China Retailing
China Retailing
China Retailing
The authors are indebted to Zhu Jingtian who conducted the interviews upon which this article
is based.
59
60 HEIDI VERNON-WORTZEL & LAWRENCE H. WORTZEL
Output in both the industrial and agricultral sectors has risen dramatically
over the last several years. The abandonment of the commune system and
return to townships and collectives has resulted in greatly increased ag-
ricultural production and the proliferation of "side-line industries." The
sidelines enterprises of agricultural townships produce simple consumer
goods from shirts to plywood paneling and employ peasants who would
otherwise drift to the cities.'^ Other changes in industry, exclusive of ag-
riculture, are also far-reaching and their impact is still not entirely clear. ^
Neither the state wholesaling nor the state retailing system was designed
to accommodate a situation in which efficiency and expanded output rather
than equity were paramount. Nor was the state system geared to accept
goods produced by sideline industries. There were few incentives for the
state system to handle more or different goods, to get merchandise to the
consumer as efficiently as possible, or to pass on cost savings to the
consumer. Consequently, the first free market producers had to wholesale
and retail the goods themselves. Many were collectives selling the output of
their sideline industries.
As free market goods became more available, entrepreneurs took ad-
vantage of the increased opportunities of the marketplace and began to
specialize either in manufacturing or distribution. Free market retailers now
include both individual proprietors and collectives. Free market retailing,
though still small in proportion to China's total retail sales, has grown rapidly.
Individual stores have continued to specialize in different categories of goods
and to employ a wider range of retail strategies.
ing countries, this type of store is neither the principal retail outlet for the
merchandise classifications it carries, nor one of several competing stores in
the neighborhood. The neighborhood convenience store competes princi-
pally with the more remote and much larger state-owned store. Its competi-
tive strategy is comparable to that of the industrialized country convenience
store that vies with the supermarket for customers. It competes much in the
same way through service augmentation and through providing time and
transaction convenience. Because of the paucity of local, neighborhood
competition, the neighborhood convenience store can and does command a
price premium over the state-owned store. There are not yet so many
neighborhood stores that they must compete with each other using price
leadership strategies.
There are also neighborhood speciality stores. There are several types,
ranging from tiny stalls specializing in perishables (such as fruit) to dress
shops to service businesses (such as barber shops and restaurants). Their
strategies are based on service augmentation and product differentiation.
The fruit stalls and the restaurants base their strategy on offering better
quality or better service than that available in the state store. A dress
shop, for example, may offer alterations in addition to better quality
materials and construction.
Free Market Located RetailersFree market areas attract a ple-
thora of retail merchants. Included in the Guangzhou free market area are
butcher shops,fishand seafood retailers, retailers of preserved foods, folk
medicine hawkers, and jade merchants. Retailers located in these free
market areas compete not only wi the state-owned stores, but very
intensely with each other. They compete with state stores using mer-
chandise differentiation strategies, offering merchandise that is either
unique or of better quality. For example, a store or stall would offer dried
mushrooms that are unobtainable in state stores and might even have been
harvested and dried in another province. The mushroom harvester might
have shipped them or even brought them directly to the store or stall that
sells them at retail.
These retailers compete with each other using both service and person-
ality augmentation and price leadership strategies. Each will try to attract
steady customers by building a personal relationship with them. While the
aggregate price level in the free market may be higher than in state stores,
competition is becoming intense among free market retailers. Prices are
not fixed, bargaining is encouraged, and most retailers will shave prices
where necessary.
When the distribution system was state-owned, individuals could not take
advantage either of differential availability or of the arbitrage opportunities
offered by inter-province price differentials. Now that fi-ee market retailing
is allowed, enterprising retailers travel from province to province in search
of merchandise that is either unavailable at home or can be purchased more
advantageously than at home.
Cigarettes, for example, can be sold for 2 yuan a pack in Chongquing but
cost only 1 yuan per pack in Shanghai. Part-time entrepreneurs from Chong-
quing travel to Shanghai where they buy packs of cigarettes for 1 yuan and
resell them to wholesalers in Chongquing for 1.5 yuan. They claim to earn
200 yuan per month, or twice their salary as factory workers, at this sideline
business.'
The dress shop included in our sample did a substantial proportion of its
business in wholesale sales to retailers from other provinces. Some of the
free market retailers selling dried food, such as mushrooms, also have
substantial inter-provincial wholesale businesses.
The shoppers who buy for resale hand-carry their purchases, travelling
from place to place on the very inexpensive but uncomfortable railroad
system. Their porterage provides a way around the capacity limitations of
the physical distribution system. The quantities they can carry necessarily
are limited, and the goods in which they trade are restricted to items that are
relatively low in bulk but high in value. Interestingly, intra-provincial whole-
saling has already spawned at least one other business in Guangzhou. The
principal customers of the hotel included in our interview sample were
out-of-tovm retailers who had come to Guangzhou in search of merchandise.
In fact, one of the key services provided by the hotel owner is advice on
where to find the best buys; another is providing a safe place to keep money
and goods.
Many of the free market sellers, including those selling fresh meats, fish,
and vegetables and those selling preserved foods, have also developed
substantial local wholesale businesses. Their customers are the privately
owned restaurants. Since these restaurants compete by offering better
quality food or food not obtainable in the state-owned restaurants,
restauranteurs naturally gravitate to free market sources for their needs.
Since free market restaurants can command higher prices for their food,
they pay the higher prices demanded by free market retailers.
cate. The FEC is issued only to foreign visitors and only in exchange for hard
currency. It is the only currency accepted at tourist hotels, restaurants
catering to foreigners, and Friendship stores (stores set up solely for
tourists).
When state-owned institutions were the only place to use FECs, most
foreign exchange earnings flowed back to the Chinese government because
there was little or no opportunity for local citizens to use FECs if and when
they acquired them. But with the advent of free market retailing, an informal
import/export market has appeared, with free market retailers playing a key
role. A cadre of money changers and middlemen has appeared. The money
changers buy FECs both from local Chinese and foreign visitors. Although
the value of a yuan and the FEC are exactly the same when used to purchase
goods at a state store, money changers will pay a premium in yuan when
buying FECs and will sell them to individuals who want to import. Many of
these importers are free market retailers.
The middleman group is primarily composed of Hong Kong Chinese who
travel to Guangzhou (an easy trip by train or boat) laden with small, high
value consumer products such as watches and tape decks purchased in Hong
Kong. These imports are not limited to goods made in Hong Kong. Japanese
and even Western made goods may be included. The middlemen sell these
items to free market retailers, who in turn sell them to local Chinese. The
free market retailers may accept payment from their customers in FECs at
one price or in joian at a higher price, depending on their own currency
needs. So, in a sense, these retailers are also performing a money-changing
function.
Likewise, the Hong Kong middlemen do not always require pa5niient from
the retailer in FECs. Many of the middlemen are engaged in two-way trade
and will accept yuan, which they then spend in Guangzhou for locally
produced products such as dried mushrooms or traditional medicines. The
middlemen will then bring these back to Hong Kong and sell them at a profit,
using the Hong Kong dollars earned to buy more consumer goods to carry
back to Guangzhou.
The impact of this informal import/export trade extends well beyond
Guangzhou because it also constitutes a key part of the inter-provincial
wholesale trade. The Guangzhou free market retailers who deal in imported
goods wholesale their imports inter-provincially, as well as sell them at
retail. A significant proportion of the retailer/buyers who come to Guang-
zhou come in search of imported goods.
In summary, what has developed in Guangzhou, even at this early stage,
is a retailing system that exhibits diversity in both form and function and that
conducts wholesale trade and import/export trade as well as retailing. The
wholesale component is likely to be found in other parts of China as well. But
the import/export component is likely to be found principally in Guangzhou
and a few other southern cities with easy access to Hong Kong.
FREE MARKET RETAILING IN CHINA 69
Future of the Free Market Retailer
China is a country of great diversity, and the extent and speed of change
varies significantly by location and by industry. Therefore, generalizations
about the future of free market retailing may not apply uniformly across the
country. Free market retailing is, at present, a very attractive opportunity to
make money. If free market retailing is held to a small proportion of total
retail sales, and if the state system is not radically changed, free market
retailers should continue to prosper. But if free market retailing is either
allowed unbridled growth or if the state system is given more freedom of
action in terms of location, pricing, and strategy, competition will become
much more intense in the free market.
Our expectation is that free market retailing will be allowed to grow.
One reason is that growth will spread the profits more broadly. A second
reason is that continued expansion can stimulate growth in the output of both
manufactured consumer goods and agricultural products by providing acces-
sible distribution channels and the possibility of higher retums to producers.
In addition, unemployment has been increasing in the cities and the free
market distribution system provides jobs for some urban residents who
would otherwise be unemployed.
A shakeout seems most unlikely, unless retums fall to levels that make
free market retailing less attractive than working in a state-provided job.
This does not seem probable because growth in the number of attractive
state-provided jobs will be limited and because economic growth will offer
additional opportunities for new retail entrants without cutting into either the
state or existing free market system to the point at which either is
threatened.
If the Chinese government continues its present policies, evolution in
two directions seems likely. One direction is toward the establishment of
some larger stores, government regulations permitting. The population
density of China's large cities, coupled with rising incomes, mitigates in
favor of bigger retail units. At present, the size limitation appears to be
government imposed. If establishments are to grow, it will be to the extent
that there are adequate supplies of consumer goods and available capital for
expansion.
The second direction will be in the evolution of an infrastmcture to
service free market retailers and to link them more effectively with man-
ufacturers. With the evolution vdll come specialization; some retailers who
are now also doing wholesale business will evolve into dedicated wholesal-
ers. Manufacturers will look for reliable, consistent means for getting their
merchandise to retailers. This will also contribute to the development of
wholesaling. Specialist salespeople, representing manufacturers and
wholesalers, will evolve and so will sectors specializing in transportation,
both intra- and inter-city. The potential effects of these changes in the
70 HEIDI VERNON-WORTZEL & LAWRENCE H. WORTZEL
retail system are many and cumulatively can have an impact on the Chinese
economy that extends well beyond the retailing sector.
It is impossible at this point to identify either the depth or breadth of the
impact because the free market arrangements are too new to be used as
predictors. We can, however, point out some of the likely possibilities and
their potential effects.
market. Now she makes about $40 a week as a fast food retailer, more than
six times the wage of the average factory worker. '^
The potential problem side of free enterprises is exemplified by govern-
ment engineers who moonlight at the privately owned Shanghai O.K. Infor-
mation & Technology Research & Development Co. Their moonlighting
gives them wages as high as $352 a month, more than twice the salary of
Deng Xiaoping and about seven times that of the wages of government
engineers. ^"^ Now that there are things to buy, the temptations are hard to
resist, even though the engineers risk resentment from those whose op-
portunities are not as great.
There are major issues with which the Chinese are going to have to deal
if they continue to support a system in which a peasant can have a
substantially higher income than a government employee and in which a
government employee can earn much more moonlighting than in his gov-
ernment job. Faculty members of universities, doctors, and other profes-
sionals are finding that the salaries paid them by state put them at an
increasing disadvantage in terms of purchasing goods that make their lives
more pleasant. The result is that the best and brightest may defect from
such occupations.
The situation in Hungary provides a reasonable comparison. Of all the
Eastern European countries, Hungary is the one in which the free market
has prospered (although not to the same extent or in quite the same
direction as in China). The effect, however, is much the same. Govern-
ment workers, highly educated academics, and health care personnel are
paid by the state. They look at a less comfortable, dimmer future in terms
of ability to purchase goods that add to the quality of life. Many are
choosing careers as restaurant owners and shopkeepers rather than as
executives in the large state-owned firms.
Despite the economic disadvantages, some still stay with the state
sector. But those Hungarians who stay have advantages that Chinese state
employees do not. Hungary's proximity to Western Europe and the free-
dom to take vacations outside the Communist bloc siphon off some of the
discontent over earning power. In addition, many professionals are able to
attend meetings abroad and to gain prestige that is not available to their
wealthier, entrepreneurial countrymen. For the Hungarian, there are
other compensations for low wages. To the Chinese businessman or
woman, compensation is overwhelmingly economic. The only reward is
the ability to pay for the Hong Kong-purchased television, refrigerator, or
stereo system.
Choosing the path of economic reward is not without its risks, however.
The private sector entrepreneur must forego many state benefits, includ-
ing free medical care and a pension. In addition, there is always the threat
of a backlash against progress, probably not as severe a backlash as the
Cultural Revolution, but worrisome nevertheless. This concern that en-
72 HEIDI VERNON-WORTZEL & LAWRENCE H. WORTZEL
trepreneurship might corrupt the political purity of the Party was evident in
a People's Daily editorial. The paper warned party members to demon-
strate austerity and not to follow the examples of peasants who used their
money to build impressive homes and to buy Japanese vans. '^ National
leaders are, as prime minister Zhao Ziyang put it, "wading a river by
groping stone by stone for solid footing on the riverbed." If such a backlash
occurs, the entrepreneur might not only lose everything but might also be
prohibited from taking a new position in any state-owned undertaking;
there is the threat of consignment to economic and political limbo.
Effects on Consumers
Free market retailing has the potential of affecting consumers in three ways.
It can introduce inequities in the way goods are distributed, it can change the
mix of goods that are available, and it can affect the efficiency, either
positively or negatively, with which they are distributed.
Equity EffectsEquity can be affected when income distributions change
as they have now with the introduction of free enterprise. Before the Four
Modernizations, incomes in China were relatively equal, regardless of one's
job, and prices were controlled. So far, free market retailing has not affected
the equitable distribution of essentials. This is because the Government has
kept a firm hand on the distribution, and thus the price, of essentials.
However, the potential for inequitable distribution is there, as we can see in
the decrease in grain production. When given the freedom to decide what to
produce, many farmers choose to produce those crops that promise better
economic retum. In this situation, free market retailing of grain could result
in price increases that will, of course, have an impact on the state worker
much more than on the new affiuent class.
But if one wants to apply equity considerations to non-essentials, then the
conclusion is that free market retailing has introduced inequities into the
system. Before free market retailing, for example, the purchase of a televi-
sion required a couponfromthe work unit with no variation in the price of the
set. Since incomes were relatively equal, everyone had relatively equal
access to a set. Now any newly wealthy entrepreneur can manage to acquire
a set imported through Hong Kong, regardless of his (or her) official
entitlement, because he can pay the premium that the availability of the set
commands. As long as the state stores are able to get merchandise, the
consumer can buy at a lower price; but if not, consumers will pay more.
Free market retailers' choices of merchandise are based on what these
merchants think they can profitably sell rather than on a government plan or
on what is equitable. To the extent that they can get a good price for an item,
they are willing to pay a correspondingly high price to obtain it. Manufactur-
ers producing for the free market are motivated to produce whatever gives
the best retum, a circumstance which may not coincide with what the
FREE MARKET RETAILING IN CHINA 73
economy needs. Given a price-controlled state system operating alongside a
free market, it is likely that manufacturers will realize even more clearly that
they can get better returns by producing those goods demanded by the free
market sector.
Changes in the Mix of Goods AvailableWith access to the free
market, many consumers should find that they have access to a broader
range of products and to broader assortments within product types. The
growth of free market retailing encourages the manufacture of new products
because manufacturers can easily enter a distribution system that reaches
consumers and allows them to get prices for their goods that exceed their
costs. Now that manufacturing enterprises can retain some or all of their
profits, they have an incentive to produce for the free market. Similarly, free
market retailers have an incentive to stock broader assortments because
they profit directly from any increased sales generated by assortment
breadth.
The benefits of a broadened product mix available in Guangzhou extend
beyond Guangzhou. When peddlers come to Guangzhou to purchase prod-
ucts to take back for resale in their native provinces, the customers in
those provinces have access to goods that are not normally available
through the state system. The process of free enterprise in which indi-
vidual entrepreneurs move goods from one area to another may help to
eliminate some of the bottleneck that now exists in China's internal dis-
tribution system without requiring extensive capital investment.
Free market retailing should also increase the flow of better quality
goods. Until recently, under the state system, wholesalers paid growers
the same price for poor tasting or appearing apples as for better quality. In
that system, a more reliable or better-sounding radio did not command a
premium that justified the effort necessary to produce it. Now, factories
that do not produce quality goods are admonished and are not permitted to
retain earnings for bonuses, while the quality producers are allowed to
prosper. Consumers, even under the old state system, became discrimi-
nating as soon as there was some choice in quality. Certain brands of
bicycles would languish unsold in department stores while other brands
would be bought immediately. Consumers would wait for weeks or months
to acquire high quality products.
Since free market retailers can set their own prices, they can pay
manufacturers more for better quality in those cases where consumers are
willing to pay a premium. And they will select only those items that are
well-made and offer good value, since they must bear the economic losses
generated by unsaleable goods. The effect should be to accelerate the
movement to better quality.
In a small way, free market retailing is increasing theflowof imports into
China and broadening the range of goods available without putting pressure
on its balance of payments. Some consumers will benefit as a result, but it
74 HEIDI VERNON-WORTZEL & LAWRENCE H. WORTZEL
Conclusion
Probably the most optimistic conclusion that one can come to is that the
introduction of free market retailing has raised some interesting new pos-
sibilities for the accelerated development of the Chinese economy. But free
market retailing will not automatically lead to the realization of these pos-
sibilities. Realization depends on how well and how sensitively the transition
is managed.
The promises and consequences of free market retailing, as they are
being worked out in Guangzhou and elsewhere in China, transcend even the
critical issue of equity and efficiency in this command economy. Free market
retailing is changing the very structure of China's retail distribution and has a
profound impact on the type and quality of goods available to China's one
billion plus citizens. The free market fosters new arrangements in currency
transactions and in import opportunities. Even the internal distribution
system feels the effect of this grov^nng trend.
It is far too early to draw major conclusions about the impact of free
76 HEIDI VERNON-WORTZEL & LAWRENCE H. WORTZEL
References
1. Richard Baum, ed., China's Four Modernizations: The New Technological Revolution
(Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1980), p. 21.
2. Heidi Vemon-Wortzel, "Equity and Efficiency in the Distribution of Non-Food Consumer
Goods in China: Shanghai as an Example, "Asian Survey (Summer 1983).
3. John A. Reeder, "A Small Study of a Big Market in the People's Republic of ChinaThe
'Free Market' System," The Columbia Jounral of World Business (Winter 1983), p. 74.
4. The New York Times, May 27, 1982, p. 2.
5. Robert Michael Field, "Changes in Chinese Industry Since 1978," The China Quarterly
(December 1984), p. 745.
6. Asiaweek (November 1985), p. 23.
7. Erdener Keynak, Marketing in the Third World (New York, NY: Praeger Publishers,
1982).
8. Lawrence H. Wortzel, "Retailing Strategies for Today's Changing Marketplace, "/(M<r-
nal ofBusiness Strategy (forthcoming).
9. Tom Ashbrook, "A Chinese Cornucopia," The Boston Globe, November 14, 1985, p. 2.
10. Ibid.
11. Ross Terrill, "Capitalism and 'Dancing Fever,' Sichuan Style," The Boston Globe, May
25, 1986, p. 63.
12. The Journal of Commerce, June 11, 1985, p. 5A.
13. The Boston Globe, November 27, 1985, p. Al.
14. The Journal of Commerce, July 9, 1985, p. 5A.
15. The Wall St. Journal, March 11, 1985, p. 32.