Reimagining The Introductory Material in Teaching Money Creation and Monetary Policy

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 21

The Journal of Economic Education

ISSN: (Print) (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/vece20

Reimagining the introductory material in teaching


money creation and monetary policy

Andre R. Neveu

To cite this article: Andre R. Neveu (2020): Reimagining the introductory material in
teaching money creation and monetary policy, The Journal of Economic Education, DOI:
10.1080/00220485.2020.1804505

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/00220485.2020.1804505

Published online: 14 Aug 2020.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 167

View related articles

View Crossmark data

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=vece20
THE JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC EDUCATION
https://doi.org/10.1080/00220485.2020.1804505

ECONOMIC INSTRUCTION

Reimagining the introductory material in teaching money


creation and monetary policy
Andre R. Neveu
Economics Department, James Madison University, Harrisonburg, VA, USA

ABSTRACT KEYWORDS
The money creation and monetary policy chapters in the leading introduc- Capital requirements;
tory textbooks commonly present an outdated and misleading approach introductory economics;
that is now largely irrelevant. A preferable model would help students monetary policy;
money creation
understand that money and monetary policy are about bank and house-
hold motives, the importance of capital, and the role of credit. An updated JEL CODES
approach would move beyond the current orthodoxy, which assumes both A22; E50; E51
that the mechanical base-multiplier explains monetary policy and the
quantity theory explains inflation. Monetary policy has evolved dramatically
in the last 40 years. Therefore, textbook authors and teachers of introduc-
tory macroeconomics might consider some of these suggestions to help
explain recent events.

In recent decades, innovations in the banking system and monetary policy have changed the
financial sector’s role in the real economy. Yet, during the COVID-19 pandemic and in the wake
of the Great Recession, economists struggled to explain how the modern banking system and
monetary policy works in practice. Central banks have struggled to restart growth through expan-
sionary monetary policy. Short-term interest rates are historically low—even negative for some
sovereign debt—and yet inflation has remained below respective targets for several years. The
Federal Reserve has made attempts to clearly explain innovative changes to policy—such as inter-
est on reserves, quantitative easing, and other liquidity programs. Yet, economists have largely
spent the last ten years trying to explain these innovations to undergraduate students using the
approaches of an earlier era. While many economists like Bowles and Carlin (2020) have argued
that the materials being taught to undergraduates need a thorough reconstruction, there is a nat-
ural hesitancy to depart too much from what has worked in the past. This article aims to bridge
the status quo and complete reconstruction by using a focus on profit-seeking and bank capital,
which uses a balance sheet approach that can be applied at a modular level. Once in place,
money, credit, and real-world monetary policy can be more clearly explained to undergraduates.
This approach offers connections between banking, the financial crisis, and its aftermath—and
lays the groundwork for discussions on wealth, inequality, and debt. The exposition of financial
markets and money might be updated to open the door for how monetary policy and regulation
could be applied in a contemporary real-world context (McLeay, Radia, and Thomas [2014a, b]
provide one example of this). Monetary policy remains one of the least understood economic
topics in large-scale assessments (Walstad, Rebeck, and Butters 2013), and improving understand-
ing requires a re-evaluation of how the topic is taught.

CONTACT Andre R. Neveu [email protected] Department of Economics, James Madison University, 800 South Main
Street, Harrisonburg, VA 22807, USA.
ß 2020 Taylor & Francis Group, LLC
2 A. R. NEVEU

The two approaches discussed here that require re-inspection are the basic reserve-constrained
base-multiplier (B-M) (i.e., the money multiplier) and the quantity theory of money (QTM).
Instructors of introductory and intermediate macroeconomics are often undermining their
own credibility by trying to explain the past decade and beyond using these approaches.
Unfortunately, status quo bias presents a strong roadblock to textbook authors and publishers
who might be interested in transitioning. Bowles and Carlin (2020) note the “15% rule” as a bar-
rier to how much publishers will allow new books to deviate from the standard macroeconomics
textbook. Therefore, we might look to one of the standard introductory and intermediate text-
book authors for guidance on how his books have changed since the crisis. Mankiw (2020b)
noted that when describing the banking system, his introductory treatment has evolved since
2008 to include capital and leverage due to their prominent role in the crisis. The new coverage
by Mankiw (2020a) describes these new components alongside the B-M model and QTM.
The key issue is that both B-M and QTM are teachable, testable, and deeply ingrained in not
only introductory, but also in intermediate and upper-level textbooks and materials. Both topics
are also included in the AP Macroeconomics and Test for Economics Literacy exams, meaning it
is treated as fundamental to both the high school and college curricula. Our introductory materi-
als reflect their upper-level counterparts and are often simplified so that nonspecialists can teach
the material. It is important to offer new materials to guide textbook authors and instructors
toward a simple real-world approach that can be later applied in upper-level coursework.
This article is also an attempt to motivate discussion regarding the usefulness of what we are
teaching our high school and undergraduate students—many of whom only ever take one course
in economics. I am neither advocating for a greater emphasis on unconventional monetary policy
(as in Gertler 2013), nor am I trying to raise the profile of real-world examples (as in Coppock
and Mateer 2018; McConnell, Brue, and Flynn 2018; Parkin 2018; and others). Rather, the article
stresses the importance of teaching a more appropriate set of banking system fundamentals, with
the objective being for students to understand not just the role of liquidity, but also capital, lever-
age, regulation, the profit motive, and interbank lending markets.
The article proceeds as follows. First, the literature on the modern banking system and under-
graduate teaching materials is introduced, focusing first on what might be considered in need of
revision, followed by a set of broad suggestions for reforming what is taught. This is followed by
a suggested exposition, starting with an introduction to the foundations of money and debt that
focuses on a role for credit in the economy. Therein I provide a discussion of wealth, income,
and personal balance sheets. The exposition continues to discuss money creation with a focus on
how banks create money through lending. This section includes discussions on reserve and capital
requirements, as well as the role of federal funds loans. The final section of the exposition
describes the difference between capital and reserve constrained banking as well as the regulatory
role for the Federal Reserve’s tools (instruments), targets, and goals. The final section concludes.

Problems with the B-M and QTM approaches


In leading undergraduate teaching materials, B-M and QTM often receive a great deal of
emphasis. In a post-crisis world, the mechanical B-M method of money creation works to cement
the idea that banks are only an intermediary with no real role in our economy and not the pri-
mary providers of credit. The B-M approach was a convenient framework for describing the
financial system, but evidence shows this description only appeared to be correct (McLeay, Radia,
and Thomas 2014a). This flawed treatment as an intermediary hampers the discipline’s ability to
explain issues like excessive risk-taking, the effect of regulation, and policies such as capital injec-
tions. The QTM framework has similarly been a convenient fallback with its own shortcomings.
The QTM prediction that money growth and prices move together in lockstep over the long run
is confronted with new evidence contrary to its predictions. Gertler (2013) notes there is no
MONEY CREATION AND MONETARY POLICY 3

QTM link between reserves and inflation. Goods price inflation and the growth of the money
supply no longer are correlated to the degree they were in the past. Over the past 20 years in the
United States, average annual CPI inflation was 2.1 percent, nominal GDP grew at 4.0 percent,
while M1 and M2 each rose at annual rates of 6.1 percent.1 At the start of the Fed’s quantitative
easing (QE) programs in 2008, it was common to hear from both economists and pundits that
the Fed was courting hyperinflation. In fact, since QE began, inflation has been below the Fed’s
target rate of 2.0%.2
Pedagogically, these frameworks are typically first used to explain how the world works in the-
ory, and then later abandoned for a narrative approach to discuss real-world examples. While it
is somewhat normal for our teaching models to depart from reality to a degree, the narratives
that follow are generally in defiance of the fundamental assumptions inherent in the approaches
rather than nuance, which had been assumed away.
The ability to create money out of thin air might be the most important lesson from the
B-M approach and is fundamental to any discussion where credit creation is thought to be an
important driver behind real economic activity (Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist 1999). The Fed
does intervene in the market for funds, and the stories of open-market operations like increasing
bond purchases to raise reserves are workable. However, in reverse, we expect the Fed to sell
bonds, contracting the supply of money, and thus raising interest rates. In the 2008 report on
open market operations, the Fed admits that, in practice, they do not do this. They note, “[t]he
outright sale of U.S. Treasury securities that commenced on March 7 [2008] were the first sales
in nearly two decades” (Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Markets Group [FRBNY] 2009,
13). Furthermore, during the Fed’s three rate increase cycles since 1990, the monetary base did
not significantly shrink but instead grew throughout each tightening period.3 It would appear
some reconciliation is in order.

Reviewing the economic literature and textbook treatments


Recent research has shown that a more complete understanding of how the Fed influences the
real economy should be based on bank balance sheet strength and risk perception (Disyatat
2011). Currently, this is not how banking is taught, and macroeconomists have helped perpetuate
several general misconceptions. For one, in most general equilibrium macro models, the financial
system had become much of an afterthought, with the central bank having only power to impact
the economy through changes in interest rates (Woodford 2000). With the addition of financial
frictions to general equilibrium models, there was an improvement in explaining negative shocks
and responses to them (Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist 1999). Unfortunately, when these more
advanced models are explained in their most basic terms to undergraduate students or the general
public, the common explanations often run counter to the more fundamental models they were
first taught.
Most of the leading textbooks devote substantial space to describing the role of reserve
requirements and the B-M model. Thirteen introductory textbooks were reviewed in preparing
this article: Acemoglu, Laibson, and List (2018); Colander (2020); Coppock and Mateer (2018);
The CORE Team (2017); Cowen and Tabarrok (2017); Frank et al. (2019); Greenlaw and Shapiro
(2017); Hubbard and O’Brien (2017); Krugman and Wells (2018); Mankiw (2020a); McConnell,
Brue, and Flynn (2018); Parkin (2018); and, Stevenson and Wolfers (2020). Ten of these books
include—in varying detail—a description of the B-M approach, while only Acemoglu, Laibson,
and List (2018), The CORE Team (2017), and Stevenson and Wolfers (2020) do not.4 All of these
books, with the exceptions of The CORE Team (2017), McConnell, Brue, and Flynn (2018), and
Stevenson and Wolfers (2020), discuss QTM in some capacity.5
The most outstanding treatments here include Acemoglu, Laibson, and List (2018), who intro-
duce banking via a profit-driven approach, addressing issues of capital and risk. Later, money is
4 A. R. NEVEU

developed via QTM, and they eliminate the B-M model in favor of a reserve-demand/reserve-sup-
ply model. Stevenson and Wolfers (2020) eliminate both B-M and QTM and explain money cre-
ation using a narrative approach. Finally, The CORE Team (2017)—supported by Bowles and
Carlin (2020)—provides the most unique approach. They first describe the reason for lending and
borrowing as the result of consumption smoothing, with an approach that uses indifference
curves and budget constraints to optimize intertemporally. The CORE Team (2017) later
describes money creation using balance sheets but eschews the B-M approach.
Many of these books address some shortcomings of the B-M approach via leakage, and the dif-
ference between required and desired reserve ratios is portrayed as fundamental to incorporate
household and bank behavior (Thornton, Ekelund, and DeLorme 1991; Gamble 1991).6 Today—
in the real world—reserve requirements, or the distinction between desired and excess reserves is
by and large unimportant. With the advent of sweeps accounts, reserves had already become less
restrictive than in the past (Bennett and Peristiani 2002). Deposit management by banks had
made it such that banks determined their own level of deposits to a degree, and thus could create
their own reserves. Long before the financial crisis, banks ceased to be reserve-constrained by
being able to tap into overnight interbank loan markets. In the United States, the Fed admittedly
did not “buy and sell bonds” as it was generally believed. Instead, the Fed generally worked
through the repo market, temporarily buying and selling assets with future commitments to
reverse those transactions. Reserves are endogenously created to meet bank demand. Few of these
changes are detailed in the textbooks reviewed. While the main goal is not to include topics like
repos in an introductory exposition, the treatment suggested here provides a framework for these
discussions.
It does not appear that the use of the B-M approach is simply to motivate the process of mul-
tiple deposit creation. A common approach to teaching B-M at the introductory level stresses the
importance of how the Fed influences the economy through monetary aggregates (M1 and M2),
which then impacts interest rates. This outcome is often explained as the result of the Fed using
open-market operations to increase reserves and, therefore, expansion of the money supply.
Reference to 2008 is usually treated as a special case, where much of the simplified approach is
replaced with a narrative.
Intermediate textbooks present a similar approach. Mankiw (2019) describes monetary policy
as “the government’s control over the money supply.” Later, this exposition develops money cre-
ation via the B-M approach, and subsequently adds a discussion on capital, leverage, and leakage.
The subsequent discussion on monetary policy starts by discussing changes in the monetary base,
which students would presumably link back to the earlier B-M approach. Mankiw notes the fail-
ure of the B-M model to predict massive growth in the money supply by explaining that the
money multiplier is kept low because interest paid on reserves encourages banks to hold more
excess reserves. Blanchard (2017) opens his book with stories about the financial crisis, failing
banks, bad balance sheets, and mortgage origination, but never returns to describe another bank
balance sheet. The subsequent explanation of money uses a “money-demand/money-supply”
framework, explaining central bank money increases or decreases with open-market operations.
Thus, financial intermediaries and exogenous money play a central role, with banks and money
creation receiving only a minimal role in the economy.7
Interest on reserves (IOR) was first implemented in the United States in 2008, but other coun-
tries like Canada and the United Kingdom had been using this tool for some time. The countries
using IOR before 2008 typically have no reserve requirement, and generally leave most liquidity
decisions up to the banks themselves. A few introductory textbooks provide some detail on the
role of interest paid on reserves since the crisis, but it is typical that more space is spent on
reserve requirements and discount rates. Interest on reserves generally appears as an afterthought,
as opposed to a substantive part of the B-M framework. Yet, our current models imply that IOR
is the primary backstop preventing runaway inflation. A more suitable exposition might
MONEY CREATION AND MONETARY POLICY 5

incorporate interest on reserves as a more important functional role in the profit-seeking financial
system. When the financial system has ample excess reserves, even with an IOR policy in place,
bankers can still seek out lending opportunities that offer a higher return. They might be
restricted, however, by a lack of interested borrowers at the rates being offered, or if banks are
otherwise uncomfortable making loans to prospective borrowers at market-bearing rates. Capital,
capital requirements, and credit constraints offer crucial insights into why banks might not be
lending—or people might not be borrowing.
Most of the textbooks noted here have downplayed the role played by capital and the importance
of the profit motive in creating credit, focusing instead on the B-M approach.8 Gertler (2013) targets
educators in his description of the importance of the “credit channel” in monetary policy and
describes the irrelevance of the money multiplier or quantity theory of money. Gertler instead
suggests we refocus our attention on the importance of credit and inside money. Carpenter and
Demiralp (2012) note that the credit channel itself often relies on a narrow bank-lending channel,
like that discussed by Kashyap and Stein (2000). Carpenter and Demiralp (2012) show further
that there is no discernible link between reserves to money supply and, finally, to bank lending.
Thus, bank lending is demand-driven, implying an important role for household needs, moods
on risk, and balance sheet strength (Disyatat 2011).
Effective financial regulation has struggled to keep pace with innovation, facing difficulties in
the years following the financial crisis (Tarullo 2019). Tarullo repeatedly notes the important role
played by capital requirements, hardly even mentioning liquidity requirements or reserves. While
liquidity measures were important in the height of the credit crisis, the residual effect of the
Great Recession has been a long-term change to the treatment of capital. The federal funds mar-
ket has changed since the crisis, with different actors and instruments in use (Craig and
Millington 2017; Wolla 2019).
While textbooks are notoriously slow to change, the Federal Reserve might be expected to
offer some clarity in their educational materials. Some recent research reflects a more modern
approach (Wolla 2019), while other new materials continue to echo the typical textbook explanations
given over the past several decades (FRBSL n.d.[a], [b]). The idea that monetary policy is conducted
by changing the quantity of reserves rests on the notion that banks are reserve-constrained. This
then links to the popular misconception that banks “lend out deposits” or “lend out reserves” when
we know this is not the case (McLeay, Radia, and Thomas 2014a).
Combining the typical B-M and QTM approaches leads many students to believe that banks
are a passive intermediary serving little purpose other than to multiply reserves at the Fed’s
request. Reality defies this belief, as the financial sector made up 20 percent of the entire stock
market capitalization in mid-2019 and has averaged 26.5 percent of all domestic profits
since 2009.9

Changes to the typical exposition of money creation


Outlined below are changes in the typical exposition of money creation in monetary policy that
would provide students with a more accurate framework for understanding the banking system.
In addition to outlining these changes, I provide a sample exposition of introductory material
that incorporates these changes.

Deposit creation without money multiplier


The stories told in textbooks about central bank influence often rely on the money multiplier (B-
M) model, which mainly only exists in a world where banks are strictly reserve-constrained. In a
reserve-constrained setting, banks would like to increase loans (and therefore deposits) at any
moment to a perfectly elastic demand for credit curve, but their limited reserves are stopping
6 A. R. NEVEU

them. The reality is that this has not been true for several decades in the United States or other
developed economies. It is relevant in countries like China and Turkey who routinely use reserve
requirements as a monetary policy tool. However, it would be more appropriate to teach these
special cases outside of introductory courses.
The definition of money and the explanation of its creation is expanded here to emphasize the
importance of inside money (i.e., bank money), and the ability given to lenders to create money
and manage their monetary base in a world without reserve constraints. Gray (2011) notes that
in 2010, nine countries out of 121 reported having no reserve requirements—Australia, Canada,
Denmark, Hong Kong, Mexico, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Timor-Leste, and the United
Kingdom. Today in the United States, banks maintain reserves for several reasons other than
meeting statutory requirements. De-emphasizing the B-M model will allow instructors to spend
time explaining the important roles for liquidity and capital.

Bring a focus on capital


Many leading introductory textbooks describe money creation using balance sheets. However, of
the 13 textbooks reviewed here, only seven used any form of capital in their balance sheets
(Acemoglu, Laibson, and List 2018; Coppock and Mateer 2018; The CORE Team 2017; Greenlaw
and Shapiro 2017; Hubbard and O’Brien 2017; Mankiw 2020a; McConnell, Brue, and Flynn
2018). Others exclude any discussion of capital (Cowen and Tabarrok 2017; Krugman and Wells
2018; Frank et al. 2019), while a few do not use balance sheets for describing money creation
(Colander 2020; Parkin 2018; Stevenson and Wolfers 2020). The Basel banking accords place a
much higher value on capital regulations versus liquidity—which comes not just as reserves but
other highly liquid assets. The B-M process is unimportant as banks and other financial institu-
tions are seeking to create profits to pay out to shareholders or accumulate capital. Without a
model of banking grounded in capital and the profit motive, leverage and most banking regula-
tion make little sense to students. Students are rarely given the opportunity to examine how one
of the most salient aspects of the 2007–8 financial crisis—widespread foreclosures and falling
property values—affected both personal and bank balance sheets.

Drop or move quantity theory of money


Too often, students are taught the B-M approach such that the Fed controls outside money (M0),
and, therefore, inside money creation (M2). Perhaps they are taught that there is some leakage
through currency or excess reserve holdings, but that these factors are generally stable and, there-
fore, the B-M approach is rather mechanical. This then typically leads to a QTM discussion of
the long-run impact of the quantity of money (usually M2) on the price level. Thus, we might
expect students to believe if the Fed buys a $1,000 bond, it creates $10,000 new dollars through
the B-M process, and we should therefore see prices rise by a corresponding amount.
Empirically, some of this may hold to a degree in the long run (McCallum and Nelson 2010).
However, the connection between the Fed’s short-run actions and money creation is less than
clear (Thornton 2014). The deeper underlying assumption most textbooks are trying to work
around is that monetary policy is solely a short-run matter related to interest rates, with no long-
term effects. The quick transition to the long run relies on a tight connection between monetary
aggregates and inflation. In fact, the evidence on this is often mixed. Gertler and Hofmann
(2018) show a weak link between money creation and inflation, and, in low inflation countries,
De Grauwe and Polan (2005) show nearly no relationship between monetary aggregates and infla-
tion. De Grauwe and Polan directly address their approach in comparison to earlier work by
Dwyer and Hafer (1999), who do not differentiate between high- and low-inflation countries
when they show M2 is proportionally related to changes in the price level over the medium term.
MONEY CREATION AND MONETARY POLICY 7

Furthermore, if the Fed is not exogenously controlling M2, then there is a flaw in connecting
mechanical price growth to the mechanical B-M approach. The literature has become fragmented
on the role of monetary aggregates in price and output growth, and it might be reasonable to
want students to understand that there is a disconnect between what the Fed does to change
interest rates and how money growth, credit creation, and prices react in both the near term and
long term. Given the way the short run and long run are connected in our existing textbooks, it
is typical for students to misunderstand and misuse the concept of money neutrality. With stu-
dents confused about the length of time it takes to reach the long term, the current pedagogical
approach may inadvertently downplay the importance of banks in credit creation in the
short term.
After this exposition—B-M to QTM—students are right to ask about the role of quantitative
easing. It is confusing to tell students that the central bank spurs lending by adding reserves and
that this should result in accelerating inflation, when direct experience since 2008 tells everyone
otherwise. This is not to say that the quantity theory should not be taught at any point, but that
it might be better suited to sections of the course related to the long term or kept in intermediate
books, which universally include the approach.

A proposed exposition
In the proposed exposition below, money is introduced as it often is in other textbooks.
However, the major difference is in the emphasis on credit and measuring wealth. This is used to
motivate the subsequent discussion on stock versus flow variables, and the difference between
nominal and real. Discussing the notion of intertemporal exchange of real activity provides a
basis for discussing the role of interest rates here that would be discussed in an earlier section. It
is also presumed that the Federal Reserve as an institution has been established at an earlier
point. Additional sections for consideration outside of this exposition would be to add a discus-
sion on M0, M1, and M2 for the United States and discuss the way the framework built here fits
into a post-crisis world, including quantitative easing and the elevated role played by IOR.
With minor changes, one could incorporate blocks 1, 2, and 3 (including 3a and 3 b) as a free-
standing module on money creation.10 In the exposition here, I have used detailed balance sheets
and T-accounts to display both the stock and flow for consistency. For brevity, the T-accounts
are kept to a minimum after their introduction. The inclusion of both might seem cumbersome
at first but does provide a convenient platform to discuss the main differences between income
and wealth, and the process of credit and money creation.
The mechanics of monetary policy are introduced in block 4, where an interbank loan is used
to exemplify the movement of reserves in the banking system. Should the author or instructor
want to skip this detail, block 4a—with slight modifications—is enough to introduce monetary
policy. Block 5 is the closest that we come to recreating the B-M approach by explaining when
constraints to capital and liquidity become binding. This block could be cut by those wishing to
avoid concerns about constraints or adding too many balance sheets. Keeping this block, how-
ever, helps explain both lender of last resort responsibilities and the role of the FDIC in resolving
failing banks. Without the detail of transactions and write-downs, block 6 gives a free-standing
example of capital and liquidity constraints. Block 6 is best to include as an explanation of why
ample reserves might not be associated with runaway money creation or inflation. When seeking
to avoid teaching QTM, students might naturally question what is preventing runaway inflation
when reserves are ample. If excluding blocks 4 and 5, it is possible to explain modern banking in
some detail with only block 6. Block 7 is a summary of the instruments, targets, and goals of
monetary policy, and block 8 is an aside on sweeps programs, which have fundamentally changed
the calculation of required reserves. While it is recommended that block 7 be included here, block
8 A. R. NEVEU

8 is entirely optional. Thus, at a minimum, it is suggested to include blocks 1, 2, 3, and 6. A


more complete exposition would entail adding one or more of the optional sections.

Money, debt, & credit (block 1)


The suggested exposition begins by introducing students to money as an abstract social and polit-
ical concept. As a social construct, money functions as it does—facilitating exchange, measuring
value, and storing value—because people agree that it exists. As a political construct, states
authorize their money for the payment of taxes and require it to be accepted in payment for
debts. In this sense, nations can be considered as the protectors of the debts between occupants
of politically delineated boundaries. Presenting the traditional functions of money—alongside a
standard of deferred payment—sets the stage for a discussion of the relationship between money
creation and household debt. It is worth noting that the standard of deferred payment reflects the
fact that debts are created whenever there is a delay in completing a transaction. It is also sug-
gested that instructors relay the difference between the stock and flow concepts of wealth,
income, credit, deficit, and debt.
In discussing debt, it is useful to note that debts do not need to be denominated in terms of
official state-issued currency. Students can then envision the real nature of debt by thinking about
how they might owe a friend a favor or other obligation. Debt is often vilified, when the true
concern might be that a person or entity has taken on too much debt. It might be more effective
to encourage students to think of debts as symbolizing promises of future real activity. When a
person or entity takes on more future real obligations than they can deliver, it is common that
both the debtor and creditor renegotiate the terms of repayment.11 Yet, in most circumstances,
debts are repaid. In this way, debt represents the social and community ties that take place
over time.

Wealth and balance sheets (block 2)


As is typical in many textbooks using balance sheets, a suggested exposition would include a bal-
ance sheet and T-account for an individual before showing the same concepts for banks or busi-
nesses. Here, the ideas of assets, liabilities, and net worth can be introduced. Providing a
discussion of liquidity in balance sheets is common in existing textbooks, and important to later
discussions of bank insolvency and illiquidity. A household balance sheet that has a negative net
worth value is suggested to help facilitate discussion on the differences between rich and poor,
high v. low income, consumption v. savings, inequality, and the technical meaning of bankruptcy.
The household might be in a negative net worth scenario because they are borrowing money
to get an education, investing in their own human capital. Discussing the intertemporal exchange
taking place helps students understand that their human capital investment is expected to pay for
itself through additional future earnings. This arrangement—borrowing money to go to school—
is usually a good deal for both the borrower and the lender. It is only when real promises are
unfulfillable that borrowers face bankruptcy.

Banks and money creation (block 3)


Banks can be described using balance sheets and T-accounts in much the same way as we
described household finances. Banks are different, though, in that they are profit-seeking institu-
tions, looking to make money for their investors (i.e., more specifically their equity holders or
shareholders). The discussion of stock versus flow concepts also applies here to bank revenue
from borrower interest payments, asset appreciation, dividend payments, and changes to net
equity. Students can benefit from the following realistic example involving amortization. A person
MONEY CREATION AND MONETARY POLICY 9

Table 1. Jupiter bank-initial balance sheet.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Cash $50,000
Capital $50,000
Total $50,000

Table 2. Jupiter bank: T-account after initial deposit.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Cash þ$1,050
Deposits þ$1,050
Total þ$1,050 Total þ$1,050

Table 3. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after initial deposit.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Cash $51,050 Deposits $1,050
Capital $50,000
Total $51,050 Total $51,050

who owes $3,000 to a bank for a loan, with an 11% annual interest rate, repaid over four years,
would have to make regular monthly payments of $77.50. At first, the principal repayment is $50,
and the remaining $27.50 is interest.12 Over the course of the loan, this person pays $3,722,
which is $722 in interest, on top of the $3,000 of principal. At no point do they make a big
$3,000 payment, but instead make many smaller monthly payments.
A sample exposition continues here to emphasize the profit and risk-taking motives of banks.
Banks, just like other businesses, start with capital (i.e., equity or net worth). The example begins
with a group of investors who are opening Jupiter Bank. The owners want to pool financial
resources to incorporate as a bank and make a profit. Let’s imagine a group of 50 investors who
each contribute a $1,000 cash investment for a total of $50,000, as in table 1.
As investors, we might think that stored cash is not going to generate much of a return. We
would be right. If prices rise over time due to inflation, the investors’ money buys fewer real
goods each year. Investors want their assets to grow over time so that they have greater wealth
and can buy more real goods. Thus, the bank owners decide to hire managers who will take
some calculated risks on their behalf. In order to operate as a bank, depositors are needed, and
loans would be made. To attract business, the newly founded bank might offer higher interest
rates on their deposits than other banks. Let’s suppose they offer a 1% annual return on deposits,
along with a host of other benefits like debit cards, and online banking.
An initial deposit of $1,050 is made, which is a liability to Jupiter as the bank now owes
money to its depositor. The changes are reflected in a T-account (table 2) and the new balance
sheet (table 3).

Reserves (block 3a)


At this point, we introduce the concept of a reserve requirement, breaking the cash holdings of
our fictional bank into required reserves and excess reserves. In this regard, it is important to
take care to note that “vault cash” is called just “reserves” in banking terminology, and that it is
functionally equivalent to electronic money. Introducing both regulators here is important for the
purpose of reflecting upon later, as both the Federal Reserve (Fed) and Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation (FDIC) are relevant. Another key point that is often missed in existing expositions is
that reserve requirements apply only to deposits—and not savings or other accounts.
10 A. R. NEVEU

Table 4. Jupiter bank: reclassifying assets from table 3.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $105 Deposits $1,050
Excess reserves $50,945 Capital $50,000
Total $51,050 Total $51,050

Table 5. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after security purchase.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $105 Deposits $1,050
Excess reserves $30,945
Securities $20,000 Capital $50,000
Total $51,050 Total $51,050

Furthermore, in the U.S. system, banks must maintain a percentage of deposits—on average—
over a two-week maintenance period.
Next, it is suggested to discuss how both required and excess reserves are the primary source
of liquidity in the banking system. When banks need to meet withdrawals or move money
around to other banks, they do it with reserves. The Fed acts as a “bank for banks,” helping
transfer money between banks, while also being able to create reserves out of thin air using a
computer keystroke. As is shown below, reserves move with transactions, and banks will often
borrow them from each other for various reasons. The reserve requirement for this exposition is
set at 10 percent. With this reserve requirement, the balance sheet can be rewritten, as in table 4.
Beginning in October 2008, U.S. banks have been paid interest on their reserve balances. In early
2020, the interest rate on reserves (IOR) was set at 1.6% annually.13 So, with this interest earned
on reserves, Jupiter Bank is currently getting a positive monthly cash flow simply from offering
deposit services to its customers and storing reserve balances. Note that if the Fed were to
increase this interest rate, banks would likely increase the interest rate they are charging custom-
ers who borrow money.
At this point in the exposition, Jupiter Bank’s managers decide to purchase some U.S. govern-
ment bonds (i.e., Treasuries). While the return on U.S. Treasuries is usually relatively low—
around 2% in early 2020—it is typically higher than cash or the IOR rate. This presents a good
opportunity to discuss the role played by risk and collateral in our profit-seeking venture. It can
also be noted that there is a very liquid market for Treasuries, and it is easy to turn them into
cash quickly. In table 5, we show that Jupiter takes $20,000 of its cash (i.e., reserves) and uses it
to buy government bonds.
Starting from table 5, Jupiter’s managers make loans. The important point to take away from
this portion of the exposition is that the interest and fees on the loans made will allow them to
pay interest to depositors, finance their operations, and create a profit for shareholders. In this
exposition, I assume a potential business owner wants to borrow $20,000 at an interest rate of
8%, meaning she would pay about $1,600 in interest in the first year. When the bank makes this
loan, the bank deposits the funds into an account for her at Jupiter Bank so that she can use the
money later, paying her the same 1% rate of return on her deposits. Jupiter creates this loan, and
this transaction is reflected in table 6, with a new balance sheet in table 7. Students can notice
here that the process involves reserves turning into a loan, then deposits, and finally back
into reserves.
Jupiter’s new balance sheet in table 7 has increased by $20,000 on both sides, just as the T-
account described. This emphasis on stock and flow helps students see that banks are able to
make money and loans out of thin air. The loan is an asset to the bank, and while there is a risk
that it will not be repaid, the bankers can be seen as willing to take this risk in order to make a
profit. It may be helpful to note here that the bank’s earning a profit relies upon the borrower
MONEY CREATION AND MONETARY POLICY 11

Table 6. Jupiter bank: T-account due to new loan and deposit.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Excess reserves $20,000
Loan þ$20,000
Deposits þ$20,000
Required reserves þ$2,000
Excess reserves þ$18,000
Total þ$20,000 Total þ$20,000

Table 7. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after new loan & deposit.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $2,105 Deposits $21,050
Excess reserves $28,945
Securities $20,000
Loans $20,000 Capital $50,000
Total $71,050 Total $71,050

fulfilling her end of the deal, doing the real work in the future necessary to repay the loan
and interest.
A typical exposition takes this process and repeats it until reaching the point that all reserves
are required, lending is maximized, and the base-multiplier is described. Instead, we focus on the
role played by reserves as a necessity in the transfer of money from one party to another. A typ-
ical exercise here could be to describe how our business takes a portion of their new deposits and
uses them to purchase materials to support their own operations. Here we can see how money
moves out of her deposit account, and a corresponding amount of reserves must go with it.

Capital requirements and lending (block 3b)


With an understanding of money creation and the profit motive in place, an exposition might
then address the role of capital requirements, the capital ratio, and the role for leverage.
Addressing solvency and liquidity—and their respective regulators—can help students separate
the concepts. While capital ratios are complicated in practice, for illustrative purposes, we set the
capital requirement at 10% of loans. In table 7, the total amount of loans is $20,000, and 10% of
this would be $2,000. The bank, with $50,000 in capital, is well above the $2,000 requirement.
We might note that Jupiter’s managers are free to make more loans if they wish. This can be tied
back to reserve requirements as well, with $30,050 in reserves for $20,050 in deposits, $28,045 in
excess of the legal requirement.
In our example, we suppose that a new round of $30,000 in lending takes place. From table 7,
we note that the bank does not have enough in excess reserves (because $28,045 < $30,000), and
making the loan would leave them with only a portion of the reserves they are required to have.
However, because our customer redeposits the money at Jupiter—shown in the T-account in
table 8—there is no shortfall in required reserves. We can point out that, in this situation, the
total amount of reserves between tables 7 and 9 is unchanged. It is only the portion that is con-
sidered to be required that has changed. This portion of the exposition explains that reserves are
closer to an accounting trick rather than a pile of physical paper. This lends itself to a better
explanation of the purpose and action behind federal funds loans or the repo market.

Federal funds loans (block 4)


Picking up from our previous balance sheet, we presume our customer spends their borrowed
money to finance their business. After the money is transferred out of Jupiter, we see reserves
12 A. R. NEVEU

Table 8. Jupiter bank: T-account due to new loan and redeposit.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Excess reserves $30,000
Loan þ$30,000
Deposits þ$30,000
Required reserves þ$3,000
Excess reserves þ$27,000
Total þ$30,000 Total þ$30,000

Table 9. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after new loan & redeposit.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $5,005 Deposits $50,050
Excess reserves $25,045
Securities $20,000
Loans $50,000 Capital $50,000
Total $100,050

Table 10. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after $30,000 in borrowed money is spent.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $2,005 Deposits $20,050
Excess reserves $1,955
Securities $20,000
Loans $50,000 Capital $50,000
Total $70,050 Total $70,050

Table 11. Jupiter bank: T-account due to interbank loan.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Interbank loan þ$1,955
Excess reserves þ$1,955
Total þ$1,955 Total þ$1,955

Table 12. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after interbank loan.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $2,005 Deposits $20,050
Excess reserves $0 Interbank loan $1,955
Securities $20,000
Loans $50,000 Capital $50,000
Total $72,005 Total $72,005

and deposits fall by a corresponding amount. At this point in the exposition, the bank is no lon-
ger meeting its reserve requirements, and excess reserves are negative, indicating a shortfall in
reserves (table 10). In this case, it can be viewed as total reserves being $50, with a shortfall of
reserves of $1,955. Here, we can introduce the normally functioning overnight market, either by
federal funds or repo transactions. Because borrowed funds incur a cost, we assume they borrow
the smallest amount needed (table 11). This interbank loan shows up as a liability to Jupiter in its
new balance sheet (table 12). It is worth noting here that it typically costs banks more to borrow
funds from other banks when compared to deposits. In early 2020, the federal funds rate was
around 1.6%, in comparison to the 1% return on deposits assumed here. We can note here that
the federal funds rate market loans are not collateralized in comparison to either the repo market
or discount loans, where firms must post assets like government securities as collateral to borrow
money at similar rates. Furthermore, a key feature of the interbank loan market is that banks do
not have to hold reserves against these funds. Thus, it is a way banks can meet their requirements
without having to maintain additional reserves.
MONEY CREATION AND MONETARY POLICY 13

Table 13. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after open market sale of securities.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $2,005 Deposits $20,050
Excess reserves $10,000 Interbank loan $1,955
Securities $10,000
Loans $50,000 Capital $50,000
Total $72,005 Total $72,005

(Block 4a)
As long as there are excess reserves somewhere in the system—and other banks believe the bor-
rowing bank is likely to repay—banks have access to necessary funds to increase lending and
deposits. At this point, we introduce the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), open-market
purchase/sale, repo transactions, and the target federal funds rate. If overnight borrowing costs
rise and there is a shortfall in reserves with many banks trying to borrow—the Fed can inject
liquidity into the system by creating reserves out of thin air to temporarily purchase assets like
Treasuries from a bank or the general public. We assume here that the Fed buys $10,000 of
bonds directly from Jupiter—even if this is an unlikely real-world scenario in normal times
(table 13).14
In this scenario, the Fed is fulfilling its role as the lender of last resort and ultimate source of
liquidity to the system. If the system is illiquid—as is often the case during crises—then the cre-
ation of credit for borrowers might slow down more than anticipated. The role of credit in our
economy is emphasized with this exposition, describing how it helps finance firm operations and
helps smooth consumption by households.

Binding constraints and bankruptcy (block 5)


In lieu of the B-M model, this exposition suggests approaching money creation by first addressing
binding constraints of capital and liquidity. Starting from table 13, we can observe that Jupiter
can make more loans and still meet both its capital and reserve requirements. An explanation
that parallels with the B-M story would be that with $50,000 in capital, they can make up to
$500,000 in loans with a 10% capital requirement. Also, with $12,005 in reserves, they would be
able to support up to $120,050 in deposits. This might seem to align more with the B-M model,
but with access to the overnight market for reserves, our bank could increase lending to a much
greater degree and borrow the reserves necessary to meet any requirement. It is worth reiterating
that the goal of the bank is to make a profit and holding on to reserves only earns the interest on
reserves rate of 1.6% paid by the Fed. We can then use an example of Jupiter’s managers target-
ing a level of $150,000 in loans to customers who redeposit their money back into the
bank (table 14).
To reach the target level of loans of $150,000, Jupiter would have had to make $100,000 in
additional loans, or 10 times the excess reserves in table 13. With these additional loans, we can
show the bank has exactly 10 percent of its deposits held as reserves, and well over $15,000 in
capital required. Thus, the bank is meeting both liquidity and capital requirements.
At this point in the exposition, we can address the role of down payments, collateral, and
issues of foreclosure and firm bankruptcy. For example, using a write-down of $10,000, we can
show that banks will reduce their capital a corresponding amount (table 15).
In our balance sheet in table 16, Jupiter’s loans and capital decline together. The bank still
owes its depositors their money back, and their reserves are not available to reflect losses. The
owners of the bank suffer these losses, and the bank’s overall balance sheet shrinks.
Taking this a step further, we now assume that Jupiter has made a lot of bad loans, so many
in fact that they lose another $45,000 in value (table 17). The new balance sheet would show a
14 A. R. NEVEU

Table 14. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after increasing loan portfolio.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $12,005 Deposits $120,050
Excess reserves $0 Interbank loan $1,955
Securities $10,000
Loans $150,000 Capital $50,000
Total $172,005 Total $172,005

Table 15. Jupiter bank: T-account due to $10,000 write-down on loan portfolio.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Loans $10,000 Capital $10,000
Total $10,000 Total $10,000

Table 16. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after $10,000 write-down on loan portfolio.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $12,005 Deposits $120,050
Excess reserves $0 Interbank loan $1,955
Securities $10,000
Loans $140,000 Capital $40,000
Total $162,005 Total $162,005

Table 17. Jupiter bank: balance sheet after $45,000 write-down on loan portfolio.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $12,005 Deposits $120,050
Excess reserves $0 Interbank loan $1,955
Securities $10,000
Loans $95,000 Capital $5,000
Total $117,005 Total $117,005

negative value for net worth in table 17. At this point, we can discuss insolvency, moral hazard,
and the role played by the FDIC. A point addressed in this exposition is that the FDIC usually
tries to intervene well before the bank is insolvent and helps arrange for another bank to buy the
failing one. Another bank might want to buy access to Jupiter’s depositors, their remaining loan
portfolio, or the physical locations and employees.

Capital v. reserve constrained banking (block 6)


Regulation of both capital and liquidity plays an important role in banking. Starting with another
fictional bank—Callisto Bank—we discuss the role of regulation. This provides an opportunity to
discuss capital ratios and leverage. In table 18, Callisto Bank has a debt-to-equity ratio of 14-to-1.
The leverage ratio provides insight into the regulatory environment and risk-taking because it
represents the amount of borrowed money relative to their own capital. Callisto’s capital ratio is
an 8-to-1 ratio, or 12.5% of loans held as capital.15 Using the 10% requirement from earlier, this
bank is meeting its capital requirement. With $200,000 in deposits and $30,000 in total reserves,
the bank is also well above its reserve requirement with a 15% ratio.
As an alternative to the B-M approach—which reflects on only one requirement—we examine
competing regulatory standards. This raises the question as to how much lending this bank could
do and still meet both statutory requirements. With existing reserves, the bank could support
deposits of up to $300,000 (table 19).16 This level of lending would imply the bank is holding
loans that place it at more risk than regulators would prefer. Callisto’s capital ratio at this point
is only 6.8%, below its 10% requirement of $22,000. Thus, Callisto is capital-constrained, but not
liquidity constrained. If Callisto wanted to increase lending while still meeting their capital
MONEY CREATION AND MONETARY POLICY 15

Table 18. Callisto bank: balance sheet.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $20,000 Deposits $200,000
Excess reserves $10,000 Interbank loan $10,000
Securities $75,000
Loans $120,000 Capital $15,000
Total $225,000 Total $225,000

Table 19. Callisto bank: balance sheet with proposed loan expansion based on reserve requirement.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $30,000 Deposits $300,000
Excess reserves $0 Interbank loan $10,000
Securities $75,000
Loans $220,000 Capital $15,000
Total $325,000 Total $325,000

Table 20. Callisto bank: balance sheet with proposed loan expansion based on capital requirement.
Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $23,000 Deposits $230,000
Excess reserves $7,000 Interbank loan $10,000
Securities $75,000
Loans $150,000 Capital $15,000
Total $255,000 Total $255,000

requirement, they could increase lending from $120,000 in table 20 to $150,000. Thus, while
Callisto might be able to borrow more reserves on the overnight market, their level of capital
constrains their lending. This is highly relevant to teaching a coherent explanation of the financial
crisis in the late 2000s or the Fed’s response to the COVID-19 pandemic.
Table 20 is more representative of the modern system, where banking operations are more
constrained by access to capital and capital requirements than by reserve or liquidity require-
ments. After the 2008 financial crisis, the Federal Reserve increased reserves in the system by
nearly $4 trillion. This increase spurred fears of an overwhelming increase in lending, but those
predictions failed to understand that banks were already constrained by capital requirements and
a lack of demand for new lending. Following the housing crisis that started in 2006, bank capital
had been decimated. Banks were not necessarily eager to make new loans just because they
were given the reserves to do so. Instead, they faced much tighter oversight of their capital,
while many banks were facing a crisis of solvency. The Fed can do only so much when banks
face solvency issues because that is left to the FDIC, which does not typically help recapitalize
banks. Banks were left to raise capital on their own and were under pressure to find investors
who would be willing to give banks money in exchange for ownership stakes in what were now
undercapitalized banks. In 2008, the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) authorized the
government purchase of an ownership stake in financial institutions that were deemed systemically
important. These institutions were effectively nationalized as the government took a large control-
ling stake in the banks. The government did not overwhelmingly restrict the banking operations of
these institutions, although TARP did come with some additional oversight responsibility.

Federal Reserve tools/instruments, targets, and goals (block 7)


In this section of the exposition, we present and make a distinction between the Federal Reserve’s
tools (or instruments), targets, and goals. With the preceding exposition, the ability for certain
tools to be used in certain situations can be made clearer. Open market operations, interest on
reserves, reserve requirements, and discount lending has already been addressed. Balance sheet
16 A. R. NEVEU

Table 21. Callisto bank: balance sheet with savings accounts.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $20,000 Deposits $200,000
Excess reserves $0 Savings $10,000
Securities $75,000
Loans $130,000 Capital $15,000
Total $225,000 $225,000

Table 22. Callisto bank: T-account due to sweeps.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Deposits $50,000
Savings þ$50,000
Required Reserves $5,000
Excess Reserves þ$5,000
Total $0 Total $0

Table 23. Callisto bank: balance sheet after sweeps.


Assets Liabilities þ Net Worth
Required reserves $15,000 Deposits $150,000
Excess reserves $5,000 Savings $60,000
Securities $75,000
Loans $130,000 Capital $15,000
Total $225,000 Total $225,000

operations, which are arguably different than pure open-market operations, can be addressed in
this framework. Because the central bank is attempting to influence interest rates other than the
federal funds rate, we can see how extraordinary action influences both banks and firms through
changes in their incentives. Separating tools from targets can show how intermediate objectives
might influence economic activity like consumption or investment. While the Fed had historically
targeted the money supply, they currently focus more of their efforts on the federal funds rate
target and manipulating other interest rates. Finally, this exposition provides a path to discuss the
difference in tools, targets, and goals. Meeting the goals of full employment and stable prices is
rather detached from the typical story of open-market operations increasing reserves, lending,
and prices. Until the COVID-19 crisis, the Fed had not ever attempted to directly increase lend-
ing. Their recent actions fit the story presented here, though, as lending must increase—or stop
rapidly declining—to prevent further departure from their goals.

An aside on sweeps (block 8)


As a final piece to this exposition, there is one other regulatory complication that has made the
U.S. banking system less reserve-constrained and more subject to capital constraints. Take the
example of Callisto Bank again, which now instead of having interbank loans has savings deposits
from its customers in the amount of $10,000. This bank could make loans under its capital require-
ment (up to $150,000 as seen in table 21), but they do not have any reserves to make the—for
example, $5,000—loan they would like to. What the bank can do is reclassify some of its deposits
as savings. They do this because savings accounts are not subject to reserve requirements.17
The changes to the balance sheet must lead to an increase in excess reserves of $5,000, which
we can get by switching $50,000 out of their deposits and into savings as in tables 22 and 23.
The size of the balance sheet does not change in these steps—and total reserves do not change—
only how their money is categorized changes. After this recategorization, the bank is free to make
more loans and increase the size of its balance sheet.
MONEY CREATION AND MONETARY POLICY 17

Banks sweep deposits into non-reserve-requiring savings accounts for the purpose of reducing
their need to hold reserves, so that the bank can purchase assets that offer depositors a higher
rate of return. In the years after this was made possible in the early 1980s, bank reserves fell to
approximately seven percent of total deposits prior to the financial crisis in 2008. Prior to 2008,
there were only about $45 billion in reserves in the entire banking system, with about $30 billion
being vault cash. This meant there were only about $15 billion in reserve balances with the Fed
and $2 billion in excess reserves. These reserves supported checkable deposits of approximately
$600 billion in 2008.

Conclusion
The main takeaway from this article and sample exposition is that the banking system is more
likely to make loans based on a borrower’s ability to repay their debt, and not simply because
they have low-return reserves held as an asset. Potential borrowers, some of whom were hurt in
the financial crisis or its aftermath, might also be hesitant to take out loans. If banks are less
interested in giving loans, and borrowers are not as interested in taking out loans, then we would
expect to see loan creation slow down. No amount of reserves will help undercapitalized banks
issue new loans.
This begs the question of how many students have been taught that runaway inflation is “right
around the corner,” based on the Fed’s quantitative easing programs. The only thing they might
hear that is preventing this was the Fed paying 0.25% on reserves. It is at least partially true that
IOR helps constrain the central bank’s target overnight rate, but it is not yet clear how effective
the IOR is at constraining lending.
In some ways, textbook authors have made small transformations to how economics is taught
at the undergraduate level. The one place where, shockingly, this has not seemed to penetrate is
in our introductory model of banking and money. Textbooks still speak of the money creation
process as if the broader supply of money were exogenously determined by the central bank.
However, rarely does one see a discussion of the role of bank capital or the importance of credit,
debt, and inside money. The primary importance is still seemingly based on reserves and how
central bank operations control the supply of outside money. Here, I build a modern description
of the banking system that can be used to discuss the central bank’s existing tools and the rele-
vance of capital. To the point, the money creation process is still relevant, but the profit motive—
seen nearly everywhere else in economics—could play a larger role.
To help students understand money creation and the role of central bankers and regulatory
authorities, it might help to shift from the story that commercial banks are simply financial
intermediaries lending out unused cash. A more realistic story of banks accounts for their profit-
seeking nature and the ability to create money out of thin air. Newly-created money is then used
to finance risky ventures, where the transaction takes place intertemporally, and there is always
the possibility that the borrower fails to repay. This type of model can help our students improve
their understanding of the relationship between financial markets and real variables.

Notes
1. Over the past 10 years, M1 and M2 grew at average annual rates of 8.6% and 6.2%, while inflation
measured 1.7% per year and nominal GDP grew at 4.0%.
2. In June 2009, Arthur Laffer predicted that due to quantitative easing, “we can expect rapidly rising prices
and much, much higher interest rates over the next four or five years.” https://www.wsj.com/articles/
SB124458888993599879.
3. If looking at only reserve balances at the central bank, this amount generally declined from around $30
billion in 1990 to under $10 billion in 2008. Looking at the 18-year period from 1990 to August 2008, the
one-month change in the monetary base is hardly predictive of the one-month change in the effective
18 A. R. NEVEU

federal funds rate, with a negative correlation of 0.11. If looking only at monthly changes in the more
restrictive “reserve balances held at the central bank,” this correlation falls to 0.05. (Author’s
calculations.)
4. Online resources are increasingly available to help students learn introductory materials on this topic. For
example, Cowen and Tabarrok (2017) provide a 7-minute video explaining the money multiplier process
at https://youtu.be/93_Va7I7Lgg. This video has over 150k views. Several other available videos online
describe the same approach with slight variations. For example, the widely referenced Khan Academy has
one video with over 325k views at https://youtu.be/F7r7l1VG-Tw, and a second with 26k views at https://
youtu.be/gd8B-zrMSYk. YouTube also hosts materials by less well-known economists discussing the same
approach. Jacob Clifford has approximately 540k views at https://youtu.be/JG5c8nhR3LE, and Jason
Welker has had over 140k views https://youtu.be/Ov2Sd-QRi_g. All download measures are current as of
February 2020.
5. McConnell, Brue, and Flynn (2018) treat QTM as an explicit part of an explanation of monetarism in a
separate section.
6. Leakages are the combination of increases to public cash holdings and excess reserves.
7. Jones (2018) introduces money via QTM in a long-run model, and later uses money-demand and money-
supply like Blanchard (2017) to develop an IS-MP model of the economy. Abel, Bernanke, and Croushore
(2020) first explain money as exogenous in their IS-LM exposition. Later in the text, money is created via
a more detailed B-M approach, where tools like interest on reserves can be used to reduce the money
multiplier. In Mishkin’s (2019) textbook on money, credit, and banking, he develops an even more
detailed B-M approach than Abel, Bernanke, and Croushore, starting with the simplest model and
breaking it down. The final sentences of the chapter explain the role interest on reserves might have
played in the decline of the multiplier.
8. Acemoglu, Laibson, and List (2018) describe the credit market before banking, but still focus on the
process of intermediation for banks as reliant upon savings decisions made by households. They also stick
to a form of QTM that strictly adheres to a stable velocity of money in the long run.
9. Total market capitalization was estimated using the Wilshire 5000 index for all financial firms (https://
wilshire.com/Portals/0/analytics/indexes/characteristics/wilshire-5000-characteristics.pdf) and profit ratios
are available from the BEA’s Table 6.16D of the NIPA tables.
10. A full student-focused exposition of this material is available on request or on demand at https://aneveu.
com/econ200-book.
11. Social and political norms can help arbitrate the renegotiation under certain circumstances such as death.
Suppose a person owes their bank $1,000, but passes away suddenly. The bank might try to recoup their
losses by taking over ownership of the person’s house or car.
12. The $3,000 is the principal on the loan, the 5% represents the interest rate, and the four years represents
the term to maturity. The $77.50 figure is found by using an amortization calculator like those found at
https://www.amortization-calc.com/loan-calculator/.
13. The Fed pays banks interest on reserves with money created out of thin air.
14. Notice that the Fed is effectively using newly created money to bid up the price of bonds that are for sale
on the open market. This would lead to an increase in the price and a decline in the interest rate. In our
example here, this is what the Fed is trying to accomplish. When interest rates are rising away from the
Fed’s target federal funds rate, they inject liquidity to ease the upward pressure. If interest rates are falling
below their target, their goal is to extract liquidity, lowering prices and raising interest rates.
15. We are assuming here that the debt issued by the bank takes only the form of loans, and equity only
comes in the form of capital.
16. Note again, we are assuming all loans created are immediately held as deposits.
17. Technically, sweeps are not savings accounts, but this simplification is made to make it clear that deposits
are still relatively liquid.

ORCID
Andre R. Neveu http://orcid.org/0000-0002-5259-9989

References
Abel, A. B., B. Bernanke, and D. Croushore. 2020. Macroeconomics. 10th ed. New York: Pearson Education.
Acemoglu, D., D. Laibson, and J. A. List. 2018. Economics. 2nd ed. Boston, MA: Pearson.
Bennett, P., and S. Peristiani. 2002. Are U.S. reserve requirements still binding? Economic Policy Review 8 (1):
53–68.
MONEY CREATION AND MONETARY POLICY 19

Bernanke, B. S., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1999. The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle frame-
work. In Handbook of macroeconomics, vol. 1C, 1st ed., ed. J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, 1341–93. New York:
Elsevier.
Blanchard, O. 2017. Macroeconomics. 7th ed. Boston, MA: Pearson.
Bowles, S., and W. Carlin. 2020. What students learn in economics 101: Time for a change. Journal of Economic
Literature 58 (1): 176–214. doi: 10.1257/jel.20191585.
Carpenter, S., and S. Demiralp. 2012. Money, reserves, and the transmission of monetary policy: Does the money
multiplier exist? Journal of Macroeconomics 34 (1): 59–75. doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2011.09.009.
Colander, D. 2020. Macroeconomics. 11th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill Education.
Coppock, L., and D. Mateer. 2018. Principles of macroeconomics. 2nd ed. New York: W. W. Norton.
The CORE Team. 2017. The economy: Economics for a changing world. New York: Oxford University Press.
Cowen, T., and A. Tabarrok. 2017. Modern principles of macroeconomics. 4th ed. New York: Worth Publishers.
Craig, B. R., and S. Millington. 2017. The federal funds market since the financial crisis. Economic Commentary,
No. 7. Cleveland, OH: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
De Grauwe, P., and M. Polan. 2005. Is inflation always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon? Scandinavian
Journal of Economics 107 (2): 239–59. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9442.2005.00406.x.
Disyatat, P. 2011. The bank lending channel revisited. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43 (4): 711–34. doi:
10.1111/j.1538-4616.2011.00394.x.
Dwyer, G. P., Jr., and R. W. Hafer. 1999. Are money growth and inflation still related? Economic Review 84 (2):
32–43.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Markets Group (FRBNY). 2009. Domestic open market operations during
2008. https://www.newyorkfed.org/medialibrary/media/markets//omo/omo2008.pdf (accessed July 29, 2019).
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (FRBSL), n.d.(a). In plain English: Making sense of the Federal Reserve. https://
www.stlouisfed.org//media/images/education/in-plain-english/pdfs/in_plain_english.pdf (accessed July 29, 2019).
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (FRBSL). n.d.(b). Making sense of the Federal Reserve: A closer look at open
market operations. https://www.stlouisfed.org/in-plain-english/a-closer-look-at-open-market-operations (accessed
July 29, 2019).
Frank, R. H., B. S. Bernanke, K. Antonovics, and O. Heffetz. 2019. Principles of macroeconomics. 7th ed., vol. 1.
New York: McGraw-Hill Education.
Gamble, R. C., Jr. 1991. The money-creation model: Another pedagogy. Journal of Economic Education 22 (4):
325–29. doi: 10.1080/00220485.1991.10844725.
Gertler, M. 2013. Monetary policy after August 2007. Journal of Economic Education 44 (4): 329–38. doi: 10.1080/
00220485.2013.825110.
Gertler, P., and B. Hofmann. 2018. Monetary facts revisited. Journal of International Money and Finance 86:
154–70. doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2018.04.006.
Gray, S. T. 2011. Central bank balances and reserve requirements. IMF Working Papers 11/36. Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund. doi: 10.5089/9781455217908.001.
Greenlaw, S. A., and D. Shapiro. 2017. Principles of macroeconomics. 2nd ed. Houston, TX: OpenStax.
Hubbard, R. G., and A. P. O’Brien. 2017. Macroeconomics. 6th ed. Boston, MA: Pearson.
Jones, C. I. 2018. Macroeconomics. 2nd ed. New York: W. W. Norton.
Kashyap, A. K., and J. C. Stein. 2000. What do a million observations on banks say about the transmission of
monetary policy? American Economic Review 90 (3): 407–28. doi: 10.1257/aer.90.3.407.
Krugman, P., and R. Wells. 2018. Macroeconomics. 5th ed. New York: Worth Publishers.
Mankiw, N. G. 2019. Macroeconomics. 10th ed. New York: Worth Publishers.
———. 2020a. Principles of macroeconomics. 9th ed. Boston, MA: Cengage Learning.
———. 2020b. Reflections of a textbook author. Journal of Economic Literature 58 (1): 215–28. doi: 10.1257/jel.
20191589.
McCallum, B. T., and E. Nelson. 2010. Money and inflation: Some critical issues. In Handbook of monetary
economics, ed. B. M. Friedman and M. Woodford, 97–153. New York: Elsevier.
McConnell, C. R., S. L. Brue, and S. M. Flynn. 2018. Macroeconomics. 21st ed. New York: McGraw Hill Education.
McLeay, M., A. Radia, and R. Thomas. 2014a. Money creation in the modern economy. Bank of England Quarterly
Bulletin 54 (1): 14–27.
———. 2014b. Money creation in the modern economy: An introduction. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 54
(1): 1–13.
Mishkin, F. S. 2019. The economics of money, banking, and financial markets. 12th ed. New York: Pearson
Education.
Parkin, M. 2018. Macroeconomics. 13th ed. Boston, MA: Pearson.
Stevenson, B., and J. Wolfers. 2020. Principles of macroeconomics. New York: Worth Publishers.
Tarullo, D. K. 2019. Financial regulation: Still unsettled a decade after the crisis. Journal of Economic Perspectives
33 (1): 61–80. doi: 10.1257/jep.33.1.61.
20 A. R. NEVEU

Thornton, D. L. 2014. Monetary policy: Why money matters (and interest rates don’t). Journal of Macroeconomics
40 (2014): 202–13. doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2013.12.005.
Thornton, M., Jr., R. B. Ekelund, and C. D. DeLorme. Jr. 1991. The money-creation model: An alternative peda-
gogy. Journal of Economic Education 22 (4): 317–24. doi: 10.1080/00220485.1991.10844724.
Walstad, W. B., K. Rebeck, and R. B. Butters. 2013. Test of economic literacy: Examiner’s manual. 4th ed. New
York: Council for Economic Education.
Wolla, S. A. 2019. A new frontier: Monetary policy with ample reserves. St. Louis, MO: St. Louis Federal Reserve.
https://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/page1-econ/2019/05/03/a-new-frontier-monetary-policy-with-ample-
reserves (accessed July 29, 2019).
Woodford, M. 2000. Monetary policy in a world without money. International Finance 3 (2): 229–60. doi: 10.1111/
1468-2362.00050.

You might also like