don’t come close to fully funding their care, which today’s workers subsidize. The
subsidy is getting larger even as it becomes more difficult to maintain: next year there will be 3.7 working people for each
Medicare beneficiary; if you’re in your mid-40s today, there will be only 2.4 workers to subsidize your care when you hit
retirement age. The experience of other rich nations should also make us skeptical. Whatever their histories, nearly all
developed countries are now struggling with rapidly rising health-care costs, including those with single-payer systems.
From 2000 to 2005, per capita health-care spending in Canada grew by 33 percent, in France by 37 percent, in the U.K. by
47 percent—all comparable to the 40 percent growth experienced by the U.S. in that period. Cost control by way of
bureaucratic price controls has its limits.

UNCOMPETITIVE

In 2007, health companies in the Fortune 1,000 earned $71 billion. Of the 52 industries represented on Fortune’s list,
pharmaceuticals and medical equipment ranked third and fourth, respectively, in terms of profits as a share of revenue.
From 2000 to 2007, the annual profits of America’s top 15 health-insurance companies increased from $3.5 billion to $15
billion.

In competitive markets, high profits serve an important social purpose: encouraging capital to flow to the production of a
service not adequately supplied. But as long as our government shovels ever-greater resources into health care with one
hand, while with the other restricting competition that would ensure those resources are used efficiently, sustained high
profits will be the rule.

Health care is an exceptionally heavily regulated industry. Health-insurance companies are regulated by states, which limits
interstate competition. And many of the materials, machines, and even software programs used by health-care facilities
must be licensed by state or federal authorities, or approved for use by Medicare; these requirements form large barriers to
entry for both new facilities and new vendors that could equip and supply them.

Many health-care regulations are justified as safety precautions. But many also result from attempts to redress the
distortions that our system of financing health care has created. And whatever their purpose, almost all of these regulations
can be shaped over time by the powerful institutions that dominate the health-care landscape, and that are often looking to
protect themselves from competition.

Take the ongoing battle between large integrated hospitals and specialty clinics (for cardiac surgery, orthopedics, maternity,
etc.). The economic threat posed by these facilities is well illustrated by a recent battle in Loma Linda, California. When a
group of doctors proposed a 28-bed private specialty facility, the local hospitals protested to the city council that it was
unnecessary, and launched a publicity campaign to try to block it; the council backed the facility anyway. So the nonprofit
Loma Linda University Medical Center simply bought the new facility for $80 million in 2008. Traditional hospitals got
Congress to include an 18-month moratorium on new specialty hospitals in the 2003 Medicare law, and a second six-month
ban in 2005.

The hospitals’ argument has some merit: less complicated surgical cases (the kind specialty clinics typically take on) tend to
be more profitable than complex surgeries and nonsurgical admissions. Without those profitable cases, hospitals can’t
subsidize the cases on which they lose money. But why are simple surgeries more profitable? Because of the nonmarket
methods by which Medicare sets prices.
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 9 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

methods by which Medicare sets prices.

The net effect of the endless layers of health-care regulation is to stifle competition in the classic economic sense. What we
have instead is a noncompetitive system where services and reimbursement are negotiated above consumers’ heads by large
private and government institutions. And the primary goal of any large noncompetitive institution is not cost control or
product innovation or customer service: it’s maintenance of the status quo.

OUR FAVORED HOSPITALS

In 1751, Benjamin Franklin and Dr. Thomas Bond founded Pennsylvania Hospital, the first in America, “to care for the sick-
poor and insane who were wandering the streets of Philadelphia.” Since then, hospitals have come to dominate the
American medical landscape. Yet in recent decades, the rationale for concentrating so much care under one roof has
diminished steadily. Many hospitals still exist in their current form largely because they are protected by regulation and
favored by government payment policies, which effectively maintain the existing industrial structure, rather than
encouraging innovation.

Between 1970 and 2006, annual Medicare payments to hospitals grew by roughly 3,800 percent, from $5 billion to $192
billion. Total annual hospital-care costs for all patients grew from $28 billion to almost $650 billion during that same
period. Since 1975, hospitals’ enormous revenue growth has occurred despite a 35 percent decline in the number of hospital
beds, no meaningful increase in total admissions, and an almost 50 percent decline in the average length of stay. High-tech
equipment has been dispersed to medical practices, recovery periods after major procedures have shrunk, and
pharmaceutical therapies have grown in importance, yet over the past 40 years, hospitals have managed to retain the same
share (roughly one-third) of our nation’s health-care bill.

Hospitals have sought to use the laws and regulations originally designed to serve patients to preserve their business model.
Their argument is the same one that’s been made before by regulated railroads, electric utilities, airlines, Ma Bell, and
banks: new competitors, they say, are using their cost advantages to skim off the best customers; without those customers,
the incumbents will no longer be able to subsidize essential services that no one can profitably provide to the public.

Hospitals are indeed required to provide emergency care to any walk-in patient, and this obligation is a meaningful public
service. But how do we know whether the charitable benefit from this requirement justifies the social cost of expensive
hospital care and poor quality? We don’t know. Our system of health-care law and regulation has so distorted the
functioning of the market that it’s impossible to measure the social costs and benefits of maintaining hospitals’ prominence.
And again, the distortions caused by a reluctance to pay directly for health care—in this case, emergency medicine for the
poor—are in large part to blame.

Consider the oft-quoted “statistic” that emergency-room care is the most expensive form of treatment. Has anyone who
believes this ever actually been to an emergency room? My sister is an emergency-medicine physician; unlike most other
specialists, ER docs usually work on scheduled shifts and are paid fixed salaries that place them in the lower ranks of
physician compensation. The doctors and other workers are hardly underemployed: typically, ERs are unbelievably
crowded. They have access to the facilities and equipment of the entire hospital, but require very few dedicated resources of
their own. They benefit from the group buying power of the entire institution. No expensive art decorates the walls, and the

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 10 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

waiting rooms resemble train-station waiting areas. So what exactly makes an ER more expensive than other forms of
treatment?

Perhaps it’s the accounting. Since charity care, which is often performed in the ER, is one justification for hospitals’
protected place in law and regulation, it’s in hospitals’ interest to shift costs from overhead and other parts of the hospital to
the ER, so that the costs of charity care—the public service that hospitals are providing—will appear to be high. Hospitals
certainly lose money on their ERs; after all, many of their customers pay nothing. But to argue that ERs are costly compared
with other treatment options, hospitals need to claim expenses well beyond the marginal (or incremental) cost of serving ER
patients.

In a recent IRS survey of almost 500 nonprofit hospitals, nearly 60 percent reported providing charity care equal to less
than 5 percent of their total revenue, and about 20 percent reported providing less than 2 percent. Analyzing data from the
American Hospital Directory, The Wall Street Journal found that the 50 largest nonprofit hospitals or hospital systems
made a combined “net income” (that is, profit) of $4.27 billion in 2006, nearly eight times their profits five years earlier.

How do we know whether the value of hospitals’ charitable services compensates for the roughly 100,000 deaths from
hospital-borne disease, their poor standards of customer service, and their extraordinary diseconomies of both scale and
scope? Might we be better off reforming hospitals, and allowing many of them to be eliminated by competition from
specialty clinics? As a society, couldn’t we just pay directly for the services required by the poor? We don’t know how many
hospitals would even survive if they were not so favored under the law; anyone who has lost a loved one to a preventable
hospital death will wonder how many should.

YOU ARE NOT THE CUSTOMER

What amazed me most during five weeks in the ICU with my dad was the survival of paper and pen for medical instructions
and histories. In that time, Dad was twice taken for surgical procedures intended for other patients (fortunately interrupted
both times by our intervention). My dry cleaner uses a more elaborate system to track shirts than this hospital used to track
treatment.

Not every hospital relies on paper-based orders and charts, but most still do. Why has adoption of clinical information
technology been so slow? Companies invest in IT to reduce their costs, reduce mistakes (itself a form of cost-saving), and
improve customer service. Better information technology would have improved my father’s experience in the ICU—and
possibly his chances of survival.

But my father was not the customer; Medicare was. And although Medicare has experimented with new reimbursement
approaches to drive better results, no centralized reimbursement system can be supple enough to address the many variables
affecting the patient experience. Certainly, Medicare wasn’t paying for the quality of service during my dad’s hospital stay.
And it wasn’t really paying for the quality of his care, either; indeed, because my dad got sepsis in the hospital, and had to
spend weeks there before his death, the hospital was able to charge a lot more for his care than if it had successfully treated
his pneumonia and sent him home in days.

Of course, one area of health-related IT has received substantial investment—billing. So much for the argument, often made,
that privacy concerns or a lack of agreed-upon standards has prevented the development of clinical IT or electronic medical
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 11 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

that privacy concerns or a lack of agreed-upon standards has prevented the development of clinical IT or electronic medical
records; presumably, if lack of privacy or standards had hampered the digitization of health records, it also would have
prevented the digitization of the accompanying bills. To meet the needs of the government bureaucracy and insurance
companies, most providers now bill on standardized electronic forms. In case you wonder who a care provider’s real
customer is, try reading one of these bills.

For that matter, try discussing prices with hospitals and other providers. Eight years ago, my wife needed an MRI, but we
did not have health insurance. I called up several area hospitals, clinics, and doctors’ offices—all within about a one-mile
radius—to find the best price. I was surprised to discover that prices quoted, for an identical service, varied widely, and that
the lowest price was $1,200. But what was truly astonishing was that several providers refused to quote any price. Only if I
came in and actually ordered the MRI could we discuss price.

Several years later, when we were preparing for the birth of our second child, I requested the total cost of the delivery and
related procedures from our hospital. The answer: the hospital discussed price only with uninsured patients. What about my
co-pay? They would discuss my potential co-pay only if I were applying for financial assistance.

Keeping prices opaque is one way medical institutions seek to avoid competition and thereby keep prices up. And they get
away with it in part because so few consumers pay directly for their own care—insurers, Medicare, and Medicaid are
basically the whole game. But without transparency on prices—and the related data on measurable outcomes—efforts to give
the consumer more control over health care have failed, and always will.

Here’s a wonderful example of price opacity. Advocates for the uninsured complain that hospitals charge uninsured patients,
on average, 2.5 times the amount charged to insured patients. Hospitals defend themselves by contending that they earn
from uninsured patients only 25 percent of the amount they do from insured ones. Both statements appear to be true!

How is this possible? Well, hospitals bill according to their price lists, but provide large discounts to major insurers.
Individual consumers, of course, don’t benefit from these discounts, so they receive their bills at full list price (typically
about 2.5 times the bill to an insured patient). Uninsured patients, however, pay according to how much of the bill the
hospital believes they can afford (which, on average, amounts to 25 percent of the amount paid by an insured patient).
Nonetheless, whatever discount a hospital gives to an uninsured patient is entirely at its discretion—and is typically
negotiated only after the fact. Some uninsured patients have been driven into bankruptcy by hospital collections. American
industry may offer no better example of pernicious “price discrimination,” nor one that entails greater financial vulnerability
for American families.

It’s astonishingly difficult for consumers to find any health-care information that would enable them to make informed
choices—based not just on price, but on quality of care or the rate of preventable medical errors. Here’s one place where
legal requirements might help. But only a few states require institutions to make this sort of information public in a usable
form for consumers. So while every city has numerous guidebooks with reviews of schools, restaurants, and spas, the public
is frequently deprived of the necessary data to choose hospitals and other providers.

THE STRANGE BEAST OF HEALTH -CARE TECHNOLOGY

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 12 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

One of the most widely held pieces of conventional wisdom about health care is that new technology is relentlessly driving
up costs. Yet over the past 20 years, I’ve bought several generations of microwave ovens, personal computers, DVD players,
GPS devices, mobile phones, and flat-screen TVs. I bank mostly at ATMs, check out my own goods at self-serve supermarket
scanners, and attend company meetings by videoconference. Technology has transformed much of our daily lives, in almost
all cases by adding quantity, speed, and quality while lowering costs. So why is health care different?

Well, for the most part, it isn’t. Whether it’s new drugs to control previously untreatable conditions, diagnostic equipment
that enhances physician productivity, or minimally invasive techniques that speed patient recovery, technology-driven
innovation has been transforming care at least as greatly as it has transformed the rest of our lives.

But most health-care technologies don’t exist in the same world as other technologies. Recall the MRI my wife needed a few
years ago: $1,200 for 20 minutes’ use of a then 20-year-old technology, requiring a little electricity and a little labor from a
single technician and a radiologist. Why was the price so high? Most MRIs in this country are reimbursed by insurance or
Medicare, and operate in the limited-competition, nontransparent world of insurance pricing. I don’t even know the price of
many of the diagnostic services I’ve needed over the years—usually I’ve just gone to whatever provider my physician
recommended, without asking (my personal contribution to the moral-hazard economy).

By contrast, consider LASIK surgery. I still lack the (small amount of) courage required to get LASIK. But I’ve been
considering it since it was introduced commercially in the 1990s. The surgery is seldom covered by insurance, and exists in
the competitive economy typical of most other industries. So people who get LASIK surgery—or for that matter most
cosmetic surgeries, dental procedures, or other mostly uninsured treatments—act like consumers. If you do an Internet
search today, you can find LASIK procedures quoted as low as $499 per eye—a decline of roughly 80 percent since the
procedure was introduced. You’ll also find sites where doctors advertise their own higher-priced surgeries (which more
typically cost about $2,000 per eye) and warn against the dangers of discount LASIK. Many ads specify the quality of
equipment being used and the performance record of the doctor, in addition to price. In other words, there’s been an active,
competitive market for LASIK surgery of the same sort we’re used to seeing for most goods and services.

The history of LASIK fits well with the pattern of all capital-intensive services outside the health-insurance economy. If
you’re one of the first ophthalmologists in your community to perform the procedure, you can charge a high price. But once
you’ve acquired the machine, the actual cost of performing a single procedure (the marginal cost) is relatively low. So, as
additional ophthalmologists in the neighborhood invest in LASIK equipment, the first provider can meet new competition by
cutting price. In a fully competitive marketplace, the procedure’s price will tend toward that low marginal cost, and
ophthalmologists looking to buy new machines will exert downward pressure on both equipment and procedure prices.

No business likes to compete solely on price, so most technology providers seek to add features and performance
improvements to new generations of a machine—anything to keep their product from becoming a pure commodity. Their
success depends on whether the consumers will pay enough for the new feature to justify its introduction. In most consumer
industries, we can see this dynamic in action—observe how DVD players have moved in a few years from a high-priced
luxury to a disposable commodity available at discount stores. DVD players have run out of new features for which
customers will pay premium prices.

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 13 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

Perhaps MRIs have too. After a long run of high and stable prices, you can now find ads for discount MRIs. But because of
the peculiar way we pay for health care, this downward price pressure on technology seems less vigorous. How well can
insurance companies and government agencies judge the value of new features that tech suppliers introduce to keep prices
up? Rather than blaming technology for rising costs, we must ask if moral hazard and a lack of discipline in national health-
care spending allows health-care companies to avoid the forces that make nonmedical technology so competitive.

In 2002, the U.S. had almost six times as many CT scanners per capita as Germany and four times as many MRI machines
as the U.K. Traditional reformers believe it is this rate of investment that has pushed up prices, rather than sustained high
prices that have pushed up investment. As a result, many states now require hospitals to obtain a Certificate of Need before
making a major equipment purchase. In its own twisted way, this makes sense: moral hazard, driven by insurance, for years
allowed providers to create enough demand to keep new MRI machines humming at any price.

But Certificates of Need are just another Scotch-tape reform, an effort to maintain the current system by treating a
symptom rather than the underlying disease. Technology is driving up the cost of health care for the same reason every
other factor of care is driving up the cost—the absence of the forces that discipline and even drive down prices in the rest of
our economy. Only in the bizarre parallel universe of health care could limiting supply be seen as a sensible approach to
keeping prices down.

THE LIMITS OF “COMPREHENSIVE” HEALTH -CARE REFORM

A wasteful insurance system; distorted incentives; a bias toward treatment; moral hazard; hidden costs and a lack of
transparency; curbed competition; service to the wrong customer. These are the problems at the foundation of our health-
care system, resulting in a slow rot and requiring more and more money just to keep the system from collapsing.

How would the health-care reform that’s now taking shape solve these core problems? The Obama administration and
Congress are still working out the details, but it looks like this generation of “comprehensive” reform will not address the
underlying issues, any more than previous efforts did. Instead it will put yet more patches on the walls of an edifice that is
fundamentally unsound—and then build that edifice higher.

A central feature of the reform plan is the expansion of comprehensive health insurance to most of the 46 million Americans
who now lack private or public insurance. Whether this would be achieved entirely through the extension of private
commercial insurance at government-subsidized rates, or through the creation of a “public option,” perhaps modeled on
Medicare, is still being debated.

Regardless, the administration has suggested a cost to taxpayers of $1 trillion to $1.5 trillion over 10 years. That, of course,
will mean another $1 trillion or more not spent on other things—environment, education, nutrition, recreation. And if the
history of previous attempts to expand the health safety net are any guide, that estimate will prove low.

The reform plan will also feature a variety of centrally administered initiatives designed to reduce costs and improve quality.
These will likely include a major government investment to promote digitization of patient health records, an effort to
collect information on best clinical practices, and changes in the way providers are paid, to better reward quality and deter
wasteful spending.

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 14 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

All of these initiatives have some theoretical appeal. And within the confines of the current system, all may do some good.
But for the most part, they simply do not address the root causes of poor quality and runaway costs.

Consider information technology, for instance. Of course the health system could benefit from better use of IT. The Rand
Corporation has estimated that the widespread use of electronic medical records would eventually yield annual savings of
$81 billion, while also improving care and reducing preventable deaths, and the White House estimates that creating and
spreading the technology would cost just $50 billion. But in what other industry would an investment with such a massive
annual return not be funded by the industry itself? (And while $50 billion may sound like a big investment, it’s only about 2
percent of the health-care industry’s annual revenues.)

Technology is effective only when it’s properly applied. Since most physicians and health-care companies haven’t adopted
electronic medical records on their own, what makes us think they will appropriately use all this new IT? Most of the
benefits of the technology (record portability, a reduction in costly and dangerous clinical errors) would likely accrue to
patients, not providers. In a consumer-facing industry, this alone would drive companies to make the investments to stay
competitive. But of course, we patients aren’t the real customers; government funding of electronic records wouldn’t change
that.

I hope that whatever reform is finally enacted this fall works—preventing people from slipping through the cracks, raising
the quality standard of the health-care industry, and delivering all this at acceptable cost. But looking at the big picture, I
fear it won’t. So I think we should at least begin to debate and think about larger reforms, and a different direction—if not
for this round of reform, then for the next one. Politics is, of course, the art of the possible. If our health-care crisis does not
abate, the possibilities for reform may expand beyond their current, tight limits.

A WAY FORWARD

The most important single step we can take toward truly reforming our system is to move away from comprehensive health
insurance as the single model for financing care. And a guiding principle of any reform should be to put the consumer, not
the insurer or the government, at the center of the system. I believe if the government took on the goal of better supporting
consumers—by bringing greater transparency and competition to the health-care industry, and by directly subsidizing those
who can’t afford care—we’d find that consumers could buy much more of their care directly than we might initially think,
and that over time we’d see better care and better service, at lower cost, as a result.

A more consumer-centered health-care system would not rely on a single form of financing for health-care purchases; it
would make use of different sorts of financing for different elements of care—with routine care funded largely out of our
incomes; major, predictable expenses (including much end-of-life care) funded by savings and credit; and massive,
unpredictable expenses funded by insurance.

For years, a number of reformers have advocated a more “consumer-driven” care system—a term coined by the Harvard
Business School professor Regina Herzlinger, who has written extensively on the subject. Many different steps could move
us toward such a system. Here’s one approach that—although it may sound radical—makes sense to me.

First, we should replace our current web of employer- and government-based insurance with a single program of
catastrophic insurance open to all Americans—indeed, all Americans should be required to buy it—with fixed premiums
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 15 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

catastrophic insurance open to all Americans—indeed, all Americans should be required to buy it—with fixed premiums
based solely on age. This program would be best run as a single national pool, without underwriting for specific risk factors,
and would ultimately replace Medicare, Medicaid, and private insurance. All Americans would be insured against
catastrophic illness, throughout their lives.

Proposals for true catastrophic insurance usually founder on the definition of catastrophe. So much of the amount we now
spend is dedicated to problems that are considered catastrophic, the argument goes, that a separate catastrophic system is
pointless. A typical catastrophic insurance policy today might cover any expenses above, say, $2,000. That threshold is far
too low; ultimately, a threshold of $50,000 or more would be better. (Chronic conditions with expected annual costs above
some lower threshold would also be covered.) We might consider other mechanisms to keep total costs down: the plan could
be required to pay out no more in any year than its available premiums, for instance, with premium increases limited to the
general rate of inflation. But the real key would be to restrict the coverage to true catastrophes—if this approach is to work,
only a minority of us should ever be beneficiaries.

How would we pay for most of our health care? The same way we pay for everything else—out of our income and savings.
Medicare itself is, in a sense, a form of forced savings, as is commercial insurance. In place of these programs and the
premiums we now contribute to them, and along with catastrophic insurance, the government should create a new form of
health savings account—a vehicle that has existed, though in imperfect form, since 2003. Every American should be
required to maintain an HSA, and contribute a minimum percentage of post-tax income, subject to a floor and a cap in total
dollar contributions. The income percentage required should rise over a working life, as wages and wealth typically do.

All noncatastrophic care should eventually be funded out of HSAs. But account-holders should be allowed to withdraw
money for any purpose, without penalty, once the funds exceed a ceiling established for each age, and at death any remaining
money should be disbursed through inheritance. Our current methods of health-care funding create a “use it or lose it”
imperative. This new approach would ensure that families put aside funds for future expenses, but would not force them to
spend the funds only on health care.

What about care that falls through the cracks—major expenses (an appendectomy, sports injury, or birth) that might exceed
the current balance of someone’s HSA but are not catastrophic? These should be funded the same way we pay for most
expensive purchases that confer long-term benefits: with credit. Americans should be able to borrow against their future
contributions to their HSA to cover major health needs; the government could lend directly, or provide guidelines for
private lending. Catastrophic coverage should apply with no deductible for young people, but as people age and save, they
should pay a steadily increasing deductible from their HSA, unless the HSA has been exhausted. As a result, much end-of-
life care would be paid through savings.

Anyone with whom I discuss this approach has the same question: How am I supposed to be able to afford health care in
this system? Well, what if I gave you $1.77 million? Recall, that’s how much an insured 22-year-old at my company could
expect to pay—and to have paid on his and his family’s behalf—over his lifetime, assuming health-care costs are tamed.
Sure, most of that money doesn’t pass through your hands now. It’s hidden in company payments for premiums, or in
Medicare taxes and premiums. But think about it: If you had access to those funds over your lifetime, wouldn’t you be able
to afford your own care? And wouldn’t you consume health care differently if you and your family didn’t have to spend that

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 16 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

to afford your own care? And wouldn’t you consume health care differently if you and your family didn’t have to spend that
money only on care?

For lower-income Americans who can’t fund all of their catastrophic premiums or minimum HSA contributions, the
government should fill the gap—in some cases, providing all the funding. You don’t think we spend an absurd amount of
money on health care? If we abolished Medicaid, we could spend the same money to make a roughly $3,000 HSA
contribution and a $2,000 catastrophic-premium payment for 60 million Americans every year. That’s a $12,000 annual
HSA plus catastrophic coverage for a low-income family of four. Do we really believe most of them wouldn’t be better off?

Some experts worry that requiring people to pay directly for routine care would cause some to put off regular checkups. So
here’s a solution: the government could provide vouchers to all Americans for a free checkup every two years. If everyone
participated, the annual cost would be about $30 billion—a small fraction of the government’s current spending on care.

Today, insurance covers almost all health-care expenditures. The few consumers who pay from their pockets are simply an
afterthought for most providers. Imagine how things might change if more people were buying their health care the way they
buy anything else. I’m certain that all the obfuscation over prices would vanish pretty quickly, and that we’d see an end to
unreadable bills. And that physicians, who spend an enormous amount of time on insurance-related paperwork, would have
more time for patients.

In fact, as a result of our fraying insurance system, you can already see some nascent features of a consumer-centered
system. Since 2006, Wal-Mart has offered $4 prescriptions for a month’s supply of common generic medications. It has also
been slowly rolling out retail clinics for routine care such as physicals, blood work, and treatment for common ailments like
strep throat. Prices for each service are easily obtained; most are in the neighborhood of $50 to $80. Likewise, “concierge
care,” or the “boutique” style of medical practice—in which physicians provide unlimited services and fast appointments in
return for a fixed monthly or annual fee—is beginning to spread from the rich to the middle class. Qliance Medical Group,
for instance, now operates clinics serving some 3,000 patients in the Seattle and Tacoma, Washington, areas, charging $49
to $79 a month for unlimited primary care, defined expansively.

It’s worth pausing over this last example. Many experts believe that the U.S. would get better health outcomes at lower cost if
payment to providers were structured around the management of health or whole episodes of care, instead of through
piecemeal fees. Medicare and private insurers have, to various degrees, moved toward (or at least experimented with) these
sorts of payments, and are continuing to do so—but slowly, haltingly, and in the face of much obstruction by providers. But
aren’t we likely to see just these sorts of payment mechanisms develop organically in a consumer-centered health-care
system? For simplicity and predictability, many people will prefer to pay a fixed monthly or annual fee for primary or
chronic care, and providers will move to serve that demand.

Likewise, what patient, when considering getting an artificial hip, would want to deal with a confusion of multiple bills from
physicians, facilities, and physical therapists? Aren’t providers likely to organize themselves to provide a single price to the
consumer for care and rehabilitation? And won’t that, in itself, put pressure on providers to work together as efficiently as
possible, and to minimize the medical errors that would eat into their joint fee? I suspect we would see a rapid decline in the
predominance of the fee-for-service model, making way for real innovation and choice in service plans and funding. And the
payment system would not be set by fiat; it would remain responsive to treatment breakthroughs and changes in consumer
http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 17 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

payment system would not be set by fiat; it would remain responsive to treatment breakthroughs and changes in consumer
demand.

Many consumers would be able to make many decisions, unaided, in such a system. But we’d also probably see the rise of
health-care agents—paid by, and responsible to, the consumer—to help choose providers and to act as advocates during
long and complex care episodes.

How else might the system change? Technological innovation—which is now almost completely insensitive to costs, and
which often takes the form of slightly improved treatments for much higher prices—would begin to concern itself with
value, not just quality. Many innovations might drive prices down, not up. Convenient, lower-cost specialty centers might
proliferate. The need for unpaid indigent care would go away—everyone, recall, would have both catastrophic insurance and
an HSA, funded entirely by the government when necessary—and with it much of the rationale for protecting hospitals
against competition.

Of course, none of this would happen overnight. And the government has an essential role to play in arming consumers with
good information. Congress should require maximum transparency on services, prices, and results (and some elements of
the Obama administration’s reform plan would move the industry in this direction). We should establish a more
comprehensive system of quality inspection of all providers, and publish all the findings. Safety and efficacy must remain
the cornerstone of government licensing, but regulatory bias should favor competition and prevent incumbents from using
red tape to forestall competition.

Moving from the system we’ve got now to the one I’ve outlined would be complicated, and would take a long time. Most of
us have been paying into an insurance system for years, expecting that our future health-care bills would be paid; we haven’t
been saving separately for these expenses. It would take a full generation to completely migrate from relying on Medicare to
saving for late-life care; from Medicaid for the disadvantaged to catastrophic insurance and subsidized savings accounts.
Such a transition would require the slow reduction of Medicare taxes, premiums, and benefit levels for those not yet eligible,
and a corresponding slow ramp-up in HSAs. And the national catastrophic plan would need to start with much broader
coverage and higher premiums than the ultimate goal, in order to fund the care needed today by our aging population.
Nonetheless, the benefits of a consumer-centered approach—lower costs for better service—should have early and large
dividends for all of us throughout the period of transition. The earlier we start, the less a transition will ultimately cost.

Many experts oppose the whole concept of a greater role for consumers in our health-care system. They worry that patients
lack the necessary knowledge to be good consumers, that unscrupulous providers will take advantage of them, that they will
overspend on low-benefit treatments and under-spend on high-benefit preventive care, and that such waste will leave some
patients unable to afford highly beneficial care.

They are right, of course. Whatever replaces our current system will be flawed; that’s the nature of health care and, indeed,
of all human institutions. Our current system features all of these problems already—as does the one the Obama reforms
would create. Because health care is so complex and because each individual has a unique health profile, no system can be
perfect.

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 18 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

I believe my proposed approach passes two meaningful tests. It will do a better job than our current system of controlling
prices, allocating resources, expanding access, and safeguarding quality. And it will do a better job than a more government-
driven approach of harnessing medicine’s dynamism to develop and spread the new knowledge, technologies, and
techniques that improve the quality of life. We won’t be perfect consumers, but we’re more likely than large bureaucracies to
encourage better medicine over time.

All of the health-care interest groups—hospitals, insurance companies, professional groups, pharmaceuticals, device
manufacturers, even advocates for the poor—have a major stake in the current system. Overturning it would favor only the
300 million of us who use the system and—whether we realize it or not—pay for it. Until we start asking the type of
questions my father’s death inspired me to ask, until we demand the same price and quality accountability in health care
that we demand in everything else, each new health-care reform will cost us more and serve us less.

$636,687.75

Ten days after my father’s death, the hospital sent my mother a copy of the bill for his five-week stay: $636,687.75. He was
charged $11,590 per night for his ICU room; $7,407 per night for a semiprivate room before he was moved to the ICU;
$145,432 for drugs; $41,696 for respiratory services. Even the most casual effort to compare these prices to marginal costs
or to the costs of off-the-shelf components demonstrates the absurdity of these numbers, but why should my mother care?
Her share of the bill was only $992; the balance, undoubtedly at some huge discount, was paid by Medicare.

Wasn’t this an extraordinary benefit, a windfall return on American citizenship? Or at least some small relief for a distraught
widow?

Not really. You can feel grateful for the protection currently offered by Medicare (or by private insurance) only if you don’t
realize how much you truly spend to fund this system over your lifetime, and if you believe you’re getting good care in
return.

Would our health-care system be so outrageously expensive if each American family directly spent even half of that $1.77
million that it will contribute to health insurance and Medicare over a lifetime, instead of entrusting care to massive
government and private intermediaries? Like its predecessors, the Obama administration treats additional government
funding as a solution to unaffordable health care, rather than its cause. The current reform will likely expand our
government’s already massive role in health-care decision-making—all just to continue the illusion that someone else is
paying for our care.

But let’s forget about money for a moment. Aren’t we also likely to get worse care in any system where providers are more
accountable to insurance companies and government agencies than to us?

Before we further remove ourselves as direct consumers of health care—with all of our beneficial influence on quality,
service, and price—let me ask you to consider one more question. Imagine my father’s hospital had to present the bill for his
“care” not to a government bureaucracy, but to my grieving mother. Do you really believe that the hospital—forced to face
the victim of its poor-quality service, forced to collect the bill from the real customer—wouldn’t have figured out how to
make its doctors wash their hands?

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 19 of 20
The Atlantic Online | September 2009 | How American Health Care Killed My Father | David Goldhill 9/6/09 4:34 PM

The URL for this page is http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/200909/health-care

SUBSCRIBE TO THE ATLANTIC TODAY!


Take advantage of our great rate to subscribe to a year of The Atlantic Monthly.
Go to the following Web address to sign up today:
http://www.theatlantic.com/subscribe12

All material copyright The Atlantic Monthly Group. All rights reserved.

http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/200909/health-care Page 20 of 20

You might also like