Dollar and US Power
Dollar and US Power
Dollar and US Power
Paper presented at the conference “Currencies of Power and the Power of Currencies” organized by
the International Institute of Strategic Studies in Bahrain from September 29, 2012 to October 2, 2012.
Today the US dollar is undoubtedly the top international currency. This is true by any of the
conventional measures, for its public or private international roles, whether it is measured as unit of
account, medium of exchange, or store of value (the three traditional roles of money). The first part of
the paper is devoted to justifying this assertion. The second part of the paper then goes on to ask
whether this is likely to continue in the medium term, and concludes that it is. The third part of the
paper asks whether this widespread use of the dollar confers great privileges in terms of US power in
the world, and concludes that the main source of advantage stems from private rather than public use
of the dollar.
Consider first official use of the dollar. The dollar is the currency most commonly used by countries to
express their exchange rate objectives: at least 37 of the 146 1 currencies of International Monetary Fund
(IMF) members express their objectives in terms of pegging to the dollar, 2 as opposed to at least 21
(mainly but not exclusively advanced countries) which claim to float and at least 20 which are pegged to
some other single currency (mainly the euro) or the Special Drawing Right (SDR). (It was not possible to
infer the exchange-rate objective of the remaining currencies from the information given in
International Financial Statistics (IFS).)
The US dollar is absolutely dominant as the intervention currency: Most countries intervene in nothing
except dollars. It is the major unit in which about 60 percent of official foreign exchange reserves are
held ($3,548 billion of the total reserve holding of $10,422 billion are in identified dollar holdings, with
some part of the $4,718 billion also held in dollars by central banks that for some reason are unwilling to
declare even to the IMF the composition of their holdings).
1
There are 188 members of the Fund, but many of them share currencies: the euro, the East Caribbean dollar, the
CFA franc, or Ecuador uses the US dollar.
2
The IMF no longer publishes a table showing the exchange rate regime of each member, so I examined the
country pages in IFS. Countries counted as pegging to the dollar were those which showed a constant official rate
in terms of the dollar throughout the period; countries with minimal variation; and countries with a constant one-
way movement (e.g., consistent with a dollar peg combined with a policy of offsetting inflation by a regular crawl).
1
Similarly, the US dollar dominates private use, although official estimates of these private magnitudes
are notable by their sparcity. It was estimated in the past that close to a half of all international trade
was invoiced in dollars (Hartmann 1998), as opposed to under 12 percent of world trade that involved
the United States in 2011. So far as foreign exchange trading is concerned, most takes place against the
dollar, resulting in a share of foreign exchange trading of about 85 percent (the sum of the two sides
adding to 200 percent, since a trade is necessarily of one currency against another). Although the euro
had more bond issues than the dollar for a time, most international transactions involve the dollar. And
most private international holdings of liquid assets are denominated in terms of dollars (if, unlike equity,
they are denominated in anything at all): There are no good statistical estimates of the size of this
portfolio, but it is usually reckoned to be a lot larger than the holdings of official reserves.
It is thus undeniable that the US dollar presently constitutes the most important component, indeed the
vast bulk, of international money. For a time it looked as though the euro might constitute a serious
competitor, but the recent difficulties in the euro area have resulted in it ceasing to be a threat to the
pre-eminence of the dollar. The Chinese are still taking the first steps to establishing the renminbi as an
international currency. The use of the yen has shrunk, along with the Japanese economy. The same is
true of the pound sterling. For the moment, the dollar is quite unrivalled.
If there is no plausible competitor to the dollar among national currencies, what of the international
level? In 1970 the IMF created the SDR, which was not named as an international currency because of a
simmering dispute as to whether the SDR was really money or credit. But the Committee of Twenty
which was created in 1972 to design a successor to the Bretton Woods system wanted to see the SDR as
the “central reserve asset of the system,” and since reserves are normally thought of as international
money this would seem to have settled the dispute. However much the C-20 may have dreamed of
making the SDR the center of the system, it clearly has not come to pass in the past 40 years. The SDR
has no private international role at all. On the official level, a single currency (Myanmar’s kyat) is pegged
against the SDR. Central banks cannot intervene in SDRs because intervention involves transactions with
the private sector. In terms of reserves, less than 3 percent of the total was last year held in SDRs. The
dollar continues to reign.
Cohen (2004, 10–11) lists the factors that determine demand to hold a currency internationally. He
argues that demand is shaped by three attributes. The first is widespread confidence in the future value
of a currency, backed by political stability in the country of origin. Without such confidence, it is
impossible to imagine people voluntarily choosing to hold a particular money, given that they have any
choice. The second is the qualities of “exchange convenience” and “capital certainty”—a high degree of
transactional liquidity and reasonable stability of asset value, the key to both being the existence of
well-developed financial markets which are open to nonresidents. The final factor is a money that
promises access to an extensive transactional network, which seems to give a strong advantage to a
large country. (Notice that his list does not include “backing” for the currency, which is often held up by
lesser thinkers as a key attribute. What matters to give a money “moneyness” is not assurance that one
2
can get repaid by the issuer, but certainty of being able to find someone else who will be only too
pleased to accept the money. Holders of money do not want the trouble of being repaid.)
Consider which currencies are likely in the future to satisfy these conditions. One needs to consider all
the currencies that were mentioned in the previous section, and possibly in addition the rupee, which
may emerge as a contender for reserve currency status at some time in the future. Cohen is right to
argue that widespread confidence in the future value of money depends on both political stability and
being able to trust the country’s authorities not to tolerate inflation. It is in the dimension of political
stability that recent travails in the euro area have been particularly damaging, since all the members of
the euro area, and certainly their collectivity, can no longer be regarded as politically stable. The
secondary reserve currencies—sterling, the yen, and the Swiss franc—score quite well on the political
stability criterion, but there are perhaps lingering doubts about the depth of the United Kingdom’s
attachment to anti-inflationary policy and abut Japan’s political stability. China is also generally judged
as politically stable, although some of us worry that one of the things that people generally want as they
become richer is a stake in how they are governed, and China still has to make the transition to
democratic governance (which has often proved stormy). India does not face that particular concern,
but has concerns of its own. So far as attachment to price stability is concerned, China’s record since the
hyperinflation was stabilized in 1951 looks pretty impressive, but India’s much less so: It seems that
price stability is regarded as inflation of under 10 percent, which is unlikely to impress international
investors.
The most widely satisfied criterion is presently the second one, possession of well-developed capital
markets that are open to all: not only the United States and the euro area satisfy this condition, but also
all the secondary reserve currencies. On the other hand, China and India clearly do not satisfy this
condition at the present time. However, China has been moving in this direction and one would expect
that it will be able to fulfill this criterion relatively quickly, say within 10 or 20 years. It is often held up as
a stumbling block preventing China from acquiring a reserve role, but it is likely to prove a temporary
block. The same is true of India: if anything, India seems overanxious to liberalize its international
currency dealings.
But the final factor is the most important one. It is this which distinguished the United States and the
euro area from the secondary reserve currencies: The fact that they each had an enormous home
market seems to have been the decisive factor in establishing their international roles. However, if it is
right that the euro area is now out of the running because of the political doubts about its future, the
key question becomes how long the US supremacy will persist. After all, China is already by some
measures the largest economy on earth (Subramanian 2011), and it will certainly become the largest by
all measures within the next few years. Moreover, it is this factor that is likely to propel India’s claim to
reserve currency status, since the large size of its population guarantees that it will become the third
largest economy in the world unless its growth rate falls far more than is currently anticipated. However,
while Cohen is correct in diagnosing the importance of an extensive transactional network in causing a
currency to become internationalized, he does not mention a second critically important factor: the role
of the existing network of transactors in this market. Those who wish to transact in this market are not
greatly interested in the fact that the good citizens of Idaho overwhelmingly use the dollar, but they are
3
vitally interested in the fact that the dollar is already used extensively in London, Frankfurt, Dubai,
Singapore, Hong Kong, and wherever else international trades are executed. This factor gives a great
deal of inertia to the international role of currencies. Because of inertia, I see the dollar having a great
advantage over any other national currency for the next quarter of a century. (However, I would
hesitate to forecast for as long as 50 years.)
Rather than an alternative national currency, could the SDR supplant the role of the dollar? Eichengreen
(2009) has argued that it would be necessary to transform the SDR into a private asset if its
attractiveness to official holders is to be materially increased, since any use of the SDR as intervention
currency would be possible only once the official sector is able to transact with the private sector. I have
replied that this is mistaken, since an important potential role of the SDR is that of providing
precautionary reserves which do not derive their utility from an expectation that they will be used in
intervention (Williamson 2009). But even on this less demanding criterion, there is no sign of the
international community showing that enthusiasm for holding the bulk of their reserves in SDRs which
would be indispensable for an SDR solution to come to pass. Accordingly (with sadness) I conclude that
an international solution is unlikely. The dollar is likely to remain the top international currency.
The central question that has been posed to me is to reflect on the extent to which the US gains
additional leverage by virtue of the international role of the dollar. Economists have typically given a
partial answer to this question.
The standard economic analysis holds that the United States gains by international use of the dollar
because of the collection of seigniorage. Historically the term seigniorage meant the ability of the
sovereign to make a profit when it minted metal into money. In our context the term is used to signify
the ability to make a profit from international holding of the currency. There are generally reckoned to
be two sources of profit from foreign holdings of the dollar. One arises from holdings of dollar bills (in
practice, $100 bills) by foreigners (in practice, mainly drug dealers): In effect, the US gains an interest-
free loan to the extent that foreigners hold dollar bills. The other arises from the fact that many
foreigners wish to hold dollar assets. The preferred form of assets are US Treasury bills, and therefore
the interest rate on US Treasury bills is somewhat lower than it otherwise would be; and the saving is
regarded as a part of seigniorage. In reality the demand for many dollar assets is higher as a result of the
international role of the dollar, and therefore their price is somewhat higher than it otherwise would be.
But because they bear interest the profit the United States makes is merely given by the few basis points
by which the interest rate the United States pays is lower than it otherwise would be. This may be even
less than the profit yielded by the foreign holdings of dollar bills: Although the base is vastly larger
(perhaps of the order of $20 trillion as opposed to $414 billion to $672 billion (Truman 2012)), the saving
4
is in terms of basis points 3 as opposed to the whole interest rate in the case of additional holdings of
dollar bills.
It can be objected that the real US gain lies in the ability to finance payments deficits without thought
and without stockpiling previous reserves. It can be replied that same is true of other developed
countries that are able to borrow in their own currencies: The fact that many of them have not run
deficits is due to the fact that they have maintained their currencies at reasonable levels, rather than
because of an inability to finance a deficit. And insofar as the United States is unable to manage its
exchange rate as a quid pro quo of the seigniorage benefit, the United States loses from the dollar’s
role.
Economists typically evaluate the reserve role of a currency as a case of trading off the benefits of being
able to finance payments deficits more cheaply against the costs of losing full freedom to manage their
own exchange-rate policy. In the case of the United States, the Dollar Standard involves a bargain
whereby the United States gains cheap finance, in return for other countries having full freedom to
manage their exchange rates; but in consequence the exchange rate of the dollar adjusts as a residual.
The dollar acts as the so-called nth currency. In the case of the United Kingdom, in the later days of the
sterling balances the holders of sterling made it clear that they expected the United Kingdom to avoid
devaluing in return for their continuing to hold sterling. In both cases the advisability of maintaining a
reserve role of the currency is determined by one's view of the trade-off between the benefits in terms
of financing and the costs in terms of freedom to manage the exchange rate. It is not surprising that
many economists have therefore concluded that a reserve currency role is not a good bargain.
It has often been argued that the large indebtedness of the United States makes it vulnerable to threats
to move holdings out of dollars on the part of foreign governments. But it is a moot point as to whether
the United States should fear such a threat. In a floating exchange rate world, the effect of such a shift
would be a dollar depreciation of whatever size were needed to persuade private holders to hold an
equivalent volume of dollars. The fact that private holdings of dollars are so much larger than official
holdings suggests that this might not be a large depreciation. In any event, there is a countervailing
factor: the fear of a large foreign holder of dollars that it would induce a reduction in its own wealth if it
were to initiate a shift from dollars. As Keynes once observed, when I owe my bank a thousand dollars, I
have reason to fear my banker; if I owe it a million, he fears me. In the case of the United States, it owes
several trillion dollars to China, and there is nowhere else with financial markets that are large enough
to give China a realistic possibility of moving more than a small fraction of its holdings. Any Chinese
threat to move the bulk of these balances would certainly result in dollar depreciation, so a threat to
shift the balances is not credible. Far more credible is the notion that the balances act as a restraining
influence on any Chinese inclination to engage in acts that would be regarded as hostile by the United
States. This is not to say that China will accept orders from the United States in order to defend its dollar
holdings; Chinese leaders have made perfectly clear that they cannot be blackmailed in this way, and
that what they regard as vital national interests (like Taiwan) are not negotiable. Nor indeed does the
3
McKinsey (2009) has suggested a figure of between 30 and 200 basis points, but even the lower figure strikes me
as on the high side.
5
United States not value continued dollar holdings by China sufficiently highly to be hesitant about words
that might suggest that it would contemplate actions that could place the dollars in jeopardy. The
Chinese leadership is nevertheless bound to be circumspect about threatening to shift out of dollars.
It is only China, and possibly Japan, which holds dollar balances sufficiently large to face major
difficulties in redeploying them should occasion be perceived to demand their removal. No other
countries need to take account of the danger of forfeiting a large part of national wealth should they
shift out of the dollar.
But note that this traditional analysis is mainly concerned with the official role of the dollar. It is only via
the foreign holdings of dollar bills and assets that private actions are deemed relevant. One needs to ask
whether it is really true that having the overwhelming majority of international assets denominated in
dollars has no impact on the power of the United States.
It is difficult to see how US power in many dimensions is enhanced by virtue of the widespread private
international use of the dollar. For example, the US ability to wage war in Iraq and Afghanistan was in no
way dependent upon private international use of the dollar. This would seem to be generally true of the
use of armed force. Nor is US influence on Pakistan (for example) influenced by the holdings of many
private foreigners in dollars. (However, official Pakistan benefited from the US-led clampdown on
terrorist financing after 9/11, since this induced many rich Pakistanis to repatriate their holdings of
financial wealth.)
There seems to be one large exception: the ability of a country to enforce a financial blockade, such as
that currently directed against specified Iranian entities. (It would be possible to expand this into a total
financial blockade, but this has not yet occurred.) The United States can order its own companies not to
do business with Iran, but this power is present in any sovereign government and is in no way
dependent on the role of the dollar. But because third countries generally pay Iran in dollars, the United
States government does have additional leverage. Any payment in dollars ultimately involves a transfer
on the books of the Federal Reserve banks (neglecting the trivial case in which both the recipient of
funds and the payer have accounts at the same bank, which hardly seems likely for international
payments). The Fed can require that any institution for which it does business has to certify that it either
has no prohibited connection with Iran or is in receipt of a waiver. They can similarly require that an
institution that contracts with the Fed impose similar requirements on the institutions on behalf of
which they are acting. (Of course, the Fed does not inspect each transaction, but depends upon financial
institutions to do the screening, with stiff penalties possible if prohibited transactions slip through. A
recent example occurred when Standard Chartered Bank was accused by the New York state
Department of Financial Services of having hidden some $250 billion of financial transactions with Iran.)
Thus the United States has the ability to stop transactions in terms of dollars. Insofar as foreign
institutions insist on paying out of their dollar holdings, and/or Iran insists on receiving dollars, Iran is
going to be vulnerable to US pressure.
Is it possible to conceive of a way of side-stepping such pressures? Clearly this would be possible by
mutual agreement to stop using the dollar. The most likely country to contemplate this is China: instead
6
of China paying Iran in dollars, it would be possible for China to pay Iran in renminbi, which could be
used by Iran to import from China. (Even here there is a caveat: The particular Chinese institution that
issued the renminbis could be penalized by the United States if it was also involved in trade with the
United States, since the US government has the power to prohibit US companies doing business with it.)
Unless Iran wished to import from some third country which had in turn agreed to accept payments in
renminbi, presumably because it had obtained a guarantee that it could spend the renminbi in China, it
would be restricted to using its renminbi balances to import directly from China. But since China has a
good range of products available, the thought of its balances being limited in this way would not be
particularly devastating.
It would be difficult to conceive of many other countries being able to persuade Iran to accept payment
in their own currency. India seems to be the next most promising candidate, though India probably has
more compelling reasons for wanting to maintain good relations with America than China. The rupee
also promises to be usable for a wide range of goods, even if not as extensive as those accessible in
China.
Are there many other countries which the United States might wish to blockade in the same sort of way
that it has sought to do to Iran? I am unable to name any. But it would be wrong to read a great deal
into this: In international relations the unexpected is liable to occur. The fact is that having the
international financial markets operate in terms of dollars gives the United States a power which other
countries do not have. It is a power that could be used against any country at a particular point in time,
and it is impossible to foresee exactly under what circumstances the power might be used. That does
not mean that it should be ignored.
It is natural to consider the relationship between this position and the typical economist’s view outlined
at the beginning of this section. The “economist’s view” is one about the public sector role, whereas the
preceding argument is that it is the role of the private sector that gives the United States extra influence.
It follows that the two would be incompatible only if it were true that the private role of the dollar was
dependent upon the dollar continuing to play a major role as a reserve currency, which seems very
doubtful. The economic skepticism is compatible with private international use of the currency giving a
potent additional power to the government.
The question has been raised of the relationship of this analysis to QE3 (the third round of easing of
monetary policy announced by the Federal Reserve since hitting the liquidity trap). This easing was
motivated by the continued weakness of the US economy and the hope of contributing to its revival. It
will have as a side effect a depreciation of the dollar against any other currency which permits it (the
remainder will accumulate additional reserves). The Fed has promised to leave this policy in place until
there are clear signs of economic revival in the United States. It is perhaps unfortunate that the actions
of the Fed are solely motivated by the perceived needs of the US economy and that it takes no account
of spillover effects on the rest of the world, but this is one of the effects of that institution called
national sovereignty. It is therefore unlikely to change unless and until the world adopts some
alternative form of governance.
7
Conclusion
I have argued in his paper that the US dollar is well-established in its role as the dominant international
money. The one currency that looked as though it might offer serious short-run competition, the euro,
has for political reasons ceased to be a rival. Nor does there seem any prospect of an international
currency becoming a threat to US dominance. Moreover, I do not think the dollar is likely to be seriously
challenged in this role in the next quarter century.
The extent to which this gives the United States additional power in the world economy is subject to
more serious debate. I identify two ways in which the international role of the dollar contributes to US
power in the world: by making China more hesitant to jeopardize its relations with Washington (though
only China, apart from possibly Japan, is a large enough holder to be subject to such considerations);
and by contributing to the ability of the United States to impose a blockade on other countries.
I have the impression that the additional national power which stems from commanding an
international currency tends to be exaggerated by strategic thinkers. One needs to designate the specific
mechanisms which would be involved rather than assuming the result.
References
Cohen, Benjamin J. 2004. The Future of Money. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Eichengreen, Barry. 2009. The Dollar Dilemma: The World’s Top Currency Faces Competition. Foreign
Affairs (September/October).
Hartmann, Philipp. 1998. Currency Competition and Foreign Exchange Markets: The Dollar, the Yen, and
the Euro. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
McKinsey Global Institute. 2009. An Exorbitant Privilege? Implications of Reserve Currencies for
Competitiveness. McKinsey Global Institute Discussion Paper (December). Available at
www.mckinsey.com/mgi.
Subramanian, Arvind. 2011. Eclipse: Living in the Shadow of China’s Economic Dominance. Washington:
Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Truman, Edwin M. 2012. John Williamson and the Evolution of the International Monetary System. PIIE
Working Paper 12-13. Washington: Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Williamson, John. 2009. Why SDRs Could Rival the Dollar. PIIE Policy Brief 09-20. Washington: Peterson
Institute for International Economics.