A Global View of Business Insolvency Systems
A Global View of Business Insolvency Systems
A Global View of Business Insolvency Systems
68423
A Global View of Business Insolvency Systems
A Global View of Business
Insolvency Systems
Charles D. Booth
Christoph G. Paulus
Harry Rajak
LEIDEN • BOSTON
2010
This book is printed on acid-free paper.
K1375.G58 2009
346.07'8–dc22
2009039585
© 2010 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank
1818 H Street, NW Washington, DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000 Internet:
www.worldbank.org E-mail: [email protected]
All rights reserved. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this volume do
not necessarily reflect the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the
governments they represent.
The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The
boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do
not imply any judgement on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any
territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.
For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with
complete information to the Copyright Clearance Center Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers,
MA 01923, USA; telephone: 978-750-8400; fax: 978-750-4470; Internet: www.copyright.com.
All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the
Office of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax:
202-522-2422; e-mail: [email protected].
.... Liquidation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74
.... Rehabilitation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
.... Administrator’s Financial Responsibility . . . 78
... Governance: Creditors and Creditors’ Committees . 79
.... Organization of Creditors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
.... Creditors’ Committee Functions . . . . . . . . . . . 79
.... Transparency and Approval Rights . . . . . . . . . 80
.... Organization of Creditors’ Committees . . . . 81
.. Administration: Collection, Preservation, and Disposition
of Property . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83
... Rights of Secured Creditors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85
... Retention of Title Claimants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86
... Other Priorities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86
... Procedure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
.. Disposing of the Debtor’s Assets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
.. Contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91
... Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91
... Decision to Terminate the Contract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
... Decision to Continue the Contract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94
... Risks to Counterparties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
... Assignment of Contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
... Procedure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
... Special Contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101
... Leases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103
... Setoff, Netting, and Derivatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104
.. Avoiding Pre-Proceeding Transfers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
... Generally . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106
... Intentional Fraud . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
... Transactions at an Undervalue . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
... Preferential Transfers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111
... Defenses. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
.... Defenses to Avoidance Other Than
Preferential . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
.... Defenses to Preferential Transfer
Avoidance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114
... Suspect Periods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114
... Security Interests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115
... Procedure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
.. Avoiding Post-Insolvency Transfers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
.. Special Treatment of Partnerships . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117
viii contents
Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 267
. Articles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 267
. Books . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 273
. Institutional Authors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 275
Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 277
ABOUT THE AUTHORS
Anne-Marie Leroy
General Counsel and Legal Vice-President
The World Bank Group
chapter one
INTRODUCTION
We live in a time in which insolvency laws are being rewritten all over
the world for the first time in a century. As investment and employment
have become more global, there has been a sharp rise in interest in the
application of insolvency procedures as part of the overall scheme of
commercial and corporate law. There is also a growing need for lawyers
and judges to gain an understanding of the insolvency procedures to be
found in other jurisdictions where a multinational company may have
assets and operations.
The purpose of this book is to provide a coherent overview of the insol-
vency systems found around the world. Its intended audience includes
academics, judges, lawyers, and policymakers. Its focus is on businesses
rather than natural persons.1 We hope to give the reader a sense of some
of the principal approaches to managing the general default of a busi-
ness debtor. We will discuss the nature of the costs and benefits arising
from the various policy choices legislators have made. In the process, we
will emphasize the close interrelationship among various elements of an
insolvency regime so that these elements can be viewed as part of an
overall system and not just as a series of policy decisions about partic-
ular rules, such as the method of initiation of an insolvency case or the
balance struck in setting the boundaries of an avoidance power. As we
identify these points, we want to avoid either generalizations too abstract
to be useful or a mass of confusing detail.
We will also avoid the easy labels so often used in this field, like
describing a system as “pro-debtor” or “pro-creditor.” There are some
useful generalizations to make, but the reality of insolvency systems is
that they have multiple policy goals and those goals are often in tension
with each other. We identify both the policies and the tensions, discussing
the various compromises that have been adopted under various legal
1 We do not exclude natural persons in business from this study, but we focus
primarily upon businesses that are corporations or other types of legal entities.
chapter one
other taught for many years in Hong Kong and writes frequently about
Asian insolvency laws and trends. The English author writes about British
and Commonwealth insolvency laws and has edited commentaries in
which a number of European authors analyze the insolvency systems in
their home countries. The German author is a leading expert in civil
law insolvency systems and has served as a consultant on insolvency
matters for the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank. We
hope that these varying perspectives come together to provide a well-
rounded summation of the principal systems found around the world.
Insolvency law is often misunderstood as a sort of legal mortuary when
in fact it is a hospital where the assets and the expertise of a business
injured by management mistakes or the vagaries of the free market are
recapitalized or rechanneled to renewed productivity and social benefit.
The insolvency process is uniquely intertwined with many other aspects
of a country’s laws. It is also the ultimate scale in that the rights of
entrepreneurs, workers, and creditors must be properly balanced if an
economy is to reach its maximum potential. Those characteristics make
its study both important and intellectually rewarding.
Charles Booth
University of Hawaii
Christoph Paulus
Humboldt Universität-Berlin
Harry Rajak
University of Sussex
.. Overview
1 Debtors and creditors may, of course, be men or women or legal entities. We use
the neuter form of the pronoun here because this discussion is largely concerned with
commercial debtors, a high proportion of which are entities.
chapter two
2 Secured transaction law reform and insolvency law reform are most effective if
they go hand in hand and if changes are promulgated according to a time schedule.
Nevertheless, it is not uncommon for calls for insolvency law reform to arise only after
the onset of financial crisis and for the reform of secured transaction laws to follow years
later, if at all. Unfortunately, this has been the trend in Asia after the onset of the
Asian Financial Crisis. The initial waves of law reform focused primarily on insolvency
law independently of secured transactions. Only in the last few years have some of these
countries commenced the reform of secured transactions laws that will enable them to
gain the benefits of the combined law reform synergy.
systems for the enforcement of debt
German systems) depend much more upon secured credit law as the
lynch pin of their systems than do others. The balance drawn between
secured and unsecured credit is a defining characteristic of a commercial-
law system.
While debt enforcement has a strong and necessary relationship to
insolvency proceedings, it has its own important and independent role
to play in an economic system. Insolvency proceedings are not effective
tools for debt collection as such. A collective proceeding is too cumber-
some and expensive, and too dangerous to the survival of a debtor’s busi-
ness, to be useful for the purpose of forcing payment of a particular debt.
Thus this chapter begins by examining systems for the collection of unse-
cured debt. It should be noted that in every jurisdiction there are inter-
sections between the enforcement of debt and the criminal law. In some
jurisdictions, nonpayment of debt is treated directly as a criminal matter,
while in others criminal charges, or contempt of court, may arise from
related events, such as violation of a court order to turn over certain assets
to creditors. For the most part, this book does not address these criminal-
law consequences.3
In this chapter the discussion of secured credit focuses upon its use
as a mechanism for enforcement of a particular debt. It also serves
as a powerful priority position in an insolvency proceeding in many
insolvency systems. We will discuss that aspect of secured credit in the
insolvency chapters.
4 Of course, court judgments may involve many others forms of relief, but those are
tion office (Betreibungsamt). See Christoph Stäubli and Nicole Battistini-Kohler, Swiss
Insolvency and Restructuring Law—A Short Overview and Some Issues of Debate in Cor-
porate Restructurings in Switzerland, J. Bankr. L. & Prac. , at Art. , III(B) (Oct.
). See generally, Stephen V. Berti, Swiss Debt Enforcement and Bankruptcy Law
().
systems for the enforcement of debt
6 See, e.g., In re Hilde, F.d (th Cir. ). California and Florida are two
jurisdictions in the United States that permit recording of a judgment against all a debtor’s
movable property. See Elizabeth Warren and Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Law of
Debtors and Creditors – (th ed., ).
chapter two
Banking Corporation v. Hurley [] All E.R. , [] B.C.L.C. .
systems for the enforcement of debt
tunity to buy back the property within some period of time or subject
to lawsuits from various claimants for the property, then the assets will
bring much lower prices because of the perceived risk of loss to the buyer.
The modern trend is to give the debtor a reasonable opportunity to buy
prior to or at the time of the sale, but not later. As to disputes from rival
claimants to the property, they are left to be settled in the determination
of the proper distribution of the proceeds of sale, without tainting the
good title of the buyer at the sale.
... Priorities
It goes without saying that a debtor that is the subject of an enforcement
action is highly likely to have other unpaid creditors, so that there may
be a creditor race to seize the debtor’s assets. That fact gives rise to a need
for legal rules to determine priorities in the property or its proceeds as
among judgment creditors. Priority rules will also be needed vis à vis
other persons with interests in the property, notably secured creditors
chapter two
and tax authorities. Concerns that exist in this area are similar to those
involving priorities of secured creditors, where they are discussed.8
In establishing a system of priorities among judgment creditors, it
is also important to integrate that system with the secured credit pri-
orities. This point is often overlooked, even in sophisticated legal sys-
tems, because the two laws—judgment enforcement and secured credit
enforcement—are often located in different parts of the statute books.
For example, the judgment enforcement statute may say that the priority
of a creditor in a movable “relates back” to the creditor’s filing with the
court for enforcement, regardless of the actual date of seizure of the prop-
erty. A secured credit law may say that a secured creditor’s priority arises
upon registration of its interest, regardless of the actual date of the loan.
One law or both should say which of these priorities overrides the other
in case of a conflict between a judgment creditor and a secured creditor,
but this is not always done.
Once such a system of priorities has been established, it becomes more
important to establish a registry of judgments and judgment liens, with
indices, so that creditors can learn about rights already accrued against
debtors. Such a registry should be part of the registry that includes secu-
rity interests or the two should be linked. Given modern capabilities, it
may be more practical and useful to simply link various registries so that
one search will encompass them all. The United States is, unfortunately,
an example of a jurisdiction that does not have such a capability in official
form. Private credit services in effect provide the cross-registry searches
but necessarily without the priority effects that could be established in an
official system.
It should be noted that the question of priority between secured cred-
itors and employees has been particularly contentious in many jurisdic-
tions, especially upon the commencement of insolvency proceedings.
9 See Arthur Anyuan Yuan, Enforcing and Collecting Money Judgments in China from
a U.S. Judgment Creditor’s Perspective, Geo. Wash. Int. L. Rev. ().
10 See, e.g., Gary B. Born, International Civil Litigation in United States
Courts – (d ed. ); Eberhard Braun, Commentary on the German Insol-
vency Code ().
chapter two
11 For an extraordinary summary, see Ulrich Drobnig, Present and Future of Real and
Personal Security, European Rev. Priv. Law . See generally, Symposium, Har-
monised Modernization of the Law Governing Secured Transactions, Unif. L. Rev.
(). Eva-Maria Kieninger offers a set of “cases,” fact situations with commentary
applying to each set of facts the laws of various European countries, a useful compara-
tive device. Security Rights in Movable Property in European Private Law (Eva-
Maria Kieninger ed., ).
12 For one example of the importance of security in movables in enhancing the
availability of commercial credit, see Nuria de la Peña & Heywood W. Fleisig, Romania:
Law on Security Interests in Personal Property and Commentaries, Rev. of Central
and East European Law, ().
13 For a truly extraordinary comparative study of security interests in many jurisdic-
tions, see Philip R. Wood, Comparative Law of Securities and Guarantees (London ).
Another important source is the UNCITRAL, Legislative Guide on Insolvency Law
(). Other excellent sources are listed in the Bibliography.
14 Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Control of Wealth in Bankruptcy, Tex. L. Rev. ,
– ().
15 See infra .., ...
systems for the enforcement of debt
16 Note that the United Kingdom has recently adopted some major changes in its
Canada and the United States, which are similar but which are quite different from the
Mexican system. The Personal Property Security Acts found in the Canadian provinces
are similar to, although not identical with, Article of the Uniform Commercial Code as
adopted in all of the states of the United States.
18 The Islamic approach is sui generis and is discussed at ...
chapter two
19 See generally, Burkhard Jakel, Outlines of Security Interests Under German Law,
in Bridge & Stevens, Cross-Border Security and Insolvency (); Tibor Tajti,
comparative Secured transactions Law ().
20 Bundergerichtshof (Supreme Court), Juristenzeitung ().
21 Tajti, supra note , at –.
22 Tajti, supra note , at –.
23 See generally, Roy Goode, Principles of Corporate Insolvency Law (d ed.,
).
systems for the enforcement of debt
charges are liens on specific assets while floating charges are potential
liens on most, if not all, of the debtor’s property. The key differences are:
(a) those who deal with the debtor in the ordinary course of business
take free of the interest created by a floating charge; (b) the floating
charge is subject to a “carve out” in favor of unsecured creditors; and (c)
the floating charge holder has a very favorable enforcement mechanism
in the form of an administrative receiver. The receiver, generally an
accountant and always a qualified insolvency practitioner, is appointed
by the secured party. The receiver generally acts in the interests of the
secured party, although formally the receiver is the company’s agent.
In the United States, secured credit law is found in the Uniform
Commercial Code, Article , revised with effect from in all the
American states. The Personal Property Securities Acts (“PPSAs”) in
Canada (and now in New Zealand as well) were based upon Article
but represent a substantial modernization in comparison with the
and versions of the United States statute. They are now in effect in
all of the Canadian provinces in one form or another. Article and the
PPSAs are often joined in discussion as the North American approach,
even now when the approach has spread to the South Pacific. The most
important characteristic of the North American system is unity. It brings
together to a unique extent all of the types of collateral and transactions
likely to be important in a modern secured credit regime.
The characteristic differences of the North American system are in
coverage and enforcement. In its near universality of coverage, it is like
the British system but may go even further under the revised Article
in covering a huge range of transactions. On the other hand, the North
American system does not contemplate management of a business and
sale of the collateral by a receiver appointed by the secured party, even
where the creditor has a general lien, so its enforcement system varies
greatly from the British approach. The North American secured creditor
is benefited by a system of self-help repossession and sale, avoiding the
need for judicial enforcement, unlike many other systems.
The French system is much less favorable to secured creditors and
much more complex. There are special rules for various forms of prop-
erty, such as intellectual property and inventory. There is a general busi-
ness lien—the nantissement du fonds de commerce, or enterprise mort-
gage—but it specifically excludes inventory and immovables. A security
interest must be perfected by registration or possession, except in the
case of a vendor’s lien. On the other hand, leases must be registered. The
French system includes a large number of privileges imposed by law and
chapter two
ruptcy Law () [hereinafter “Mexican Statement”]. Another post-Cold War example
of reform is Hungary, which has a system that includes elements of the United States and
the United Kingdom systems along with some unique local features. Tajti, supra note ,
at .
25 See infra ..
systems for the enforcement of debt
rity is generally much less important than secured credit and we do not
attempt to include it in this brief survey of secured credit.
note .
27 Akzessorietät is the term for this parallelism of the defenses of the primary debtor
28 See, e.g., Ulrich Drobnig, Recent Legislative Trends in the Field of Personal Security,
29 Note that in the German system priority arises less frequently as an issue because
there is not generally permitted a second assignment of a movable. Tajti, supra note ,
at .
30 These are United States terms found in Article but they have gained widespread
priority; and (ii) that other creditors, secured or unsecured, know of the
existence of any security interest and can price their credits accordingly.
Thus the required notice accomplishes the general purposes of trans-
parency in any market but is especially important here because it relates
to specific legal rights in specific property.
The goals of a modern system of secured credit are to satisfy the needs
set forth in the prior two paragraphs as efficiently and inexpensively as
possible.33 Each of these goals is addressed in different ways in various
legal systems around the world. One of the reasons for the variation is
the tension or conflict among these goals.34 Because of the great variety
of secured credit systems, it is difficult to generalize about them. How-
ever, certain patterns are discernible. Two are especially important: the
requirement of publicity and the control of assets after default.
Most countries, both common law and civil law, have some form of
publicity for at least some security interests in movables, but there is enor-
mous variation in the extent of such systems and the approaches used to
provide public notice. By way of example, most security interests in the
United Kingdom must be registered to be enforceable, while in Germany
most security interests are not registered but are fully enforceable. The
consequences of the two approaches ripple throughout the secured credit
and insolvency systems of each country. Thus there is actually a judi-
cial presumption in Germany that a debtor’s assets are subject to security
interests, illustrating that the system of unregistered interests requires a
prudent creditor to assume that a business’s assets will be subject to pri-
ority claims by others.
A second pattern relates to control of assets, especially after default.
Most legal regimes put post-default control in the hands of courts or
administrative agencies that use public officers to enforce security rights.
However, private enforcement is found in a number of countries, most
of them common law jurisdictions. In the common law countries other
than the United States there has been a longstanding use of the “floating
33 See, for example, the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development’s “Ten
Core Principles,” which accompanied its Model Law on Secured Transactions,
discussed in Security Rights in Movable Property in European Private Law,
supra note , at –.
See also Jacob S. Ziegel, The EBRD Model Law on Secured Transactions—Some Cana-
dian Observations, in Festschrift für Ulrich Drobnig zum siebzigsten Geburt-
stag (Jürgen Basedow ed., ).
34 For example, in some countries, like Germany, where the bank lenders are especially
strong, there is a concern that strong forms of security might create an imbalance between
lenders and borrowers.
systems for the enforcement of debt
35 Section , Enterprise Act —applicable to Great Britain (i.e. England, Scot-
land, and Wales but not Northern Ireland, § () Enterprise Act ).
36 See infra ...
37 See infra ...
chapter two
.... Generally
The largest difference among systems of secured credit is the extent to
which title-retention systems are included or excluded from the system.
Most countries have the legal concept of title retention, where the owner
of goods contracts to give to another (the debtor) the right to possess
and use the goods but with the understanding that the owner retains
title (ownership) to the goods. The two most common examples of title
retention are found in the sale of goods and the lease of goods. The seller
of goods often retains title until the full price of the goods has been paid.
Similarly, the owner-lessor of goods retains title to goods and will have
the right to reclaim them at the earlier of (i) default under the lease by
the debtor or (ii) the end of the lease. Both arrangements have much
in common with a security interest, including the fact that the party
extending credit is entitled upon default under the contract to obtain the
return of the specific goods, not merely to sue for monetary damages.
That difference is, of course, crucial in insolvency cases, where unsecured
creditors often get little or nothing.
The broader concept, which includes title retention, is title finance. It
includes devices that are like title retention in the use of title to the prop-
erty as a way of gaining many of the advantages associated with secu-
rity interests, but often with fewer of the detriments. In title finance the
financier has title or ownership of the asset as opposed to a mortgage
systems for the enforcement of debt
or security interest. Apart from hire, purchase, and finance leases, other
examples are trade finance forms, including retention of title; discount-
ing, factoring, or forfeiting of commercial receivables; sale and leaseback;
sale and repurchase (“repo agreements”—commonly used for investment
securities and important in financial markets); and stock borrowings.
Perhaps one might include in this bracket securitizations of receivables
and repackagings of debt securities, of which there are many variations.
In essence, title finance often has the commercial effect of security.
Indeed, many of the techniques are designed to avoid the obstacles of
pledge laws. The attitude of jurisdictions toward title finance has ranged
from enthusiasm to hostility. Some jurisdictions encourage the escape
from the cage of mortgages and hence support form over substance.
Others, like the United States and German systems, seek to rebolt the
gate: they recharacterize a title transaction as security with the result that
it often fails for noncompliance with a pledge rule or is reintroduced into
the regime covering security interests (such as Article of the United
States Uniform Commercial Code). Some legal systems protect one form
(such as seller’s retention of title to goods) but not others.
Reservations of title have longstanding importance in continental
Europe. A reservation or retention of title clause is generally found in
an agreement between a buyer and seller and provides that the seller
transferring property thereunder retains ownership of such property
until satisfaction of the conditions in the agreement, such as payment
in full. By agreement, the reservation may extend to the proceeds of the
goods if sold, to the extent traceable. On the other hand, some civil law
systems are hostile to this device.38
Retention of title devices are not confined to sellers but also may be
used by lenders or other providers of financing for the sale of property.
Retention of title effectively provides a security for payment of the pur-
chase price. The well-recognized effect of such clauses is to confer upon
the holder of the reservation of title a prior right or security interest in the
goods in question. These clauses protect sellers against the rights of other
secured creditors holding security interests, as well as against preferential
rights granted as a matter of law. Retention of title devices often do not
require registration or notice and hence may operate as a hidden interest
when such clauses may be enforced without notice or registration to any
(); Boris Kozolchyk, Law and the Credit Structure in Latin America, Va.
J. Int’l L. , , n. (Apr. ).
chapter two
ences and possible ways for harmonization, in Security Rights in Movable Property
in European Private Law, supra note , at .
chapter two
44 Where a system does not do so, there is pressure on lawyers and judges to develop
alternative measures that in turn weaken the existing registration system. See, e.g., J.O.
Fabunmi, Contract Registration and Perfection, Lesotho L.J. , (–)
(Nigeria).
systems for the enforcement of debt
... Enforcement
All modern systems provide for the achievement of the second goal of
secured credit, a mechanism for enforcement of a security interest by
seizure and sale. One of the most persistent defects in security systems is
may not assign the debt. For example, this is the case in the United States. UCC §§ – –
–.
47 See Grant Gilmore, Security Interests in Personal Property ().
49 On the other hand, countries like Switzerland seem to have efficient public enforce-
ment. See Peter Straub, Remedies under Security Interests (Switzerland) at , in Ian
Fletcher & Odd Swarting, Remedies Under Security Interests ().
50 See, e.g., id.
51 Lampros Vassiliou, Legal Issues: Thailand, Siam Premier Guide to Restructuring
54 The Slovak Republic is an example. These methods, however, are often limited to
circumstances in that the debtor cooperates. In Indonesia, sale is by the State Auction
office.
55 See White & Summers, Uniform Commercial Code (th ed.) at § –.
56 See infra ...
57 Standard Chartered Bank v. Walker [] WLR ; American Express Inter-
national Banking Corporation v. Hurley [] BCLC ; Knight v. Lawrence []
BCLC .
systems for the enforcement of debt
... Priority
The third goal of the secured creditor, to obtain priority in the proceeds
of sale over others who have claims to the debtor’s assets, creates three
categories of issues: publicity (registration), the primacy of the secured
creditor’s priority (whether subject to subordination in favor of other
priorities or privileges), and the rule for establishing priority (by date or
category).
.... Publicity
The existence of any priority in a debtor’s assets or a specific asset of
a debtor necessarily creates a problem of publicity. The credit market,
like all markets, operates most efficiently when it is the most transparent.
Information about a debtor’s finances is central to the pricing of credits
for that debtor. No datum is more important than the existence of pri-
orities for certain creditors in the assets of the debtor because in case of
default the value of those assets will be lost to creditors not enjoying an
equal or superior priority in them. Therefore, in principle there should
be public disclosure of any such priority. (The fact of having taken the
correct steps for publicizing the secured party’s interest in particular col-
lateral is often called in English “perfection” and the secured party who
has completed those steps is often said to be “perfected.”) The most com-
mon method of publicity is registration in a public office.
Nonetheless, no legal system is perfectly successful in requiring pub-
licity concerning all priorities (privileges) in a debtor’s assets. Even those
systems that maximize such publicity and impose significant sanctions
for failure to publicize have some exceptions for some priorities. Yet there
are great differences of degree in various systems as to the amount of pub-
licity concerning security interests, title retention, and other priorities.
Some require most such interests to be disclosed to the market, while
others produce very little disclosure.
The usefulness of a registration system depends greatly on the sanction
for failure to register or otherwise publicize the existence of a security
interest. Many systems make proper registration a condition of priority
over third parties, but some do not.58
58 For example, the new perfection law in Japan imposes this sanction for security
interests (actually assignment of title as security) in claims but not for security interests
in other movables.
chapter two
.... Exemptions
The most important single reason for incomplete disclosure is the exemp-
tion of title-finance interests. Thus, for example, the North American
system requires registration of most security interests under pain of
forfeiture or subordination of the interest for non-compliance, yet an
increasingly important category of financing, lease title-retention, does
not require registration in the United States and Ontario.59 A similar rule
for title retention is found in Spain. In the United States, the effects of
this exclusion are mitigated in practice by precautionary filings by many
lessors. Conversely, the French system exempts vendor’s liens from reg-
istration but requires registration of many leases. In Germany, there is a
greater effect than in the other countries mentioned because the avail-
ability of the title-retention device for various types of modern financ-
ing means non-disclosure is so widespread as to leave the market with
little meaningful information about priority interests in a debtor’s assets.
And in the United Kingdom, at least three institutions—setoff, the unpaid
vendor’s lien, and the resulting trust—that emerge from the general prin-
ciples of equity enable a position akin to that of secured creditor to be
established, despite the absence of registration or any other form of pub-
licity.60
.... Registration
Aside from the extent of a registration requirement, there are three
main variations among registration systems: detailed or general; officially
reviewed or merely filed as submitted; and multiple registries or central-
ized registries.
Some systems (for example, the French) require detailed informa-
tion to be filed with a public official, often including the security con-
tract itself. These systems typically insist upon a fairly detailed and spe-
cific description of the collateral and the credit being extended. They
may require refiling for future extensions of credit. Other systems (for
59 The other Canadian provinces with PPSAs have adopted the rule that all commercial
leases over one year in length must be registered under the PPSA.
60 London & Cheshire Insurance Co Ltd v. Laplagrene Property Co Ltd [] Ch. ;
National Westminster Bank Ltd. v. Halesowen Presswork and Assemblies Ltd. []
AC ; Barclays Bank Ltd. Quistclose Investments Ltd [] AC .
systems for the enforcement of debt
example, the Spanish and the North American) require only a brief
notice, including items like the debtor’s name and address, the creditor’s
name and address, and a general description of the collateral, often by
category or type. The assumption underlying the second approach is that
the third party searching the public record for this information needs
only to be alerted to a possible problem so the debtor or creditor can
be contacted for fuller information. The second system provides less
information, at least initially, but is inexpensive to administer. The first
system is more likely to lead to invalidation of security interests for
technical and formal reasons, making their value less predictable.61 On
the other hand, the second system presumes a commercial culture in
which accurate information will be readily provided by the secured party
in response to a third-party inquiry.
To some extent, the two approaches just outlined for the content
of a registration overlap with the adoption of two different roles for
the registering public agency. In some systems, the agency conducts a
content review of each filing by a secured party and refuses to accept the
filing unless it provides properly the information required. This approach
is supported by the view that third parties should be able to rely on
a degree of control exercised by the responsible public agencies and
that commerce will function more smoothly with that confidence. This
“content review” approach may be more common where detailed content
is required.
The other approach is to accept any filing that appears conforming,
with little review by the agency. In this sort of system, the sanction for
failure to provide proper information is post hoc, in that the filing may
later be considered wholly or partially invalid because of the defect,
with a consequent loss of priority. This second approach has the great
advantage that the registry does not require a large number of employees
and elaborate rules, so that its functioning is cheap and fast. The secured
party has a substantial incentive to make the filing accurate, lest it be held
later to be invalid, while any problem as to the content of the registration
will have to be reviewed only in the small minority of cases where the
debtor defaults. Such an inexpensive system may be especially attractive
to countries in the development process that might otherwise find it
difficult to support a comprehensive registry. The second approach also
lends itself to an electronic registration system, which is much cheaper
61 Substantive review by the filing office may lead to refusals to file and therefore delays
and faster than paper records and easier to set up and maintain. On the
other hand, a system with substantive review may be thought desirable
where parties do not have ready access to legal advice and therefore the
official review in effect assists them in filing forms that are legally correct
and enforceable.
The third question about registries is the degree of centralization. Ide-
ally, there would be one registry covering all possible contractual interests
(security interests and title retention interests) and legal privileges (pri-
orities by operation of law). The OHADA treaty is an example of one cen-
tralized registry, although admittedly in the context of exclusion of vari-
ous types of property and transactions from the coverage of the treaty.62
With one registry, a party dealing with a debtor (purchaser or creditor)
could easily and cheaply determine all interests other persons might have
in the debtor’s property. Unfortunately, no country has yet achieved this
ideal. There remain considerable differences of degree among countries,
with some having unified the registration process much more than oth-
ers.
The most important division is between movables and immovables
(personal and real property). Even modern systems generally have sepa-
rate registries for security in land, although with a variety of rules about
movables that are associated with land, such as machinery installed in a
building (“fixtures”). Hawaii is the only state in the United States with a
single statewide recording office for immovables and movable property
(i.e., real estate and Uniform Commercial Code Article ). Within the
category of movables, few countries have reached the ideal of a single reg-
istry, but some countries still have many separate registries (or other sys-
tems of publicity), while others have reduced the number of registries to a
few. Multiple registries may arise from having different registries for dif-
ferent types of collateral, different types of transactions, or different types
of industries (for example, farm products or commercial inventory). It is
not uncommon for legal privileges (priorities as a matter of law) to be
unregistered or to use a different registry. Multiple registries may also
arise, especially in federal states, from having registries administered at
the local or provincial level of government rather than at the national
level. Such is the situation in the United States where the Uniform Com-
mercial Code registries are administered at the state level but the transfer
of copyrights are the administered at the federal level in the United States
Copyright Office. This, in turn, has led to debate as to whether the federal
filing is exclusive or whether a filing may be made in either the United
States Copyright Office or by a U.C.C. filing.63
It seems clear that developed economies will move in the direction of
electronic registries that tend to favor less detailed notice and minimal
agency review, although an electronic registry does not require those
attributes. The key point is that electronic registration solves most of the
problems of multiple registries because it permits on-line searches of all
registries and the use of internet links among registries.
The search logic of the electronic system is also of great significance.
As the search logic of computers improves, the need to search under a
permutation of names (that is especially problematic for individuals) will
likely ease. For countries setting up new systems, a possible improvement
in the process to lead to greater accuracy in searches could be to search
by identification number and not by name.64
63 See, e.g., National Peregrine, Inc. v. Capitol Federal Savings and Loan Association of
Denver (In re Peregrine Entertainment, Limited), B.R. (C.D. Cal. ) (finding
that receivables generated by a copyright must be filed in the federal system).
64 On the other hand, the revisions to Article of the Uniform Commercial Code in
the United States had unintended consequences, because computers are so literal minded.
Meghan M. Sercombe, Good Technology And Bad Law: How Computerization Threatens
Notice Filing Under Revised Article , Tex. L. Rev. ().
65 Tajti, supra note , at .
chapter two
of setting aside a certain portion of the proceeds of sale for unsecured creditors. See,
e.g., Andrew McKnight, The Reform of Corporate Insolvency Law in Great Britain, []
J.I.B.L. . There is a similar “carve out” in German law but it supports administrative
costs. Braun, supra note , at , at § . A number of civil code regimes give a priority
to administrative costs to some extent.
chapter two
leges,” that arise from transactions that enhance the property in question, take priority
over security interests and other priorities that arose earlier in time. These liens them-
selves may rank in reverse chronological order, last in time first in priority. For exam-
ple, France and the United States provide a “retention right” (not to be confused with
title retention), or “possessory lien,” that is given to certain providers of services such as
lawyers, accountants, or mechanics.
72 Another right of secured creditors, one that is both more and less than a priority, is
the right of separation from an insolvency proceeding See, e.g., Stacey Steele, Insolvency
Law in Japan, in Insolvency Law in East Asia – (Roman Tomasic ed., );
Braun, supra note , at –.
systems for the enforcement of debt
.... Proceeds
In a modern economy, collateral of one type is constantly transformed
into another. In an ordinary sale of goods, for example, inventory be-
comes accounts receivable or instruments, then cash, then the cash goes
to the purchase of the next batch of inventory. It is characteristic of highly
developed systems of secured credit that they extend the secured party’s
interest to the new type of collateral arising from the original collateral.
That process can be viewed as value-tracing through the transformations
of collateral.73 Thus the security interest in inventory becomes a secu-
rity interest in the resulting accounts receivable, and so on. Systems vary
greatly in the extent to which they extend the security interest to “pro-
ceeds” and whether the extension is automatic. The German and North
American systems are perhaps the most expansive in this regard.
The extension of security interests in proceeds makes security interests
much more effective, but it also raises a number of legal problems. One
legal problem is publicity. The new type of collateral that represents
proceeds of the original collateral may be subject to different publicity
rules. If, for example, the original collateral was an airplane subject to
a certificate of title system and the proceeds of its sale is a promissory
note, the method of publicity for the first (notation on the certificate)
will be different than the method for the second (probably possession or
registration). If the secured party is required to re-publicize (re-perfect),
then it must closely watch the debtor’s business. If not, then a later party
will not be alerted by the publicity represented by the title notation.
A second major problem is conflict in priorities between the secured
party with the priority interest in the original collateral and the one with
the priority interest in the new collateral. A typical example is a bank
account, in that both the bank (as lender) and the debtor’s inventory
supplier (on the basis of a proceeds claim) may have an interest. The
solutions to these and many other proceeds problems are complex.
To explore these solutions is beyond the scope of this chapter. Because,
as noted earlier, the German system creates a general commercial expec-
tation that there will be unpublicized security interests, the addition of
proceeds interests without publicity is not necessarily a serious burden.
Parties have made commercial adjustments to the system, although there
may be different views as to the efficiency of the required adjustments.
... Cross-Border
Internationally, there have been a few initiatives to develop cross-border
systems of secured credit, although these efforts are in the early stages.76
74 See, e.g., Afredo L. Rovira, Alehandro I. Lubinski, & Gonzalo Rovira, Security
Interests Under Argentine Law at (derecho de retención). This article makes the point
that property other than a debt can be retained if it relates to a claim against the debtor.
75 See infra ...
76 See, e.g., Nicola Yeomans, UNCITRAL Convention on Assignment of Receivables:
Toward a Uniform International Law of Bulk Assignments? [] J. Int. Bus. L. Rev. ;
Christel Bourbon-Seclet, Cross-Border Security Interests in Movable Property: An Attempt
at Rationalising the International Patchwork: Part , [] J. Int. Bus. L. Rev. ; Roy
Goode, The Protection of Interests in Movables in Transnational Commercial Law, Unif.
L. Rev. (). See generally UNCITRAL, Legislative Guide ().
systems for the enforcement of debt
Aside from these efforts, courts are required to apply choice-of-law rules
to determine which laws control as to transnational security interests
when the collateral is in more than one country. The traditional rule is
that the place of location of the collateral (“situs”) is controlling and that
is the rule in most countries.77 However, Article in the United States
has adopted a rule of the debtor’s state of incorporation as a substitute in
most domestic transactions involving intangible collateral like accounts.
In part, this change was a response to the difficulty of “locating” modern
intangible collateral like accounts and intellectual property. Most legal
systems have fictional “locations” for such collateral (for example, the
place where an account is to be paid) as a method of applying the
traditional situs rule. These questions are underdeveloped and in the
process of reexamination in many countries, so it is not possible to state
very much detail about their resolution. Some legal systems permit the
parties to choose the applicable law.78
Perhaps the most odd choice-of-law rule is found in the revision of
Article of the Uniform Commercial Code in the United States. For
debtor corporations organized under the laws of a country other than the
United States, perfection for non-possessory security interests requires
registration in the jurisdiction of the debtor’s place of business or chief
executive office, subject to an ex post determination by a United States
judge that the jurisdiction of registration has a system that has roughly
the same consequences that would apply under United States law.79
tive //EC amending Directive //EC (settlement finality). Cf. France Eases
Restrictions on Collateral and Netting, Int’l Fin. L. Rev. (June ).
See, e.g., Nuria de la Peña & Heywood W. Fleisig, Romania: Law on Security Interests
in Personal Property and Commentaries, Rev. Centr. & E. Eur. Law ().
81 See Tajti, supra note , at . See generally Frederique Dahan and John Simpson,
The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development’s Secured Transaction Project: A
Model Law and Ten Core Principles for a Modern Secured Transaction Law in Countries of
Central and Eastern Europe (and elsewhere), in Kieninger.
82 See, e.g., Tajti, supra note , at n. (Serbia). See generally, Hernando de Soto,
§ .. See Bender et al., Modern Real Estate Finance and Land Transfer –
(d ed. ).
85 Id. at .
86 See ALI Mexican Statement App. E, .
87 For a sampling, see the authorities collected in Westbrook, supra note , at n. .
chapter two
.. Introduction
.. Valuation
2 Harry Rajak, Director and Officer Liability in the Zone of Insolvency: A Comparative
cism. See generally, Henry Hu & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Abolition of the Corporate Duty
to Creditors, Colum. L. Rev. ().
4 Janis Sarra, The Oppression Remedy: The Peoples’ Choice, in Annual Review of
5 See Andrew Keay & Michael Murray, Making Company Directors Liable: A Com-
parative Analysis of Wrongful Trading in the United Kingdom and Insolvent Trading in
Australia (), International Insolvency Review –.
chapter three
that point is the time when reasonable grounds exist for suspecting that
the company is insolvent or would become insolvent if a further debt
were incurred. A strict rule prevails in Germany, where the director of a
GmbH has the duty to check constantly whether or not the company is
insolvent. If so, the director has the duty to seek a company filing within
three weeks.
These provisions also include some defenses for a responsible person:
for example, that he took every step that ought to have been taken to
minimize the potential loss to the company’s creditors after the time he
became aware (or ought to have become aware) of the unavoidability
of insolvency. An additional defense recently proposed in Hong Kong
(the provision has not yet been enacted), that only applies to senior
managers, provides that a senior manager will not be liable if, before
the company incurred debt whilst trading in insolvent circumstances, he
issued a “warning notice” in the proper form to the company’s board of
directors.
() Several jurisdictions (e.g., the United Kingdom, Hong Kong) have
enacted statutory directors’ disqualification regimes, pursuant to which,
when companies are wound up, directors may be disqualified from serv-
ing as corporate directors if they are found to be unfit. These regimes
are as effective as the overall corporate and regulatory culture of which
they are part. For example, although the provisions in the United King-
dom and Hong Kong are almost identical, the United Kingdom provi-
sions have been far more frequently applied than those in Hong Kong.
The relevant law in the United Kingdom is the Company Directors
Disqualification Act . It provides that where the court has made a
disqualification order against a director or the director has given a dis-
qualification undertaking to the Secretary of State that has been accepted,
the director risks going to prison or exposing himself to personal liability
if he contravenes the order or undertaking. The order or undertaking is
interpreted substantively—the director cannot simply act as if he is no
longer a director, such as by changing his job description. He also cannot
give instructions for others to manage the company. In addition to being
prevented from acting as a director, an individual subject to an order or
corporate insolvency legislation
() United States—The United States has not enacted fraudulent trad-
ing or wrongful/insolvent trading provisions. It relies on common law
doctrines and state corporate laws.9 In the United States directors are
not infrequently forced to accept disqualification from public companies
through enforcement actions by the Securities and Exchange Commis-
sion. Directors in the United States are rarely held personally liable for
continuing to trade while a company is insolvent, and the application of
the “business judgment rule” works to the directors’ advantage. However,
class actions against directors are becoming increasingly common. The
“Directors in the Twilight Zone” project categorizes the United States as
a low risk jurisdiction for directors.
6 These issues and others are set out in a pamphlet issued by The Insolvency Service.
The Insolvency Service, Company Directors Disqualification Act and Disqualified
Directors: Effect of disqualification orders and disqualification undertakings, that may be
found at http://www.insolvency.gov.uk/pdfs/guidanceleafletspdf/cddadd.pdf.
7 See http://www.companieshouse.gov.uk/ddir/.
8 Philip Wood, “Overview,” Directors in the Twilight Zone II (INSOL ).
9 See generally, Hu & Westbrook, supra note .
chapter three
Rather, the effect of fraudulent and wrongful trading (or directors’ dis-
qualification) provisions is the fact that rational directors will attempt to
avoid the application of such provisions by seeking assistance or filing for
bankruptcy protection rather than by engaging in the offending behavior.
To prevent such wrongful behavior (and, in turn, to prevent many
bankruptcies from occurring), the best safeguards are strong corpo-
rate governance and the efficient and effective enforcement of creditors’
rights.11 However, it must be borne in mind that effective corporate gov-
ernance procedures are more effective when they are part and parcel of a
strong corporate governance culture. In countries with such a strong cul-
ture, such as the United States, related factors include the active partic-
ipation of shareholders on corporate boards, the requirement that com-
panies publicize adverse corporate news in a timely and efficient fashion,
and the publication by leading magazines and newspapers of the atten-
dance record of directors and of the correlation of directors’ pay to cor-
porate performance. Class actions can also have a beneficial effect on cor-
porate governance.
A strong corporate governance culture is often less likely to take hold
in jurisdictions in which most companies are closely held—i.e., family
controlled—and less responsive to outside, public pressure. Closely held
companies are often reluctant to disclose adverse corporate news. In such
jurisdictions, it is necessary for the government and banks to jointly push
for effective corporate governance. At present, the global flow of capital is
another factor that leads to increased awareness of corporate governance
by such companies, because international capital is more likely to flow to
companies dedicated to effective corporate governance.
Overall, throughout Asia historically there has been less transparency
and less willingness by banks and financial institutions to disclose bad
news to the market than in the West. Consider, for example, the reac-
tion to Russia’s default on its international bond obligations in .
While United States banks and investment banks were quick to disclose
their expected losses from the default, such disclosure was quite rare in
Asia, a result of less comprehensive disclosure laws and a more secre-
tive Asian approach to disclosure. For example, it has been reported that
Japan’s banks apparently have objected to the promulgation of regulations
requiring banks to disclose the extent of their losses on derivatives.
In the aftermath of the Asian financial crisis many called for
the reform of corporate governance procedures in Asia. Although some
changes have been made over the last decade, for the most part the
changes have not been dramatic. For example, after the collapse of Enron
an article in the Asian Wall Street Journal compared the situation in
the United States with that in Asia and concluded that “Enronitis” is a
problem in the United States because Americans had wrongly thought
that there was transparency; in contrast, in Asia, Enronitis was not much
of a problem because people already assumed that there was little or no
transparency.12
However, at least in relation to disclosure, the gap has been narrow-
ing, as is evidenced by the responses to the recent sub-prime crisis in
the United States. Global capital now demands more, and quicker, dis-
closure. More recently, it has not only been banks in the United States
that have disclosed (and later revised upwards) their expected losses on
investments related to the sub-prime crisis; banks in Europe and Asia
have also been disclosing (and revising) their expected losses on invest-
ments related to the sub-prime crisis.
This discussion is necessarily limited to those aspects of special impor-
tance in and near insolvency but effective corporate governance
throughout the life of a corporation is of great importance to any com-
mercial law system. Notably, the World Bank has been active in assess-
ing the effectiveness of domestic corporate governance systems around
the world and is furthering its efforts in collaboration with the OECD
through the Global Corporate Governance Forum.13
12 See Sarah McBride & Phillip Day, Asia Looks Immune to “Enronitis”—Region’s
Investors Long Ago Learned not to Expect Transparency, Asian Wall St. J., Feb. , .
13 See http://www.worldbank.org/ifa and http://www.worldbank.org/gcgf.
corporate insolvency legislation
15 Douglas W. Arner, Charles D. Booth, Berry F.C. Hsu, Paul Lejot, Qiao Liu &
Frederick Pretorius, Property Rights, Collateral and Creditor Rights in East Asia, in East
Asian Finance: Selected Issues Part III.B, – (Ismail Dalla ed., World Bank, ).
16 Id. at –.
chapter three
law. Making SOEs comply with insolvency prematurely can lead to dra-
matic increases in the unemployment rate as well as a significant knock-
on or domino effect on the financial sector that will, in turn, be forced to
write off high levels of NPLs.
It is not surprising that difficulties arise in these periods of transition
from the many conflicts of interest inherent in dealing with the admin-
istration of SOEs. Power struggles often arise. An insolvency law that
attempts to assert jurisdiction over all SOEs will often be opposed by gov-
ernment authorities that have been responsible for supervising particu-
lar SOEs, often for many years. In countries with SOEs it is not unusual
for the relevant state authority to have to give permission for an SOE to
file an insolvency proceeding. Thus, such authorities will try to retain
their influence over the SOEs subject to their control by lobbying for
the exemption of SOEs from the new insolvency law. Of course, as the
number of exemptions increases, the effect of the new insolvency law will
diminish for it is often the case that the entities most in need of the new
insolvency law are the oldest or largest and, in many cases, the most inef-
ficient SOEs. Whether or not the exemptions can be kept to a minimum
is a political issue far removed from insolvency law.
China, for example, has been dealing with this very issue. One of the
most significant areas of debate regarding the new Chinese insolvency
law was whether to apply the new law to SOEs. At an early stage it was
clear that there was a split in the drafting committee about how best to
proceed. However, during the years that the debate was ongoing, the Chi-
nese government commenced an ambitious scheme to close or otherwise
deal with those SOEs in most need of assistance. In essence, during this
period China established a bifurcated insolvency system with many of
the SOE insolvencies being handled under government policy decrees
and regulations and all other insolvencies being commenced under the
applicable insolvency laws.17 The new PRC Enterprise Insolvency Law
came into operation on June , . The goal of the Chinese govern-
ment is eventually to subject all SOEs to the new law, which will no longer
be administered subject to State Council regulations. However, it might
well be premature to proclaim the end of policy bankruptcies in China.
Article of the new law provides that the insolvency of SOEs shall be
handled within the time limit and to the extent stipulated in regulations
Recent Developments in China and Vietnam, () Colum. J. Asian L. , –
().
corporate insolvency legislation
issued by the State Council. In January , the State Council issued
opinions exempting roughly , SOEs from the new law through .
Only time will tell whether China’s dual track system will come to an end
in or whether further extensions will continue to be made.
18 Of course, in retrospect it is clear that the debate over the propriety of winding up
the company was but the first stage of the battle waged by TPI’s management to retain
control over the company.
chapter three
or is “unable to pay its debts as they become due” (the traditional “equity”
test in common law countries). Several civil law countries use cessation
of payments as the test.19
19 European Principles § .. Tests often vary for voluntary and involuntary petitions.
20 Because the United States Chapter regime may be used to save value for equity
owners as well as creditors, an insolvency requirement would obviously be at cross-
purposes with one important function of its insolvency law.
21 ALI Mexican Statement at –. See also UNCITRAL, Legislative Guide on In-
procedures while there is still time to save the business, see Section
... below. Note also that in many jurisdictions (for example, France)
proceedings may be initiated by public authorities.
At the same time, it is important to remember that a number of systems
are unitary, in that they contemplate a proceeding being initiated without
an initial choice between liquidation and rehabilitation, with that choice
made following an observation period (e.g., France, Germany, Mexico).
Those systems have some important advantages,24 but one cost of such a
system is the complication of the choice of initiation standards because
both liquidation and rehabilitation situations have to be envisioned.
In systems that are not unitary, so that the original application repre-
sents a choice of liquidation or rehabilitation, there may be a mechanism
for conversion from one to another. Such a system permits the debtor
or a stakeholder to ask that the proceeding be converted from the initial
type of proceeding to one thought to be more appropriate.
ever, some types of property raise conflicting policy issues. What about
lists of customers and their shopping and personal preferences that (in
some countries) conflict with the customers’ rights to privacy? While
their use by a rehabilitating debtor may be unobjectionable, should they
be sold to an unrelated company with whom the customer did not intend
to deal?26
... Lawsuits
All modern systems forbid enforcement of judgments, but some might
allow pending actions by or against the debtor to continue as far as judg-
ment without special court approval. Generally, that exception creates
some risks for stakeholders because debtors in the midst of financial cri-
sis may not be devoting the attention or the resources to defending or
prosecuting actions as they would under other circumstances. Thus, for
example, a default judgment for an inflated amount might be entered
against a debtor and taken as conclusive in the insolvency proceeding
whereas, on a proper adjudication, the action might have been dismissed
or judgment entered for a smaller amount. Such a result prejudices all
other creditors. One of the virtues of an insolvency proceeding is that it
usually permits all claims to be resolved in one court.
The Model Law itself excepts pending litigation under some circum-
stances. One concern is the running of a statute of limitations if suit
cannot be brought, thus barring a claim from being made. Suits can be
itor were allowed to take this asset and sell it to reduce its own liability,
the other creditors would be likely to receive nothing in the corporate
insolvency. However, if the secured creditor were subject to a morato-
rium, this would perhaps increase the likelihood that the bank holding
the security interest in the machinery could be protected at the same
time that the unsecured creditors could benefit from the cash flow gen-
erated from the sale of widgets produced by the manufacturing equip-
ment. Of course, to justify this intrusion into the secured creditor’s rights,
the insolvency law might ensure that the secured creditor is adequately
protected for any diminution in value of the secured asset that occurs
during the period that the creditor is prevented from asserting its pre-
existing rights against the machinery. This simple example demonstrates
the importance of understanding the place of the moratorium, or stay, in
a reorganization structure as well as the policy justification for delaying
the secured creditor’s assertion of its rights.
.... Protection
The protection for secured creditors restrained by a moratorium can
take a variety of forms. Clearly the adversarial process of discretionary
access regimes provides the opportunity for those who are opposed to the
debtor’s entry into the protective regime to state their case and to provide
evidence in support. Where the regime is automatic at the instance of
the debtor, there will invariably be a right for those who believe that the
regime is inappropriate to apply to court to have the protection set aside.
For example, in Australia, where the regime is automatic, protection of
other interests is provided by the requirement for the appointment of an
administrator, who is almost always a qualified accountant.
In the United States, the creditor may apply early, and often, for “relief
from the automatic stay” unless it is granted “adequate protection” of its
security interest. That protection is typically given by periodic payments
from the debtor or by an additional lien on other property of the debtor,
along with insurance coverage and similar protections. In addition, un-
der the United States system, if the protection given to the secured credi-
tor turns out to have been inadequate, it becomes a “super-priority” cred-
itor, ahead of almost all others, in the remaining assets of the debtor. In
other systems, secured creditors may have additional protections.29
29 See infra .... See also UNCITRAL, Legislative Guide on Insolvency Law
().
chapter three
().
31 Id, text at n. .
32 See infra ...
corporate insolvency legislation
bility of extension by the court for up to six months. Beyond six months,
the agreement of creditors will be necessary. Further protection has
been incorporated into the proposed Hong Kong legislation through
special treatment being provided for “major secured creditors,” which
are defined as creditors with a charge (fixed and/or floating) over sub-
stantially all of the assets of a company. Where a provisional supervi-
sion is commenced, within three days of commencement the provisional
supervisor must notify in writing any major secured creditor. The major
secured creditor has three days to respond to the provisional supervisor
as to whether or not it will support the provisional supervisor’s efforts to
draft a proposal for voluntary arrangement. If the major secured credi-
tor agrees, it too will be bound by the moratorium. If it does not agree,
then the provisional supervision will immediately cease and the major
secured creditor will be able to assert its pre-existing rights and appoint
a receiver (or receiver and manager) to protect its interests. In contrast,
all non-major secured creditors will be bound by the moratorium subject
to a right to seek exemption where the facts so justify.
The other large element of change was noted earlier—the fact that
the country of origin of the receivership system, the United Kingdom,
has adopted new legislation that greatly restricts its use, opting in favor
of a rehabilitation system governed by an administrator charged with
observing the interests of all creditors. It is fair to say that in all such
systems, the trend is strongly in favor of subjecting secured creditors to
the moratorium, although with often elaborate provisions for protection
of the value of its collateral as discussed herein.
.... Liquidation
In regard to the liquidation or winding up of an insolvent company,
there is a broad consensus that the pre-commencement management
should be replaced by qualified independent officials (administrators)
with authority to administer the estate for the benefit of creditors. Such
an official is generally entitled to take control of the property of the
company upon his appointment, and the company and third parties
should surrender property to him at that time. The official would have
the authority to delegate certain powers back to the company directors
and officials who would be required to report back to the administrator.
Although there is general agreement as to this principle, there are several
issues that are less likely to find such broad support.
The usual procedure would be for an independent official to be ap-
pointed by the court upon the commencement or declaration of the liqui-
dation. In an involuntary case, to appoint an official before a winding-up
order or order for relief is made, the court must balance certain factors.
To enable an independent official to be appointed prior to the making
of an order could create great hardship for a company if a winding-up
order or an order for relief was not eventually made. On the other hand,
if an official cannot be appointed as of the date of the filing of a petition,
this might lead to the dissipation of the company’s assets and thereby dis-
cussing the use of provisional measures to protect the debtor’s assets where a preliminary
moratorium is unavailable).
corporate insolvency legislation
.... Rehabilitation
In rehabilitation a number of jurisdictions appoint an administrator as in
liquidation but a number of others permit prior corporate management
to remain in control, an approach often called the “Debtor in Possession.”
One reason for the difference might be to take into account the fact that in
a rehabilitation scenario a company may well have spent weeks or months
negotiating with its creditors before any court process has taken place as
to the terms of a possible rescue. Thus, when a petition is filed it may
well be in a pre-packaged form or well along the way to the resolution of
many of the issues. The presumed expertise of business people to run the
company, rather than an accountant or lawyer appointed by the court,
is another reason. Moreover, in some jurisdictions only the company is
able to petition for rescue, not the creditors, and retention of manage-
ment control is therefore an incentive for timely filing.38 Although the
different approaches to control of rehabilitation are discussed more fully
in Section ., it should be noted here that there are commonly these
options:
i. exclusive control of the proceeding by an independent administra-
tor or supervision of management by an independent administrator
or supervisor; or
ii. exclusive control of the proceeding shifting to an independent ad-
ministrator only if existing management proves incompetent or
negligent or has engaged in fraud or other misbehavior.
The first option has two alternatives:
a. exclusive control of the proceeding by an independent administra-
tor; or
b. supervision of management by an independent administrator or
supervisor.
The norm in Commonwealth jurisdictions and other jurisdictions fol-
lowing English company law is the (i)(a) approach in that once a com-
pany is ordered wound up the management’s powers cease and an inde-
pendent administrator, a member of the independent insolvency practi-
tioner profession (usually initially trained as an accountant), is appoint-
ed. At the other extreme, adopting the second option, is the United States
with a strong debtor-in-possession culture. Two countries adopting the
middle ground—the (i)(b) approach—are Canada and Mexico.
The new Chinese insolvency law offers another permutation—it pro-
vides for the appointment of an administrator to manage the debtor’s
property and business affairs but also permits the debtor to apply to the
court for permission to manage its property under the supervision of the
administrator.
A DIP, or modified DIP approach, may prove particularly useful for
closely held, family run companies whose management might be reluc-
tant to petition for corporate rescue if it automatically leads to their
replacement by an outside administrator.
38 That limitation may be de jure or, as in the United States, de facto because of the
39 See Harry Rajak, Can A Receiver Be Negligent?, in The Corporate Dimension,
Arguably, part of the explanation for these occurrences is the fact that all
official committees can hire legal and other professional advisors (to be
paid for by the estate) and once one committee is armed in this way oth-
ers will follow. Another factor is the United States proclivity for debating
matters in open court.
The traditions and practices in other jurisdictions are quite different.
However, it is unfair to conclude (as have some United States courts)44
that other systems are less fair than American procedures because they
rely primarily on the skills of an experienced insolvency practitioner
serving as administrator rather than on the active involvement of cred-
itors in the process and the holding of more judicial hearings. A bal-
ance must be struck. Each approach has its merits and when evaluating
each system one must balance the increases in time and costs that result
from holding more frequent judicial hearings and involving more profes-
sionals in the committee process against the benefits resulting from the
increased transparency of the process.
For example, in jurisdictions where there are fewer well-trained insol-
vency professionals, the civil law approach of the appointment of an
interventor or inspector (or another creditor representative) has its mer-
its. The reliance on such an individual is also tied to the overall insol-
vency culture and the level of participation sought by creditors. There is
a tradeoff—there is no doubt that the use of an interventor or inspector
is more efficient than a full-blown creditor committee approach; on the
other hand, it is not as democratic and transparent.
Another difficult area is the composition of the committee. At one
extreme is the committee of inspection (British in origin) in which a vari-
ety of parties with an interest in the proceedings, including both creditors
and shareholders, may serve on the committee;45 at the other extreme is
the United States plethora of committees with not only separate com-
mittees of secured creditors but also the possibility of separate creditors’
committees for trade creditors, bondholders, and employees.
Rules and procedures are required to deal with such things as the call-
ing of meetings of creditors, the eligibility of persons to attend and par-
v Certain Freights of M/V Venture Star, BR (DNJ ), appeal dismissed,
Fd (d Cir. ).
45 Only recently in did the Hong Kong courts rule that shareholders need not
Once the debtor’s interests in property have been ascertained, the prop-
erty must be collected. To assist the administrator in collecting the prop-
erty of the debtor, the insolvency legislation and rules need to include a
combination of sticks and carrots to ensure that company directors com-
ply. One such stick is to make the failure to comply with the require-
ments a ground for the disqualification of the director.47 In Hong Kong,
although these sections are not used as frequently as they are in England,
they do address common problems such as the non-submission of books
of account and the submission of incomplete books. A recurring prob-
lem in Hong Kong is that a Hong Kong company goes into liquidation but
most of its assets are in mainland China. When the directors either fail
to submit proper books of account or submit incomplete books, it makes
it difficult, if not impossible, for the liquidator to locate the assets. These
problems also demonstrate the cross-border difficulties that can occur.
Attention must also be paid to the ability of administrators to force
third parties to turn over property belonging to the estate. To what
48 Professional liens may include liens of accountants and lawyers securing payment
Holding plc (Joint Administrators) v. Spicer & Oppenheim (Re British & Commonwealth
Holdings plc (No )) [] AC ; De Lange v Smuts NO and others, South African
Constitutional Court— () SA (CC); () BCLR (CC).
50 See infra ..
corporate insolvency legislation
charge said than with what the parties’ actual rights were.56 This decision
has been seen as concluding this debate—at least for the present.
56 National Westminster Bank plc v Spectrum Plus Ltd [] United Kingdom HL .
57 See supra ...
58 Some systems put these charges ahead of secured creditors as well.
corporate insolvency legislation
61 See Philip Smart & Charles D. Booth, Provisional Supervision and Workers’ Wages:
mon shareholders ranking below all creditors). In the United States, for
example, such claims are “subordinated,” while in Belgium they are not.63
The international trend is to cut back on the categories of protected
creditors in an effort to increase the distribution to unsecured creditors
generally. In the case of workers’ claims, this is easier in those jurisdic-
tions where the government is able to provide sufficient protection of
workers’ claims outside an insolvency proceeding.
Tax claims are another target. Australia has abolished the priority for
tax claims; interestingly, tax collection has actually increased as it appears
that the Australian tax authorities are more vigilant in policing their
debtors now that they can no longer rely on a priority in an insolvency
proceeding. On the other hand, critics argue that these changes merely
shift the burdens of insolvency onto other shoulders, mostly the taxpay-
ers’.
... Procedure
Procedures for resolving disputes over claims made against the debtor’s
assets will reflect the procedures generally following in litigation in each
country. Peculiar to an insolvency proceeding, however, is the role of
the administrator, who generally has the job of objecting to claims that
appear invalid or overblown, although creditors usually have the right to
object as well. This centralization reduces costs and is more efficient than
expecting each creditor to object for the common benefit.
Systems vary in their emphasis on thoroughness versus speed in the
claims process. The United States, for example, makes a claim “allowable”
in the amount claimed, unless an objection is made. Germany has a
similar system. A variety of rules can be found concerning deadlines for
filing claims and whether a debtor’s listing of a creditor is sufficient to
constitute a claim.
In looking at systems as a whole, the most important factor is whether
the claims process delays the proceeding as a whole, whether liquidation
or rehabilitation. A system that permits disposal of assets or approval
of reorganization to go forward while resolving claims later is likely
to produce larger dividends for creditors. However, that approach also
creates some difficulties as to voting.64
63 Lernout & Hauspie Speech Products N.V. v. Stonington Partners, Inc., F.d
case that the proceeds from such procedures are on the low side. This
result is further exacerbated in jurisdictions with poorly functioning
market economies or in insolvencies of state-owned enterprises where
the government wears many hats in the proceedings and might well serve
(or have a close relationship with the party that is serving) as seller, buyer,
and auctioneer, all in one.
One device increasingly used, especially in the sale of whole busi-
nesses as going concerns, is the “stalking horse” bidder. The administrator
arranges a contingent sale to an interested party at a set price, but the con-
tract states it may be cancelled (broken up) if a higher bid is received in a
stated time. To give the first bidder an incentive to enter into such a con-
tract, it will be paid a “breakup” fee of a substantial amount if its contract
is displaced by a higher bid. This device is sophisticated and sometimes
controversial but has become important in recent years.
Another problem is presented when a jurisdiction’s non-insolvency
laws prohibit or restrict foreign ownership in certain industries or sec-
tors. In an insolvency, such national policies are likely to lead to a lower
realization for assets and thus smaller distributions to creditors.
Overall, there are no factors more important in the disposal of assets
than maximum transparency and maximum publicity. Publicity attracts
buyers and transparency defeats fraud and collusion.
Finally, in keeping with the goal of maximizing the estate for the bene-
fit of creditors, the administrator may be entitled to abandon assets with
negative or insignificant value, providing the abandonment does not vio-
late compelling public policies (for example, abandonment of an envi-
ronmentally dangerous property). Notice to creditors of abandonment
should be required, however, as a check against carelessness or abuse.
.. Contracts
... Introduction66
Most insolvency laws allow the administrator to elect to continue or
repudiate (“accept or reject”)67 contracts based on a cost-benefit analysis
66 See generally, UNCITRAL Legislative Guide, ; Roy Goode, Principles of Cor-
porate Insolvency Law §§ ––, – (d ed. ). (United Kingdom); Eur
Prin. –, § ; Ian F. Fletcher, Insolvency in Private International Law –
().
67 Many different terms are used for the same actions. “Assume” is used here for
chapter three
of what is in the best interest of the creditors, accepting good bargains the
debtor had made and rejecting bad ones.68 In particular, rehabilitation
may depend on the ability to enforce contracts notwithstanding a right
of cancellation in the event of insolvency, to cancel contracts (including
labor contracts) to enable the enterprise to downsize its workforce to a
reasonable level, or to avoid burdensome contracts. The principle encour-
ages policy makers to take account of other policies that may provide a
compelling case for altering the commercial expectations and bargains
of the parties.
The calculus of costs and benefit of performing a contract is somewhat
different in insolvency than in a normal business context. If the contract
is accepted, in most countries it must be performed or damages paid in
full as a cost of the case.69 If the contract is rejected, the damage claim of
the counterparty is usually treated as a pre-insolvency unsecured claim,
which receives only a small percentage payment in most cases.70 Thus
acceptance can only be justified where the benefit to creditors is greater
than the full cost of performance, while rejection is appropriate when the
cost of performance by the debtor would be greater than the sum of:
a. the benefit of reciprocal performance still due from the counter-
party; and
b. the expense of paying a low-percentage damage claim for breach of
contract.
The decision is made almost entirely on the basis of the creditors’ inter-
ests, not those of the counterparty, but many insolvency systems provide
certain protections for the counterparty as well, especially in the case of
acceptance and continued performance.
Many contracts contain clauses forbidding assignment of the contract,
which would prevent the debtor’s rights from passing to the adminis-
trator. Many contracts also contain “insolvency clauses” (also known as
“ipso facto” clauses) that cancel the contract or permit its cancellation in
“adopt,” “accept,” “perform,” or “opt to perform.” “Reject” is used for “disclaim,” “disas-
sume,” or “refuse to perform.” “Assume” means to agree to perform a contract and “reject”
means to breach it.
68 For example, see the Mexican law, LCM article .
69 For example, in France such costs become “Article ” expenses and debts of the
estate. Anker Sorenson and Paul J. Omar, Corporate Rescue Procedures in France
() at , –. Germany, see Braun, supra note , at –.
70 Apparently, rejection damages are given a higher priority in Japan. See Council of
case of the insolvency of one of the parties (see below). If these clauses
are enforced in an insolvency proceeding, they will lessen or eliminate
the power of the administrator to maximize the value of the estate by
accepting good bargains and rejecting or disclaiming bad ones.
Discussions of contracts in insolvency often refer to “executory” con-
tracts. Obviously, nothing can or should be done about a contract that
is fully performed on both sides. Thus an executory contract is one in
which performance remains to some extent undone. Yet if the only per-
formance left is payment by the debtor to the counterparty or payment by
the counterparty to debtor, little thought is required about any contract
issue, because there is nothing left but a debt. It is the mutual dependence
of obligations that makes adoption or rejection of a contract an important
and often difficult business decision. Unfortunately, this state of mutual
dependence has sometimes been elevated from a business difficulty to
a legal one with the claim that only a contract with performance due on
both sides is executory enough (has a quality of “executoriness”) such that
it is permitted to be adopted or rejected.71 This mistake—a supposed legal
rule that only a contract with executoriness can be adopted or rejected—
in turn can give rise to a great conceptual tangle. The key point is that
mutuality is not a legal condition but an occasion for business judgment
as to whether the performance to be received by the debtor by adoption
is worth more than the cost of the debtor’s performance.
There are detailed rules governing different types of contracts, includ-
ing employee contracts72 and leases of real estate.73
insolvency. The harm is just the same, in most cases, as the harm suffered
by other creditors whose contracts happened to have been finished by
the time the insolvency proceeding began, so that the debts to them were
already fixed. (Excluded from this section are rights in rem or other rights
to obtain specific property, which are discussed elsewhere.) As such, the
counterparty has no more entitlement to percent payment or
percent performance than any other unfortunate general creditor. To give
it full payment or performance is to violate the equality principle, unless
creditors generally will benefit from doing so.
In many systems, the counterparty may not receive non-damage reme-
dies even if it would have been entitled to such remedies outside of insol-
vency. The reason is that other remedies—for example, delivery of goods
the debtor had manufactured but not shipped prior to the start of the
insolvency proceeding—would represent the equivalent of percent
payment to the counterparty, while other creditors of the same class—
almost always general, unsecured creditors without priority—would be
receiving far less. Therefore other remedies would violate the equality
principle. On the other hand, this view is not always followed. Some sys-
tems, for example, will permit a buyer of goods to demand shipment even
though the effect is to prefer the buyer over other unsecured contract
creditors. The policy reason for this result is not clear but it is consistent
with the rule in many civil law countries outside of insolvency that buy-
ers may demand delivery of goods from defaulting sellers.74 Similarly, in
common law countries, performance in kind may be required where the
contract is for the sale of real estate (immovable).75
good bargain has been preserved for their benefit and the counterparty,
having been paid as provided by the contract, has no legitimate com-
plaint. Any insolvency system should permit such results and most do.
The counterparty might have what amounts to an option to get out of
the contract if the contract contains an “insolvency termination” clause,
permitting termination of the contract if either party enters an insolvency
proceeding. Because on the facts of the example just discussed there is no
risk to the counterparty, its reason for termination might be merely that it
wants to get out of a bad bargain and make the , units profit for itself.
To avoid that result, some countries override such clauses, making them
unenforceable in insolvency while others permit them to be effective.76
This policy decision is an important one, especially in the context of
rehabilitation, where the power to accept good bargains may be essential
to rescue.77 It represents another instance of the balancing of the interests
of other creditors and other stakeholders generally against the interests of
a creditor counterparty to an incompletely performed contract. Much the
same situation may arise from an “anti-assignment” clause that forbids
the debtor from transferring its rights under the contract to a third
party. As discussed below, if such a clause is enforced in an insolvency
proceeding, it might prevent the estate or administrator from acquiring
the debtor’s rights in the contract.78 Again, some systems render such
a clause ineffective against an administrator so as to preserve the value
of the debtor’s bargain for the benefit of creditors. If such clauses are
permitted, the counterparty may get a windfall by virtue of escaping from
its bad bargain.
Nonetheless, some policymakers favor limiting an administrator’s
power by full or partial enforcement of an insolvency-termination clause.
Reasons supporting the right of a counterparty to cancel contracts under
such clauses are in reality arguments against the administrator’s power to
accept or breach contracts. These arguments include the following:
76 For example, see the LCM, art. ; Braun, supra note , at , § ; Eur. Prin.
–, § .
77 See generally Goode, supra note , at , –, (criticism of rule enforcing
property being “conveyed” by operation of law to a legal entity, the insolvency estate, at
the moment the proceeding is opened. In those systems, an anti-assignment clause might
be claimed to prevent the property from passing into insolvency at all. Those insolvency
systems that conceive of the debtor’s property as remaining in the debtor, but taken from
his possession and control by the administrator, may not have the same difficulty with an
anti-assignment clause.
chapter three
– Where the parties have made several contracts between them, the
insolvent can “cherry pick”—that is, claim selective performance of
contracts profitable to the insolvent but cancel others. It is unrea-
sonable for a defaulter to have an advantage denied to the innocent
counterparty. One response would be a rule permitting a court to
aggregate apparently separate contracts where the parties intended
mutual dependence. For example, the debtor may have entered into
a franchise contract with a franchisor while also getting from the
franchisor a lease of the real estate where the debtor would operate
the franchise. The parties may have intended that the two apparently
separate contracts depend upon each other but may not have used
specific language to make this clear. In that case, the administrator
might be required to accept both or reject both, as if they were one
contract.79 On the other hand, if the debtor has two separate con-
tracts to buy two different types of goods from the same counter-
party and there is no contract language linking them together, the
law may conclude that they are truly separate and the debtor may
accept or reject either of them in the interests of creditors.
– If the administrator accepts some contracts and rejects others, the
result may be to prevent netting.80 One response is to permit netting
of some contracts and not others, leaving to the courts the some-
times difficult task of isolating contracts that should be eligible for
netting from those that are not. Alternatively, a finance ministry
could maintain a list of contracts exempted for netting purposes.
If a selective approach is not adopted, then all netting must be per-
mitted or none at all, and either of those choices will produce inef-
ficiencies.
– The insolvent estate is often unable to perform so there is no point
in forcing the other party to await a largely theoretical choice by the
administrator. If, however, the law permits a counterparty to ter-
minate unilaterally under an insolvency or non-assignment clause,
two serious problems are created. The first is that rehabilitation
will often become impossible because the business cannot main-
tain crucial contracts in the early stages of recovery. The second
problem, which arises even in liquidation, is that the possible ben-
efit of assigning a profitable contract to an eligible transferee is lost.
A response to this difficulty is to adopt a procedure that forces an
81 For example, in a liquidation case in the United States a contract is deemed rejected
(breached) unless the administrator adopts it within days of the opening of the
proceeding. U.S.C. § (d)(). In Mexico, the LCM sets a -day period in article ,
third paragraph. See ALI Mexican Statement , sec. I, . Germany, Braun, supra note
, at .
82 For example, the Mexican law provides that the contract continues unless the
, and Goode, supra note , () at , (in United Kingdom system, an
administrative receiver is personally liable for adopted contracts but an administrator
is not, although a new contract takes priority over administrator’s fees).
chapter three
85 Cf. ....
86 E.g., the United States. U.S.C. § .
chapter three
contract will not be transferable. In the systems that override the anti-
assignment clause so the administrator may transfer the contract to a
third party, the counterparty is generally entitled to some protection. For
example, the court may be required to determine that the third party
is a solvent and capable party to such a contract. Or the administrator
may be required to make some guarantee of the performance of the
third party (such as a bond) in a way that insulates the counterparty
from unreasonable additional risk. On the other hand, once assignment
is approved, the law may provide immunity from further liability under
the contract for the estate or administrator.
... Procedure
While avoiding the details of procedure, which necessarily vary from one
system to another, it is important to focus on some procedural points of
special importance in the area of contracts. The first is timing. Most sys-
tems have some time limit within which the administrator must decide
to continue or not continue each pre-insolvency contract of the debtor.87
Some have specific limits in the statute while others require the coun-
terparty to make a demand for a decision, after which the administra-
tor has a certain time to decide.88 Most systems anchor this procedure
with a default rule: if the administrator does not declare continuance or
non-continuance within the specified time, then the contract continues
or does not continue. Systems that adopt non-continuance as the default
rule89 sometimes have a different rule or no rule in a rehabilitation pro-
ceeding as opposed to a liquidation.
Two other procedural points often arise in the contract field. One is
that some systems require judicial approval of the administrator’s deci-
87 For example, in the United Kingdom the counterparty can demand a decision with-
in days. Fletcher, supra note , at –. In France, the time is one month. Soren-
son-Omar, supra note , at . In Indonesia, the period is set by the court if the parties
cannot agree on a time. Benny S. Tabalujan, Indonesian Insolvency law () at –
.
88 It is sometimes provided that certain types of contracts are subject to special timing
rules. For example, in France a lessor can demand surrender of the lease if rent is not paid
for two months. Sorenson-Omar, supra note , at . In the United States, a commercial
lease of an immovable or a movable must be adopted or rejected within days. U.S.C.
§ (d)(), ().
89 For example, this rule prevails in Indonesia. Tabalujan, supra note , at . The
Mexican system is one that adopts continuance as the default rule. See LCM art. XX. The
same is true in Belgium and, for the most part, in Italy. Harry Rajak, Peter Horrocks &
Joe Bannister, European Insolvency: A Practical Guide ().
corporate insolvency legislation
sion while others leave it entirely to that official (for example, the United
States and the United Kingdom, respectively). The second is the question
of continuation of a contract by conduct. That is, if the administrator
acts in a way consistent with continuation of a contract (as by encourag-
ing employees to continue to work), even though no formal continuation
is declared, will the administrator and the insolvency estate be bound?
This question is quite sophisticated and often not addressed in the insol-
vency statute. For example, the law in the United States on this point is
quite unclear. On the other hand, in the United Kingdom the possibility
of adoption by conduct is so clear that the statute expressly protects the
administrator from adoption of employment contracts by conduct dur-
ing the first days of an administration (rescue) procedure.90
There is a third question even less often addressed: what are the
obligations between the administrator and the counterparty during the
period within that the administrator is allowed to consider whether to
continue the contract or not? Must the counterparty perform as required
by the contract during that time? Must it prepare to perform where such
preparation cannot await the administrator’s decision? In either case,
if the contract is not continued, the counterparty may have incurred
damages after the opening of the insolvency proceeding while waiting
for the administrator’s decision. The law may have to determine to what
extent the resulting claim should be paid pro-rata as a pre-proceeding
claim or in full as a claim incurred by the administrator for the benefit of
creditors.
90 Section (), sch. B, United Kingdom Insolvency Act . In relation to employ-
ment contracts, an administrator will be liable (subject to the protection that any such
liability will be charged on and payable out of property of that the administrator had
custody) where he or she has “adopted” the contract of employment, and subject to the
provision that “action taken within the period of days after an administrator’s appoint-
ment shall not be taken to amount or contribute to the adoption of a contract.” See also
Goode, supra note , at –, ; ––, –.
chapter three
91 Some cases in the United States have gone so far as to deny acceptance even
in rehabilitation cases, where the debtor is in fact the same person with whom the
counterparty original contracted. See, e.g., In re Catapult Entertainment, Inc., F.d
(th Cir. ). Norway is another country where licensing agreements may not be
adoptable. Rajak, Horrocks & Bannister, supra note , at .
92 Yet another example: Under the recent Mexican law, no contract for services may
be rescinded, on whatever side the debtor may be—provider or purchaser. ALI Mexican
Statement , Sec. I,.
corporate insolvency legislation
... Leases
Leases in many legal systems may be regarded as a hybrid form, lying
between contract law and property law. Thus it is not surprising that
many systems have special rules for leases,97 although most treat them
under the general conceptual and legal structure associated with con-
tracts. Real property (immovable) leases may have different rules than
personal property (movable) leases. Within the category of immovables,
there are often distinctions between residential leases and commercial
93 For example, in Mexico see ALI Mexican Statement , sec. I,; in the United
Kingdom, see Fletcher, supra note , at ; Goode, supra note , at –.
94 For example, the United States provision (United States Code § ) and the United
law rules.98 On the other hand, in some countries, including the United
States, setoff is an election by the counterparty and is restrained by the
automatic stay, so it may not be exercised without court approval once a
proceeding has begun.99
However, many countries provide an exception for certain financial
contracts.100 Policymakers have been persuaded that a number of these
financial contracts should enjoy virtually complete exemption from the
insolvency process (including the moratorium, the contract rules, and
the distribution rules), giving the counterparties to these sorts of con-
tracts far more favorable treatment than most creditors.
Netting is a more controversial subject.101 Nonetheless, some jurisdic-
tions (e.g., Belgium, France, Luxembourg) have granted exceptions to
the general insolvency rules for certain types of netting, again primarily
in the area of financial contracts, but its acceptance is significantly less
widespread than for setoff. The policymaker has similar policy consider-
ations to weigh in considering exemptions for netting.
The United Kingdom has a heady mix of principles. Netting is pro-
vided for by legislation in the financial services sector in domestic
cases.102 Yet, the netting arrangements of an international agreement
were specifically rejected by the House of Lords as incompatible with
United Kingdom insolvency principles. Finally, it might be mentioned
that the United Kingdom falls into the category of jurisdictions in which
insolvency setoff is compulsory.103
98 Goode, supra note , §§ – – –; pp. –. Some countries prohibit setoff
post-proceeding.
99 See U.S.C. § . See also UNCITRAL, Legislative Guide on Insolvency Law
().
100 In general, these are contracts that include “repurchase agreements” or “repos,”
[] AC .
chapter three
... Generally
Three of the four types of avoidable pre-proceeding transactions are
avoidable because they are generally regarded as unfair or financially
harmful to the interests of all of the debtor’s stakeholders, especially
if they are executed in contemplation of a likely insolvency. These are
transfers in intentional fraud of creditors, transfers at an undervalue,
and preferential transfers to certain creditors.106 A transaction may fall
into these categories retrospectively—that is, it may be a transaction that
would not be regarded as morally or legally wrongful ordinarily but is
104 However, Germany has much broader provisions that may permit avoidance of
almost any action that disadvantages creditors. Christoph G. Paulus, Lessons to Learn
from the Implementation of a New Insolvency Code, Conn. J. Int’l L. ().
105 See, for example, § , United Kingdom Companies Act . See also ...
106 These general types of avoiding actions also appear in many systems in forms
107 The German system of changing burdens for different types of transactions is
illustrative. Braun, supra note , at §§ –, –. Another example is from
the United States system: a provision that presumes insolvency for the days before
bankruptcy, for the purpose of preference avoidance. United States Bankruptcy Code
§ (b)(). See infra ...
chapter three
109 See, e.g., Braun, supra note , at (German law).
chapter three
transfer knew the debtor was illiquid. The same transaction might be
set aside in the Netherlands if done within one year of insolvency, if the
debtor knew of damage to creditors from the transaction (presumed) and
it is shown that the person receiving the transfer knew of the prejudice to
creditors. In the United States, a transfer can be avoidable, and the prop-
erty recovered, regardless of the intent of the debtor or the knowledge
of the transferee, if the debtor was insolvent at the time of the transfer,
the value given the debtor by the other party was “less than reasonably
equivalent value,” and the transfer was made within one year of the filing
of the insolvency proceeding.
The changes in knowledge required or, just as important, in the burden
of proof concerning knowledge are well illustrated by a German example.
If the debtor transferred property to another during the suspect period,
the transfer might be characterized in three ways: as a congruent delivery,
an incongruent delivery, or an immediately detrimental contract. If a
transfer is a congruent delivery—that is, a transfer performed by the
debtor within the suspect period—and was in perfect accordance with
the underlying contractual or legal obligation, it would not be avoidable
unless the receiving person had knowledge that the debtor had ceased to
fulfill its obligations as they became due or knew about the filing of the
petition. If, however, such delivery did not take place in accordance with
the underlying obligation—i.e., if such delivery was performed before the
due time, if what was delivered was different than what was owed, or if
there had been no obligation at all for such delivery—then such delivery
was incongruent and recoverable if the receiving person could not prove
its ignorance about the debtor’s ceasing of payments or the filing of a
petition. The third category—the immediate detrimental contracts such
as an undervalue sale—covers more broadly what is already dealt with
by the section on transactions for inadequate consideration, except as to
remedy. If the contractual obligations were performed within the suspect
period, the section on immediate detrimental contracts allows for a full
recovery of the delivered goods—and not just that part for which no
consideration was given.110
The ultimate example of a transaction at an undervalue is a gift.
Because the debtor receives no exchange for a gift, if it is given at a time
when the debtor is in financial distress and unable to pay creditors, it is
often avoidable. In a number of systems (for example, Canada) the gift
110 To be sure, in detail these rules are a bit more complicated than described here. See
113 F.d (d Cir. ). English law applied: no preference
114Philip Smart, Charles D. Booth & Stephen Briscoe, Hong Kong Corporate Insol-
vency Manual, p. ().
corporate insolvency legislation
... Defenses
Although the avoidance of harmful transactions serves important poli-
cies, it also creates some serious risks in the marketplace. The assur-
ance that legal and customary transactions are final and legally protected
is very important. The possibility of avoidance of an otherwise proper
transaction risks introducing uncertainty into the market, with a conse-
quent reduction in efficiency and an increase in costs. For that reason, the
gains from avoidance actions in an insolvency context must be carefully
balanced against the costs imposed on ordinary market transactions. Dif-
ferent insolvency systems have drawn the line at different points. The
principal method for protecting the market has been to give defenses to
the person receiving the transfer. The defenses may include a claim that
this person lacked a certain knowledge or state of mind, gave full value,
or was engaged in a protected sort of transaction. Where such a defense
exists, a person in the market who fits one of these categories need not
be concerned about the risk of having to return the property obtained in
a transaction.
Sometimes these protections are stated as defenses, while in other
jurisdictions they may instead be one of the elements that constitute the
avoidance action. In either situation, presumptions are often employed,
depending on the circumstances of the transfer.
116 However, due to one of a series of drafting errors in Hong Kong, this is not the
case for corporate directors who receive preferences. Smart et al., supra note , at
pp. –. These drafting errors exist in Hong Kong because the changes to the corporate
preference provisions were made by incorporating the definition of “associate” from
personal bankruptcy law rather than through the promulgation of a definition better
suited to corporate transactions.
117 See supra ...
chapter three
... Procedure
Generally, it is the administrator of the insolvency who is authorized
by law to bring Paulian actions. Such actions in many systems require
a full lawsuit just as in the case of a commercial lawsuit of the usual kind.
As indicated above, such litigation may require of either party proof of
state of mind or knowledge, which is very difficult. The difficulty of proof
may mean that the party with the burden of proof will most often lose.
Perhaps even more difficult are questions of valuation, especially if the
relevant time for valuation is some time in the past. For an appraiser to
testify as to the value of a property claimed to have been transferred at
an undervalue two years before is very difficult, especially if property
values have been volatile since that time. As with other elements of an
insolvency system, the shape of the avoiding powers may depend on the
resources available to the system. If accountants and appraisers are hard
to find and expensive to employ, then a system may focus on intentional
or reckless transfers rather than merely unwise ones.
The questions arising from the dual nature of partnerships are clearly
reflected in the German legislation: even though partnerships (in par-
ticular the so called Offene Handelsgesellschaft [OHG] and the Kom-
manditgesellschaft [KG]) generally are not entrusted with their own legal
individuality, they do have some legal capacities that reflect the economic
need of treating them as more than just an aggregation of several (nat-
ural and/or legal) entities. One of these capacities is that a partnership
as such is potentially subject to an insolvency proceeding; i.e., a part-
nership can be the debtor in an insolvency proceeding. One has, thus,
to distinguish precisely between the insolvency of that partnership and
those of its partners—they do not necessarily go hand in hand. To the
degree, however, that the partners are personally liable for all debts owed
by the partnership, the partnership’s creditors have next to their regu-
lar insolvency claim against the insolvent partnership an accessory claim
against the partners who might not yet be in an insolvency proceeding.
To avoid in such an instance the risk that those creditors will act against
the partners directly, Section of the German Insolvency Ordinance
entrusts the administrator during the course of the partnership’s insol-
vency proceeding with the exclusive right to enforce such claims against
the partners; they are to be realized to the benefit of the estate as a whole.
The United States has a similar approach.
How complicated this issue might become in practice is amply demon-
strated by the law of the United Kingdom; it provides more than dif-
ferent ways of dealing with a partnership’s insolvency. The main (but not
exclusive) legislative guidance is the Insolvent Partnerships Order .
As a general paraphrase, however, it is fair to summarize that the law’s
corporate insolvency legislation
.. Introduction
of the business. The importance of the process in this context lies in its
independence of any assistance from, or approval by, any court or other
public institution. Yet its inability to bind creditors who refuse to be party
to the agreement made a formal rehabilitation pathway inevitable.
2 For another view of this history, see Philip Wood, Principles of International
for South Africa S. Afr. L. J., , – (). On Official Management, see
Australian Law Reform Commission (the Harmer Report, ) . For a plea in defense
of Official Management, see McCabe, Official Management v. Reorganisation Under
Chapter of the United States Bankruptcy Code: In Defense of Official Management
[] Australian Business Law Review .
5 Now at §§ –, South African Companies Act .
6 See, for example, Rajak & Henning, op. cit.
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
The Common Law of the United Kingdom, on the other hand, has
its own provision for business rescue—the institution of receivership
that, for one reason or another, was rejected by the South African legal
system.7 Flexible and responsive principles of equity in the legal system
were skillfully fashioned to create this institution, which is discussed
more fully below8 and which may be regarded as the mainstay of the
United Kingdom’s business rescue provision for the last hundred years
or more.
Nor is the United Kingdom unique in the creation of a Common Law
system to provide for the possibility of a rescue rather than a liquidation
of a bankrupt business. The United States, which shares the same Com-
mon Law system as the United Kingdom, developed what was described
as the “equity receivership” as an instrument for the reorganization of
bankrupt corporations, both independently of and alongside Federal
Bankruptcy Acts, for the period of at least years prior to the enact-
ment of the US Bankruptcy Code in .9 Unlike the United Kingdom’s
institution of receivership, the equity receivership in the United States has
passed into history, eclipsed by statute, although its debt to the common
law is clear. “When [the U.S.] Congress finally added a meaningful cor-
porate reorganization option to the Bankruptcy Act in the s,” Pro-
fessor Skeel tells us, “it took all of its cues from the railroad receivership
techniques that had long been used in the courts.”10
The modern era in statutory rehabilitation regimes was initiated by
the United States, with Chapter of its Bankruptcy Act of . Some
countries like the United Kingdom followed this lead by creating statu-
tory regimes for the first time; in other cases, like Australia and Germany,
the newly created regimes in and , respectively, replaced out-
dated ones. In Central and Eastern Europe, after the fall of the Soviet
Union, new bankruptcy codes were enacted in some countries and, in
7 This is a vastly interesting topic but not one we can pursue here. A starting point
for those interested in this kind of divergence between legal systems may be the South
African Appellate Division decision of Conradie v. Roussouw [] ad (South
African Law Reports), in which South Africa rejected the Common Law doctrine of
Consideration in contract.
8 See infra ...
9 See David Skeel, Jr., Debt’s Dominion () , , –; Clifford Billig,
other countries, long dormant codes from the pre-Soviet-era were resus-
citated and updated. The German reform has been especially important
and influential.11
This new-style rehabilitation regime can now be found in a substan-
tial number of legal systems throughout the world, and the process of
rescue and rehabilitation of a bankrupt business (as opposed to its liqui-
dation) is recognized by all recent international treaties and other instru-
ments dealing with insolvency proceedings.12 It is important to observe
that all such regimes are created by statute and that such statutes usually
lay down a comprehensive procedure to be followed by whoever seeks
protection under the regime. One might describe such regimes as “for-
mal rehabilitation” regimes, although terms such as “rescue,” “reorgani-
zation,” “restructuring,” “arrangement,” “administration,” “composition”
or “reconciliation” are all used.
There is little significance, if any, in the differing terminology thus
employed, but it may be of interest to note that in the United King-
dom, for example, discussion has centered on the desirability of avoid-
ing reference to words such as insolvent, insolvency, and bankruptcy
when describing business rehabilitation regimes. It is thought by some
that avoiding the use of such words helps to remove a stigma that might
otherwise attach to those associated with the insolvent business that is
likely to benefit from the regime. If it is indeed the case that a business
rehabilitation regime might be shunned, despite its potential for bene-
ficial use, on account of the terminology used, then clearly it would be
desirable to avoid the off-putting terms.
11 See Harry Rajak, Rescue Versus Liquidation in Central and Eastern Europe, Tex.
No /, arts. (), (a) read with Annex I, UNCITRAL, Model Law on Cross
Border Insolvency (), preamble (e), art. (a), OHADA Uniform Act Organising
Collective Proceedings for Wiping off Debts arts , (http://www.jurisint.org/ohada/text/
text..en.html); World Bank Principles & Guidelines for Effective Insolvency and Cred-
itor Rights Systems, Introduction and Executive Summary, ¶¶ –; Principles –.
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
dation.13 Even where the entry threshold to the formal regime is substan-
tially lower, a private workout in the form of a creditors’ composition—
which could be seen as an example of an informal business rehabilitation
regime—retains its attractiveness. By taking an informal route, the reha-
bilitation can be conducted without the necessity of oversight or approval
by the court, which can be costly, complicated, and time-consuming.
This lack of court oversight may, however, also be a disadvantage
where, for example, the debtor takes advantage of it to defraud the
creditors. There is a further disadvantage with informal rehabilitation
in that there is nothing equivalent to the automatic stay or moratorium
provided by legislation to prevent a creditor from initiating or continuing
legal proceedings, or, where appropriate, self-help remedies14 against the
debtor for payment of a particular debt. And if a substantial number of
creditors favor an informal rehabilitation but one creditor demurs and
threatens legal proceedings against the debtor, there will be a temptation
to remove the threat to the business life of the debtor posed by the
rogue creditor by assisting or encouraging the payment of that creditor
in preference to the others.
This difficulty is often described as the “hold out” problem, because it is
in the interest of one creditor to threaten to “hold out” in order to receive
better treatment than other creditors with similar legal rights. Naturally,
the other creditors will be unwilling to agree under those circumstances.
A type of commercial blackmail might thus be seen to be encouraged.
Furthermore, and of particular relevance to an insolvent debtor with
assets in a different jurisdiction, the contract enshrining the informal
workout is unlikely to give sufficient authority to anyone seeking the
repatriation of assets belonging to the debtor from a foreign court.
One of the developments in large corporate bankruptcies in the United
Kingdom in the past two decades has been a mechanism to secure
13 For example, under the ancient German company rehabilitation regime (vergleichs-
verfahren) for a composition to be accepted, a minimum of of the claims of the unse-
cured creditors had to be guaranteed. This regime did not provide an automatic stay and
did not apply to preferential or secured creditors. See Oscar Couwenberg, Survival Rates
in Bankruptcy Systems: Overlooking the Evidence, Eur. J. L. & Econ. () (this
article is of much value and can also be found at http://www.som.eldoc.ub.rug.nl/FILES/
reports/themeE//E/E.pdf).
14 For example, a creditor who has supplied goods to the debtor may be able to assert
rights of ownership against those goods in the possession of the debtor (by reference to
a provision in the contract of supply in terms of which the supplier retained ownership
until the goods had been paid for in full) and simply remove those goods from the debtor.
For a discussion a creditor’s right of retention, see supra ., ...
chapter four
20 Régis Blazy, Bertrand Chopard, Agnès Fimayer, Jean-Daniel Guigou, Financial Ver-
sus Social Efficiency of Corporate Bankruptcy Law: the French Dilemma?, d Annual Con-
ference on Empirical Legal Studies Papers (). Although the United States techni-
cally has a multiple-entry system, recent empirical work suggests that Chapter of the
Bankruptcy Code functions like a single entry system for most corporate debtors that
are larger than tiny. Elizabeth Warren and Jay L. Westbrook, The Success Of Chapter :
A Challenge To The Critics, Mich. L. Rev. () (Most significant corporate
debtors file in Chapter and the courts then promptly separate winners and losers).
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
reservation the proposition that seeking to keep alive a business that has
no likelihood of survival is a serious waste of resources, the dynamic
effects of rehabilitation should not be ignored or underestimated. Reha-
bilitation may carry with it the endeavor and commitment of equity hold-
ers and unsecured creditors, and this may be crucial in effecting the busi-
ness’s rescue. In assessing the likelihood of rehabilitation, therefore, the
opportunity must be provided for evaluating the degree of active and
beneficial support that the rehabilitation will be likely to receive from
the debtor’s equity holders and unsecured creditors.
... Access
Some jurisdictions permit the debtor to take steps of its own accord lead-
ing directly to the establishment of the rehabilitation regime and the pro-
tective moratorium against the creditors’ claims (“automatic access”).21 In
contrast, other regimes require initiation of a process—almost always a
court process—during which the court will investigate the claim that the
debtor should be placed in the rehabilitation regime and decide one way
or the other. The extent to which it is likely that the debtor will regain
financial independence is invariably of central concern to the decision-
maker in this process and it is therefore appropriate to describe such
regimes as having “discretionary access.”
Two variations in jurisdictions with automatic access should be ob-
served. In the United States, the debtor can obtain automatic access to
protection under Chapter of the United States Bankruptcy Code
by filing a notice in the Bankruptcy Court, which ipso facto triggers the
rehabilitation regime and its protective moratorium. In Australia, on the
other hand, the rehabilitation regime (called “voluntary administration”)
21 The United States and Australian business rescue regimes have been longstanding
examples of automatic access at the instance of the debtor. Recent legislative changes have
now brought automatic access to the UK, see infra.
chapter four
at §§ ()(a), .
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
which backdates the commencement of the winding up to the date of the presentation of
the winding up petition, does not apply, so a company whose winding up has commenced
by the date on which the notice is filed for the moratorium solely by reason of § () is
not regarded as being wound up for the purposes of Sch. ()(b)—see Sch. ().
35 ¶ ()(f) Sch. A, UK Insolvency Act .
36 ¶ ()(fa), Sch. A, as amplified by ¶ , Sch. B, UK Insolvency Act .
37 ¶ ()(g) Sch. A, UK Insolvency Act .
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
likely to be the debtor’s most vulnerable period, given that in almost all
instances, it will be making a public statement of its insolvency and that
anything between a few hours and a few weeks might elapse between
the presentation of the petition and the court’s decision granting the
order of Administration. This problem was solved in the UK—in relation
to its old-style Administration—by a provision to the effect that the
initiation of the Administration proceedings itself, automatically brought
into immediate effect a preliminary protective moratorium prohibiting
any enforcement procedures against the debtor, except the appointment
by a secured creditor of an administrative receiver under the provisions
of a floating charge.38 This preliminary moratorium remained in force at
least until the court reached its decision and was continued if the court
decided to grant an administration order.39
Without a provision automatically triggering the moratorium on pre-
sentation of the petition, a debtor might be seriously compromised in
searching for the protection of the business rescue regime. The petition
might be challenged on the ground that the debtor did not meet the insol-
vency or near insolvency standard and the delay caused by this might
make the difference between the survival or death of the debtor. In these
circumstances, it is imperative that procedures are available for ensuring
that, if there is such a requirement, it can be established one way or the
other, simply and quickly.40
An insolvency or near-insolvency requirement will clearly have some
effect on when a debtor seeks the protection of the rescue regime. Such a
requirement will prevent too early a move for such a protection. Creditors
would rightly object to a moratorium at a time when the debtor was
able to meet their claims. On the other hand, it is important for any
effective business-rescue regime that debtors be encouraged to initiate
rescue proceedings earlier rather than later. The opening of a proceeding
while the debtor still has assets and operations of value, before all has
been lost, is of special importance in rehabilitation. The hospital is of no
use if the patient is already in a terminal condition.
The two Japanese rehabilitation procedures provide an illustration
of different approaches. In a civil rehabilitation proceeding, a secured
38 § , UK Insolvency Act ; see (c) “Sufficient Protection for all Interests”, below.
Infra ...
39 § , UK Insolvency Act .
40 See supra ..; see also UNCITRAL, Legislative Guide on Insolvency Law
().
chapter four
creditor can enforce its security interest but a debtor can apply for a tem-
porary stay that prohibits enforcement of a security interest for a certain
period. On the other hand, commencement of a corporate reorganiza-
tion proceeding automatically operates as a stay on the enforcement of
security interests.
Where there is an automatic moratorium, there is a risk of debtor
abuse. Because most creditors operate in the dark, at least to some
extent, they often have too little information to be able to accurately
assess whether the debtor, who has sought the protection of the rescue
provision, has truly reached a stage of financial distress so close to
insolvency that the creditor will not be able to succeed in opposing
the maintenance of the proceeding. Policymakers must make a difficult
choice. Systems that place too heavy a burden on a debtor both as
to seriousness of financial condition, and proof as to that condition,
discourage filing until it is too late for effective rescues to be undertaken.
On the other hand, a system that permits abuse of the moratorium will
lose the confidence and support of creditors.
More often, perhaps, the risk is that debtors will fail to initiate insol-
vency proceedings soon enough. It is possible—indeed desirable—to
tackle this issue from both creditor and debtor standpoints. As noted in
the section on enforcement of security,41 an effective system of enforce-
ment of both unsecured and secured debts is one answer to this problem.
If a debtor has not paid, but can pay, then threatening to seize its assets is
likely to produce payment. On the other hand, if the debtor cannot pay,
that same threat is likely to precipitate an appropriate insolvency filing
by the debtor.
From the debtor’s standpoint, two common approaches may encour-
age appropriate early initiation by debtors. The first is to provide sanc-
tions against officers and directors who unduly delay initiation. These
sanctions have been discussed above.42 The second is to provide incen-
tives for filing (or to curtail disincentives). The debtor-in-possession rule,
which permits the company management to run its own rehabilitation
effort, greatly reduces the disincentive that loss of control of the com-
pany presents to management. Management is likely to be much more
willing to seek insolvency protection if it has a prospect of continuing its
employment and its direction of the enterprise. This advantage, although
original management of the debtor and the third person, the latter may
ask the court to bring to an end the protective rehabilitation regime.
In addition to these formal approaches, it is worth noting that in prac-
tice it is not uncommon for an Administrator in the United Kingdom
to seek—and often to find—cooperation with the existing management.
Much will depend on the circumstances of each case, especially the rea-
sons for the insolvency and the anticipated reliability and responsibil-
ity of the original management. In the new-style Administration regime,
which retains the feature of an outside, professionally qualified insol-
vency practitioner being appointed to act as Administrator with all the
powers of the board of directors, this appointment will now frequently
be made either by the board of directors itself or by the creditor (almost
invariably the debtor’s bank) that holds a floating charge.45 It seems
highly likely that, at least in the cases where the appointment is made
by the board, there will be an increase in fruitful cooperation between
the Administrator and the board in the management of the debtor.
In enacting this new-style Administration, the United Kingdom had
to deal with the problem of the competition between the debtor and
its bank creditor. Until , the latter was often entitled to appoint an
Administrative Receiver—as opposed to an Administrator—to manage
the debtor in the regime of Administrative Receivership, rather than
Administration.46 The big difference between these regimes was that the
Administrative Receiver was under a primary obligation to the bank
creditor, whereas the Administrator’s primary responsibility is to the
creditors as a whole. It was in recognition of this huge role played by the
bank creditor in the management of its bankrupt debtor that the bank
retained a share of the right to appoint the Administrator in the new-
style Administration.
Now that both debtor and bank creditor are committed to Administra-
tion, the issue may well come down to “whose Administrator?” Under the
new legislation, before a company or its directors can make an appoint-
ment out of court, they must give five business days’ notice to a float-
ing charge holder who is empowered to appoint an Administrator.47 In
giving the requisite notice, the company or its directors must reveal to
the floating charge holder the identity of the proposed Administrator.
This could open up depressing possibilities as the company and the float-
ing charge holder cultivate their particular pet Administrators. One may
hope that the professionalism of the insolvency practitioners will elimi-
nate this kind of competition. It is unrealistic to expect the same degree
of cooperation between the board and the Administrator where the latter
is appointed by the bank creditor, as existed when the appointment was
made by the board; but it is realistic to expect the same degree of coop-
eration as existed between board and Administrative Receiver under the
prior regime.
In the United States, there may also be something similar by way of
informal cooperation between dominant creditors and a board of direc-
tors, despite the stark picture to the contrary that the concept of the
debtor in possession often conjures. It is clearly sometimes the case that,
prior to the debtor’s filing for protection under Chapter , an arrange-
ment will have been arrived at whereby the funding of the debtor in an
insolvency proceeding will have been arranged and some members of the
board of directors selected in accordance with the wishes of the dominant
creditors.48 It is also worth remembering that the U.S. Bankruptcy Code
also enables the court to appoint an examiner or a trustee to assist or
replace the existing management of the debtor.
It is invariably the case that whoever manages the debtor while the
latter is in the rehabilitation regime is under an obligation to prepare a
plan for the payment of the debts of the business and the future regulation
of the debtor.
48 This statement hardly needs authority, it being implicit in much that is now written
about Chapter ; but see e.g. David A. Skeel, Jr., Creditors’ Ball: The “New” New Corporate
Governance in Chapter U. Pa L. R. (); Lubben The “New and Improved”
Chapter Ky. L. J. (); Henry Hu & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Abolition of the
Corporate Duty to Creditors, Colum. L. Rev. (). See also, infra, ...
chapter four
committees where a case includes a large number of creditors. Id. at – (¶ –).
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
57 See, for example, § and ¶¶ –, Sch. B, UK Insolvency Act .
58 See Andrew Keay, McPherson’s Law of Company Liquidation () –.
59 See, e.g., § D, Australian Corporations Act , para. ()(b), Sch. B, UK
referred to therein.
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
with the proceeds of the sale of the business being generally applied in
discharging the claims of preferential and secured creditors, often to the
virtual exclusion of the ordinary creditors.
Yet, some systems—notably Chapter in the United States—permit
the possibility of equity retaining some value. That approach may be of
special value where a business that has fallen on hard times may depend
for its recovery and survival on its owners. A famous chef, for example,
may be the key to the survival of a restaurant. Rigid rules about eliminat-
ing equity may make it impossible for creditors to negotiate a satisfactory
resolution with such essential equity owners, even where most creditors
might wish to do so. In such circumstances, the route to a successful res-
cue may well be a preparedness on the part of the creditors to grant a
continuing (although perhaps smaller) stake for all or some of the share-
holders of the bankrupt company in the rescued company. This may be
seen as little different from the necessity of granting priority to those pre-
pared to finance the bankrupt company so as to ensure its survival over
all those creditors whose debts were incurred prior to the insolvency.
... Financing
Priority given to post-insolvency commencement lenders to induce the
financing of a rescue process is effectively a surcharge against the entire
estate and its assets. One form of priority for those advancing money or
goods is an administrative priority that gives precedence in repayment
over the general unsecured creditors, but not over a secured creditor,
with respect to its collateral. An intermediate approach allows lenders
and those advancing goods to take a security interest in the debtor’s
secured and unsecured assets. In some jurisdictions, a senior or priming
security interest or lien can be granted in exceptional circumstances.
Some countries make all options available to accommodate the unique
needs and circumstances of particular cases, either by their bankruptcy
code or by general principles of law, especially the law of contract.
Thus, if a court concludes that priority financing involving collateral is
in the best interests of the creditors and is not prejudicial to the existing
secured creditors, the court should be able to approve the financing.
Such financing alternatives are likely to present a threat to unsecured
creditors who may see the remaining assets of the debtor consumed by
chapter four
the financing party, leaving nothing for them if the rehabilitation effort
fails.61 This calls for a carefully balanced approach.
It is no exaggeration to describe the issues of post-commencement
financing and priority as presenting some of the most difficult issues of
the rescue process. It is undeniable that singling out a business for a reha-
bilitation attempt—however achieved—may deal a double blow to the
existing unsecured creditors. In the first place, the latter are temporarily
denied the normal commercial remedies for attempting to recover the
property or money that they are owed. Second, the selected business will
commonly require not only the negative help of a creditors’ moratorium
but also the positive assistance of a further cash injection. Without this, it
is likely that most rehabilitation attempts will fail and thus bring into dis-
repute the rehabilitation process. And it is obvious that the further cash
injection will only materialize if this new credit is prioritized sufficiently
to make repayment probable. Thus, existing unsecured creditors both are
denied their commercial remedies and suffer new creditors (or, at least,
new credit) leapfrogging ahead of them. Added to this, they may have
to stomach the grant to the erstwhile investors in the failed company a
stake in the rescued company. Secured creditors, on the other hand, are
generally protected against this possible watering down of their interest.
The issue of post-insolvency funding exposes not only the often oppos-
ing interests of secured and unsecured creditors62 but also the tension
between pre-existing creditors and those whose ongoing supplies are crit-
ical to the continuation of the business. The obvious necessity of giving
priority to the providers of new cash or liens or to creditors who supply
essential goods appears in the earliest and most restrictive of business
rehabilitation regimes.63 Yet even in the more modern systems, this pri-
ority must be carefully delineated so as to ensure the least possible inter-
ference with the claims of the pre-existing creditors. In France, for exam-
ple, the law is drafted so as to ensure post-insolvency priority only where
the new debts are incurred for the purpose of continuing the enterprise
and only so long as the appointed administrator or the debtor have not
exceeded the power conferred on them by the judgment establishing the
rehabilitation regime.64 On the other hand, these limitations must not be
nance providers a priority over, at least, unsecured creditors. Id. at (¶¶ –).
62 See supra ..
63 See § , Companies Act (South Africa). A fine example in the modern rescue
constructed in a way that leaves those who supply essential goods to the
bankrupt debtor unsure about whether they will be paid. Needless to say,
the monopoly or near monopoly capacity to supply vital products for the
continuation of a business provides fertile opportunities for commercial
exploitation and potential havoc with traditional hierarchies in claims in
insolvency.65
The position of secured credit is central to the question of what priority
may be conferred on creditors who extend credit or deliver goods to
the debtor after the onset of the insolvency. The traditional and still
widely held position is to permit no interference with the control by
a secured creditor over the property that constitutes the security. This
substantial championing of the position of secured credit, however, must
now be seen as under threat by imaginative provisions that go so far as to
enable the uncoupling of the secured creditor from the debtor’s assets that
constitute the security (the collateral). Some jurisdictions even provide a
priority for post-insolvency creditors ahead even of pre-existing secured
creditors, although this must be seen as somewhat unusual.
The point is that the dynamic use of the debtor’s assets, perhaps by
new management, may have a marked effect in increasing the debtor’s
resources to the obvious benefit of all the unsecured creditors and that a
secured creditor should not be permitted to hinder this. There is scope
for allowing the debtor to dispose of property that constitutes security or
collateral but this should not be prejudicial to the creditor with an interest
in the collateral.66
At first blush it may seem surprising that the United Kingdom’s Insol-
vency Act of has taken a lead in this regard. The United Kingdom,
with its floating charge, has often been seen as a jurisdiction that ele-
vates the protection of secured credit high above the claims of unsecured
creditors and investors seeking a continuation of the business in the hope
of its trading out of insolvency. Yet it is perhaps because of the exten-
sive nature of the floating charge, very often drafted to ensure security
for a single creditor (almost invariably the bank) over all the debtor’s
assets, that the legislature felt it was necessary to give other interests pri-
ority over this form of security,67 including granting to an Administrator
65 See Leyland DAF Ltd v. Automotive Products plc [] BCC .
66 See ¶¶ –, Sch. B, UK Insolvency Act .
67 See §§ (), (), UK Insolvency Act , which enable preferential creditors
expenses incurred by Administrators and Administrative Receivers may also be paid out
of floating charge assets, see § ()(c), (), Sch. B, UK Insolvency Act .
68 See ¶¶ –, Sch. B, UK Insolvency Act .
69 See supra ..
70 United States Bankruptcy Code , ¶¶ (c)(), (a)(); see also ¶¶ –
Sch. B, UK Insolvency Act on the power to seek information and ¶¶ – on the
establishment and operation of the creditors’ meeting.
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
Firm: An Empirical Analysis, J. Fin. (); Lynn M. LoPucki & William C. Whit-
ford Corporate Governance in the Bankruptcy Reorganization of Large Publicly Held Cor-
porations U. Pa. L. Rev. , ff. ().
72 See supra ..
73 Id.
74 See infra ...
chapter four
75 The UNCITRAL Legislative Guide would impose on the debtor a duty to disclose
relevant information but would ultimately charge the “insolvency representative” with
gathering such information. Id. at , .
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
... Formulation
The decision of how much external public supervision should be given
to possible rehabilitation plans is a delicate one that should be tailored
to each jurisdiction’s political, cultural, and economic circumstances.
Flexibility is crucial, given the enormous variations in businesses and
industries and the varying challenges faced by particular debtors. On
the other hand, where expertise is limited, more structure and public
supervision may ensure more realistic and sustainable plans. It is rare,
now, for legislation to be over-prescriptive in this regard, given the major
breakthrough achieved by the new wave of rehabilitation regimes in
departing from the earlier generation’s insistence on entitlement to the
benefit of the regime being dependent on establishing the likelihood that
the creditors would all be paid in full.85
Although restrictions on the plan are undesirable, a jurisdiction just
beginning the development of a rehabilitation culture may wish to adopt
rules that describe the key elements of a plan that must be addressed.
Examples would include a clear and complete description of the rights of
each creditor (or class of creditors) under the plan and default provisions
that would go into effect if the debtor defaults in performing under the
plan. There should also be a detailed explanation of the likely results for
creditors if the plan is defeated and the debtor is put into liquidation.
Plans or schemes in use in various countries can be consulted for the key
points to be included.86
86 See, e.g., American Law Institute, International Statement of United States Bank-
ruptcy Law at Appendix G, at (sample plans in large cases in various countries).
For further illustrations of typical U.S. plan provisions see any one of hundreds of
reported cases, e.g. In Re Kreider Bankr. LEXIS ; Bankr. Ct. Dec. . A
Corporate Voluntary Arrangement (“CVA”) often constitutes the plan that concludes a
U.K. Administration, see Roy Goode, Principles of Corporate Insolvency Law (rd
ed., ) –. See also UNCITRAL, Legislative Guide on Insolvency Law –
().
87 United States Bankruptcy Code § .
88 ¶ , Sch. B, UK Insolvency Act .
89 Id., at ¶¶ –.
90 Id., at ¶ .
91 Id., at ¶ .
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
92 Part , §§ –.
93 See § ()(b) & (c) (the old § ), UK Insolvency Act .
94 The current one being that of ; see §§ – for the provisions relating to the
Scheme of Arrangement.
chapter four
receive, so that all the creditors in a class are given the same treatment (or
the same choices). The advantage of the second system is that it permits
different treatment of different creditors while avoiding potential con-
flicts of interest among creditors in a particular class. Different treatment
of creditors with the same legal rights is often desirable. For example,
banks and public bondholders may prefer very different treatment, even
though both are secured or both are unsecured. More often, lenders and
suppliers will have different interests even if they have the same types of
claims from a legal perspective. Suppliers, for example, may more often
be willing to receive less payment in exchange for quick cash, while banks
would prefer a larger percentage of what they are owed, even if paid over
a longer period.
This, indeed, is the French system. The creditors are divided into two
separate classes, apparently not on the basis of preferential and non-
preferential or secured and non-secured but on the basis of suppliers of
goods and services on the one hand and credit establishments on the
other. Two committees are formed and any creditor with five percent
or more of the total debt of his class is entitled to be a member of the
committee. The committees vote separately and the decision is taken by
each committee by a majority of its members, representing at least two-
thirds of the total amount of the debts owed to all the members of the
committee.
In jurisdictions that support classification of claims, rules governing
classification should be clearly stated and designed to avoid abuse. The
primary purpose for classifying claims is to satisfy the requirement to
provide fair and equal treatment of creditors, treating similarly situated
claims in the same manner. Classification also makes it easier to ensure
that special claims such as those of secured and preferential creditors are
treated in accordance with the priority established under the law.
In some cases, classification makes it easier to treat the claims of major
creditors, who may be persuaded to opt to receive a different treatment
from the general class of unsecured creditors, where such treatment is
necessary to render the plan feasible. In such cases, the treatment for
these major creditors is generally on less favorable terms than other,
similarly situated creditors. Finally, classification may be a useful means
of overriding the vote of a class of creditors that votes against the plan
where the class is otherwise treated in a fair and equitable manner.95
95 This override, which has come to be known as a “cramdown” based on its effect,
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
allows the court to conclude that a rejecting class should be compelled to accept the plan
where the class is to be paid in strict accordance with the relative priority of creditor
claims and will receive under the plan a distribution in an amount equal to or greater
than such creditors would receive in a liquidation proceeding. The rationale is that these
creditors cannot claim “foul” if their recovery is at least as good as they would have
received if they had prevailed in having the enterprise liquidated.
96 We are indebted for these insights into Japanese business rescue provision to assis-
tance from Professor Junichi Matsushita of Tokyo University and to the paper filed by Dr.
Shinjiro Takagi at the World Bank’s Global Forum on Insolvency Risk Management Stan-
dards and Strategies for the Next Decade, January –, , Washington D.C. Shinjiro
Takagi, Restructuring in Japan Int’l Insolv. Rev. ().
97 ALI Mexican Statement at –.
chapter four
constitute the security, they should not only be entitled to vote on any
proposal but that voting on a plan should be by separate classes with
a “cramdown” to prevent obstruction of a feasible plan. An insolvency
system must address the electoral structure of forced acceptance of a
plan. One is majority rule by a vote of creditors overall while the other is
acceptance by the majority in each class. Dissenting minorities overall
or by class are required to accept the results of the vote. Nearly all
modern systems have this feature, which solves the “hold out” problem.98
Fairness can be ensured, as in the United States and Mexican examples,
by providing that dissenters must receive equal treatment with approvers.
As indicated above, “cramdown” usually refers to a rule that imposes a
rehabilitation plan on a whole class, a majority of which has voted against
the plan.99 It constitutes an exception to the rule that a plan fails in a
“by class” system unless every class accepts. The United States’ system
is one example with such a rule. Naturally, a cramdown rule requires
strict control over the circumstances in which it can be used. In the
United States, for example, cramdown against a secured creditor requires
payment of the secured creditor’s collateral value plus a market rate of
interest (thereby giving that creditor the equivalent of the “present value”
of its collateral), while cramdown against unsecured creditors requires
that any junior interests, including the equity owners, receive nothing,
so that the creditors effectively own the company.
Voting in separate classes also protects bona fide creditors from the
oppressive behavior of certain creditors who may, for example, wish
to undermine the debtor so as to further other, unrelated interests.100
A related problem is presented by insider creditors. The concept of
the “inside creditor” is well established in insolvency law. Essentially it
connotes a creditor who can be expected to cast his vote as a creditor
contrary to the interests of the creditors as a class, on account of wanting
to favor the interest of a director or shareholder or other insider of the
company. The creditor in question is likely to have a close relationship
with the insider, as a spouse or other relative. The United Kingdom
concerns) of Re Holders Investment Trust Ltd. [] W.L.R. and Re Hellenic &
General Trust Co Ltd. [] W.L.R. .
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
its approval is “not likely to be followed by liquidation, or by the need for further financial
reorganization,” except as provided in the plan itself. U.S.C. § (a)(). Opposing
experts routinely testify on this point in the larger cases.
chapter four
best features of each. Most of the restructuring of the company and the
negotiation of a new capital structure is done outside of court, but then a
rehabilitation plan is presented to an insolvency court for approval, often
already endorsed by creditors. The main benefit of the formal proceeding
is, once again, to force dissenters to acquiesce and thus resolve the hold-
out problem.104
104 See Vanessa Finch, Pre-Packaged Administrations: Bargains In The Shadow Of Insol-
vency or Shadowy Bargains, , J.B.L. –; see also infra ...
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
a plan but stresses the importance of notifying potentially affected creditors. UNCITRAL
Legislative Guide, – (¶¶ –).
106 See infra Chapter .
corporate rehabilitation proceedings
.. Conclusion
to seek this help early might have the effect of pushing some debtors into
rehabilitation regimes too soon, with possible adverse consequences for
existing creditors.
The issue here is linked with that of ease of access. In general, the more
complicated and expensive the procedure for access, the more reluctant a
debtor is to seek the help of the rehabilitation regime, especially at a time
when, to the debtor, recovery would seem probable. This would argue
for the United States’ system of automatic entry, but European coun-
tries and countries that were formerly British colonies have a long his-
tory of resistance to automatic entry to a regime that bars creditors—
however temporarily—from their enforcement rights. There are, it must
be recognized, certain cultural sensitivities that have to be considered.
Throughout Europe, even where practice suggests that protection under
a rehabilitation regime is readily granted, court involvement is still, gen-
erally, insisted upon. Only in the United Kingdom have recent proposals
been made for providing automatic access into a protective rehabilitation
regime without court sanction, although even there this reform has been
hedged in with certain significant qualifications.107
The rehabilitation culture in Europe is less well-developed than it is
in the United States. In general, the structure of rehabilitation regimes
in Europe is comprehensive, but it would be fair to add that there is little
participation by unsecured creditors and stockholders in the process. The
general assumption is that such interests do not have much to gain from
the rehabilitation process and that to attempt to do so is a waste of time
and money.108
In the United Kingdom, it has been argued that the ubiquity of the
floating charge and administrative receivership, with its propensity for
overall control of the insolvent debtor, has been a major disincentive to
the active participation of unsecured creditors and stockholders. Some
contend that this is a major cause of the lack of confidence that prevails
in the business rehabilitation process. They say that the receivership sys-
tem negates the many enterprising features in the rehabilitation processes
of the United Kingdom and other western European countries, including
such features as the establishment of creditors’ committees, the require-
ment of sharing full information as to the conduct of the rehabilitation
process, and so on. The predominant legal and commercial culture is of
considerable significance in the operation of the rehabilitation regime.
109 Although it should be noted that the appointment of a rescue officer to the existing
.. Introduction
1 For instructive and entertaining descriptions of the workout process, see Michael
Mortitz & Barrett Seaman, Going for Broke: The Chrysler Story (); Tom Wolfe,
A Man in Full, Chapter ().
chapter five
2 See generally, United States Securities And Exchange Commission, Report on the
Study and Investigation of the Work, Activities, Personnel, and Functions of Protective
and Reorganization Committees ().
3 See e.g., Statement of Principles for a Global Approach to Multi Creditor Workouts,
An informal rescue arises within the concept of business rescue and pre-
supposes a debtor either in or near serious default vis-à-vis its creditors. It
is classed as informal because it is contemplated as being outside the legal
institutions of insolvency, in particular the business rescue regime (which
is more than likely to have been created by statute). The rescue may well
seek to alter the rights of some or all of the creditors vis-à-vis the debtor
in order to enable the latter to continue or renew trading with either no
debt or a smaller burden of debt than it had before rescue. In principle,
the alteration of these rights requires the consent of each creditor and
therefore presupposes unanimous agreement among all the creditors to
the informal rescue. In fact, as we shall see, in the large scale rescue in
which a substantial part of the claims against the debtor is carried by
chapter five
6 See the discussions on the London Approach and Pre-packaged Bankruptcy, infra
.., ...
chapter five
would also argue, certainly in the case of large-scale debtors but also more
widely, in favor of as wide representation as possible of all groups that
have an interest in the debtor’s business.
A successful reorganization also presupposes that one or more of
those who are directly interested in the debtor’s business believe that
some form of rescue of the debtor is both possible and desirable. It is
possible, although highly unusual, that all those who are interested in
the debtor’s business—employees, other senior creditors, other junior
creditors, management, investors, possibly one or more public interests
with legally enforceable powers vis-à-vis the debtor such as a relevant
government department, the debtor itself—are in agreement as to the
way forward for the debtor. Such might be described as a successful
informal workout and, to the extent agreed, restructuring of the debtor.
Any court involvement would be simply to provide an official imprimatur
for the parties’ agreement.
A further significant feature of an informal rescue is the absence of a
moratorium on all claims and enforcement processes against the debtor;
hence, the need for strong initial support for the informal process. It
follows that an informal process is almost invariably restricted to cases
where either: () there is substantial agreement among all the creditors
as to the way forward for the debtor; or () the senior creditors have the
will to seek agreement for a plan for the debtor’s future and they carry
the weight or authority to restrain other creditors from taking steps that
might lead to the liquidation of the debtor or are able to provide the
financing that will permit smaller creditors to be satisfied.
There can be little doubt that early action in the form of consultation
between a debtor that is insolvent, or nearing insolvency, and major
creditors substantially increases the chances of a successful informal
outcome for all who have an interest in the debtor’s business. A recent
development in the United Kingdom has been the increasing role for
insolvency practitioners in acting as monitors and advisers in the debtor’s
business while the latter is a going concern, as opposed to carrying out
what has so often been the provision of last rites and a decent burial for
a business beyond rescue for failing to seek help early enough.
The fact that this has emerged especially in the United Kingdom may
be connected with two important initiatives in the radical overhaul of
informal workouts and restructuring
goal, that is, to achieve a solution that is supported by creditors, shareholders and
management.” (Chris Wai Kit Lee, op. cit. p. ).
chapter five
creditors are the most powerful interests in the debtor’s business, some
jurisdictions give powerful voice to the public interest10 and others grant
blocking powers to organized labor.11 Furthermore, it is possible that
senior creditors themselves may favor a rescue. In that case the agreement
of, or at least some compromise with, the most junior interests, such
as management and investors, may need to be sought. However weak
a hand the latter might have, they are quite likely to have the potential
of wrecking a rescue attempt by carrying out a threat to put the business
into liquidation.
10 This sentiment can be seen, for example, expressed by Robert Zafft (Senior Corpo-
rate Governance Specialist, OECD) and Lampros Vassiliou, in their presentation Policy
Implications from the Second Forum on Asian Insolvency Reform, to the Second Forum of
the OECD’s regional overview on the form and substance of Asian Insolvency Reform,
December , at (“While cutting up and selling off pieces of the business might
fully satisfy secured creditors’ claims, it is wasteful to the economy—and unfair to unse-
cured creditors, shareholders and employees—to do so where the claims of creditors can
be satisfied in some other manner.”), available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd///
.pdf.
11 The best example may be France, although it should be added that the blocking
... Receivership13
Despite the growing interest in multilateral approaches, the grand old
lady of private workout and restructuring is a decidedly unilateral insti-
tution, namely Receivership, discussed earlier. It was developed by the
Common Law in England and Wales and exported to several countries
in the period of the British Empire. Although this institution may now
be—at least in the United Kingdom—in serious decline,14 its conception
and efficacy is not without interest in the present discussion.
15 Receivership evolved out of the principles of the English Common Law. Scotland,
for example, which has a somewhat different legal system from England and Wales, only
received the institution of receivership by statute, as recently as with the passing of
the Companies (Floating Charges and Receivers) (Scotland) Act.
16 This analysis is couched in the past tense, because, apart from a few very specialised
lates into the comment that “[a] bank which frustrates an orderly work-
out for a company may find that other banks are less likely to be construc-
tive next time round when their roles are reversed.”19 It is also pointed out
that with a now active distressed corporate debt market, dissenting finan-
cial institutions can sell their debt and not incur the opprobrium of the
other banks by breaking ranks.20
The procedure of the London Approach is, thus, essentially the agree-
ment by all banks for voluntary restraint for a period to enable the debtor
to seek to work out its difficulties. This voluntary procedure owes much
to the strong support (and therefore authority) of the Bank of England,
which in the early years of the London Approach took an active role in
some of the major workouts. It is now content to leave the workout to
the lending banks concerned. It cannot be denied that the success of the
London Approach owes a great deal to the weighty authority of the Bank
of England although there are clearly other factors that pull banks and
other financial institutions into line in support of a multi-bank workout
of a large corporation.21
The success of the London Approach—and quite possibly of the pre-
packaged insolvency approach discussed in the next section—may also
in a deeper and more indirect way owe much to the approach to corpo-
rate and commercial activity in the common law world, in particular the
United Kingdom and North America. These approaches may be related to
a growing acceptance in the common law world of an informal and dereg-
ulated environment as being best for business and of the corporation as
an appropriate vehicle for purely private commercial arrangements.
In civil law countries, however—and perhaps here Germany is a sound
example—the corporation may be perceived to a greater extent as a pub-
lic institution. This may, in turn, suggest a more formal commercial and
financial environment that is perhaps less ready to embrace informality
in the approach to workouts and reconstructions.
19 P. Kent, The London Approach () Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin ,
; see also John Armour and Simon Deakin, Norms in Private Insolvency Procedure:
The “London Approach” to the Resolution of Financial Distress (ESRC Centre for Busi-
ness Research, Univ. of Cambridge Working Paper No , ), pp. –, and at
http://www.cbr.cam.ac.uk/pdf/wp.pdf.
20 Belcher, Ibid.
21 Armour & Deakin, op. cit.
informal workouts and restructuring
22 Douglas W. Arner, Charles D. Booth, Paul Lejot & Berry F. Hsu, Property Rights,
Collateral, Creditor Rights and Insolvency in East Asia, Tex. Int’l L.J. , ().
23 See ADB Office of the General Counsel, Insolvency Law Reforms in the Asian and
Pacific Region, Report of the Office of the General Counsel on TA -Reg: Insolvency
Law Reforms, Law and Policy Reform at the ADB , – (). South Korea was the
one jurisdiction that the study noted as an exception to this observation. Id.
chapter five
.. Conclusion
relies on the threat of formal procedures that, given the substantial sup-
port for the plan, are more than likely to defeat the stubborn holdout.
The success of these procedures will rest in large part on whether
their supporting backgrounds—in one case the authority of the partic-
ular agency, in the other the formal procedures—are in place. Another
possibility is to hope that through the establishment of such informal
processes, the opportunity would arise to strengthen the authority of the
agency chosen to be responsible for the implementation of the process.
The fiscal regime may be influential in underpinning or undermining a
particular process. If a jurisdiction offers fiscal advantages as an incentive
to encourage the employment of particular procedures, they may have a
better opportunity to succeed.
Finally, it may be of some interest to consider very briefly the matter
of informal workout procedures for small- and medium-sized debtors.
This has not been addressed in the body of this chapter because it would
seem that the discussion in the previous chapter that is concerned with
formal procedures provides a perfectly good example of what is, in
effect, an informal regime for small company debtors. Recent reforms to
the United Kingdom’s Corporate Voluntary Arrangement24 enable this
regime to be invoked by the debtor itself with a minimum of formality
thus underlining an observation made in this chapter, namely that formal
and informal workout procedures are not now—if they ever were—
mutually exclusive.
.. Introduction
2 Perhaps the most famous have been the Maxwell Companies in the United King-
4 This opposition or tension was one reason the Chinese Bankruptcy Law took
years to prepare.
5 The UK dispensation in this regard is especially interesting, see infra ...
6 See infra ..
7 See infra ...
employee rights in insolvency
8 The Cork Report (so named after the chair of the review committee responsible for
12 Roy Goode, Principles of Corporate Insolvency Law (d ed., ), p. .
13 Wang Huaiyu, An International Comparison of Insolvency Laws, (OECD Fifth
Forum for Asian Insolvency Reform, (– April ), http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/
//.pdf.
14 “It is very important for enterprises to maintain their banking relationships as a
source of financing. But employees are necessary to actually run an enterprise.” (Id. p. ).
15 Id. p. .
employee rights in insolvency
16 Such an approach usually requires a strong Social Security System. In Germany, for
Sarra survey makes it apparent that a wide variation in the nature and
scope of the employee priority exists from country to country. The report
of the survey contains a series of charts and country summaries that set
forth these variations in detail. Claims by employees may stretch from
unpaid wages or salary, to damages for unfair dismissal or termination
of employment without cause or requisite notice, to unclaimed benefits
such as holiday pay or maternity leave. And even within each of these cat-
egories there are further variations—for example, caps as to the amount
or as to the period of employment for which a priority is granted.18 It
is also the case that in some of these countries, other provisions outside
the insolvency system ensure that employees recover some, or even all,
of salary or wage arrears.
Third, employee preferential claims generally cede priority to the
claims of secured creditors, where the security is fixed or immovable.
As we have seen above, only five countries—Brazil, Chile, Columbia,
Indonesia, and Malaysia—resist this dominant position absolutely, and
four more—the Czech Republic, France,19 Russia, and Mexico—do so
under certain conditions. This picture does, however, change consider-
ably where the security is not fixed or immovable but consists of the tan-
gible and intangible assets that the debtor uses, acquires, consumes, and
disposes of in the course of the operation of the business. This type of
security is described in the OECD Report discussed above as a “floating
security.” In further countries—actually eight if one treats England,
Scotland, and Wales as the single country of Great Britain—employee
creditors have priority over secured creditors, whose claim is protected
by a floating, as opposed to a fixed, security.
International and regional organizations have given much thought to
the issue of the claims by employees in the event of their employer’s insol-
vency. The International Labour Organization adopted the Protection of
Wages Convention in , Article of which provides that:
In the event of the bankruptcy or judicial liquidation of an undertaking,
the workers employed therein shall be treated as privileged creditors either
as regards wages due to them for service rendered during such a period
prior to the bankruptcy or judicial liquidation as may be prescribed by
18 Id. at –.
19 France appears in the Annex to Wang Huaiyu, An International Comparison of Insol-
vency Laws, as conferring priority, subject to certain conditions, to employee creditors
over secured creditor claims, but is not identified as such in the summary quoted above
(see supra note ).
employee rights in insolvency
The European Union has not addressed the issue of priority for employee
claims against an insolvent employer but it has addressed the issue of
an employee payment guarantee. It issued a Directive in ,20 the first
preamble of which provided as follows: “Whereas it is necessary to pro-
vide for the protection of employees in the event of the insolvency of
their employer, in particular in order to guarantee payment of their out-
standing claims, while taking account of the need for balanced economic
and social development in the Community; . . . .” Under Article . of this
Directive, member states of the European Union were required to estab-
lish a guarantee institution that would pay employees any outstanding
contractual claims they have against their employer that would not be
paid on account of the employer’s insolvency. Provision was made for
member states to limit the extent of the guarantee institution’s liabil-
ity. Furthermore, under this Directive, member states were required to
ensure that where prior to insolvency the employer had failed in its duty
to make compulsory contributions on the employees’ behalf to insur-
ance institutions under national statutory social security schemes, the
employees’ benefit entitlement was not to be adversely affected. The point
is made in this provision of the Directive that a deduction at source of
income will have been made by the employer from the employees’ salary
or wages to fund the employees’ social security contributions.21
The Directive was amended in 22 essentially to take account
of insolvency developments within the European Union. This amending
Directive makes this clear in the following preamble:
In order to ensure legal certainty for employees in the event of insolvency
of undertakings pursuing their activities in a number of Member States,
and to strengthen workers’ rights in line with the established case law
of the Court of Justice, provisions should be introduced which expressly
state which institution is responsible for meeting pay claims in these
cases and establishes as the aim of cooperation between the competent
administrative authorities of the Member States the early settlement of
employees’ outstanding claims. Furthermore it is necessary to ensure that
Member States relating to the protection of employees in the event of the insolvency of
their employer (//EEC).
21 Article , Directive //EEC.
22 Directive //EC of the European Parliament and of the Council, September
.
chapter six
23 Article a–d.
24 See §§ –, Employment Rights Act .
25 See § ()(a), Employment Rights Act .
26 The UK removed the preferential creditor status of tax and related state claimants;
27 Annex C, .–., World Bank’s Principles and Guidelines for Effective Insolvency
claims against the bankrupt estate is common but, given the competition
for funds out of this estate and the strong claims of secured creditors,
such status will rarely be the complete solution.
The result has been adoption of the two-pronged approach of prefer-
ential creditor status and a state-administered guarantee fund to cover
a reasonable part of the loss suffered by employees. While the guaran-
tee fund is not as widespread as preferential creditor status, it is a legal
requirement in all member states of the European Union and is also
a feature of the legal systems of Australia and Japan. The introduction
of such an institution is under active consideration in both China and
India.
... Pensions
The recovery of contractual entitlement to current wages and benefits
is not the only or even necessarily the major concern of employees faced
with a bankrupt employer. Many loyal, longstanding employees may have
a substantial proportion of their overall income—perhaps between
percent and percent—invested in a retirement pension and in many
cases this pension investment will have been with the bankrupt employer.
In many instances the decline in the employer’s financial health cou-
pled with the control that the employer is able to exercise over the man-
agement of the pension fund has led to the pension being inadequately
funded. In the worst cases, the employer has used the pension fund in a
desperate attempt to shore up the business. The control by the employer
over the pension fund, effected by the appointment of directors of the
employer corporation as trustees of the pension fund, and the failure of
the latter to act as independent trustees have enabled this gross conflict
of interest and duty.
A lack of funding generally creates a claim against the insolvent com-
pany but the priority given to that claim varies considerably. Professor
Sarra has summarized the results of her survey in this regard:
Numerous jurisdictions of the studied treat pension related claims on
the same basis as wage claims in terms of priority or preference. They have
created a statutory priority for pension claims, including claims for failure
to make remittances to a pension or superannuation fund and for general
underfunding of the pension promise.. . .
In contrast, other jurisdictions treat such claims as unsecured claims, even
where wage claims are given a preference. However, these jurisdictions
need to be assessed on the basis of whether or not employer-sponsored
employee rights in insolvency
This problem has been addressed in two other ways: legislation to try to
ensure independence in the administration of pension funds and invest-
ment guarantee institutions established by the state to replace lost funds.
As an illustration of the first approach, the United Kingdom moved
swiftly in the wake of the Maxwell scandal, establishing a committee of
enquiry29 and acting on its report. In , the United Kingdom legisla-
ture enacted the Pensions Act, which has since been replaced by the Pen-
sions Act . This provides for a Pensions Regulator with wide powers
to oversee the administration of pension funds, including provision for
the appointment of independent trustees and for the removal or suspen-
sion trustees. Among its many far-ranging provisions, the Pensions Act
has what was described in its predecessor Act as a whistleblowing
section:30
Duty to report breaches of the law
28 See Sarra, supra note . Professor Sarra points out that general social insurance, as
Committee was chaired by Professor Sir Roy Goode and the report was published in
September .
30 Section of the UK Pensions Act .
chapter six
32 But see Henry Hu and Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Abolition of the Corporate Duty to
34 U.S.C. § –.
35 C Termination of Employment Convention, ; for the text, see http://www
.ilo.org/ilolex/english/convdisp.htm.
36 Council Directive //EC of July ; for the text, see http://eur-lex.europa
38 See s. , UK Trade Union and Labour Relations (Consolidation) Act .
39 See Sarra, op. cit. p. .
chapter six
40 See Nina Baecklund & Mathias Winge, Wage Guarantee in Reconstructuring [sic]
45 Article ..
chapter seven
.. Overview
Any law—be it the best one—is of little use unless there are personnel
who are willing and capable to transform the written rules into reality and
daily practice.1 If the current authors were forced to choose, we would
opt for bad law and good personnel over good law and bad personnel.
Any discrepancy between the law on the books and the law in action
leads inevitably to some kind of implementation gap2 that need not
necessarily cause inefficiency but that in any case distorts to a higher or
lesser degree the original intentions of the law. In the field of insolvency
there are two actors whose integrity and expertise are central to the
functioning of the insolvency system: judges and administrators. While
lawyers, accountants, and other professionals are also important, these
two actors perform the core tasks. Thus learning about the qualities of
these actors is almost always more important to an understanding of an
insolvency system than knowledge of its legal rules and procedures.3 The
key elements are their backgrounds—educational and practical—their
expertise, and their roles in the system. Closely related is knowledge
of the procedural systems in a given jurisdiction, systems that likely
operate in insolvency among many other aspects of that country’s legal
institutions. We do not attempt a discussion of procedures in that broader
sense.
1 See Christoph Paulus, Germany: Lessons to Learn from the Implementation of a New
implementation gap are presented by Terence Halliday, Closing the Implementation Gap:
Why Good Laws Fail and We Can Help Them Succeed, available at: http://www.worldbank
.org / WBSITE / EXTERNAL / TOPICS / LAWANDJUSTICE / GILD / ,contentMDK:
~ pagePK:~piPK:~theSitePK:,.html.
3 Especially in this area it is important to view debt collection and enforcement of
security outside of insolvency as part of the overall “insolvency” system. See supra ..
chapter seven
.. Judiciary
5 See, e.g., Elizabeth Warren, Bankruptcy Policy, U. Chi. L. Rev. ();
Douglas G. Baird, Loss Distribution, Forum Shopping, and Bankruptcy: A Reply to Warren,
U. Chi. L. Rev. ().
judicial and administrative institutions
.. Administrators
not mutually exclusive and are exercised with varying emphasis. One is
to develop and guarantee a certain level of constant high qualification,
trustworthiness, and professional ethos among the administrators (see
Section . below). Another complementary device is to make it finan-
cially attractive to follow the path of the statutory provisions (see Section
. below).
A few jurisdictions from various backgrounds have been selected
for the demonstration of the diversity with which these issues may be
resolved in legislation (see Section . below). Needless to say that there
is no abstract generalization intended (nor possible) as to which solution
might be more preferable than the other. But it is noteworthy that all
laws take at least some pain to make sure that the administrator displays
special qualifications that make him suitable for this kind of fiduciary
position between the debtor and the creditors and that justify special
rules about its remuneration.
It should also be noted that jurisdictions vary as to the professional
training usually expected of an administrator.7 In the majority of juris-
dictions, lawyers perform this function, but in a good number of juris-
dictions (mostly common law countries) accountants are typically em-
ployed. In yet a third group of countries, the function is performed by
public officials. The choice likely depends upon a mix of highest possible
qualification, local tradition, controllability, and trustworthiness. Also to
be considered is whether an administrator should be in every case an
individual or whether a legal entity should be admissible for this posi-
tion as well.
selection to the judge alone without giving any indications as to necessary qualifications.
judicial and administrative institutions
true, at least, for all those jurisdictions that entrust the administrator
with more power than just being a kind of executing arm of the court
or any other decisionmaker. It is a truism not only in times of economic
difficulties that insolvencies have an enormous impact on the overall
(macro) economy. The administration of these cases requires so much
economic, legal, organizational, and, quite often, psychological skills that
most jurisdictions put some effort into establishing a selection system
that attempts to ensure that only highly qualified persons in fact become
administrators.
The most common baseline requirements are education and a profes-
sional qualification or business experience. As discussed elsewhere, juris-
dictions are divided between using lawyers or accountants as administra-
tors. Generally, either type of professional must have satisfied the relevant
professional requirements, which usually include the necessary educa-
tion. However, it is possible for business people to serve as well. Where
that is true, it is necessary to state education and experience requirements
for them.
The following examples from a few different jurisdictions demonstrate
that the selection, supervision and remuneration of administrators can be
done in quite a number of ways. To begin with the latter, remuneration
might be calculated either on a time basis or on a value basis whereby
the latter is capable of many specifications. Not least important is the
identity of the person who decides about the remuneration (court or
creditors or a supervising body). Depending on the choice, incentives for
efficiency can be given: the time-based remuneration model encourages
the administrator to really engage in the affairs rather than just ticking off
the various tasks. On the other side, the danger with this approach is that
proceedings might be dragged on endlessly,9 a problem that is apparently
non-existent in Switzerland but is complained of, however, in numerous
other countries. In case of a value-based remuneration, the administrator
is induced to increase the estate to the greatest extent possible that, in
turn, is for the benefit of the common creditors. The disadvantage thereby
is the administrator’s potential concentration on value increasing efforts
and, thus, a lesser interest in other topics in the proceeding.
9 As just one example out of many possible, Colombia has developed such a sys-
tem despite contradicting legal rules in its Reorganization Law of December ,
.
chapter seven
sue the administrator who generally is personally liable for his adminis-
tration if they think that something has been done less efficiently than
it could or should have been done.14 Some jurisdictions, however, have,
apart from the two control mechanisms described so far, a third one: a
supervising authority independent from the insolvency courts and the
creditors in the given case.15
All these measures serve the purpose of safeguarding the best possible
outcome in each insolvency case and, at the same time, of strengthening
the general public’s confidence in the administrators’ qualification. It is
hard to overemphasize this task: Whereas neither commercial law nor
the overall economy usually demand any specific personal abilities or
particular qualifications from general business persons—as long as these
persons are acting successfully—the pattern changes when the enterprise
gets into financial difficulties and begins to threaten the credit given by
the creditors. If and when this is the case and an insolvency proceeding
is to be opened, there exists proof of a certain failure that is seen in most
jurisdictions as a justification for a change of the requirements. From
now on, the interests of the creditors need to be taken into stronger
(sometimes even exclusive) consideration.16
It is for this reason that the general scheme of activity changes once an
insolvency proceeding has been opened. The most evident indication of
this change is the appointment of the administrator who is now put in
charge over the debtor’s estate. This is true also in most jurisdictions that
provide for the possibility of a debtor in possession (DIP)—that is, the
managing person is left in charge despite the opening of the insolvency
proceeding; they pay tribute to the new circumstances by establishing
a surveillance institution such as a trustee or examiner who supervises
all or certain acts and transactions (to be) done by the DIP.17 In light
14 Of course, a system that permits such suits too liberally will find that few are willing
to serve as administrators or that they demand very high fees.
15 For an overview of jurisdictions that have established a formal system of supervi-
Duty to Creditors, Colum. L. Rev. () (criticizing this trend).
17 See IMF, Orderly & Effective Insolvency Procedures, , p. et seq., and World
Bank, Revised Principles for Insolvency and Creditor Rights Systems (Draft ), Prin-
ciple C ., Legislative Guide on Insolvency Law (); available at: http://www
.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/insolven/–_Ebook.pdf. As practical examples,
see, e.g., § of the Vietnamese Bankruptcy Law (); § f. German Insolvency
Ordinance.
chapter seven
... Australia
The Corporations Act (Cth) provides rules in Sections et seq.,
et seq., , and et seq. as to how to become an administrator.
These rules are specified by the Policy Statement of the Australian
Securities & Investments Commission (ASIC) from Sept. , .18
Accordingly, to become a “registered liquidator” a natural person resid-
ing in Australia must fulfill the following criteria: (s)he must either be
a member of The Institute of Chartered Accountants in Australia (or
another prescribed body) or hold a university degree (or diploma of
an equivalent institution) that certifies that the candidate has attended
three years of study in accountancy and two years in commercial law
or can provide other qualifications equivalent to the two criteria men-
tioned before; furthermore, the candidate must have experience with the
winding up of companies; and, finally, the ASIC must be satisfied that
the applicant is capable of performing the duties and is otherwise fit and
proper.
With respect to the appointment for a given insolvency case, Sections
C and D establish standards that disqualify the respective person—
namely having certain connections with the debtor or being themselves
the subject of an administration proceeding. Once appointed, the admin-
istrator has to present to the creditors prior to the first meeting a state-
ment of independence; this is supposed to be a safeguard against dispro-
portionate friendliness towards the debtor.
Section E rules that the administrator’s remuneration shall be
determined by the debtor’s creditors or by the court—in both cases based
on the calculation offered by the administrator. The administrators are
regulated and supervised by the ASIC.
... Canada
Pursuant to Section of the Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act (), the
Superintendent of Bankruptcy—a governmental authority—is in charge
of licensing and supervising administrators. The requirements for receiv-
ing a license differ depending on whether an individual or a corporation
applies. The details of the prerequisites are set down in a directive19 that
has been issued by the Superintendent on the basis of Section ()(d)
of the Act. Accordingly, an individual needs either a university degree,20
a minimum of five years relevant work experience, or a relevant pro-
fessional designation. Furthermore, the applicant must have completed
the three-year National Insolvency Qualification Program by passing the
final National Insolvency Examination successfully. Finally, the appli-
cant must be of good reputation and character and he is supposed to
be suitable—that is, he must demonstrate in an oral exam, apart from
his skills and abilities, his ethical standards and so on.21 If a corporation
applies for a license, it is supposed to prove inter alia, its solvency and the
majority of its directors and officeholders must hold a license as individ-
uals.22
Section et seq. of Appendix A of the Directive reserves investiga-
tion rights to the Superintendent in that he shall verify (and guarantee)
that the licensed administrator meets at any time the requirements and
qualifications necessary for obtaining a license.
For the specific case, the administrator has to be neutral towards
the debtor and the secured creditors,23 and in exercising his duties he
shall “. . . comply with such code of ethics respecting the conduct of
trustees. . . . ”24 He may be replaced by the creditors at any time pursuant
to Section . Creditors also decide the administrator’s remuneration.25
... Finland
Finland has no insolvency licensing system. Any member of the Finnish
Bar Association may be chosen for a specific case to become adminis-
19 Directive No. , Trustee Licensing, issued on March , , available at: http://
www.strategis.ic. gc.ca/epic/internet/inbsf-osb.nsf/en/bre.html.
20 Not necessarily a degree in law.
21 See supra n. , §§ –.
22 See supra n. , §§ – for details.
23 §§ . and . of the Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act ().
24 See id., § ..
25 See id., § .
chapter seven
has to deal” or of the time he has spent with the case. The determination
of which of these alternatives is to be chosen in a specific case is left to
the creditors or if they fail to do so, to the court.
32 For the details, see Code of Federal Regulation Part . § .(b) makes as a
condition, for example, that the candidate possesses “integrity and good moral character,”
“be courteous and accessible to all parties with reasonable inquiries,” “be a member of
good standing of the bar of the highest court,” or be a certified public accountant, holding
a certain bachelor’s degree, and so on.
33 See §§ and of the Bankruptcy Code.
34 See § (a) of the Bankruptcy Code.
35 See § of the Bankruptcy Code.
judicial and administrative institutions
... Slovakia
In its newly enacted Insolvency Trustees Act (), Slovakia sets out
the pre-conditions that a person (or legal entity) must fulfill in order to
get into the administrator pool.36 Thus, a prospective administrator—
not necessarily a lawyer—must participate in a professional training
and learning program, pass a professional exam, and register with the
authorities. Furthermore, it is requested that this person has unrestricted
legal capacity and a good reputation. The pool of administrators stands
under the supervision of the Ministry of Justice, which is given broad
powers, including the right to impose fines or even remove a person
from the administrators’ registry. For an individual case, the court selects
“randomly;”37 the creditors are given the opportunity, however, to replace
this randomly selected administrator by another administrator through
a vote in the first creditors’ meeting.
... China
The new Chinese Insolvency Statute from provides in Section
the selection and appointment process of the administrator. Accordingly,
pursuant to Paragraph , it is up to the Supreme Court to determine the
method for selection and remuneration of an administrator. In contrast,
Paragraph states that the insolvency court (peoples’ court) appoints
the administrator in the individual case. However, if the creditors are
of the opinion that this particular administrator does not cope—legally
and/or factually—with the tasks of this position the creditors’ assembly
can request an exchange.
A similar mechanism applies with respect to remuneration: it is the
peoples’ court that determines the amount. But the creditors’ assembly is
given the right to express its different view to this court.
36 Like the present Slovakian law (but unlike its predecessor rules), the Estonian one
has quite elaborate rules about the administrators’ qualification, selection, and remuner-
ation in§ ff. of the Bankruptcy Act .
37 It should be noted that in some small countries, the neutrality requirement for
an administrator sometimes poses problems because there are just not enough peo-
ple who would not know each other. Random selection could be an escape from this
trap.
chapter seven
38 See the General Commentary to the Principles of European Insolvency Law, et seq.
(W. McBryde, A. Flessner, & S. Kortmann, eds., ). See also UNCITRAL, Legislative
Guide on Insolvency Law – (¶¶ –) ().
39 Note that the US law, for example, requires as a general attitude “being courteous,”
see supra n. ; the new Brazilian Insolvency Law from states in art. that “the
administrator shall be a reputable professional, preferably a lawyer, economist, business
manager or accountant . . ..” Similarly, the UNCITRAL Legislative Guide states that it
“may be desirable for the insolvency representative to possess certain personal qualities,
such as integrity, impartiality, independence and good management skills.” UNCITRAL,
Legislative Guide on Insolvency Law – (¶ )().
judicial and administrative institutions
the administration under various aspects. See chapter , § of the Bankruptcy Act.
42 With respect of such lists, one has to distinguish between what might be called
“closed lists”—that is, where the circle of candidates remains practically unchanged—and
“open lists.” Generally speaking, the latter appear to be more acceptable.
43 Even though Finland and Slovakia are aligned on this point, the division line is most
likely not that between common law and continental law. It might rather have to do with
a different educational tradition: in England (and its “derivatives”) the strong power of
the Inns of Court and on the Continent the judge as the all-knowing jurist.
44 As is the case, for example, according to art. of the Bankruptcy and Insolvency
but for a certain period of time (for example, three years as is the case in
the United Kingdom). However, such a system requires certain adminis-
trative costs that might appear to be superfluous because a person who
falls behind the standard of professional administering will no longer be
appointed as administrator in individual cases. This observation leads to
the insight that the above-mentioned bifurcation continues to exist with
respect to the control of the competence of a once-admitted administra-
tor. It can be exercised, too, on two levels: first, on a general level—that
is, the person in question becomes expelled from the pool of adminis-
trators; or, second, on an individual level—that is, he will no longer be
entrusted with the administration of individual cases.45 The latter is prob-
ably cheaper and the former more thorough in that it erases even the pos-
sibility of collusive actions between a judge and an unsuitable adminis-
trator.
45 It is noteworthy in this context that the German Constitutional Court has decided
that a once frequently appointed administrator has no claim whatsoever that he will be
re-appointed in the future as well, see Decision from May , , available at http://
www.bundesverfassungsgericht.de/entscheidungen/rs_bvr.html.
46 See supra ..
judicial and administrative institutions
47 Explicitly regulated, for example, in art. , par. of the Spanish Ley Concursal
to ensure that information available to the firm in a certain capacity is not conveyed to
other parts of the firm. It is sometimes extended to the idea that one part of the firm is
acting independently so as not to be influenced by the interests of the rest of the firm.
49 The expression “Chinese walls” is meant to express the idea of separation by effective
50 One might call this control mechanism “internal control” in that it applies to the
53 For a description of the history, task, and success of this institution, see H.G. Kant-
vency Regime for Czech Corporate Debtors and Their Creditors, Butterworth J. Intl.
Banking Fin. L. () (discussing the law in force until June , ).
chapter seven
55 See additionally, for example, art. of the Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act
of Barbados.
56 See, e.g., the Chinese Bankruptcy Statute, § par. . The Swiss example of a public
to base this calculation on the time spent. Even though this is a fairly
objective standard, it has its flaws60 in that it might give an incentive for
unnecessary prolongation of the proceeding. The alternative is to take the
value of the estate as the basis for calculation. But here, a further distinc-
tion can be made: if the relevant value is that of the estate at the beginning
of the proceeding, later efforts to increase the estate’s value through, for
example, the use of avoidance powers might be neglected. In contrast, if
the relevant value is the estate as it is to be distributed to the creditors,
then previous efforts to clarify which assets do and do not belong to it
might be neglected. The examples show that there is, generally speak-
ing, no “one size fits all” answer. Under such circumstances, it might be
worthwhile to consider the use of a fixed amount to which can be added
or from which can be deducted certain amounts depending on the par-
ticular case at hand. On the other hand, calculations based on the size of
the dividends to creditors are also found in a number of systems.
Many systems require periodic reports and accounts from the adminis-
trator as an insolvency case proceeds.61
CROSS-BORDER CONSIDERATIONS
.. Overview
As a consequence of the general rule that any state has the power to
enact laws that are applicable and enforceable only on its own territory,
problems necessarily arise when and if a debtor’s insolvency stretches
beyond the borders of a state. This is primarily the case when the debtor
has assets in more than one jurisdiction. In such a case, the creditors will
be interested in including assets from the other jurisdiction in “their”
proceeding; the liquidation of these additional assets might increase the
dividend. Also in case of an envisaged rescue of the debtor, the inclusion
of assets located abroad might be essential for success or failure of the
attempt. On the other hand, creditors in the other jurisdiction might have
entered into contractual relationships with the debtor in reliance upon
the location of assets in “their” jurisdiction. The question then arises
as to whether or not this reliance on assets “at hand” deserves, or even
needs, protection—a question that is all the more valid if and when these
creditors are employees of the debtor. But reliance aside, some would
question whether it can ever be legitimate that the insolvency law of
one jurisdiction reaches out to assets positioned in another jurisdiction.
As desirable as this result might be economically, can it be reconciled
with the fundamentals of national sovereignty? On the other hand, does
this very doctrine necessitate (at least) the formal recognition of the
foreign proceeding? These are some of the questions that mark the initial
problems of international insolvency law. Needless to say, innumerable
further problems exist in this area. However, this chapter confines itself
to describing and commenting upon only the more fundamental ones—
those that have formed the starting point for national legislation.
Because of ever-growing multinational trade and investment, every
jurisdiction—even smaller ones1—must consider regulating not only
1 See, for example, Uganda, that has in its draft Insolvency Bill provisions dealing
Because this subject is so new, this discussion requires more theory and
analysis than areas that are well-developed in all national legislation. As a
matter of fact, any cross-border related insolvency legislation has to take
into account a multiplicity of considerations resulting from, for example,
2 See, for example, Friedrich Meili, Die geschichtliche Entwicklung des internationalen
Konkursrechtes, Festschrift v. Bar (Orell Füssli ); Hans Hanisch, Bemerkungen zur
Geschichte des Internationalen Insolvenzrechts in Festschrift für Franz Merz, et seq.
(W. Gerhardt et al. eds., RWS-Verlag ); Josef Kohler, Lehrbuch des Konkursrechts,
et seq. (F. Enke ).
3 Council Regulation (EC) No / (available at: http://www.europa.eu/eur-
requires equal treatment of all creditors, whether domestic or foreign, although there
is a special problem with foreign tax claims. Id. at ¶ .
5 In December , UNCITRAL started an initiative to elaborate such best practice.
the economic system of the respective country, the overall purpose of its
insolvency law, the whole legislative body relating to the pre-insolvency
situation (this might be called “turnaround or reorganization legisla-
tion”), its relationship with particular other countries, or the hoped-for
treatment of its businesses abroad. After all, an effective cross-border law
has far reaching implications including, for example, fostering informal
workout attempts at the outset of a debtor’s financial distress as it might
help to prevent the possibly troublesome task of going through an insol-
vency proceeding.
Irrespective of this multi-dimensional task, however, there are a few
fundamental issues6 that more or less explicitly underlie practically all
laws in the world on this subject. They require some brief listing and
description.
national Default, Mich. L. Rev. (); Lynn LoPucki, The Case for Coopera-
tive Territoriality in International Bankruptcy, Mich. L. Rev. (); Frederick
Tung, Fear of Commitment in International Bankruptcy, Geo. Wash. Intil. L. Rev.
(); Charles D. Booth, Living in Uncertain Times: The Need to Strengthen Hong
Kong Transnational Insolvency Law, Colum. J. of Transit. L. , – ()
[hereinafter Living in Uncertain Times]. See additionally Jay L. Westbrook, Multinational
Financial Distress: The Last Hurrah of Territorialism, Tex. Int’l L.J. ().
chapter eight
8 Note as an aside that the question of where assets are located deserves increasing
attention due to the volatility of those “important” goods and financial assets that can be
transferred very quickly from one jurisdiction to another.
9 It should be noted that this concept of sovereignty that guarantees “the ruler” full
authority over his territory (see Christian Tomuschat, International Law: Ensuring the
Survival of Mankind on the Eve of a New Century, et seq. (Martinus Nijhoff )) has
become in recent years less and less accepted in light of countervailing values advocating
for the future togetherness of the people of this world. Suffice it to mention here the
extension of public international criminal law that started with the Nuremberg Trials and
that is now—after Rwanda, Pinochet, Milosevic, and so on—a solid and steady feature of
modern international law; see also Christoph Paulus, Some Thoughts on an Insolvency
Procedure for Countries, Am. J. Comp. L. ().
10 Prominent examples for such an approach were Japan, until its new legislation came
into operation in , and China, before its new law came into operation in .
11 See also Westbrook, supra note , at .
12 See infra ..
cross-border considerations
(c) However, these two principles have rarely existed in their purest
versions; legislative practice quite often mixes or modifies them:
i. As to the mixture—a common version might be called a one-sided
universality (or one-sided territoriality). Its characteristic is that a
jurisdiction requests worldwide recognition (or at least expects it) of
its own domestic trans-border cases but bars foreign cases with the
same claim on its own territory.13 One-sided universality is not only,
shall we say, esthetically disturbing, it is obviously either arrogant
or inconsistent. A somewhat softer version requests reciprocity in
exchange for recognition of the foreign claim to universality.14
13 A recent example is the interpretation given to the old Chinese bankruptcy law prior
to the promulgation of the Chinese Enterprise Bankruptcy Law. CCIC Finance Ltd.,
v. Guangdong Int’l Trust and Inv. Corp. and Guangdon Int’l Trust and Inv. Corp. Hong Kong
(Holdings) Ltd., (In Liq.), HCA of (July , ), noted in Charles Booth,
Drafting Bankruptcy Laws in Socialist Market Economies: Recent Developments in China
and Vietnam, Colum. J. of Asian L. , , note ().
14 Article of the new Chinese Enterprise Bankruptcy Law. Moreover, a few juris-
dictions that have adopted the UNCITRAL model law make its applicability dependent
upon reciprocity—for example, Argentina (draft), British Virgin Islands, Mexico, Roma-
nia, South Africa, or (prospectively) New Zealand. UNCITRAL, Status: —Model
Law on Cross-Border Insolvency. Look Chan Ho, Overview, Cross-Border Insolvency: A
Commentary on the UNCITRAL Model Law , (Look Chan Ho ed., ).
15 See Christoph Paulus, Rechtsvergleichung im nationalen wie internationalen Insol-
venzrecht: Eine Erfolgsgeschichte, in Einheit und Vielfalt des Rechts, Festschrift für R. Gei-
mer, et seq. (R. Schütze ed., ).
chapter eight
(b) However, it has already been mentioned that such a unitary approach
faces, at least for the time being, insurmountable practical obstacles
resulting from the still existing (or perceived) disparities of quite many
areas in the laws of the various countries of this world.19 In order to over-
system.html.
17 See Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Theory and Pragmatism in Global Insolvencies: Choice
ings on a regional level. A prerequisite is that two (or more) countries have such a close
legal relationship that the differences are negligible. This was the case (at least to a certain
cross-border considerations
degree) for two countries like Austria and Germany with a long lasting common legal his-
tory and parallel developments; see Treaty between Germany and Austria on Bankruptcy,
Winding-up, Arrangements and Compositions from . See infra .. and Scandina-
vian concord. However, the Peoples’ Republic of China and Hong Kong have, even since
, not yet come to any agreement regarding the mutual recognition of their respective
insolvency proceedings.
20 It is crucial to designate thereby as precisely as possible the one and only main
proceeding.
21 See for what follows Jay. L. Westbrook, Multinational Enterprises in General Default:
The UNCITRAL Model Law and Related Regional Reforms in: Aktuelle Entwicklungen des
europäischen und internationalen Zivilverfahrensrechts (), sub part II B.
22 The example of Switzerland amplifies that a full local insolvency proceeding is not
necessarily expensive and that it can be performed in great speed. Moreover, the proto-
col in the AIOC Resources, AG case (available at: http://www.iiiglobal.org/international/
protocols/AIOCResourcesAGProtocol.pdf) shows the flexibility of the Swiss
authorities.
chapter eight
23 For the value of this argument see John Pottow, Greed and Pride in International
Bankruptcy: The Problems of and Proposed Solutions to “Local Interests,” Mich. L. Rev.
().
24 It is noteworthy that Switzerland so far has not enacted a full-fledged reorganization
proceeding; drafts are currently under discussion. Also, it should be noted that even in
liquidation cases, cooperation may lead to a greater realization of value. See supra ...
25 Somewhere in the middle of this spectrum is the frequent rule that a parallel
proceeding is not automatically initiated but only when and if certain conditions are
fulfilled; see for example, the Croatian International Bankruptcy Law (described by
Jasnica Garašić in INSOL Europe— International Case law-Alert II/, p. et seq.)
available at http://www.brsi.de/pdfs/international_caselaw_AlertNo.pdf.
26 It is also consistent with “Modified Universalism.”
cross-border considerations
... Jurisdiction
The experience especially of the last years has shown that the legisla-
tive as well as practical attempts to determine where the just-mentioned
main proceeding is to be located is anything but an easy undertaking.
These difficulties are particularly felt in the context of insolvencies of
groups.28 The formation of groups is today the predominant way of struc-
turing businesses, especially multinational firms. Instead of having all
activities bundled in one corporation, they are split up and attributed
to several separate companies that are bound together under the roof of
(usually) one company.
Practice teaches as a strong rule of thumb that, fairly often, if one com-
pany of such group goes bankrupt, the other ones will follow in a kind of
domino effect. Such an event provokes a number of intricate questions,
one of them being which jurisdiction shall be competent to open a main
proceeding and which one a parallel or ancillary proceeding, respectively.
This problem is currently probably one of the most intensely debated
issues in international insolvency law. The background of this discussion
is the need and desire to determine ex ante the competent jurisdiction
and to exclude thereby forum shopping29 to the extent possible.
Shopping in: James R. Silkenat & Charles D. Schmerler, The Law of International
Insolvencies and Debt Restructurings, , et seq.
chapter eight
30 A vigorous dispute about these questions has arisen in the United States. See
Symposium, William C. Whitford, Courting Failure? The Effects of Venue Choice on Big
Bankruptcies, Buff. L. Rev. , (). See generally Elizabeth Warren and Jay
Lawrence Westbrook, The Law of Debtors and Creditors (th ed., ).
31 See, for example, art. of the Croatian Bankruptcy Law from .
32 In re Bear Stearns High-Grade Structured Credit Strategies Master Fund, Ltd.,
B.R. (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. ), aff ’d B.R. (S.D.N.Y. ) (applying a strict
reading of the center of main interests requirement).
cross-border considerations
to local assets and there is no other proceeding pending in the world, the problem is not
chapter eight
principle that strives to have, to the extent possible, one proceeding gov-
erned by just one law. This is all the more a realistic danger since, under
the given economic circumstances, it becomes increasingly easy to trans-
fer assets from one place to another. Therefore, the decision for establish-
ing minimum requirements for the opening of a non-main proceeding
should always bear in mind that the ultimate goal should be a unitary-
universalistic proceeding. When and if this proposition is accepted, it is
self-evident that the mere location of an asset should not be enough for
opening a non-main proceeding. A prominent representative for such a
“more than just an asset” approach is the requirement of an “establish-
ment,” a requirement found in both the European Union regulation and
the Model Law. This is a term, however, that is not self-explanatory but
rather that is apt to be defined in a way that might add to the existence of
an asset, for example the presence of business activity;36 further elements
or different ones could easily be added for a more precise definition of
what shall be understood by the term “establishment.”37
one of cross-border law and may not be problematic at all. The point discussed in the text
arises because there are also insolvency proceedings concerning the same debtor in other
countries.
36 This is what the European Insolvency Regulation and the UNCITRAL Model Law
B.R. (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. ), aff ’d B.R. (S.D.N.Y. ). That case rejected
the idea that a jurisdiction of incorporation, with only formal contacts with the debtor,
could be even a non-main jurisdiction.
cross-border considerations
powers or the treatment of secured rights; less hard (but still troublesome
in many cases) is, for example, the scope of the administrator’s powers or
the granting of special privileges in insolvency proceedings. The problem
is large and complex, and we introduce only the main elements in this
brief treatment.
It is of central importance to distinguish between choice of insolvency
law and choice of non-insolvency law. As to a given dispute, both choices
may be necessary and it is crucial to see which choice a particular statute
or court decision is making. For example, take a particular claim arising
in contract and asserted to be entitled to priority in distribution. The
law governing the validity of the contract, the amount of damages, and
related issues are usually governed by non-insolvency law. Once those
questions have been answered and the amount of the claim determined,
then insolvency law will determine the proper priority in distribution.
The general rules of conflicts of law are usually not seen as per se appli-
cable in cross-border insolvency cases but are said to need adjustment to
the particular needs and peculiarities of these proceedings. The two cor-
nerstones in between which this adjustment must be placed are, on the
one hand, the above-mentioned ideal of one proceeding handling one
case according to one law. On the other hand, there is the confidence
of the people of other countries in the application of a law under which
they have acted before and have performed legal transactions. Whereas
the former principle would lead to an export of the whole body of the
domestic insolvency law to all countries where the debtor might have
assets, the latter approach tends toward a multiplicity of applicable laws:
beyond the borders of the opening jurisdiction only those jurisdictions’
laws are applicable where assets (or establishments)38 of the debtor are
located.
The contemporary compromise for the solution of these two conflict-
ing approaches is that, as a general rule, the lex fori concursus shall be
applicable, that is, the insolvency law of that jurisdiction where the insol-
vency proceeding in question has been commenced. However, there are
exceptions to this unitary and universal approach: wherever the need is
felt to protect nationals and their trust in “their” law, there are specific
rules providing either for the exclusive applicability of this law or for at
least mitigating the strict effects of the application of the lex fori con-
cursus. Widely accepted examples for such exceptions are—apart from
39 Described below in ... For the trust requirement in particular, see Christoph
Paulus & Marc Udink, European Law and Trust, EUROFENIX, ().
cross-border considerations
41 As is the case in Hong Kong. Nevertheless, the Hong Kong Law Reform Commission
has rejected recommendations for incorporating the common law jurisdictional criteria
into detailed statutory provisions. See The Law Reform Commission of Hong Kong, Report
on the Winding-Up Provisions of the Companies Ordinance (July ), at pp. –,
paras . to . & p. , ¶¶ ..to ..
42 UNCITRAL, Model Law, art. .
cross-border considerations
the requirements of a fair proceeding, see the IBA “Concordat” available at http://www
.ibanet.org/ aboutiba/IBA_Resolutions.cfm.
chapter eight
46 This is traditionally the approach of, for example, Austria, Germany, or Switzerland.
47 The main representative of this approach still is the US (even after the Bank-
ruptcy Code amendments). However, even more rigid in protecting the debtor is the
current bankruptcy law of Colombia (Law of December , ), which was enacted
in times of—then—serious economic difficulties for the Colombian economy as a whole.
48 See, for example, Argentina.
49 See, for example, France.
50 See, for example, Italy with respect to its Amministrazione Straordinaria di Grandi
Imprese in Crisi; for this proceeding see, for instance, Angelo Castagnola and Roberto
Sacchi, La nuova disciplina della amministrazione straordinaria delle grandi
imprese in stato di insolvenza ().
51 This is the understanding of, for example, the European Insolvency Regulation,
art. , par. § ; see Manfred Balz, The European Union Convention on Insolvency Pro-
ceedings, Am. Bankr.L.J., , f. (). For criticism see Gordon Johnson, The
European Union Convention on Insolvency Proceedings: A Critique of the Conventions Cor-
porate Rescue Paradigm, Int. Insolv. Rev. , ().
cross-border considerations
assets to a country where the tax laws guarantee a better surplus. How-
ever, judicial consent is crucial; if the administrators alone were to agree
on such protocols without the judges’ consent, the risk of legal liability
is extremely high. Therefore, international efforts should be increased to
find a solution that allows bridging the different historical backgrounds.56
The specific problem of any trans-border insolvency case results from the
fact that different jurisdictions clash not only in a particular question of
law (such as an issue of the laws of contract or copyright or succession)
but in a whole bundle of such questions. Suffice it to repeat what has
already been said about insolvency law as a meta-level of any domestic
law: it is closely enmeshed in the whole body of that law and it forms
even a kind of focal point for numerous fields of business law.57 The
problems resulting therefrom—problems that in earlier days led many
countries to follow the territoriality principle—can be handled by at
least three different approaches, all of which involve different degrees
of harmonization of national laws. The first is to reduce the complexity
of domestic insolvency law by distilling the underlying fundamental
principles and, thereby, to encourage present and future legislators to
follow a certain path of legal reform leading to the optimal result, with
a consequent convergence of domestic laws.58 This is more or less the
approach of the multilateral institutions such as the IMF,59 World Bank,60
and UNCITRAL61 in their respective texts. They serve, inter alia, to a
certain degree as model for some regional efforts.62
56 For this see Jay L. Westbrook, International Judicial Negotiation, supra note ;
for a guide as to how judge-to-judge communication can be established see http://www
.iiiglobal.org/international/guidelines.html (available in various languages).
57 As to the latter observation see Christoph Paulus, Verbindungslinien des Modernen
external/pubs/ft/orderly/index.htm.
60 Revised Principles on Insolvency and Creditor Rights Systems, (Draft ); avail-
pdf/ english/texts/insolven/–_Ebook.pdf.
62 See for example, The General Commentary to the Principles of European Insolvency
The two other approaches are: () drafting a model law focused on
procedure and cooperation that draws its strength from the authority of
its author. This is the path of the UNCITRAL Model Law on International
Insolvency;63 or () reducing the complexity and multiplicity of the
world’s existing international insolvency laws by creating bigger units
(regions) that share a common international insolvency law. This is what
has been done by some South American States, by the European Union,
and in Africa by OHADA.64 A first step has been taken by the NAFTA
states as well.
prises in General Default, supra note , at part III; K. Wimmer, Die UNCITRAL-Mo-
dellbestimmungen über grenzüberschreitende Insolvenzverfahren, in Zeitschrift für Wirt-
schaftsrecht et seq. (),; Claudia Tobler, Managing Failure in the New Global
Economy The UNCITRAL Model Law on Cross-Border Insolvency, B.C. Int’l &
Comp. L. Rev., et seq. (): Bob Wessels, Will UNCITRAL Bring Changes to Insol-
vency Proceedings Outside the USA and Great Britain? It Certainly Will!, Int. Corporate
Rescue et seq. ().
66 The latter point is important. The regions described in .., .., .., .. below
could use the model law as their international insolvency law insofar as the model law
works on a higher level than these regional initiatives.
67 Described in ..., ..., ..., ... below.
chapter eight
so; whenever there are two or more proceedings pending they shall be
coordinated by means of cooperation; fourth, such coordination may
encompass support for the foreign administrator, provided that assets are
at stake that “belong” to the foreign proceeding’s estate; fifth, creditors
are allowed to lodge their claims in any one of the proceedings, but their
dividend in one proceeding will be recognized in another one; sixth, the
court may turn over local assets for distribution in the main proceeding;
and seventh, a surplus in a non-main proceeding shall be handed over to
the main proceeding.
recognition procedure may take some time, despite the aids to expedition
in Articles –, Article provides for possible interim relief that may
granted in order to protect the debtor’s assets or the creditors’ interests.
(c) The effects of such recognition are, inter alia, that the foreign rep-
resentative is entitled to participate in the domestic proceedings;69 the
foreign creditors will be notified whenever necessary according to the
domestic law;70 and the foreign representative has standing pursuant to
Article , to initiate a lawsuit before the local courts regarding his avoid-
ance powers. The main effect, however, is put down in Article : subject
to the law of the recognizing state, the “commencement or continuation
of individual actions or individual proceedings concerning the debtor’s
assets, rights, obligations, or liabilities is stayed; execution against the
debtor’s assets is stayed; and the right to transfer, encumber or otherwise
dispose of any assets of the debtor is suspended.” This adds up to a mora-
torium that is, in terms of efficiency, particularly essential for any rescue
attempt, especially if it is granted promptly. Article lists further relief
that may be granted upon the representative’s request, including gather-
ing information and empowering the foreign administrator to administer
the local assets or to turn over those assets for distribution through the
main proceeding.
(d) In Chapter IV, the Model Law describes in more detail how the coor-
dination and cooperation of the multiple proceedings shall be performed.
It is especially noteworthy that it entitles not just the representatives but
also the judges to communicate with each other directly, without any
diplomatic intermediaries.71
.... Contents
(a) The Montevideo Treaty of deals with “Bankruptcies” in Arti-
cles –. This title of the treaty is applicable when a debtor has assets
not just in one jurisdiction but also abroad. Competence to commence a
proceeding is with the court where the debtor has its “commercial domi-
cile.”73 Once such a proceeding has been opened it shall have universal
effect; it does not, however, become totally clear from the text’s word-
ing how the recognition in the other member states is supposed to work.
Article states, only with respect to provisional remedies in the opening
jurisdiction, that they shall be enforceable in the other states as well; and
Article provides that the administrator’s authority will be recognized.
(b) The updated Montevideo Treaty from rephrases the predecessor
treaty without adding substantially76 new regulations.
(c) Compared with these treaties, the Bustamante Code impresses with
more clarity and precision. Chapter I of Title IX of the Convention
is titled “Unity of Bankruptcy or Insolvency.” Accordingly, Article
declares that the opening of a proceeding encompasses all assets of the
debtor wherever located within the realm of the contracting states. The
universality principle underlying this approach is specified in Article
et seq.; thus, there is automatic recognition with respect to the adminis-
trator’s powers,77 and the opening decision is, pursuant to Article ,
to be deemed res judicata also in the other contracting states—provided
that contingent publicity requirements, set out in Article , have been
fulfilled in the other states. The out-reaching effect of such universalistic
proceeding is extended also to agreements between debtor and creditors
as well as “the rehabilitation of the bankrupt.”78
The Code also arranges exceptions to the universality approach. Arti-
cle allows parallel proceedings in the other contracting states if
the debtor has “in more than one contracting State various commercial
establishments entirely separate economically.” Article declares the
lex rei sitae applicable for certain rights in rem—irrespective of the insol-
vency proceeding that has been opened in another contracting state and
that has the above-mentioned extraterritorial effect.
.... Deficiencies
Seen from a perspective as of today, the omissions and deficiencies are
obvious: all three sets of rules concentrate on a liquidation proceeding;
they neglect the quite fundamental insolvency principle of equal treat-
ment of creditors but rather care explicitly for the protection of local
creditors; and they coordinate the parallel proceedings in an insufficient
way.79 With respect to the Montevideo Treaties, it might be added that
they lack the necessary legislative clarity to limit differing interpretations
in different member states. Nevertheless, it should be emphasized once
more that the mere fact of the existence of such early international agree-
ments is noteworthy and that they already apply a number of features that
are described as the modern standard.
.... Contents
The Convention is based on the principle of a modified universality. Any
insolvency proceeding within a member state is automatically recognized
in all other member states; no exequatur is necessary or admissible. This
the European Insolvency Regulation; see, for example, Odd Swarting & Ulrika Malmberg
Livijn, The European Council Regulation of May on Insolvency Proceedings—
the First Year From a Swedish Perspective (), available at http://www.iiiglobal.org/
country/netherlands/ Nordic_Bankruptcy.pdf.
chapter eight
is true both for liquidation and for composition proceedings.82 The out-
reaching effect comprises, inter alia, the seizure of property abroad as well
as the automatic stay; as a general rule of thumb, the insolvency law of the
opening state (lex concursus)83 is applicable throughout the area covered
by the territory of the member states.84 However, primarily in order
to protect the interests of the domestic creditors, many exceptions are
provided for those assets situated in a member state where the insolvency
proceeding has not been opened, such as those in Article .
It is left to the member states to determine the criteria for opening
a proceeding. However, Article influences this free choice insofar
as it excludes from the Convention’s applicability all those proceedings
that are not based on the ground of the debtor’s residence or registered
office.85 With respect to privileged claims, Articles , , and present
a rather complicated (albeit apparently functioning) diagram that dis-
tinguishes between privileged claims against particular assets—that is,
primarily secured claims—and those of a general nature. With respect
to the latter category, a further distinction is drawn between tax claims
and other privileged claims such as labor related ones. Whereas the for-
mer may receive satisfaction only out of the sale of assets located in the
respective member state, the authorities of which do have such claim, the
other privileged creditors are entitled to their privileged satisfaction out
of all assets wherever situated.
86 For a profound discussion of its legislative history and its contents see Balz, supra
note , at et seq. Moreover, see Gabriel Moss, Ian Fletcher & Stuart Isaacs, The
EC Regulation on Insolvency Proceedings, (): Miguel Virgòs & Francisco
Garcimartín, The European Insolvency Regulation: Law and Practice, ();
Paul Omar, European Insolvency Law, (); Christoph Paulus, Europäische In-
solvenzverordnung, (); Bob Wessels, International Insolvency Law, (),
p. et seq.
87 For these institutions, there exist special Directives.
chapter eight
cf. Harry Rajak, European Cross Border Insolvency Developments, European Corporate
Insolvency Law: A Practical Guide (Rajak et al. eds., ), p. et seq.
89 See Christoph Paulus, A Theoretical Approach to Cooperation in Transnational Insol-
(c) Third, according to Article “the law of the State of the opening
of proceeding shall determine the conditions for the opening of those
proceedings, their conduct and their closure.” The second paragraph of
this article contains a rather elaborate and still not exclusive list of what
is to be seen as belonging to the lex concursus: for example, that debtors
can be subjected to an insolvency proceeding; that assets form part of
the estate; the respective powers of both administrator and debtor; the
effect of the proceeding’s opening on current contracts of the debtor; the
admissible claims to be lodged against the debtor’s estate; the ranking of
claims; the creditors’ rights after the closure of the proceeding; and so on.
93 This is true also for England; see Reinhard Zimmermann, The Law of Obliga-
(b) Another lacuna in the Regulation is its complete silence about matters
of highest practical importance, namely group insolvencies. To be sure,
this is probably, at least for the time being, the most complex and difficult
(a) Even though the statement does not grant an automatic recognition,
but follows the UNCITRAL Model Law approach of an exequatur, it
cross-border considerations
(b) One of the consequences of the recognition is that the foreign admin-
istrator has direct access to the local courts, including the right of the
foreign administrator to intervene in civil actions pending by or against
the debtor and the right to initiate such civil actions or insolvency pro-
ceedings. If there is more than one proceeding, the Principles provide
for communication between administrators and courts. In an annex it is
recommended, inter alia, to make use of modern multi-media devices
for such communication. The administrators are also encouraged to seek
agreements of cooperation, that is, protocols. Unlike the European Union
Regulation, the Principles do not eliminate the choice of how a secondary
proceeding shall be dealt with if the main proceeding strives for the
debtor’s reorganization. Instead, it recommends that in the non-main
proceeding everything should be attempted to assist the efforts of the
main proceeding.
99 Adoption of the Model Law, which the Principles recommend, largely moots this
point. It has been adopted in Mexico and the United States and will become effective in
Canada in the near future.
chapter eight
... OHADA
100 For details see http://www.ohada.com/traite.php; see also, Boris Martor et al., Busi-
ness Law in Africa—OHADA and the Harmonization Process (d ed. ); in
particular, on the international insolvency rules, see Filiga Michel Sawadogo, OHADA—
Droit des Enterprises en Difficulté, et seq. ().
101 See Uniform Act on Collective Proceedings for Wiping off Debts, art. .
102 See id., art. .
cross-border considerations
108 See for example, Thomas Felsberg, Steven Kargman, & Andrea Acerbi, Brazil over-
NR.
cross-border considerations
110 See Christoph Paulus, The Global Insolvency Law and the Role of Multinational
. Articles
in Festschrift für Franz Merz, et seq. (W. Gerhardt et al. eds., RWS-Verlag
).
Ronald Winston Harmer & Clare Wee, The Need for an Integrated Approach to
Secured Transactions and Insolvency Law Reforms, Law and Policy Reform at
the Asian Development Bank, Vol. I ().
Wang Huaiyu, An International Comparison of Insolvency Laws, OECD Fifth
Forum for Asian Insolvency Reform (– Apr. ), http://www.oecd.org/
dataoecd///.pdf.
Ronald Winston Harmer & Clare Wee, The Need for an Integrated Approach to
Secured Transactions and Insolvency Law Reforms, Law & Policy Reform at
the Asian Development Bank, Vol. (), http://www.adb.org/documents/
others/insolvency/integ_approach_secured_trans.pdf.
Nigel J. Howcroft & Hugh Gillespie, Remedies under Security Interests (Ber-
muda), in Remedies Under Security Interests, (Ian M. Fletcher & Odd
Swarting eds., ).
Henry Hu & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Abolition of the Corporate Duty to Credi-
tors, Colum. L. Rev. ().
Burkhard Jakel, Outlines of Security Interests Under German Law, in Cross-
Border Security and Insolvency (Michael Bridge and Robery Stevens eds.,
).
Gordon W. Johnson, The European Union Convention on Insolvency Proceedings:
A Critique on the Convention’s Corporate Rescue Paradigm, Int’l Insolv. Rev.
().
H.G. Kantner, The Protection of Creditors in Austrian Insolvency Proceedings,
Eurofenix .
Andrew Keay & Michael Murray, Making Company Directors Liable: A Compara-
tive Analysis of Wrongful Trading in the United Kingdom and Insolvent Trading
in Australia, Int’l Insolv. Rev. ().
P. Kent, The London Approach, Bank of Eng. Q. Bull. ().
Eva-Maria Kieninger, Evaluation: A Common Core? Convergence, Subsisting Dif-
ferences and Possible Ways for Harmonization, in Security Rights in Movable
Property in European Private Law, (Eva-Maria Kieninger ed., ).
Boris Kozolchyk, Law and the Credit Structure in Latin American, Va. J. Int’l L.
().
Chris Wai Kit Lee, Relationship Between Informal Workouts and the Courts in
Malaysia, Presentation to the Forum for Asian Insolvency Reform (Feb. –
), http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd///.pdf.
Pablo Lerner, The Chief Enforcement Officer and Insolvency in Israeli Law,
Theoretical Inquires in L. ().
Sulette Lombard, Directors’ Liability in Cases of Insolvency from a South African
Perspective, Presentation at INSOL, London (July ).
Lynn M. LoPucki, The Case for Cooperative Territoriality in International Bank-
ruptcy, Mich. L. Rev. ().
Lynn M. LoPucki & William C. Whitford, Corporate Governance in the Bank-
ruptcy Reorganization of Large Publicly Held Corporations, U. Pa. L. Rev.
().
Stephn J. Lubben, The “New and Improved” Chapter , Ky. L.J. ().
bibliography
Sarah McBride & Phillip Day, Asia Looks Immune to “Enronitis”—Region’s Inves-
tors Long Ago Learned Not to Expect Transparency, Asian Wall St. J. (Feb. ,
).
Gerard McCormack, Reforming the Law of Security Intersts: National and Inter-
national Perspectives, Sing. J. Legal Stud. ().
Andrew McKnight, The Reform of Corporate Insolvency Laws in Great Britain,
J.I.B.L. ().
Gabriel Moss, Group Insolvency—Choice of Forum and Choice of Law: The
European Experience Under the Influence of English Pragmatism, Brook.
J. Int’l L. ().
Gabriel Moss & Christoph Paulus, The European Insolvency Regulation—The
Case for Urgent Reform, Insolv. Int. ().
C.H. Parment, The Nordic Bankruptcy Convention—An Introduction (),
http://www.iiiglobal.org/country/netherlands/Nordic_Bankruptcy.pdf.
Christoph Paulus, Group Insolvencies—Some Thoughts about New Approaches,
Tex. Int’l L. J. ().
Christoph Paulus, The Global Insolvency Law and the Role of Multinational
Institutions, Brook. J. Int’l L. ().
Christoph Paulus, Judicial Cooperation in Cross-Border Insolvencies (),
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/GILD/Resources/GJFJudicialCoop-
erationinInsolvency_PaulusEN.pdf.
Christoph Paulus & Marc Udink, European Law and Trust, Eurofenix
().
Christoph Paulus, Some Thoughts on an Insolvency Procedure for Countries, .
Am. J. Comp. L. ().
Christoph Paulus, Rechtsvergleichung im nationalen wie internationalen Insol-
venzrecht: Eine Erfolgsgeschichte, in Einheit Und Vielfalt Des Rechts: Fest-
schrift Für Reinhold Geimer Zum Geburtstag (Rolf A. Schutze ed., ).
Christoph Paulus, Germany: Lessons to Learn from the Implementation of a New
Insolvency Code, Conn. J. Int’l L. ().
Christoph Paulus, A Theoretical Approach to Cooperation in Transnational Insol-
vencies: A European Perspective, Eur. Bus. L. Rev. ().
Christoph Paulus, Verbindungslinien des Modernen Insolvenzrechts, Zeit-
schrift für Wirtschaftsrecht ().
Nuria de la Peña & Heywood W. Fleisig, Romania: Law on Security Interests
in Personal Property and Commentaries, Rev. of Cent. & East Eur. L.
().
John Pottow, Greed and Pride in International Bankruptcy: The Problems of and
Proposed Solutions to Local Interests, Mich. L. Rev. ().
Harry Rajak, Director and Officer Liability in the Zone of Insolvency: A Compar-
ative Analysis, Potchefstroom Elec. L.J. ().
Harry Rajak, Can a Receiver be Negligent?, in The Corporate Dimension,
(Barry AK Rider ed., ).
Harry Rajak, Rescue Versus Liquidation in Central and Eastern Europe, Tex.
Int’l L.J. ().
Harry Rajak & Johan Henning, Business Rescue for South Africa, S. Afr. L.J.
().
bibliography
Thomas Richter, The New Czech Insolvency Act—New Insolvency Regime for
Czech Corporate Debtors and Their Creditors, Butterworths Journal of Inter-
national Banking and Financial Law, June .
Alfredo L. Rovira, Alejandro I. Lubinski, Gonzalo Rovira, Security Interests
Under Argentine Law, in Remedies Under Security Interests, (Ian M. Fletch-
er & Odd Swarting eds., ).
Janis Sarra, The Oppression Remedy: The People’s Choice, in Annual Review of
Insolvency Law, (Janis P. Sarra ed., ).
Janis Sarra, Taking the Corporation Past the “Plimsoll Line”: Director and Officer
Liability When the Corporation Founders, Int’l Insolv. Rev. ().
Meghan M. Sercombe, Good Technology and Bad Law: How Computerization
Threatens Notice Filing Under Revised Article , Tex. L. Rev. ().
David A. Skeel, Jr., Creditors’ Ball: The “New” New Corporate Governance in
Chapter , U. Pa. L. Rev. ().
Philip Smart & Charles D. Booth, Provisional Supervision and Workers’ Wages:
An Alternative Proposal, H.K.L.J. ().
Philip Smart & Charles D. Booth, Reforming Corporate Rescue Procedures in
Hong Kong, J. Corp. L. Studies ().
Alastair Smith & Andre Boraine, Crossing Borders into South African Insolvency
Law: From the Roman-Dutch Jurists to the UNCITRAL Model Law, Am.
Bankr. Inst. L. Rev. ().
Christoph Stäubli & Nicole Battistini-Kohler, Swiss Insolvency and Restructuring
Law—A Short Overview and Some Issues of Debate in Corporate Restructur-
ings in Switzerland, J. Bankr. L. & Prac. ().
Stacey Steele, Insolvency Law in Japan, in Insolvency Law in East Asia,
(Roman Tomasic ed., ).
Peter Straub, Remedies under Securities Interests—Switzerland, in Remedies Un-
der Securities Interests, (Ian Fletcher & Odd Swarting eds., ).
Odd Swarting & Ulrika Malmberg Livjin, The European Council Regulation
of May on Insolvency Proceedings—the First Year from a Swedish
Perspective (), http://www.iiiglobal.org/component/jdownloads/?task=
view. download&cid=.
Dr. Shinjiro Takagi, Restructuring in Japan, Int’l Insolv. Rev. ().
Claudia Tobler, Managing Failure in the New Global Economy: The UNCITRAL
Model Law on Cross-Border Insolvency, B.C. Int’l & Comp. L. Rev.
().
Alexander Trunk, German International Insolvency Law Under the New Insol-
vency Code: Continuity and Evolution, in Legal Aspects of Globalization (Jür-
gen Basedow & Toshiyuki Kono eds., ).
Frederick Tung, Fear of Commitment in International Bankruptcy, Geo. Wash.
Int’l L. Rev. ().
Lampros Vassiliou, Legal Issues: Thailand, in Siam Premiere’s Guide to Restruc-
turing in Asia, Asian Development Bank (), http://www.adb.org/Doc
uments/reports/restructuring_asia/Thailand.pdf.
Aparna Viswanathan, Banking and Financial Reform in India: Will it Improve
Lenders’ Rights and Recovery?, J.I.B.L.R. ().
Elizabeth Warren, Bankruptcy Policy, U. Chi. L. Rev. ().
bibliography
Elizabeth Warren & Jay Westbrook, The Success of Chapter : A Challenge to the
Critics, Mich. L. Rev. ().
Bob Wessels, Will UNCITRAL Bring Changes to Insolvency Proceedings Out-
side the USA and Great Britain? It Certainly Will!, Int’l Corp. Rescue
().
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Locating the Eye of the Financial Storm, Brook.
J. Int’l L. ().
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Multinational Financial Distress: The Last Hurrah of
Territorialism, Tex. Int’l L.J. ().
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Control of Wealth in Bankruptcy, Tex. L. Rev.
().
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Duty to Seek Cooperation in Multinational In-
solvency Cases, in Annual Review of Insolvency Law (Janis Sarra ed.,
).
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, International Judicial Negotiation, Tex. Int’l L.J.
().
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Multinational Enterprises in General Default: The
UNCITRAL Model Law and Related Regional Reforms in Aktuelle Entwick-
lungen des europäischen und internationalen Zivilverfahrensrechts (Pe-
ter Gottwald, ed., ).
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Managing Defaulting Multinationals Within NAFTA,
in Foundation and Perspectives of International Law, (Ian F. Fletcher,
Loukas Mistelis, Marise Cremona eds., Sweet & Maxwell, ).
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, A Global Solution to Multinational Default, Mich.
L. Rev. ().
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Lessons of Maxwell Communications, Ford-
ham L. Rev. ().
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Theory and Pragmatism in Global Insolvencies: Choice
of Law and Choice of Forum, Am. Bankr. L. J. ().
Jay Lawrence Westbrook, A Functional Analysis of Executory Contracts, Minn.
L. Rev. ().
William C. Whitford, Venue Choice: Where the Action Is, Buff. L. Rev.
().
James Q. Whitman, The Moral Menace of Roman Law and the Making of Com-
merce: Some Dutch Evidence, Yale L.J. ().
Philip Wood, Overview, Directors in the Twilight Zone II, , Presented at INSOL
(Mar. –, ).
Klaus Wimmer, Die UNCITRAL-Modellbestimmungen über Grenzüberschreit-
ende Insolvenzverfahrn, in Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht ().
Kazuhiko Yamamoto, New Japanese Legislation on Cross-Border Insolvency—
As Compared with the UNCITRAL Model Law, Japanese Ann. Int’l L.
().
Nicola Yeomans, UNCITRAL Convention on Assignment of Receivables: Toward
a Uniform International Law of Bulk Assignments?, J.I.B.L.R. ().
Arthur Anyuan Yuan, Enforcing and Collecting Money Judgments in China
from a U.S. Judgment Creditor’s Perspective, Geo. Wash. Int’l L. Rev.
().
bibliography
Robert Zafft & Lampros Vassiliou, Policy Implications from the Second Forum on
Asian Insolvency Reform, in Informal Workouts, Restructuring and the Fu-
ture of Asian Insolvency Reform (OECD ed., ), http://www.oecd.org/
dataoecd///.pdf.
Jacob S. Ziegel, The EBRD Model Law on Secured Transactions—Some Canadian
Observations, in Festschrift für Ulrich Drobnig zum siebzigsten Geburtstag,
(Jürgen Basedow ed., ).
. Books
Philip Smart & Charles D. Booth, Hong Kong Receivership and Corporate
Liquidation Manual ().
Philip Smart, Charles D. Booth & Stephen Briscoe, Hong Kong Corporate
Insolvency Manual ().
Anker Sorenson & Paul J. Omar, Corporate Rescue Procedures in France ().
Benny S. Tabalujan, Indonesian Insolvency Law ().
Tibor Tajti, Comparative Secured Transactions Law ().
Christian Tomuschat, International Law Ensuring the Survival of Mankind on
the Eve of a New Century ().
Alexander Trunk, Internationales Insolvenzrecht ().
Miguel Virgós & Francisco Garcimartín, The European Insolvency Regulation:
Law and Practice ().
Elizabeth Warren & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Law of Debtors and Creditors
(th ed. ).
Bob Wessels, International Insolvency Law ().
Bob Wessels, Current Topics of International Insolvency Law ().
James J. White & Robert Summers, Uniform Commercial Code (th ed. ).
Tom Wolfe, A Man in Full (Bantam ).
Philip R. Wood, Comparative Law of Security Interests and Title Finance (d ed.
).
Philip R. Wood, Principles of International Insolvency (d ed. ).
Philip R. Wood, Principles of International Insolvency ().
Philip R. Wood, Comparative Law of Security and Guarantees ().
Current Developments in International and Comparative Corporate Insolvency
Law (Joseph S. Ziegel ed., ).
Reinhard Zimmermann, Roman Law, Contemporary Law, European Law: The
Civilian Tradition Today ().
Reinhard Zimmermann, The Law of Obligations—Roman Foundations of the
Civilian Tradition ().
. Institutional Authors