Davis Daniel 2022 PHD
Davis Daniel 2022 PHD
Davis Daniel 2022 PHD
Department of Politics
University of Virginia
May, 2022
Dynasties and Corruption:
How Dynasties Threaten Accountability for Corruption
How best to control corruption is one of the most important unanswered social science questions. This
dissertation contributes to the literature on the control of corruption by looking at how dynasties limit
both vertical and horizontal accountability for corruption. In the Philippines, do areas with a higher
concentration of dynasties see fewer prosecutions for corruption? Will voters reject corrupt politicians
even when they are from a large dynasty? Can either horizontal accountability (prosecutions) or vertical
accountability (elections) control corruption in the face of dynastic power? This dissertation also
examines if a lack of prosecutions and opportunities for corruption leads to more dynasties, or if the
To shed new light on these issues, this dissertation compiles new data sets on historic land
ownership, dynastic membership, prosecutions for corruption, and elections. For some of these
problems, this is the first time large quantitative data has been used to examine the issues. For others,
the unique availability of data on these topics in the Philippines means that old questions are answered
Using this data, this dissertations shows that areas of the Philippines which had more inequality
in land ownership in the early 20th century have a higher concentration of dynasties today. In those
areas with a higher concentration of dynasties, even as corruption worsens prosecutions for corruption
remain rare. Voters in the Philippines will punish politicians indicted for corruption, but when those
politicians come from large dynasties, they are likely to be elected anyway.
ii
Table of Contents
Acknowledgments ....................................................................................................................................... iv
iii
Acknowledgments
Sitting down to write these acknowledgments is humbling because it shows just how many people gave
their time and effort to help me complete this dissertation. It amazes me that so many people were
willing to go out of their way to discuss this research and offer advice. If it takes a village to raise a child,
then it takes a city to finish a dissertation. I hope that the work here is worthy of all the energy poured
into it by a multitude of people. I am also paralyzed by the fear that I’ve forgotten to thank someone. So,
to everyone who has helped me on this long journey, I can never repay the kindness, faith, support,
From the beginning, I have been indebted to Dan Gingerich for walking me through this project
since before there even was a project. He helped shape the questions I address, and gave invaluable
advice on how to approach addressing them. He showed an unfailing knack for improving the ideas I was
working on. I have also benefited greatly from the advice and guidance of my entire dissertation
committee. John Echeverri-Gent was an unfailing pillar of support. John pushed me to think about how
my work connected with ideas that I hadn’t considered, greatly improving the project. Brantly Womack
was crucial in focusing the scope of my dissertation. At one stage, I planned to look at six or seven
countries before Brantly helped me see how little depth that would leave. Allen Hicken’s generosity with
his time has been exceptional. I had only briefly met him when I asked him to be on my committee, but
he has, again and again, spent hours offering me crucial advice. His vast knowledge of the Philippines
has been vital to my project. Sylvia Tidey has been kind enough to offer me a perspective from a
Beyond my committee, I have gotten advice and comments from a wide range of academics
from all over the world. I think it shows the best side of academia that so many were willing to take time
out of their very busy schedules to help a graduate student, who in most cases they didn’t know. The
advice, guidance, and support I received helped at every stage of working on my dissertation. I am
iv
indebted to Emiliano Bolongaita, whose work was one of the initial inspirations for this dissertation. I
want to thank Pablo Querubin who spoke with me and shared some of the initial data that got me off
the ground. I also would like to thank Nico Ravanilla, Tom Pepinsky, Paul Hutchcroft, and John Sidel all of
whom helped me think through the key ideas I was working on.
In the Philippines, I am deeply indebted to Dean Ronald Mendoza of the Ateneo School of
Government who not only hosted me when I was in Manilla, but contributed some of the key data and
most important ideas in this dissertation. Dean Ron offered me his insights into dynasties and politics in
the Philippines. He connected me with numerous people working on dynasties and public procurement.
He shared some of his crucial data and the insights necessary to build on that data. His expertise on
dynasties is what made this dissertation possible. The rest of the Ateneo School of Government was very
helpful as well, especially Jurel Yap who helped me navigate the data they have been collecting. I was
also helped by other academics in the Philippines who took the time to offer me advice and
connections. I truly appreciate the help of Joseph Capuno, Raul Fabella, and Matthew David Ordonez.
I also owe a great deal to all the people from civil society groups and NGOs who I spoke to in the
Philippines. These people are working to make the Philippines a better place and shared their insights
into how corruption in public procurement functions. Some are quoted in the dissertation, but all of
them helped me a huge amount and were crucial in developing this work. Specifically, I want to thank
Dondon Parafina, Rosa Clemente, Toix Cerna, Vivien Suerte-Cortez, and Jose Cortez. I wouldn’t have
nearly as good an understanding of public procurement without their help. They are remarkable people
who work to make the world a better place. While I was in Manila, I was also helped by many people at
the Asian Development Bank. They provided a great deal of technical know-how about how the
government functions. They were unfailingly helpful and generous with their time and insights. I truly
appreciate the help of Ruby Alvarez, Lila Mallory, Claudia Buentjen, Hanif Rahemtulla, and Vinod
Thomas.
v
I want to give an especially big thanks to Luis Abad and Isaias Ubana for their help in
understanding the politics of the Philippines. It was especially important to learn from people working in
politics how politics in the Philippines functions. I am particularly grateful for how open they were when
discussing all topics. There are several people in the Philippines I need to thank but who I can’t name. A
few people who work or worked in sensitive jobs agreed to speak with me anonymously. Their
forthrightness and deep understanding of how the government works provided crucial insights for this
dissertation. My dissertation wouldn’t be the same without their help and while I can’t name them here,
I just want them to know how much I appreciate what they did.
I wouldn’t have gotten the opportunity to go to the Philippines without generous funding from
several sources. I want to thank the Bankard Fund for Political Economy for providing the bulk of the
funding I needed to be able to spend time in the Philippines and collect so much useful information. I
also want to acknowledge the generous funding I received by way of the Bynum Grant from the
Quantitative Collaborative. Without this funding, I wouldn’t have had the time to gather the data I
Finally, I want to thank my friends and family. Without their support, I would never have been
able to finish this. It was a long road including a typhoon, flood, earthquake, volcano, and a global
pandemic. I especially want to thank my parents who have been endlessly supportive through a long
experience in grad school and my mom in particular who copy edited this entire dissertation (though
I’ve edited it more since so all the mistakes are mine alone). Thank you so much to everyone. I feel very
lucky to have received so much from so many. This work belongs to all of you.
vi
Introduction: The Long Run Effect of
Dynasties on Accountability
1
The Problem of Dynasties
Corruption is one of the most intransigent problems in governance because corruption is perpetrated by
those with the most power. While corruption also involves low level offenses, such as a police officer
asking for a bribe not to write a traffic ticket, huge sums of money change hands between top politicians
and those seeking influence across the world. These politicians work to undermine systems of
accountability and avoid punishment. This dissertation examines one important way politicians avoid
punishment for corruption: They are part of political dynasties that help shield them from being
prosecuted for corruption or being voted out for being corrupt. I look at how dynasties form, how they
limit the ability of the government to prosecute members for corruption, and whether elections can be
used to punish corruption. Unfortunately, my key finding is that once dynasties get established, they can
become self perpetuating and very difficult to root out. I also show that dynasties can create an
environment so hostile to those trying to examine their behavior that few prosecutions for corruption
occur. However, this dissertation does offer some hope by showing that when presented with evidence
of corruption, voters will reject corrupt politicians, though there are limits to how far this goes.
Dynasties allow politicians to get away with shocking levels of corruption and are very difficult to root
out.
Like corruption, political dynasties are a problem in many places. While nominally no different
from families being prevalent in any other field, political dynasties become a significant issue when they
start to keep qualified outsiders from joining the political process and protect incompetent, or criminal,
insiders from the consequences of their actions. Dynasties may replace democratic institutions, such as
political parties, as the main focus of political power building. Dynasties are a problem in countries at
very different levels of economic development. In Japan, about 25% of legislators come from a political
dynasty, in Pakistan about 44%, while in the Philippines more than half of legislators hail from dynasties.
Dynasties are also deeply enmeshed in the political process. While virtually no politician would admit to
2
being corrupt, and as I show there is a political cost to being revealed as corrupt, dynasties can’t hide.
They succeed despite, or because of, their status. They can trade on the name of politicians already
elected and the connections they bring. I will show that dynasties gain power when those already in a
strong position are able to cement their control over the state. Because dynasties are built to keep
themselves in power no matter what, corruption goes unreported and unpunished, and the normal
How do citizens hold corrupt politicians accountable? Accountability can be thought of in two
broad categories, horizontal and vertical accountability. Horizontal accountability occurs when one part
of the government holds another accountable. For corruption, this usually means one government
agency prosecuting some official in the government for corruption. Both prosecutor and official are part
of the government, hence the accountability flows from one part of the government to another,
horizontally. Vertical accountability for corruption usually means elections. The people hold elected
officials accountable for their actions. The accountability flows up from the people to the government.
This dissertation raises questions about whether either form of accountability can work and how they
interact with each other. Corrupt politicians, with the support of their dynasties, can stymie government
agencies trying to prosecute corruption. Similarly, it is unclear whether voters will hold corrupt
This dissertation will address these three central issues (corruption, dynasties, and
accountability) in three papers. The first deals with the origins of political dynasties in the Philippines.
This paper shows how dynasties grew out of land inequality and were able to take advantage of their
incorporation into the political process to cement their hold on power. The second paper will show how
dynasties stop horizontal accountability by limiting the ability of the central government to prosecute
corruption. The third paper will show that voters do punish those who are indicted for corruption, but
when candidates come from large political dynasties, their chance of election is still extremely high.
3
These papers address some of the key debates in the literature on corruption, dynasties, and
accountability. This introduction gives a general overview of the key arguments in the papers. The next
section looks at which literatures I examine and what big questions this dissertation strives to answer. A
more complete, and specific, literature review is included in each of the three papers that comprise this
dissertation.
This dissertation addresses important questions in the literature on both how dynasties begin and what
their effects are. It is generally believed that dynasties are tied to land inequality [see Main 1966, Rafi
2018, Kurniadi 2019, Wittman 2009, McCoy 1994, or Sidel 1999] but I use a novel analysis of land
ownership and elections to provide solid evidence that land and dynasties are tied together. This isn’t a
new argument, but it is traditionally only made with qualitative evidence. This dissertation adds
important quantitative work to support the connection. This dissertation also contributes to the work on
the effects of dynasties. There is a good deal of work that connects dynasties to poor economic
development [see Ali 2016, Garces et al. 2021, Mendoza et al. 2016, Geys and Smith 2017, George and
Ponattu 2017]. This dissertation contributes to the work on the effect of dynasties by showing how they
undermine governance and the political process. This also connects to dynastic survival by showing why
I also address the work on vertical and horizontal accountability, as well as how they interact.
There is a well-developed literature on the control of corruption by anti-corruption agencies [see Quah
2010, de Speville 2010, de Sousa 2009, Szeftel 2000, Heilbrunn 2004, Schutte 2012]. This isn’t surprising,
given both the huge success of the anti-corruption agencies in Hong Kong and Singapore and the
difficulty other countries have had in following their model. This dissertation contributes to this debate
4
about the success of horizontal accountability (anti-corruption agencies) by both showing the significant
failures of the Philippines anti-corruption agency (the Ombudsman) and exactly how the Ombudsman
fails. I also look at the debate about corruption and vertical accountability. One of the most important
outstanding questions in the study of corruption is if and when people vote for corrupt politicians [see
Chong et al. 2015, Hooghe and Quintelier 2013, Winters and Weitz-Shapiro 2013, Klasnja et al. 2014,
Ferraz and Finan 2007, de Vries and Solaz 2017]. This dissertation contributes to this literature on
vertical accountability by showing that voters will punish corruption when presented with evidence of
corruption, even in elections marred by clientelistic payouts. However, again dynasties act as a
limitation on accountability. Larger dynasties can get their members elected at a very high rate even
when they are known to be corrupt. Further, dynasties suppress investigations into corruption, so they
limit horizontal accountability which in turn limits what people know about corruption and limits vertical
accountability.
It’s also important to define what I mean when I talk about corruption here. The definition of
corruption as “the abuse of public office for private gain” has a long history but is often criticized as
being too Western-centric and the ideas of “public” and “private” as being too modern to truly
encompass the idea (Farrales 2005). Gingerich (2013, p8-11) points out that the idea of private gain is
too narrow as well. People might engage in corruption for the benefit of a political party rather than
themselves. However, Kurer (2005) argues that instead of thinking of this as public vs private we can see
the issue as equality. Some people are being treated differently by the state because of their
connections. As Kurer notes this idea isn’t rooted in a modern concept and encompasses different ideas
of what equality means in different times and places. This sidesteps the public vs private debate by
Even if we accept this idea of corruption, corruption encompasses a lot of behavior. However,
this dissertation looks at a subset of corruption that is narrower and clearly violates the norms of any
5
society. I look at corruption specifically as it relates to public procurement. There are different ways to
act corruptly in public procurement, but they all involve giving some benefit to specific people or
companies bidding on a public procurement contract. This corruption might involve awarding a public
procurement contract to a specific company in exchange for a bribe. It might involve creating a contract
for a non-existing public procurement (like painting a building that doesn’t exist) and then pocketing the
money. In the end, all these involve taking money from the government in one way or another. That’s
why public procurement is such a big target for corruption, it’s where the money is.
This dissertation contributes to the broader literature on corruption in terms of the work on
corruption, elections, prosecutions, and dynasties mentioned above. This dissertation contributes in
terms of adding to the literature on the measurement of corruption. There is an emerging literature that
works to measure corruption by looking at the quality of public procurement contracts [see Coviello and
Gagliarducci 2010, Auriol et al. 2016, Burgess et al. 2015, Olken 2005, di Tella and Schargrodsky 2003,
Fazekas et al. 2016]. I both present a novel data set of public procurements in the Philippines and help
validate this approach by showing the correlation between low quality public procurement contracts
The Philippines
Before giving an outline of the three papers that make up this dissertation, I will discuss why I chose to
focus on the Philippines, give some background on the history and government of the Philippines, and
show how corruption has become such an ingrained problem. I will omit a detailed look at dynasties
since the first paper is about how those came to be and why they continue to hold power. This section
6
The Philippines was a Spanish colony from 1565 to 1898, then a US colony from 1898 to 1946.
The initial Spanish colonizers employed strategies in the Philippines not dissimilar from those seen in
Spanish America. They set up encomiendas and used both force and religious conversion to bring the
native people in line (Simbulan 2005, p.16-18). The Philippines, though, failed to provide an immediately
extractable resource, like silver in the Americas. The distance from Spain and relative underpopulation
also made large scale plantation farming, like in the Caribbean, difficult. Given these difficulties, there
was never more than a small number of Spanish officials in the Philippines. Additionally, the distance
between Spain and the Philippines is so large that trade ships were usually only sent biannually.
The distance necessitated a high reliance on local intermediaries, even compared to other
Spanish colonies. By the time of the US takeover, then, the descendants of the local powerholders,
much more than any Spanish peninsulares, ran things on the ground. This was somewhat true in most
Spanish colonies but was true to a much larger degree in the far-flung Philippines. When the US took
power, the government became a semi-democracy, but the franchise was initially only extended to an
extremely small group of people. These voters were mostly the same elites from the Spanish period
(Simbulan 2005, p.40-42). In 1901, for example, less than 2% of the population was eligible to vote. The
franchise expanded with each election, but the elite had time to entrench themselves. The first paper
will describe how these elites kept power in their families, and the later papers will describe the long-
The government in the Philippines, having been a US colony, is modeled off the US. The
Philippines has a bicameral legislature, a division of power between three branches of government, and
a popularly elected president. Even compared to the US’s “Imperial” presidency, the president of the
Philippines has vast powers. Hutchcroft and Rocamora (2003, p.295) note that the Philippines president
has “control over the decisions on the suspension of the writ of habeas corpus, assumption of
emergency powers, national finance, and budgetary appropriations; and the amendment of the
7
constitution,” making the Philippines’ presidency more “rooted in Latin American practices.” The
president’s control over budgetary “pork” is especially important and helps explain why both Congress
and local power holders tend to bend to the president’s wishes. Elections in the Philippines are heavily
clientelistic with officials being judged mostly on if they can deliver pork or bribes to voters. With the
president controlling much of the money, politicians court his favor. The third paper includes a longer
While the Philippines is technically a unitary state, provinces and localities have seen their
power increase since the end of the Marcos era. Provinces and municipalities have little power to tax
directly in most cases, though property taxes are assessed locally. About 10% of the national budget is
allotted to the provinces and municipalities to spend on their priorities. Congress doesn’t directly have a
role in local spending, but by controlling the budget of national institutions, like the Department of
Public Works and Highways, they can get involved in how money is spent by those departments at a
local level. Local leaders are beholden to national interests, especially the president, for additional
money.
Political dynasties have been a problem in the Philippines since the first elections. The first
paper will describe this problem in more detail but suffice it to say the Philippines has a government
highly beholden to a relatively small number of elite dynastic families. The national government is used
as a piggy bank to buy local support, and corruption is endemic. The Philippines suffers from both petty
and grand corruption. In terms of petty corruption, according to the 2016 Asia Barometer Survey, about
30% of people in the Philippines personally experience corruption each year. For comparison, that
makes the Philippines fourth worst out of the 12 countries where the Asia Barometer asked about
corruption. Citizens are potentially exposed to corruption whenever they interact with the government.
“The excessive red tape and inefficiency of the Philippine Civil Service provide ample opportunities for
8
The Philippines also faces significant problems with widespread, institutionalized corruption.
One telling fact is that despite looting the country during Ferdinand Marcos’ time in power and being
forced to flee the country when he fell, the Marcoses have returned to power. While Ferdinand Marcos
died in ’89, his family has returned to prominence in the Philippines. Marcos’ son and one of his
daughters have served as representatives, governors, and senators in the last 20 years. His son is
currently the leading presidential candidate for the 2022 elections. His wife, while under indictment in
the Philippines in numerous cases concerning the enormous graft of her and her late husband, served
almost a decade in the Philippines’ congress. Despite numerous cases against them, they have never had
to return a substantial amount of the looted money. One decision led to an order to return about
$300,000. This is a laughable sum compared with the billions they stole.
Public procurement, which I will focus on in this dissertation, is a major source of corruption.
One of the most infamous modern scandals was the Priority Development Assistance Fund (PDAF)
scandal. The Philippines gives individual congressmen an unusually large hand in controlling budgets in
their respective districts. The most overt version of this was the PDAF. The PDAF was money for
development directed by each congressman and senator. The amount of money varied over time but
rose to about four million dollars a year under the control of each congressman. The idea was that the
congressmen could identify projects and agencies in need of funds in their district.
Even in the best-case scenario, this was a project rife with clientelistic bargains. However, at
least a dozen congressmen went far beyond just rewarding supporters with pork-barrel spending. A
group led by businessman Janet Lim-Napoles created fake NGOs that congressmen would award
contracts to. These non-existent NGOs would then pay huge kickbacks to the congressmen. When this
scandal was uncovered, Lim-Napoles was arrested along with several congressmen. One of the most
high-profile senators involved in the scandal (Bong Revilla) was found not guilty and has since run for,
and won, his old Senate seat. He had the endorsement of President Duterte’s daughter. The anti-
9
corruption court found him not guilty but still ordered him to pay back several million dollars in looted
money.
Given this background, what makes the Philippines the right case to examine the role of
dynasties, the effectiveness of different forms of accountability, or the measurement and control of
corruption? There are two broad reasons why the Philippines is a good case for all these issues. First, the
Philippines has significant problems with dynasties, lack of accountability in government, and
corruption. But this doesn’t mean that all the problems are inseparable. Instead, by looking at the
development of dynasties, different forms of accountability, and the attempts to control corruption, we
can tease out each of the problems individually as well as how they affect each other. Second, the
Philippines offers a good case to test these issues because of unique opportunities to measure all the
The interaction of dynasties, accountability, and corruption makes the Philippines a good test
case because it shows us how these problems build on each other. The first paper traces dynasties back
to their origins and their incorporation into the modern political system. From this, we will see that
dynasties don’t just take advantage of places with weak accountability or high corruption, but that they
create and exacerbate these problems. Further, we will see in the Philippines how dynasties affect
different forms of accountability. As noted before, there is a lot of work on attempts to control
corruption through both horizontal and vertical accountability. In the Philippines, we can see how
dynasties affect both these forms of accountability. The Philippines has a significant problem with
dynasties but also has had democratic elections, with two interruptions, for more than a century. The
Philippines isn’t the only country with dynasties and corruption, but the long-running problems give us
10
The Philippines also offers a unique opportunity to measure all this on a broad scale. Dynastic
relationships can be hard to track broadly without coding every politician and their family individually.
However, naming conventions in the Philippines (detailed in the papers) allow us to see who is related in
large quantitative data sets. There is no other country where family data is so easy to measure on such a
broad level. In addition, the Philippines offers a clear picture of the origins of dynasties as the US created
crucial census data at the same time as the US was creating the critical juncture that allowed dynasties
to flourish. So, we can not only see the extent of dynasties now but also see how they developed a
The Philippines also has a single anti-corruption court, so there is data on all corruption cases in
one place. In other countries, researchers might have to resort to newspaper records of prosecutions,
which might miss smaller cases. There is also a large data set on all public procurements in the
Philippines. These are a likely source of corruption, and as detailed in the second paper, we can use
these to create a measure of corruption. It’s unusual for a developing country to have such an extensive
public procurement record going back more than 15 years. Finally, the Philippines has regular elections,
and I was able to collect data on who ran and who won. This isn’t unique, but when added to the rest of
the data, the elements are in place to examine the issues. To summarize, the Philippines allows us to
collect broad data on the membership of dynasties, their origins, corruption prosecutions, corruption in
public procurement, and elections. The Philippines is a country that showcases the issues with dynasties,
corruption, and accountability and offers the opportunity to measure each issue.
The Papers
This section will describe the arguments and findings of the three papers that make up this dissertation
and how they relate to one another. The first paper looks at the origins of dynasties in the Philippines.
11
Having a class of powerful landholders isn’t unusual (especially for a country that was in many ways pre-
modern) but in the Philippines, choices made by the US helped the existing large landholders to build
their power and then to incorporate that power into the new democratic system in such a way that their
families, the emerging dynasties, were able to capture vast political power.
When the US took the Philippines from Spain, the US inherited a country with deep inequality in
land, a key form of wealth in an overwhelming agrarian country. The policies adopted by the US ended
up entrenching those who already had wealth. The US bought huge swaths of land in the Philippines
from the Catholic Church and instituted a program of land titling to create clear records of ownership.
Both these policies could have helped the poor and landless. Redistributing to those without land and
giving them clear titles to prevent abuses could have been a huge boon. Instead, the US passed the cost
of the new land on to the newly created colonial government. The government sold the land to those
who had the money to buy it, those who were already better off. The land titling system required
surveys and fees that placed it out of the reach of the poorest. Thus, those already in a strong economic
As the US was helping the landed elite increase their economic power, the US built a new
democratic government in the Philippines in such a way that those with economic power, the landed
elite, were able to take over the reins of government. The US wanted to create elections and an
indigenous legislature in their new Philippines colony. While that is not a bad impulse, the way the US
did so meant that power flowed to the landed elite. The US instituted elections very quickly and gave
over the government, and the civil service, to the Filipinos. With no existing democratic institutions, the
large landholders were able to get themselves elected to the vast majority of the seats. Once in power,
the landholders found that not only could they gain political power from the new government, but they
could also turn that political power into economic gains. By using the central government to deliver pork
to themselves, they were able to cement power so that even as the Philippines economy became less
12
reliant on agriculture, they were able to hold onto power. This way, those families who were able to
benefit from early land acquisition were able to cement themselves as political dynasties for a hundred
years.
I show quantitative evidence of this connection by looking at US census data on land inequality.
Those areas that had more land inequality in 1918, after the US had been selling off land to the elite,
have a higher concentration of dynasties in the 21st century. In other words, where land was
concentrated in a few hands after the US took over, dynasties took strongest root. Further, areas with a
higher rate of land titles issued in those first years by the US also show a higher concentration of
dynasties in the 21st century. Again, the choices made by the US helped those with means secure their
power and gave rise to long lasting dynasties. Building off this work, the second paper looks at how
dynasties in the Philippines today can avoid being prosecuted for corruption. 100 years later, dynasties
The second paper examines times when prosecutions for corruption are stymied by dynasties.
Corruption prosecutions are the purview of the Ombudsman, a national institution tasked with
investigating and prosecuting corruption. While anti-corruption agencies have worked wonders in some
countries, their record overall is mixed. In the Philippines, the Ombudsman is only weakly independent
and has limited investigative powers. This doesn’t mean the Ombudsman never makes cases, but it does
mean that their work can be interfered with. Because the Ombudsman has limited investigative powers,
they often rely on reports of corruption and those in the know testifying about corrupt practices.
However, while the Ombudsman is a national agency, dynasties are powerful on the local and provincial
level. That means that most dynasties have a hard time affecting a national agency like the Ombudsman,
but also that the Ombudsman has a hard time investigating at the local level. Mayors and governors
have a lot of power over the police and courts on the local level. Again, this doesn’t always stop the
13
Dynasties grew up using their political power to gain economic advantage. The ability to get
money through corrupt means is one of the big advantages of holding key government offices.
Therefore, corruption investigations can be a threat to all the dynasties in a province and their ability to
turn their political power into economic power. While dynasties compete against each other, sometimes
violently, they also often form alliances and work together. Not every province has the same
concentration of dynasties. As noted in the first paper, in some places, dynasties were able to put down
deeper roots than in other places. In areas where dynasties control a large number of the local and
provincial offices, they can create a cone of silence, preventing the sort of reports and informants that
the Ombudsman relies on to prosecute corruption. So, in provinces with a high concentration of
dynasties, as corruption increases, prosecutions remain rare. However, in provinces with a low
concentration of dynasties, as corruption increases, so too does the chance of a mayor or governor
being prosecuted.
This paper uses three unique data sets: a measure of the concentration of dynasties in every
province, something that isn’t possible in most countries; a measure of all the prosecutions undertaken
by the Ombudsman; and a measure of corruption based on the extensive public procurement data
available in the Philippines. This data shows that overall prosecutions increase as corruption increases
but that the effect is moderated by the concentration of dynasties. Much like the way dynasties from all
over the country in the early 20th century came together in the new central government to hand out
pork to themselves, today dynasties in the Philippines make sure that horizontal accountability fails to
stop them from making money corruptly. The third paper takes this further by looking at vertical
accountability. Do those who are indicted for corruption face consequences at the ballot box?
Horizontal accountability is not the only threat corrupt politicians face. Even if they can avoid
being sent to jail for corruption, they may face the loss of their office through elections. After all, voters
often say that corruption is one of the largest issues facing them. The Philippines, though, is a tough
14
case for vertical accountability. Elections in the Philippines are much more organized around clientelistic
payoffs than policy differences. Parties are weak and transitory with politicians often winning election to
the same office under many different party labels. Instead, voters want politicians to deliver at best pork
and at worst direct payoffs. Will voters in such a system punish corrupt politicians or will they ignore
corruption as long as they get their end? I find that across 10 elections, after the end of the Marcos
The third paper looks at half a million candidates for office and finds that for mayors there is a
statistically significantly lower chance of winning election if they have been indicted for corruption.
Other offices show a lower chance of election if they have been indicted as well, but since the main
target of anti-corruption prosecutions are mayors, the other results lack enough data to be statistically
significant. This result is important because it shows that even in a clientelistic system, and even in a
country with endemic corruption, voters are still not OK with corruption and will punish corrupt
politicians. There are some limits to this, however. First, as shown in the second paper, where dynasties
are concentrated, there are fewer prosecutions for corruption. This means that dynastic concentration
undermines both horizontal accountability and vertical accountability because poor public procurement
contracts on their own are not enough for voters to reject politicians. Second, the third paper shows
that if a candidate is a part of a dynasty with three or more members already in office, their chance of
winning election is so high that being indicted for corruption makes no difference. Voters do punish
corruption, but dynasties can short-circuit both horizontal and vertical accountability.
Conclusion
The three papers that make up this dissertation show how dynasties originate, how they keep their
power, how they allow members to get away with corruption, and how they pervert both horizontal and
15
vertical accountability. Looking at these issues in the Philippines gives us a unique opportunity to
measure the key ideas. The measure of dynasties, especially, isn’t available in other countries. We can
see how the US exacerbated land inequality in the Philippines and then incorporated the large
landholders into the government so that their families were able to keep power even as land became
less important. We can see how those dynasties today work together to prevent prosecutions for
corruption by dropping a cone of silence over areas where they are concentrated. We can see how while
voters will punish politicians known to be corrupt, dynasties can suppress this information and still help
their members get elected. These issues are important in many countries, but in the Philippines, we
don’t just have anecdotal evidence, but can see data to make the picture clear.
This dissertation continues with the papers outlined here, exploring dynastic origins, dynasties
and corruption prosecutions, and prosecutions and elections. Finally, this dissertation ends with a brief
concluding chapter that discusses what we have learned from these papers for both political science and
16
Work Cited
Ali, A. (2016). Do political dynasties hinder development?. IGC working paper reference no. S-89207-
PAK-1.
Auriol, Emmanuelle, Stephane Straub, and Thomas Flochel (2016). “Public Procurement and Rent-
Seeking: The Case of Paraguay”. In: World Development 77, pp. 395–407.
Burgess, R., Jedwab, R., Miguel, E., Morjaria, A., & i Miquel, G. (2015). The value of democracy: evidence
from road building in Kenya. American Economic Review, 105(6), 1817–1851.
Chong, A., De La O, A. L., Karlan, D., & Wantchekon, L. (2015). Does Corruption Information Inspire the
Fight or Quash the Hope? A Field Experiment in Mexico on Voter Turnout, Choice, and Party
Identification. The Journal of Politics, 77(1), 55–71. https://doi.org/10.1086/678766
Coviello, Decio and Stefano Gagliarducci (2010). “Building Political Collusion: Evidence from
Procurement Auctions”. In: IZA Discussion Paper 4939.
De Sousa, L. (2010). Anti-corruption agencies: between empowerment and irrelevance. Crime, law and
social change, 53(1), 5-22.
De Speville, B. (2010). Anticorruption commissions: the “Hong Kong model” revisited. Asia-Pacific
Review, 17(1), 47-71.
De Vries, C. E., & Solaz, H. (2017). The Electoral Consequences of Corruption. Annual Review of Political
Science, 20(1), 391–408. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-polisci-052715-111917
Di Tella, R., & Schargrodsky, E. (2003). The role of wages and auditing during a crackdown on corruption
in the city of Buenos Aires. The Journal of Law and Economics, 46(1), 269-292.
Fazekas, M., Tóth, I. J., & King, L. P. (2016). An objective corruption risk index using public procurement
data. European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research, 22(3), 369-397.
Farrales, M. J. (2005). What is corruption?: A history of corruption studies and the great definitions
debate. A History of Corruption Studies and the Great Definitions Debate (June 2005).
Ferraz, C., & Finan, F. (2008). Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects of Brazil’s Publicly Released Audits
on Electoral Outcomes *. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 703–745.
https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2008.123.2.703
Garces, L., Jandoc, K., & Lu, M. G. (2021). Political Dynasties and Economic Development: Evidence using
Nighttime Light in the Philippines. Philippine Political Science Journal, 41(3), 215-261.
George, S. E., & Ponattu, D. (2017). Understanding the economic impacts of political dynasties: evidence
from India. Unpublished manuscript, 1-58.
17
Geys, B., & Smith, D. M. (2017). Political dynasties in democracies: Causes, consequences and remaining
puzzles.
Gingerich, D. W. (2013). Political institutions and party-directed corruption in South America: Stealing
for the team. Cambridge University Press.
Hooghe, M., & Quintelier, E. (2014). Political participation in European countries: The effect of
authoritarian rule, corruption, lack of good governance and economic downturn. Comparative
European Politics, 12(2), 209–232. https://doi.org/10.1057/cep.2013.3
Klasnja, M., Tucker, J. A., & Deegan-Krause, K. (2014). Pocketbook vs. Sociotropic Corruption Voting.
British Journal of Political Science, 46(1), 67–94. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123414000088
Kurer, O. (2005). Corruption: An alternative approach to its definition and measurement. Political
Studies, 53(1), 222-239.
Kurniadi, B. D. (2019). Defending the Sultan’s Land: Yogyakarta, Control over Land and Aristocratic
Power in Post-Autocratic Indonesia. In A Thesis]. Doctor of Philosophy of the Australian National
University (Issue September).
Main, J. T. (1966). Government by the People: The American Revolution and the Democratization of the
Legislatures. The William and Mary Quarterly, 23(3), 391. https://doi.org/10.2307/1919237
McCoy, A. W. (1994). An anarchy of families: The historiography of state and family in the Philippines. An
Anarchy of Families: State and Family in the Philippines, 1–32.
Mendoza, R. U., Beja Jr, E. L., Venida, V. S., & Yap, D. B. (2016). Political dynasties and poverty:
measurement and evidence of linkages in the Philippines. Oxford Development Studies, 44(2), 189-
201.
Olken, B. A. (2005). Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment. In in Indonesia.” NBER
Working Paper# 11753.
Quah, J. S. T. (2010). Defying institutional failure: learning from the experiences of anti-corruption
agencies in four Asian countries. Crime, Law and Social Change, 53(1), 23–54.
Rafi, A. (2018). Social Reproduction of the Landed Political Elite in Pakistan (Doctoral dissertation,
University of London).
Schütte, S. A. (2012). Against the odds: Anti‐corruption reform in Indonesia. Public Administration and
Development, 32(1), 38-48.
Sidel, J. T. (1999). Capital, coercion, and crime: Bossism in the Philippines. Stanford University Press.
18
Szeftel, Morris (2000). “Between Governance and Under- development: Accumulation and Africa’s
’Catastrophic Corruption’”. In: Review of African Political Economy 27.84, pp. 287–306.
Winters, M. S., & Weitz-Shapiro, R. (2013). Lacking Information or Condoning Corruption: When Do
Voters Support Corrupt Lacking Information or Condoning Corruption When Do Voters Support
Corrupt Politicians? Comparative Politics, 45(4), 418–436.
https://doi.org/10.5129/001041513X13815259182857
Wittman, H. (2009). Reframing agrarian citizenship: Land, life and power in Brazil. Journal of Rural
Studies, 25(1), 120–130. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2008.07.002
19
Entrenching Dynastic Power in the
Philippines
20
“It may be the 21st Century, but in reality, this is still a very feudal society.”
Marites Vitug
Introduction
Dynasties are incredibly central to Filipino politics. In 2016, 81% of governors, 78% of representatives,
and 69% of mayors had a family member in office.1 As Luis Abed (Interview 2019) said, “[political]
parties are essentially an alliance of families.” Dynasties don’t just persist across positions but over time
as well. The former president’s (Benigno Aquino III) mother was president, his father would have been
president if he wasn’t assassinated, his grandfather was a long-time legislative leader, and his great-
grandfather was a general who fought for independence against the Spanish and Americans. While the
Aquinos are very famous, it’s not at all unusual for mayors and governors to have parents and
grandparents who were both in office. Dynasties have been a hindrance to the Philippines. They are
associated with lower growth (Mendoza et al. 2016), worse health outcomes (Braganca et al. 2015), and
protection of corrupt officials from prosecution (Davis forthcoming). But dynasties are not some
immutable aspect of Filipino culture. Political dynasties developed first during the Spanish colonial
period but were able to take deep root thanks to the choices made by the US after taking control of the
Philippines.
This paper examines what allowed political dynasties to take such firm root in the Philippines,
adding to the debate by bringing in new quantitative evidence. The US didn’t necessarily create
powerful families, but the US helped to strengthen and cement those families so that even a century
later they endure. This paper also examines the connection between land and dynasties. While the
power of the landed aristocracy was mostly eclipsed by the commercial and industrial bourgeoisie in the
West, in the Philippines, the end of Spanish domination and the choices made by the US allowed large
1
Ateneo School of Government
21
landholders to entrench themselves. The 18-year period between when the US took over and when the
US handed legislative power to the Filipinos was key in establishing this system of dynastic power. In
addition, the way the US built that new political system, and how that new political system allowed
landholders to turn their economic power into political power, was key to establishing the long-term
power of dynasties.
Censuses taken by the US in 1903, just after the US finished fighting anti-colonialist insurgents in
most of the Philippine’s islands, and in 1918, not long after the US handed over most power to the new
indigenous legislature give a clear view of this critical juncture. These censuses include data on how
many farms of different sizes there were in each province and how much farmland each tranche
includes. With this data on farm distribution, I will show that areas of the Philippines that had more land
inequality in 1918 had a higher concentration of dynasties in the 21st century. Areas where some
families were able to capture a disproportionate share of the land in the early 20th century are areas
where today there is a higher concentration of dynasties. I will also show how areas in the early 20th
century where the US helped wealthy farmers get clear title on their land also saw more dynasties in the
21st century. While the connection between the landed elite and power is well established, this paper
presents the first quantitative evidence of a connection between land inequality and land titling in the
This paper contributes to the literature on critical junctures and incorporation by showing how
the early US colonial period was key in cementing the wealth of large landholders and turning that into
political power. This paper also contributes to the literature on land and dynasties as well as inequality
and dynasties. This is useful for both understanding the Philippines but also for understanding how
power ossifies and how dynasties take hold generally. Finally, this paper will show that even where the
US had good intentions, creating a land titling system, there is clear evidence that it contributed to the
22
The next section begins by describing the key work on dynasties, land inequality, and critical
junctures and how this relates to the evidence at hand. Next, I will outline the development of farming
and land distribution in the Philippines, followed by a discussion of the emerging dynasties during the
period of direct US rule. Then I will outline the data available in the four censuses examined. Finally, I
will conclude by discussing how this data was used, what conclusions can be drawn, and what is left for
future work.
For most of human history, landholding was the same as holding wealth and power. Not surprisingly,
many of the early democratic systems were dominated by large landholders. In the UK, as the monarchy
weakened, the parliament became increasingly dominated by a landed elite of “between six thousand
and ten thousand families” (Jupp 1990, 54). In the UK, the power of these families waned over the 19 th
century as the franchise broadened and a capitalist economic elite, detached from the land, came to
dominate. In 19th century Germany, some political parties were organized around protecting the
economic and social power of the landed elite (Berdahl 1972). In the early US, especially in states that
could support large farms, the landed elite dominated. Main (1966, p.396) describes the members of the
Virginia House of Burgesses on the eve of the American Revolution, saying, “most of them were also
large landholders and the legislature was firmly in control of the great planters.” A decade after the
revolution, “the great landowners still controlled the lower house, though their strength was reduced
While in much of the developed world the increased quality of democracy and the shift in power
to industrial developers weakened these old landholding families, there are many places where they
persist. Nasr (1996) argues that the post-independence government of Pakistan turned to the colonial
23
era landed elite to help shore up the new state. As the landed elite were incorporated into the political
system, they were able to use spoils from that system to maintain their power. Kurniadi (2019) looks at
how in the ancient capital of Jogjakarta in Indonesia, after the autocratic period, it was the elites who
had the most land that were able to reemerge as political bosses. In Brazil, historically, land was given
out to key elites working for the crown. Today less than four percent of people own almost half the
workable land (Wittman 2009). This paper contributes to this work not by being the first to suggest that
the Philippines has problems with dynasties, or that these dynasties were originally based in the land,
but by offering clear quantitative evidence that land inequality and land policies that favor the rich
The Philippines had a colonial system of land ownership under the Spanish, not so different from
other Spanish colonies, but the enormous distance between the Philippines and Spain, and the relative
paucity of resources in the Philippines, meant that Spanish control was always light and there were
relatively few peninsulares even compared to other Spanish possessions. So, the mestizos and the
descendants of the native power holders (all intermarried) dominated even more than other places. This
power was reinforced by US policies that benefited those already in a strong position and then handed
As Pepinsky (2019) notes, we can learn a good deal from the careful analysis of single case
studies, and while this study looks just at the Philippines, we can learn much from this case that applies
broadly. The history of Filipino dynasties is a good example of the importance of critical junctures and
path dependency. In a similar vein to how Acemoglu et al. (2000) looked at colonial institutions and their
effect on the development of modern economies, this paper looks at land inequality in the 1910s and its
effect, a century later, on dynastic stability. This isn’t because things stayed the same for a hundred
years, but because there was a critical juncture around the time of the US takeover of the Philippines. As
Collier and Collier (1991) point out, a crisis usually forms the core of a critical juncture. And just as Collier
24
and Collier identified how labor was incorporated into developing Latin American states as a key critical
juncture with long-running consequences, the way the US took over the Philippines and sought to
incorporate the local elites (economic elites) into a national government was the critical juncture that
The US sought to create significant change in the Philippines, dismantling existing Catholic and
Spanish power structures, sending in thousands of teachers, and opening huge swaths of the country to
farming for the first time. The US sold off an enormous amount of land, but mostly those already in a
strong position were able to benefit. The US turned over significant power to an elected Philippines
legislature by 1916. This enabled those who benefited economically from the changes made by the US
to build their political power. Between 1903 and 1918, we see large changes in the distribution of
farmland and a huge increase in the total amount of farming. What we also see is a stronger correlation
between land inequality and the later presence of a high concentration of dynasties. The US land reform
policies benefited the well-off and the US land titling initiative helped those who were already well-off
to secure their place. The US then incorporated those elites into the new political system in such a way
that they could turn their economic power into political power and their political power back into
This paper also contributes to the examination of dynasties in the Philippines specifically. There
is a significant amount of quantitative work on dynasties in the Philippines (Mendoza et al. 2016,
Querubin 2013, Labonne et al. 2019, Dulay 2021 to name a few), but it almost entirely focuses on the
effects and control of dynasties rather than their origins. Tadem and Tadem (2016) as well as McCoy
(1994) and Sidel (1999) suggest that the US played a key role in allowing the creation of powerful
dynasties, but their accounts are purely historical and descriptive. Maurer and Iyer (2008) look at land
25
This paper addresses the origins of dynasties in the Philippines and provides specific evidence
that supports the conclusion that the US played a large role in allowing the dynasties to develop. This
analysis also gives us more leverage on some of the chicken and egg problems that plague research into
dynasties. As Mendoza et al. (2015) note, it is an open-ended question if dynasties are a cause of or
result of poor development. This is also a question more broadly in research on inequality and
corruption (Jong-Sung and Khagram 2005). Williamson (2017) further notes that there is surprisingly
little research into the whole history of inequality in the Philippines despite the existence of these
censuses from the early 20th century. This paper helps to answer both questions. First, by looking at how
existing land inequality is associated with more powerful dynasties a century later, this paper suggests
that inequality can lead to dynasties rather than dynasties just leading to inequality. Second, since we
also know that dynasties can reinforce economic inequality and poverty, this research helps show how
land inequality in the early 20th century can lead to wealth inequality much later.
This paper also contributes to the literature on land inequality and land redistribution more
generally. From the beginning of the US colonial period, there was a recognition that the Philippines
suffered from significant land inequality issues and that something should be done. The first US
governor-general, Willian Howard Taft [before he was president], made that a major US aim. However,
subsequent governors-general didn’t share his focus. Between the 1903 and 1918 censuses the US tried
to enact land reform. It has largely been seen as a failure (You 2014), and by comparing land inequality
One of the major questions in the study of land inequality is the significance of geography or
factor endowments, as well as the importance of colonial institutions (Framkema 2009). Here we have a
snapshot right at the end of the Spanish period (the census of 1903), right before the US transfers a lot
of power (the census of 1918), and after two decades of mostly home rule but before the US left (1939
and 1948). Land inequality and distribution changed a lot over this period, and it shows the importance
26
of changes in institutions. The US ended up advocating different land redistribution policies in other
Asian countries it had influence over. You (2014) explains that after World War II the US feared
communist sympathies in Taiwan and South Korea and pushed both to enact broad land reform. In both
countries, land inequality decreased substantially over the next ten years. In the Philippines there was
an armed struggle for land reform, the Huk rebellion. The Huk rebellion started as a fight against
Japanese occupation, but with the end of World War II became a broader peasant rebellion. However,
with the defeat of the Huk the threat of violent land appropriation by the peasants ended, the landed
elite retrenched, and land inequality remained high. Land reform could have been a huge boon. Race
(1972, p17) notes that in South Vietnam land redistribution attempts that simply “created hatred and
bitterness between landlord and tenant.” Instead it was the Viet Cong who successfully redistributed
This paper also examines the relationship between land inequality and the prevalence of export
crops. Von Braun et al. (1989) look at Guatemala and find that the presence of more export crops, as
well as better prices for those crops, exacerbate land inequality. This makes intuitive sense, as large
landholders don’t need subsistence farming, so they should move toward whatever will make the most
money. In addition, as they become more successful, they should be able to buy up more land to
increase profits. However, when looking at the Philippines I don’t find this same connection. I initially
suspected that export crops were associated with more dynasties, but that isn’t the case. This could be
Finally, this paper contributes to the literature on colonial institutions and corruption. Acemoglu
et al. (2000) look at settler fatalities, but the crux of their story is the importance of the institutions
developed by colonial powers. Extractive states (where few colonists could live) simply stole everything
that wasn’t nailed down and developed institutions to legitimize this theft. The example par excellence
is Peru with its enormous silver mines and modern underdevelopment. In the literature, British, or
27
sometimes French, colonies are usually seen as having legacies that promote more useful institutional
development (Bernhard et al. 2004). The British legal code is also seen as a benefit to its former colonies
which has helped with development (Daniels et al. 2011). It was two former British colonies, Hong Kong
and Singapore, that developed a lot of the modern tools for fighting corruption. Lange et al. (2006)
argue that places colonized by Spain, specifically, end up worse off than other countries with colonial
pasts.
The Philippines offers a unique opportunity to examine these colonial legacies. The Philippines
was for some 330 years a Spanish colony. It exhibits many of the problems that might be associated with
that colonial legacy. It is underdeveloped, has high corruption, and has weak rule of law. However, the
Philippines was also a US colony for 48 years. The US specifically engaged in a process of trying to build a
new political system modeled on its own, and therefore partially on the British, system. This paper looks
at how the US inherited a legacy of land inequality, but instead of reducing the problem, pushed for new
institutions which incorporated political dynasties in a way that has negatively shaped the Philippines
since. It wasn’t so much the Spanish institutions that led to the long-running problem, but that the US
The economic value of the Philippines to both Spanish and American colonial rulers was mostly
in agriculture. The Philippines has one of the largest gold reserves in the world, but even today little to
none has been successfully extracted. Bauzon (1975, p.1) notes that while it’s unclear whether private
land ownership existed before the arrival of the Spanish, it was certainly part of Spanish large-scale
farming and the introduction of cash crops. Sobritchea (1981, p.18) describes farming before the
Spanish, noting that “land in precolonial times, especially areas used for wood and grazing, was
28
considered a communal resource.” The pre-Spanish form of land ownership was largely collective and
not subject to intensive farming. The Philippines was also considered underpopulated even as late as
1900 when the US took over and farmland was not in short supply.
The Spanish also instituted land tenure systems that hugely disadvantaged the natives. Several
systems, all similar in effect to sharecropping, made many native Filipinos pay to use ancestral land or
reduced even successful farmers to near destitution (Bauzon 1975, p.4-7). This also increasingly saw
land consolidated into large holdings. Bauzon (p.9) explains, “the Spanish Government consciously
encouraged growth and development of haciendas precisely because of its desire to promote and foster
an export economy in the Philippines.” This was a major source of resentment against the Spanish that
The US took note of this problem immediately. The former Spanish government, though, was
not the only large landholder. Beyond rich mestizos, the Catholic Church (through local friars) held a
great deal of land and acted as landlords. Roth (1977) notes that the friars took on the role of not only
priest, but also of teacher, mayor, landlord, and judge. For many Filipinos, the friars were their only real
experience of the Spanish government. The US did not want to share power with the friars but the
treaty the US signed with Spain bound them to respect existing property rights in seized territory,
specifically including those of the Church. The US negotiated with the Vatican to buy the friars’ lands,
paying as much for them as it had, adjusted for inflation, when buying Alaska from Russia. The initial
plan was to redistribute the land to reduce rural unrest and lower land inequality. This was largely a
failure. Bauzon (1975) explains that the plan failed because the US did not support the ability of poor
Filipinos to successfully buy or work the land. Those already with money were able to purchase the land,
29
The US took over a country with significant problems relating to landholdings and essentially
made things worse. The end of Spanish colonialism could have been a huge boon for the poor. There
was land available to the government, but the poor got very little. As we will see later in this paper there
was a huge increase in the number of small farms in the early US period, but they worked an incredibly
small amount of land. Instead, the US cemented the power of those already on top. Bauzon (p.15) adds,
“A measure of how utterly the Americans failed in their handling of the agricultural question can be seen
in the increased frequency of rural conflict in the 1920s and the 1930s, culminating in the outbreak of
The friar lands didn’t end up going to the poor for several reasons. First, it was too expensive.
The purchase of the friar lands was backed by a loan from a New York bank that the new government of
the islands was responsible for (Ventura 2016, p.466). This created an incentive to sell off lands to those
who already had money. Second, the government wanted the land surveyed before selling it, a slow
process (p.467). Even where land was offered theoretically for free as part of a homestead program,
there were costs associated with surveying and applying that were unaffordable to the poor (p.469).
Third, distrust of the government ran high. Farmers asked why they should apply for title to the land
they had worked from time immemorial. Fourth, the program was not suited to local conditions. A
disease had killed off many of the water buffalo in the Philippines at this time so some who may have
been able to pay off loans for new land were unable to (p.470). Finally, the program was undermined by
its supervisors. The US governor-general thought that largescale farming would be in the interest of the
Philippines. Congress scolded the program administrators for not divvying up large tracts of land as the
law ordered, but to little effect (p.472). The governor-general was thus quick to call the program a
failure and place the blame on the Filipinos. By 1918 two-thirds of the friar lands had been sold off
(Maurer and Iyer, 2008). The census results we will see in 1918, then, already contain the effects of this
30
It wasn’t only in the distribution of the friar lands that the early agricultural policies failed to
help. The US also saw that most Filipinos didn’t have clear title to the land they worked. Even in areas
that had not been part of any hacienda system, historical systems of communal ownership left most
smallholders with no clear title to their farms. To alleviate this problem, the US tried to create a land
titling (or Torrens) system. This included the right of ownership conveyed on those without clear deed
who worked the land, modeled in part on the US’s history of homesteading. However, a land titling
system that could have prevented the abuses of land grabbing that had plagued the Spanish era only
benefited those with the money and connections to take advantage of the system. Like the distribution
of the friar lands, getting a Torrens title took money, time, and often a more sophisticated used of the
courts. This wasn’t difficult for the wealthier and better educated, but for the poor, those most in need
of clear title to prevent abuses, titles were hard to come by. Unlike the friar lands which had been sold
off, Torrens titles were still rare by 1918. Only 4.5% of land parcels had Torrens titles by 1918 (Maurer
and Iyer, 2008). Later in the paper, I will examine how areas that saw a higher rate of Torrens titles
Even with all these problems, the amount of farmland increased hugely in the early US years,
from about 1.3 million hectares to about 2.4 million hectares farmed. The number of farms increased
even more from about 800,000 to about 1.9 million. This is partially a result of the US loosening controls
on public lands. As Iyer and Maurer (2008) note, the cost of not having a clear title in the early US period
was not very high. There wasn’t a great likelihood of being forced off the land in this period. The poor
took some public land without title while the rich cemented their control by gaining clear legal title, the
The US also tried to keep American land ownership limited. Anti-colonialist forces in the US
Congress pressed for a restriction on the amount of land American corporations could own.
Corporations were limited to 1024 hectares (Iyer and Maurer 2008). Homesteading in the Philippines
31
was also theoretically open to individual Americans, but very few took advantage (McDiarmid 1955,
p.860). In the end, the Philippines kept laws restricting corporate ownership throughout and after the
US colonial period. Despite some fears, there was not a run of “American absentee land ownership” (p.
886). It was the powerful families in the Philippines, not US corporations, that were the center of
The US opened free trade with the Philippines after taking colonial possession, opening a huge
new market for agricultural exports. This was strongly in the interests of the Filipino elites. With the
Spanish and the friars removed, the elite were those Filipinos who had owned significant land before.
There was almost no mercantile elite at this point. Iglesias (2003) notes that the short-lived First
Philippines Republic (1889-1901) restricted suffrage to the landed and proposed to give them the friar
lands. Bauzon (1975, p.18) describes how the elite of the Philippines worked with and benefited from US
colonial control:
[…] in 1900-1901, elite collaborators helped the Americans initiate a counter-revolution, thus
doing a great disservice to the good and noble men who fought and died for Filipino liberty and
again all forms of tyranny. In 1907, after American political changes enabled them to acquire
positions of influence and authority in the colonial government, their very first act on the very
first day of the session of the Philippines National Assembly was to pass a resolution increasing
their personal allowances and remunerations. Throughout the existence of the National
Assembly, their legislation record in social welfare was zero. In 1909-10, when free trade was
being established between the Philippines and the United States, they publicly opposed free
trade, but only for electoral popularity since in private they supported free trade for the simple
reason that it meant an economic windfall for them as landlords and as producers-exporters of
cash crops. Their economic prosperity due to free trade made them oppose Philippine
independence in the 1920s and in the 1930s because it meant the termination of free trade, and
thus an end to their enormous profits.
The elite of the Philippines benefited from the US takeover in many ways. First, the US opened up
farming by selling off lands to the elite who could afford it. Second, the US interest in land titling only
benefited those who were already in a good position. Finally, free trade with the US and the resultant
boom in exports benefited those with large export-oriented plantations. In addition, the US, thanks to at
least some republican impulses, quickly devolved power to Filipinos. But in doing this at the same time
32
as they were giving more and more economic advantages to that same group, the US ensured that the
landed elite would politically dominate the country instead of just economically dominating it. The US
inherited a system with huge issues of land inequality and despite some good intentions made things
worse.
This is the first part of the reason why the early US period was a key critical juncture in the
building of dynasties in the Philippines. The US adopted land policies that saw the rich gain land and,
even more important, formal recognition of their land and economic power. This new elite was always
going to be powerful, but the US incorporated them into a new political system that helped the landed
elite turn economic power into political power. This political power then became part of a self-
sustaining cycle where the elite could use political power to generate rents and rents to build political
support.
Before moving on to discuss how the landlords were incorporated into the political system, I will
discuss the issues and changes in farming in the Philippines. The Philippines is mostly tropical, but it
stretches for more than 1,100 miles north to south. This means there are different climates on different
islands. For example, tobacco (which was a key export crop in 1903 but fell off quickly later) is only
grown in the very far north. Sugarcane, on the other hand, is grown in several places but is heavily
concentrated in the middle islands. Abaca, or Manila Hemp, is grown mostly on the northern island of
Luzon. Coconuts are grown mainly on the southern islands. The staple food crops of the Philippines are
rice and corn, depending on the island. Some of this is due to climate and some due to tradition. Some
areas consume both. Despite growing a significant amount of rice, the Philippines has always been a net
rice importer.
Animals are also raised in the Philippines for food or as agricultural tools but not in significant
numbers compared to farming. During several periods in the first half of the twentieth century, animal
33
diseases devastated populations. Right around the time when the US was taking over, a huge number of
the water buffalo used in farming were dying. During this period the Philippines exported only
agricultural products to any significant degree. Even in agriculture, only three or four crops were being
exported: Abaca, sugar, coconuts, and tobacco. Abaca began as the largest export but fell off as sugar
rose. Tobacco was the fourth and eventually declined to almost no exports. In the later 20th century,
coconuts would become increasingly important and Abaca, used to make ropes, would decline.
Table 1
Table 1 shows a quick comparison of farming over the four periods I examine. A few key changes
jump out. From 1903 to 1939 there is huge growth in the amount of land farmed. The amount of land
farmed more than triples. During this same period, there was significant population growth but less than
the growth in the area farmed. The growth in farm area versus population is even more significant
between 1903 and 1918. The farmed area nearly doubles while the population increases by about 30%.
The number of farms more than doubles between 1903 and 1918 but after that decreases and remains
flat. This could be the result of pent-up demand to have any farm for those left landless under the
Spanish. The contraction after 1918, though, even as farm area grew, suggests that it was no longer as
The Gini coefficient for land inequality is similar in 1903 and 1918 and decreases significantly in
1939 and 1948. The decrease between 1918 and 1939 is driven by the fact that the number of farms
34
decreased slightly while the total area increased. Those gains went primarily to middle-sized farms.
Direct size by size comparisons are difficult because what sizes the census takers decided to group farms
into changed greatly between censuses. The 1939 census has very different size categories from the
other three. Looking at the 1903 and 1918 censuses (with some combining2) a direct comparison is
possible.
Charts 1 and 2 show the changes between 1903 and 1918. Chart 1 shows how significant the
increase in small farms was. In 1903 there were 291,007 farms under .35 hectares. In 1918 there were
930,853. Those starting new farms were almost all in the smallest three tranches. Many people were
starting new farms but the area they covered remained minuscule. Chart 2 shows that despite the
changes in the number of farms and the amount of land farmed, the pattern of land ownership
remained very similar. In terms of farmed area, most area was farmed in mid-sized farms, while the
largest few had a very disproportionate share of land. In terms of the number of farms, the smallest
farms made up a huge share. In 1918, 930,853 farms worked only 164,761 hectares while just 2,646
farms worked 284,440 hectares. The largest farms were well entrenched and while their overall
dominance didn’t change, they benefited from changes in land titling as well.
2
For example, in 1903 there are categories for farm between 2 and 3 hectares and 3 and 5 hectares, while in 1918
it is just farms between 2 and 5 hectares.
35
Chart 1
Chart 2
600,000
500,000
400,000
300,000
200,000
100,000
-
Under .35 Between 1 and 2 Ha. 2 and 5 Ha. 5 and 10 Ha. 10 and 15 15 and 30 30 and 50 Over 50 Ha
Ha. .35 and 1 Ha. Ha. Ha.
Ha.
1903 Ha Farmed 1918 Ha Farmed
36
Political Incorporation: Emerging and Enduring Dynasties in the Philippines
While the landed elite had existed under the Spanish, they weren’t the ones holding key political power.
In much of what is now the Philippines, there was little central authority of any kind. The southern
islands were always more independent and in many respects it wasn’t until after the US takeover that
the whole of the Philippines was administered from Manila. The landed elite, though, had economic
power already under the Spanish. McCoy (1993, p. xii-xiv) writes, “Although Spanish colonials restricted
Filipino participation in governance, their colonial regime presided over a period of marked growth in
the mid-nineteenth century that, by default if nothing else, enriched Filipino landholders and urban
merchants.” As the previous section discussed, these landlords were further empowered by the changes
Economic power in land, though, was not a guaranty that landowners would emerge as
dominant political actors. The emerging landed elite were able to use political changes brought by the
US conquest to turn their increasing economic power into political power. Anderson (1988, p.11-12)
walks through how the US interest in developing power quickly entrenched the new ruling class:
But it was above all the political innovations of the Americans that created a solid, visible
‘national oligarchy’. The key institutional change was the stage-by-stage creation of a Congress-
style bicameral legislature, based, in the lower house at least, on single-district, winner-take-all
elections. The new representational system proved perfectly adapted to the ambitions and social
geography of the mestizo nouveaux riches. Their economic base lay in hacienda agriculture, not
in the capital city. And their provincial fiefdoms were also protected by the country’s immense
linguistic diversity. They might all speak the elite, ‘national’ language (Spanish, later American),
but they also spoke variously Tagalog, Ilocano, Pampango, Cebuano, Ilongo, and a dozen other
tongues. In this way competition in any given electoral district was effectively limited, in a pre-
television age, to a handful of rival local caciques. But Congress, which thus offered them
guaranteed access to national-level political power, also brought them together in the capital on
a regular basis. There, more than at any previous time, they got to know one another well in a
civilized ‘ring’ sternly refereed by the Americans. They might dislike one another, but they went
to the same receptions, attended the same churches, lived in the same residential areas,
shopped in the same fashionable streets, had affairs with each other’s wives, and arranged
marriages between each other’s children. They were for the first time forming a self-conscious
ruling class.
[…]
37
One final feature of the American political system is worth emphasizing: the huge proliferation of
provincial and local elective offices—in the absence of an autocratic territorial bureaucracy. From
very early on mestizo caciques understood that these offices, in the right hands, could
consolidate their local political fiefdoms. Not unexpectedly, the right hands were those of family
and friends. Brothers, uncles, and cousins for the senior posts, sons and nephews for the junior
ones. Here is the origin of the ‘political dynasties’—among them the Aquinos and Cojuangcos—
which make Filipino politics so spectacularly different from those of any other country in
Southeast Asia
The US effectively created a plethora of local offices that the large landholders, now more entrenched
thanks to US land sales and Torrens titling, could dominate. The US started creating local administration,
and holding local elections, as soon as they had pacified areas, even as the US fought to conquer other
The US expanded local elections as more territory was conquered. The elections, though, had a
very limited franchise. Voters had to own property or had to have been in the government under the
Spanish. Teehankee (2002) also notes that elections were conducted only on the municipal level initially.
Provincial governors and boards were elected indirectly by municipal councils. This meant that power
was heavily in the hands of those local elites, who were at this same time benefiting from land sales and
land titling. The first national elections were held in 1907. These were only for a lower house of the
Philippines legislature with the upper house being the Philippines Commission, who were appointed by
the US and under the supervision of the US governor-general. The lower house could pass laws, but they
could and were vetoed by the Philippines Commission such as when the lower house tried to
decriminalize calling for the Philippines’ independence. The 1907 elections saw only 1.1% (Teehankee
2002) of the population registered to vote; that number expanded slowly with each subsequent
election. In 1916, the US disbanded the Philippines Commission and allowed elections for both an upper
and lower chamber of the Philippines legislature. The governor-general remained the executive until
38
So, elections started right after the US conquest and by 1916 the electoral system had most of
the elements it has today. Elections started very locally and with a highly restricted franchise. This gave
the elite the first advantage in getting into office. Jurado (1977) compiled data on early elections and the
franchise. Unfortunately, data is not available for every election year. In 1909 5.2% of the population
over 21 was registered to vote, and in 1912, 5.9%. Here the data skips to 1935, where the number has
risen to 24.5%. After World War II and with independence, the number rises rapidly: 37% in 1946, 52.5%
1947, and 60% in 1949. What’s clear from this is that the franchise was quite limited until late in the US
The US not only started expanding the number of elected positions; in 1912, the new American
governor-general pushed for as much power devolution as possible in the civil service. He limited
executive power and even lowered civil service salaries to force out American bureaucrats so they could
be replaced by native Filipinos (Abinales and Amoroso 2005, p.139). The new political power of the
elected and appointed Filipinos, who came largely from the landholders, could be turned again into
There were two sources of largesse. First was the state itself. Through the “spoils” system,
Filipino politicians distributed offices (and their corresponding budgetary allocations) to relatives
and supporters. Political appointment of kin, allies, and cronies became standard practice, with
entry into government assured by the backing of a powerful politician. In exchange, an appointee
facilitated the business success of his patron and protected other members of his network within
the bureaucracy.
The other path to material enrichment was the extension of the spoils system into the
economy. Here the vehicles were state corporations established to promote colonial economic
development. The Philippines National Bank (PNB), for example, created by the Assembly to
finance sugar production and exportation, was taken over by Serigo Osmena “in violation of
every principle which prudence, intelligence and even honesty could dictate.” Osmena used
appointment to the PNB’s offices to repay political debts, without regard for appointees’
knowledge of the sugar industry or bank management.
Thus, the landholders had found political power and through political power more economic power. This
closed out the critical juncture. The US had opened a period of sweeping political change and
incorporated the Filipinos into the government in such a way that the landed elite, who the US had also
39
helped substantially, now controlled the government. Using this power, the elite could turn
governmental power into rents such that they weren’t as reliant on land anymore. The progression had
been from land to wealth to local power to national power. But once the landlords ran the government,
they only needed to turn power into rents and rents back into power to become self-sustaining. Land
itself became less important. We see a reduction of land inequality in the late US period, but by this time
the political elite, the early landholders, were well established and economically diversified. This process
survived numerous changes in regime as the elite were able to protect their core interests.
This is not to say that it was just national power that mattered. Hutchcroft (2000) points out that
national power, especially in this era, was always a lot weaker than local power. The national
government provided an opportunity for local elites to create patronage opportunities that helped them
secure their local power. As Hutchcroft notes (p. 279), “the quest for self-government [in the early
American era] became nearly synonymous with the quest for local autonomy, national legislative
authority, and patronage opportunities.” The US initially hoped that increased education and civil
society would undercut the power of these local elites and make the Philippines more democratic, but
During World War 2, Japan conquered the Philippines, leading to a difficult occupation and
eventual uprising among the peasantry (the Huk Rebellion) that lasted well after the Japanese left. Many
powerful figures collaborated with the Japanese who, in exchange, did not upset the overall power of
the elite (Anderson 1988). The US also didn’t punish the elite who had worked with Japan. Anderson
(p.14) notes that “One might have expected the returning Americans to punish the oligarchs for their
collaboration with the enemy. Senior officials in Washington indeed made noises to this effect. But the
on-the-spot Liberator was, of course, MacArthur, who had close personal and business ties with the
prewar oligarchy.”
40
After the war things fell even more into the hands of the oligarchy. They used the same tactics
but with the addition of political violence (Anderson 1988 p.15). Anderson (p.16) shows how after the
US left there was a change in the source of economic wealth, but it benefited those already in power:
The period 1954–1972 can be regarded as the full heyday of cacique democracy in the
Philippines. The oligarchy faced no serious domestic challenges. Access to the American market
was declining as post-independence tariff barriers slowly rose, but this setback was compensated
for by full access to the state’s financial instrumentalities. Under the guise of promoting
economic independence and import-substitution industrialization, exchange rates were
manipulated, monopolistic licenses parceled out, huge, cheap, often unrepaid bank loans passed
around, and the national budget frittered away in pork barrel legislation. Some of the more
enterprising dynasties diversified into urban real estate, hotels, utilities, insurance, the mass
media, and so forth.
The oligarchy sailed on now firmly in control of the state. The biggest challenge to their power didn’t
come from reform but from a new form of autocracy. The Marcoses were local landlords and
powerholders back to the Spanish period but were a minor family before Ferdinand Marcos. Marcos
attacked the oligarchy not because he was a reformer but because he wanted to centralize all power
onto himself. No man, though, rules alone. Marcos didn’t have the power to remove all the oligarchs, so
he created a policy of working with some and attacking others. The result was some changeover in who
the oligarchs were, but many families persisted, and the powerful dynastic system rolled on (Tadem and
Tadem 2016).
Post Marcos, the new constitution contained a provision aimed at limiting the power of
dynasties, which reads, “The State shall guarantee equal access to opportunities for public service, and
prohibit political dynasties as may be defined by law.” However, this has not been operationalized by
the Congress (Mendoza et al. 2019). Today in the Philippines, the majority of congressmen, governors,
and a high percent of mayors have a relative in office at the same time. The current constitution has not
Those who were in a strong position in the late Spanish era were able to grab up not only
economic but also political power under the new American administration. As America pulled back,
41
those same people were able to cement their power over the government and use that to build even
more economic power. They created a self-sustaining system where political power led to money, which
led to more power. They held onto this power through the Japanese occupation, the end of American
rule, the Marcos dictatorship, and still have it today. Most of these families no longer look to the land
for their economic security, but this dynastic system had its roots in the ability of some families to
consolidate their landholdings. The early US period was the critical juncture. The US, intentionally or not,
secured the economic base of the landed elite and then handed them political power. If this argument is
correct, we should be able to observe a correlation between the land distribution and land titling of the
early 20th century and the concentration of dynasties today. The rest of this paper will show how census
data supports the idea that it was where landed elites thrived and in areas where the US Torrens system
helped them secure their power in the early 20th century that dynasties today are most concentrated.
Data
In this section I will explain how different censuses collected different information about farming in the
Philippines. All four censuses collected information on the number of farms of different sizes and how
much land all those farms, as a group, occupied. This is what is required to make a measure of land
inequality. I will also detail how provinces themselves changed over this period and the difference
between provinces today and in the early 20th century. Finally, I will detail how dynasty concentration in
The 1903 census started just a few years after the US had taken the Philippines from Spain, and
less than two years after the end of major fighting against guerrilla forces opposing colonization. The
1903 census was conducted in an environment in which the US had not yet secured control over all
parts of the country. The Spanish never really had much control over the southern and southwest
42
islands of the Philippines, and the US fought against guerrilla forces there into the early 1910s. The 1903
census (vol 1, p.22) notes that in some areas it was necessary for armed guards to accompany census
enumerators. The 1903 census also notes the difficulty in dealing with some tribes and with the “Moro”
people of the southern islands (vol 1, p.23). The 1903 census says that their main strategy to get an
accurate census was to include governors and local powerholders in the process. Under the Spanish,
censuses had been used mostly for tax collection, so were opposed and undermined at every level. The
US leaders spent a great deal of effort bringing the Filipino leaders onboard and issuing notices and
proclamations about how this census would not be used for taxes or military conscription. The census
describes the process as successful, and Ariffin (2019) notes that the US used the census to build
stronger relations with the Filipino elite by employing them in data collection and organization.
The 1903 census explains that while they were able to get a direct headcount in most of the
Christian part of the Philippines, which was not the region with the ongoing guerilla war, they had more
issues in other places. The 1903 census notes that when they couldn’t get a direct count, they would
sometimes count houses, as some communities would take to the hills at their approach, and in some
cases census takers would ask neighboring communities (vol 1, p.20-24). The census describes a few
procedures used that give the impression they were trying whatever seemed to work. This raises
questions about the veracity of the 1903 census for some areas. Unfortunately, there is no record of
which areas exactly gave them the most trouble. A few areas are simply not included, but mostly for any
area there is data in the 1903 census. By the time of the 1918 census, however, these problems had
been overcome. There was no longer an active insurgency and the government had expanded and was
more accepted in even the remote parts of the Philippines. The 1918 census was able to reach even
remote areas that had been hard to contact in 1903 (1918 census vol 1, p.17). By the time of the 1939
43
The four censuses collected somewhat different supporting information. All four collected data
on landholdings and crop types by province. The 1918 census collected data on land titling that was not
collected in any other census. This reveals the effect of the Torrens titles, but can’t be compared across
time. Starting in 1939, the census includes information on the value of farm equipment in the same size
categories as the data on land ownership. From this, for the 1939 and 1948 censuses, I can also
construct a Gini measure of farm equipment inequality. As noted above, the four censuses use different
intervals for reporting on the sizes of farms. For example, the 1903 census has a 2-to-3-hectare tranche
and a 3-to-5-hectare tranche while the 1918 census has a 2-to-5-hectare tranche. The 1939 census is an
outlier, eliminating the larger tranches to include many smaller ones. However, this isn’t a problem in
calculating the Gini coefficient because Gini is a measure of how concentrated wealth (or in this case
land) is. Chart 3 below shows the Lorenz Curve for 1903. The orange line is the cumulative percentage of
farms and the amount of land those farms occupy. From this, we can see that 10% of the farms account
for more than 50% of the total farmland in 1903. The blue line would be a perfectly equal distribution of
land. The space between the blue and orange line, compared to just the area under the blue line, is the
Gini.
44
Chart 3
0.9
0.8
Percent of Farm Land
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
Percent of Farms
Early 20th century provinces aren’t the same as the current provinces. Between 1903 and 2020,
the Philippines doubled the number of provinces. Fortunately, the way new provinces were almost
always created was by splitting large provinces into pieces. For example, the large southern island of
Mindanao, pictured below, originally contained just five provinces. The Davao Region (in the bottom
right of the picture) was, in 1903, one province called Davao. Davao, though, conformed to the
combined borders of the five modern provinces that succeeded it. There are one or two exceptions, but
for the most part, you can compare one province in the first half of the 20th century directly to its
successor provinces.
45
This means that I had to combine the dynasty concentration or divide the land inequality. For
example, I could take all five provinces that make up the old province of Davao and average the dynasty
concentration between them (weighted for population) and compare that to the land inequality in an
earlier period. Alternatively, I could compare the dynasty concentration of each modern province to the
land inequality of the whole old province. Each method has some drawbacks. I lose some nuance by
averaging dynastic concentration. However, since the dynasty concentration is a measure of how many
seats are held by families, there is no reason it can’t be averaged over a larger region. Treating each
modern province as separate but using one land inequality measure for a large area ignores the issue
that I don’t know how land inequality varied over each section of the old province. In the end, I tried
both methods. Combining modern provinces produced the clearest results, but for 1918 both methods
I measure dynasties based on the work of Mendoza et al. (2016) who code a dynasty as two or
more family members in office in a province at the same time. Because of unique naming conventions
introduced by the Spanish, two people from the same province with the same family name are very
46
likely to be related. In addition, dynasties in the Philippines, while powerful, almost always are centered
on just one province. Therefore, the Philippines offers a unique case where dynasties can be measured
directly from election records. If there are 10 people named Ampatuan elected in the province of
Maguindanao we can say with a high degree of confidence that they have a ten-person dynasty. For
dynastic concentration I also follow Mendoza et al. and use the econometric measure HHI (Herfindahl–
Hirschman Index) created to measure market concentration. The HHI measure takes the share of seats
held by each family, squares them, and adds them together. So, if there are three dynasties in a
province holding 5% of the seats, each the HHI would be 75 (5^2 + 5^2 + 5^2).
So, what does this all look like? Below I have a map showing the 1918 land inequality by
province and the modern dynasty concentration (HHI) averaged across those same provinces. The lines
on the map are the modern provinces, but you can see the 1918 provinces by looking at areas that are
the same color. The correlation here isn’t visually apparent, partially because it is necessary to control
for the widely different populations of the provinces, but some similarities can be seen. In the southeast
of both maps, the old province of Davao can be seen to have above-average land inequality in 1918 and
high dynasty concentration in the 21st century. Zamboanga, to the north-west of Davao on the same
island, has lower than average land inequality in 1918 and lower than average dynasty concentration
today. In the next section, I will detail how the more precise statistical comparisons were made.
47
Chart 4
Methods
As noted above, the biggest challenge when comparing land inequality in 1903-1948 and dynasty
concentration today is the differences in the provinces. To deal with this I ran all the regressions by first
comparing land inequality in early 20th century provinces to the average dynastic concentration of their
modern successor provinces. Second, I ran the regressions by comparing the land dynastic concentration
of each modern province with the land inequality of the larger province it was a part of in the early 20th
century. The first method makes more sense since it isn’t necessary to assume that all the modern
successor provinces had the same land inequality as their early 20th century progenitors. To combine
modern provinces into early 20th century provinces I took an average of each province’s HHI weighted by
the number of seats in a province, which is a function of population. I also ran regressions looking at the
effect of Torrens titles on dynastic concentration and if they interacted with land inequality. The HHI
measure is the dependent variable as the theory is that changes in land inequality and more Torrens
48
titles in the early 20th century would lead to change in dynastic concentration today. To avoid over-
emphasizing the effects of any one election, I average HHI for the last 5 elections for each province.
I also used three controls for all the models. First, I controlled for the number of seats available
for election in the modern province (or the total if combining provinces). This controlled for the different
sizes of provinces today. Second, I controlled for the number of hectares farmed in the early 20th century
province. This controlled for the size of provinces in the past. Finally, I added a control for land devoted
to the key export crops (Abaca, sugar, coconuts, and in some periods tobacco). My concern was that
areas which could grow more export crops might be more subject to elite capture since the farming was
more profitable (though this does not turn out to be the case). I combined the amount of land farmed in
all three or four crops (tobacco drops off as an export) to save some degrees of freedom. Due to the
small number of provinces in the early 20th century, all the regressions are a bit underpowered. I never
have more than 45-50 degrees of freedom. I have a few more rows than provinces because the 1903
and 1918 count “subprovinces,” which were large areas nominally under the control of another
province, as separate areas. All the subprovinces from 1903 and 1918 eventually became their own
provinces.
For the 1939 and 1948 censuses, I also try a Gini coefficient for the inequality in farm equipment
for each province. Starting in 1939 the censuses recorded the value of farm equipment owned by each
of the tranches of farms. In the same way I created a land inequality Gini, I created one for the
inequality in farm equipment. Finally, in the 1948 census, they only reported tranches of farms by total
land area, not land area farmed. That means some farms were very big but farmed little land. I still
calculate the Gini based on farmed land, not just owned land, but in the 1948 census these throw off the
tranches a little. It shouldn’t throw off the data too much since farms are still roughly organized into the
same categories. Also given the similarities in the underlying data and results between 1939 and 1948,
49
Results and Discussion
I will begin by walking through the result for each of the four censuses. For each census, the models are
divided between those comparing land inequality in early 20th century provinces to modern provinces by
averaging across the old province and those models that split up the land inequality across the modern
provinces. For example, I could compare land inequality in the early 20th century province of Davao to
the average dynastic concentration of all Davao’s modern successor provinces (I label this “Old
Provinces” below). Alternatively, I could compare the land inequality of all the early 20th century
province of Davao to the dynastic concentration of each modern successor province (I label this
“Modern Provinces” below). The first way requires averaging modern dynastic concentration; the
second assumes the land inequality was the same in all parts of the old provinces. The first way makes
more sense because it doesn’t involve assuming each part of the old provinces had the same inequality.
Table 3 reports the results for the 1903 census. Models 1 and 4 look at land inequality with no
controls. The results are not statistically significant. Models 2 and 5 look at the correlation with the
proper controls. Neither result is significant. Models 4 and 5 have the sign going in the wrong direction,
i.e., more land inequality is associated with less dynastic concentration. These are the only regressions
where this happens. I have no explanation for it except random variation. Model 3 is a unique one that I
only try for the 1903 census where instead of using the Gini to measure land inequality, I use the
number of large farms (greater than 50 hectares) in each province. This has the correct sign and a p-
value of .1. This suggests that there is likely some connection between large farms and later dynasties,
but a weak one. Given how things hadn’t taken their modern form by 1903, since the US had just taken
over and hadn’t time to make fateful changes, I think these regressions show that the way things were
in 1903 didn’t set the course for today, but also weren’t completely different.
50
Table 3 (1903 Census)
Dependent variable:
Observations 45 45 45 82 82
R2 0.001 0.074 0.125 0.004 0.106
Note: *p<.1**p<.05***p<0.01
Table 4 is one of the key tables for this paper. This shows the results from the regressions for
the 1918 census. For both models 2 and 4, we have a statistically significant correlation. As the land
inequality in 1918 provinces increases, the dynastic concentration in 21st century provinces increases.
This is true whether the data is grouped by old or modern provinces. This is a remarkable result. The
idea that land inequality in 1918 could affect life 100 years later shows how important this period was
for the Philippines and how entrenched dynasties became. Provinces that had worse land inequality by
1918 show more powerful dynasties today. It’s also worth noting that this result is much stronger than
the correlation for 1903. This supports the argument that it was changes over those 15 years that
51
allowed those who benefited to seize power permanently. The economic elite who benefited from the
US programs, seen in areas with more land inequality and more Torrens titles, were able to cement their
power after 1918 by turning it into political power. Not every province changed in the same ways and
those places where land inequality became a central problem were fertile ground for the building of
political power in a way that secured it in the hands of a few families with all the problems that entails.
In Table 4, and in all the regression tables, the amount of export crops grown in a province does
not end up being statistically significant. In some model specifications not reported here it comes close,
but the sign is going the wrong way. I suspect this is because while there was an effort made to orient
the Philippines economy toward exports, it was never that successful. Farming always stayed relatively
small by international standards. Rice was the most commonly grown crop in the Philippines and yet the
Philippines remained a net importer. In addition, different areas of the Philippines have different
suitability for export crops, but dynasties are a phenomenon in all parts of the country. Some dynastic
families may grow crops for export but it’s clearly not a requirement. However, since export crops could
be correlated with both inequality and dynasties, I keep it as a control. I also ran models 2 and 4 with
the share of other specific crops (rice, corn, and the export crops), but none of the coefficients on those
crops were statistically significant. I didn’t add them to the models in Table 4 as they reduce the already
There is also the possibility that the US did not want to compete with a major agricultural
exporter with special trade status. Pepinsky (2015) looks at sugar exports and finds that while the US
had several territories that exported sugar (Hawaii, Puerto Rico, and the Philippines) in Hawaii and
Puerto Rico, the farms were owned by Americans. In the Philippines, as noted above, there was far less
American ownership. Pepinsky argues that this led to a caucus for granting the Philippines
independence to keep their exports further away. This logic may explain why export crops didn’t
52
Table 4 (1918 Census)
Dependent variable:
Observations 52 52 82 82
R2 0.029 0.173 0.033 0.169
*
Note: p<.1**p<.05***p<0.01
Table 5 shows the regressions for the 1939 census. The models with inequality alone were
omitted for space, but the coefficients weren’t statistically significant. Model 1 (which is the same as
Model 2 from the last two tables) isn’t statistically significant this time. The coefficient is very similar,
but the standard error is higher. This is interesting for a few reasons. First, I would expect some
correlation. Even if we accept that the time around 1918 was the key, those relationships should still
partially be present here. I think that explains why we have a similar coefficient but a larger standard
error. The land inequality has shifted, overall inequality went down between 1918 and 1939, but some
of those previous relationships are there. Second, it suggests that it was the earlier period that was
central to the establishment of dynasties. With inequality having decreased, this time period doesn’t
53
Models 2 and 5 use a Gini calculated by farm equipment, not landholding. On their own, these
variables are not statistically significant in any model. However, Model 3 shows an interesting result.
When the Gini for farm equipment is controlled for the Gini for landholding, it becomes close to
statistically significant (p=.056). This could suggest that it was land more than wealth that is connected
to dynastic concentration. It could also suggest that the changes since 1918 had made farming more
detached from dynasties as mechanization was coming in more during this period. There isn’t enough
evidence to state this conclusively, though, since the 1918 census didn’t have data on farm equipment.
Dependent variable:
Observations 50 50 50 82 82 82
R2 0.140 0.119 0.190 0.106 0.104 0.112
Note: *p<.1**p<.05***p<0.01
54
The 1948 census regressions are very similar to the ones for 1939. Looking at the data this isn’t
surprising since the Gini, amount of land farmed, and the number of farms are quite similar between
1939 and 1948. This, in and of itself, is somewhat surprising because the Philippines has just gone
through World War 2, but what this shows is a decade of stagnation in farming. Again, the coefficient for
Model 1 is similar to the coefficient for the same model from 1918 but with a higher standard error.
Dependent variable:
Observations 51 51 51 82 82 82
R2 0.165 0.141 0.181 0.111 0.103 0.116
*
Note: p<.1**p<.05***p<0.01
Charts 5 and 6 show the coefficient on land inequality in the main model with controls for each
census. Chart 5 includes the models based on the old provinces, and Chart 6 shows the models based on
the modern provinces. Looking at the charts shows that the coefficients are not much different between
55
each census, but the standard error changes a lot. I like to think of this in terms of a picture coming into
focus. In 1903 the effect of dynasties wasn’t quite in focus. It is in focus in 1918 and then drifts out of
focus in 1939 and 1948. This is expected, as while 1918 is the critical period, there are roots before this
Chart 5
Char 6
56
Charts 5 and 6 show the critical juncture at play. The connection between land inequality and
dynasties in 1903 is weak as the US has just taken over and is about to unleash a period of substantial
change. By 1918, the US has cemented the power of the large landholders and they are beginning to
turn that economic power into political power. Those places where the land was concentrated, a high
Gini, end up with more dynasties a century later. This doesn’t completely change by 1939 or 1948
despite a decrease in overall land inequality, because even as the elite transition from wealth in land to
wealth in government they still own much of the land at this point. The standard errors get higher
because the relationship becomes weaker, not nonexistent. The early period was the critical juncture of
land to power that is why we see the statistically significant effect for 1918.
Finally, Table 7 looks at the importance of not just land inequality but also how the US cemented
that inequality. The 1918 census, and only the 1918 census, collected data on what sort of land title
people had. As noted before, while the idea had some egalitarian merit in theory, it was those with
money who benefited much more than those who were just generally in need of land. The 1918 census
includes seven categories for land ownership. Having no title at all was most common and is the omitted
reference category for Table 7. People might also have been issued a Torrens title under the new US
system. They may hold their land by Spanish royal decree. They may hold their land informally as
something they worked which the government was trying to recognize in a sort of homesteading fashion
list as “possessory.” They might get a judicial decree declaring title on the land. They might have a
traditional private land deed, and they might be squatting on public land.
This forms an unordered categorical variable with “no title” left out as the reference category. In
Models 2 and 5, from Table 7, it is clear that those provinces with a higher percentage of Torrens titles
(compared to having “no title”) were correlated with a higher dynastic concentration in the 21st century.
Provinces with higher possessory titles are associated with lower dynastic concentration. This shows
that in places where the rich were able to get a hold of Torrens titles, they were able to build the sort of
57
power that created lasting dynasties. In areas where the poor were simply able to keep using their
traditional land or homestead its dynasties didn’t develop as strongly. This again shows the importance
of this critical juncture. The US only pursued this land titling system for a limited time before turning
over the government. In 1918, only 4.5% of land had a Torrens title, yet we still see this correlation with
dynasties suggesting that it is a good indicator for concentration of wealth. We see here how areas
where the well-off were able to cement their power would go on to have lots of dynasties, whereas
areas where the poor were able to hold onto more land see fewer dynasties.
In Models 2 and 5 the Gini coefficient is no longer statistically significant. I believe this is
because the changes in land inequality between 1903 and 1918 were tied into changes in titling. Models
3 and 6 interact Gini and Torrens titling and in both cases the interaction is statistically significant. Chart
7 below shows a graph of the interaction in Model 3. For provinces with a low percentage of Torrens
titles, increases in Gini is not associated with an increase in dynastic concentration. For provinces with a
high level of Torrens titles, increases in Gini is associated with an increase in Torrens titles. This is all a
58
Table 7
Dependent variable:
Observations 52 52 52 82 82 82
R2 0.173 0.492 0.599 0.169 0.285 0.332
Note: *p**p***p<0.01
59
Chart 7
Taken together this shows that dynasties were empowered by choices the US made in the early
20th century. Changes in land ownership laws allowed the already wealthy to increase their control over
the land in some provinces. These provinces would go on to experience a history of stronger dynasties
as those dynasties cemented their power so that even as land became less important, they were able to
hold onto their political and economic power. Chart 7 shows that it was both the effect of the US giving
titles to those with money and areas where those people held a higher percentage of the land.
Conclusion
Looking beyond the Philippines, we sometimes treat the old power of landholders as a relic of the past
with little impact on the modern world. This paper shows that those old powers can have a way of
worming themselves into the system so that even as land becomes less important, those who had
power before can keep it. This paper also shows statistical evidence that it was landholding that created
60
the power base for dynasties. This is often suggested in the literature but here we have strong evidence
How would things have been different if the US had engaged in real agricultural reform or not
helped the landed elite gain so much political power? I believe the land question is the real starting
point. If economic life is going to be controlled by a small clique, it would always be hard to keep them
out of political power. There was land to go around in the Philippines, but the US was only passingly
interested in seeing it go to small farmers. With a stronger economic base, small farmers might have
been better able to advocate for themselves and keep the large landholders from dominating so fully.
The US also mixed good instincts, turning over power to the Filipinos, with bad, only trusting the elite.
The Philippines would have been better off if either the US ensured a more equitable early distribution
of power, or if the US had tried to incorporate the poor earlier instead of after the powerful had
grabbed control.
For the Philippines, it was the choices the US made during the critical juncture right after it took
over that opened the door for dynastic power. It was also the handover of power to those emerging
dynasties, and other leaders who worked with them, that let those dynasties keep their power into the
modern world. Through the US period, the Japanese invasion, the early Republic, the Marcos
dictatorship, and today’s post-Marcos constitution, dynasties have endured in the Philippines. It is
remarkable, though, that we can so clearly see the roots of these dynasties in the problems of
61
Work Cited
Abinales, P., & Amoroso, D. (2005). State and Society in the Philippines (Pasig City. Anvil Publishing.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An
empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.
Ariffin, D. (2019). The censuses of the Philippine islands: From ethnological inquiry to the formalization
of racial categories in the American-occupied Philippines from 1903 to 1939. Social Science
Diliman, 15(1).
Anderson, B. (1988). Cacique democracy and the Philippines: Origins and dreams. New Left Review, 169,
3.
Berdahl, R. M. (1972). Conservative Politics and Aristocratic Landholders in Bismarckian Germany. The
Journal of Modern History, 44(1), 2–20. https://doi.org/10.1086/240704
Bernhard, M., Reenock, C., & Nordstrom, T. (2004). The legacy of Western overseas colonialism on
democratic survival. International Studies Quarterly, 48(1), 225–250.
Bragança, A., Ferraz, C., & Rios, J. (2015). Political dynasties and the quality of government. Unpublished
Manuscript.
Collier, R. B., & Collier, D. (1991). Shaping the Political Arena: Critical Junctures, the Labor Movement,
and Regime Dynamics in Latin America. Princeton University Press.
https://books.google.com/books?id=gIO9QgAACAAJ
Daniels, R. J., Trebilcock, M. J., & Carson, L. D. (2011). The Legacy of Empire: The common law
inheritance and commitments to legality in former British colonies. The American Journal of
Comparative Law, 59(1), 111–178.
Frankema, E. (2010). The colonial roots of land inequality: Geography, factor endowments, or
institutions? Economic History Review, 63(2), 418–451. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-
0289.2009.00479.x
Hutchcroft, P. D. (2000). Colonial masters, national politicos, and provincial lords: central authority and
local autonomy in the American Philippines, 1900–1913. The Journal of Asian Studies, 59(2), 277-
306.
Iglesias, S. (2003). Colonial and indigenous influences on local power structure in the Philippines. Asia
Europe Journal, 1(4), 541-549.
Jong-Sung, Y., & Khagram, S. (2005). A comparative study of inequality and corruption. American
Sociological Review, 70(1), 136–157.
62
Jupp, P. J. (1990). The Landed Elite And Political Authority In Britain, Ca. 1760-1850. The Journal of
British Studies, 29(1), 53–79. https://doi.org/10.1086/385949
Kenawas, Y. C. (2015). The Rise of Political Dynasties in a Democratic Society. EDGS Working Paper -
Arryman Fellow, 22, 1–58. https://www.edgs.northwestern.edu/documents/working-papers/the-
rise-of-political-dynasties-in-a-democratic-society.pdf
Kurniadi, B. D. (2019). Defending the Sultan’s Land: Yogyakarta, Control over Land and Aristocratic
Power in Post-Autocratic Indonesia. In A Thesis]. Doctor of Philosophy of the Australian National
University (Issue September).
Lange, M., Mahoney, J., & Vom Hau, M. (2006). Colonialism and development: A comparative analysis of
Spanish and British colonies. American Journal of Sociology, 111(5), 1412–1462.
Main, J. T. (1966). Government by the People: The American Revolution and the Democratization of the
Legislatures. The William and Mary Quarterly, 23(3), 391. https://doi.org/10.2307/1919237
Maurer, N., & Iyer, L. (2008). The cost of property rights: Establishing Institutions on the Philippine
Frontier under American Rule, 1898-1918.
McCoy, A. W. (1994). An anarchy of families: The historiography of state and family in the Philippines. An
Anarchy of Families: State and Family in the Philippines, 1–32.
McDiarmid, A. M. (1953). Agricultural public land policy in the Philippines during the American period.
Phil. LJ, 28, 851.
Mendoza, R. U., Beja Jr, E. L., Venida, V. S., & Yap, D. B. (2016). Political dynasties and poverty:
measurement and evidence of linkages in the Philippines. Oxford Development Studies, 44(2), 189–
201.
Mendoza, R. U., Beja Jr, E. L., Venida, V. S., & Yap, D. B. (2019). Political dynasties in the Philippine
congress. In Building Inclusive Democracies in ASEAN (pp. 7–38). World Scientific.
Nasr, S. V. R. (1996). Pakistan: State, agrarian reform and Islamization. International Journal of Politics,
Culture, and Society, 249-272.
Pepinsky, T. B. (2015). Trade Competition and American Decolonization. World Politics, 67(3), 387-422.
Pepinsky, T. B. (2019). The return of the single-country study. Annual Review of Political Science, 22,
187-203.
Race, J. (1973). War Comes to Long An: Revolutionary Conflict in a Vietnamese Province. United
Kingdom: University of California Press.
63
Roth, D. M., & others. (1977). friar estates of the Philippines. University of New Mexico Press.
Sidel, J. T. (1999). Capital, coercion, and crime: Bossism in the Philippines. Stanford University Press.
Smith, D. M. (2012). Succeeding in Politics: Dynasties in Democracies. Dissertation for the Degree of
Doctor of Philosophy, 1–242. https://escholarship.org/uc/item/0xp4r2hb
Sobritchea, C. I. (1981). The Philippine peasantry of the early colonial period. Philippine Sociological
Review, 17–23.
Tadem, T. S. E., & Tadem, E. C. (2016). Political dynasties in the Philippines: Persistent patterns,
perennial problems. South East Asia Research, 24(3), 328–340.
Teehankee, J. (2002). Electoral politics in the Philippines. Electoral Politics in Southeast and East Asia,
149-202.
Ventura, T. (2016). From small farms to Progressive plantations: The trajectory of land reform in the
American Colonial Philippines, 1900--1916. Agricultural History, 90(4), 459–483.
Von Braun, J., Hotchkiss, D., & Immink, M. D. C. (1989). Nontraditional export crops in Guatemala:
Effects on production, income, and nutrition (Vol. 73). Intl Food Policy Res Inst.
Williamson, J. (2017). Philippine Inequality across the Twentieth Century: Slim Evidence but Fat
Questions. Philippine Review of Economics, 54(2), 37–60.
Wittman, H. (2009). Reframing agrarian citizenship: Land, life and power in Brazil. Journal of Rural
Studies, 25(1), 120–130. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2008.07.002
You, J. (2014). Land Reform, Inequality, and Corruption: A Comparative Historical Study of Korea,
Taiwan, and the Philippines.
64
The Effect of Dynasties on Corruption
Prosecutions in the Philippines
65
Introduction
On the small island province of Biliran, millions of pesos meant for hospitals have gone missing. Local
advocacy groups have been working to get the Ombudsman, who is in charge of all corruption
prosecutions, to charge members of the Espina family. (Castillo 2010, p.210). The Espina, however,
dominate local politics. Two of the last three governors of Biliran have been Espinas. Their family and
allies control almost all mayoral and legislative positions. No one has been charged concerning the
missing hospital funds. Moreover, when the “former” bodyguard of one Espina murdered a political rival
in broad daylight, no Espina was charged. By contract, in Camarine Norte on the Island of Luzon, former
governor Casimiro Padilla Jr. was charged by the Ombudsman with corruption for not returning a pistol
that had been issued to him when he was in office. The Ombudsman’s office agrees that Padilla did, in
fact, return a pistol, they simply claim it was a cheaper one than he had been issued. The pistol in
question was worth about $150. After a case spanning nearly 20 years, Padilla served three years in
prison.
Is the Ombudsman able to prevent widespread corruption or hold anyone with power
accountable? Horizontal accountability, especially when taking place between different levels of the
government, is supposed to be a key tool for fighting corruption. But what affects the ability of
institutions such as the Ombudsman to hold politicians accountable? This paper focuses on the influence
of political dynasties and asks whether dynasties are insulated from any accountability in the
Philippines. In analyzing corruption, prosecutions, and dynasties in the Philippines, I find that not all
members of dynasties are protected. Instead, when a province becomes inundated with many dynasties
holding, as a group, a large number of seats, prosecutions for corruption become much less frequent. In
the Philippines, dynasties, which are most powerful at the local level, are able to keep the national anti-
corruption agency from holding them accountable, at least in places where there is a high concentration
of dynasties.
66
The weakness of the Ombudsman allows dynasties to keep prosecutors at bay. The Ombudsman
is a national organization with a single leader appointed by the president. However, the Ombudsman
has a relatively small staff and relies on reports of corruption for most investigations. In provinces where
dynasties are concentrated, these reports are less common. The Ombudsman doesn’t have the power to
wiretap or to examine bank records. When the Ombudsman does make cases, the cases tend to be
based on witnesses or audits. Dynasties can intimidate the public into silence in provinces where
dynastic power is at its strongest. Critics, the media, and local police are silenced, keeping the
The limits of horizontal accountability and the pernicious effect of dynasties are problems in
many countries, but the Philippines offers an excellent opportunity to study accountability and dynasties
because of unique opportunities to measure the key concepts. First, the Philippines has a special court
for corruption (the Sandiganbayan), from which I obtained records of all the cases. So, unlike in many
countries, we can see every person who was indicted for corruption at any level. Second, while the
Philippines is not unique as a home to powerful dynasties, thanks to unique naming conventions it is
much easier than in other countries to trace these dynasties even at the local level. Third, the
Philippines has had an online public procurement system for almost 20 years, a rarity for a developing
country. From this, I was able to create a measure of the quality of the public procurement contracts in
different provinces and localities, a strong instrument for corruption. Finally, dynasties in the Philippines
are not uniformly distributed. Some provinces have a much higher concentration than others. This
means that in some places it is much easier to get away with being corrupt. The data shows that
prosecutions for corruption increase as corruption worsens, but that it is highly conditional on the
power of dynasties.
I begin with a brief discussion of the literature on corruption, accountability, and dynasties and
this paper’s contribution to the literature. Then I will explain how prosecutions work in the Philippines,
67
and why we can measure dynasties and corruption with more accuracy than in other countries. After, I
will show how each of the key variables is measured including the models used to measure corruption.
Next, there is a review the results of the models used to test the data and the implications of these
findings. Finally, I end with a discussion what more work can be done to better understand the power of
The negative effects of corruption are well known and varied. Mauro’s (1995) early cross-national work
suggests that corruption lowers growth. Azfar and Gurgur (2006) and Di Tella and Schargrodsky (2003)
suggest that corruption worsens public health outcomes. Anderson and Tverdova (2003) show how
corruption lowers regime support. There is a long-running debate, though, about how to control
corruption. Hong Kong and Singapore had significant success in controlling corruption by creating
powerful anti-corruption agencies. Quah (2010) and de Speville (2010) suggest that these agencies are
the key to holding back corruption. Others have not been so sure. De Sousa (2009) pointed out that
while some agencies had successes, others were so constrained that they had little effect. Szeftel (2000)
argues that while Africa tried to follow the Asian model for anti-corruption agencies these agencies were
so undermined by the very leaders who created them that they failed almost immediately. Heilbrunn
(2004) argues that anti-corruption agencies will not succeed unless backed by strong government
This paper contributes to this literature by looking at when and if the anti-corruption agency in
the Philippines can prosecute elected officials for corruption. It’s not enough to just say that anti-
corruption agencies may fail, or that more powerful agencies are more successful. The Ombudsman (the
Philippines anti-corruption agency) does prosecute some people, but corruption is still a rampant
68
problem in the Philippines. This paper explores when these prosecutions go ahead and when they are
stymied. As will be described in the next section, the Ombudsman is vulnerable to political interference,
and in the Philippines, it is dynasties and not political parties that are central to the political process. As
one member of an important dynasty told me, “Parties are essentially an alliance of families” (Luis Abad,
The next paper has a more detailed breakdown of party weakness, but it’s important to
understand that parties are extremely weakly institutionalized in the Philippines. It’s not unusual for
candidates to run under different party labels in every election. Timberman (2016) describes the
situation saying, “dynasties both reflect and contribute to the almost farcical weakness of political
parties […] Duterte’s presidential campaign was loosely affiliated with the Filipino Democratic Party
(PDP)–Laban, a small regional party, and within days of his victory, more than 60 of 115 LP congressmen
switched to PDP-Laban.”
The research on dynasties in political science and economics has focused on two major areas:
why do dynasties form and persist, and what are the consequences of dynasties. This paper contributes
to each question. Dynasties persist by helping to keep their members out of jail. Political solutions aren’t
usually enough to stop dynasties. Mendoza et al. (2020) and Querubin (2011) show that term limits in
the Philippines either didn’t stop dynastic formation and may even have helped dynasties grow. On the
other hand, it wasn’t elections or new rules that broke the power of the Ampatuans, one of the largest
and most powerful dynasties in the Philippines. The prosecution and eventual conviction of its most
important members severely limited their power. This paper also contributes to understanding the
effects of dynastic power in democracies. Research has shown that dynasties are linked to increased
poverty even when accounting for dynasties being more likely in poorer areas (Mendoza et al. 2013).
Amundsen (2016) shows that in Bangladesh, like in the Philippines, dynastic power makes parties
weaker and less democratic. Folke, Persson, and Rickne (2017) show that even in more established
69
democracies, relatives of those in power make more money, similar to what Chen and Kung (2019)
found for connected firms in China. Fiva and Smith (2018) show that even in Norway’s closed list
proportional representation system (where name recognition of candidates is less of a factor) dynasties
help members get elected by boosting party connections. Davis et al. (forthcoming) show a correlation
between increased dynastic concentration and increased corruption. This paper builds on that to show
that dynasties are not just linked to more corruption but keep prosecutions at bay so that corruption
can spread.
This paper also contributes to the work on corruption by constructing a novel measure of
corruption in the Philippines, using public procurement data. As shown in Coviello and Gagliarducci
(2010), Auriol, Straub, and Flochel (2016), Burgess et al. (2015), or Olken (2005), corruption can be seen
in the poor quality of public procurement contracts in some places as opposed to others. For example,
Di Tella & Schargrodsky (2003) showed that the number of hospital procurement contracts in Argentina
that only had a single firm bidding for the contract dropped hugely when the government announced
new audits. Ravanilla et al. (2019) specifically show that in the Philippines, mayors from minor political
parties receive fewer public works projects, which are rife with corruption, than more connected
mayors. This paper contributes to the growing literature using public procurement contracts to create
more objective and broad measures of corruption [see also Fazekas et al. (2016) work on public
This paper will show that dynasties are the key factor limiting who is prosecuted for corruption
in the Philippines. As dynasties hold more and more of the elected offices in a province or municipality,
corruption prosecutions become infrequent even as the level of corruption (the level of suspect public
procurement contracts) increases. Dynasties can exploit the weakness of the Ombudsman to keep
prosecutions at bay. In places where dynasties are very strong, they alter the entire climate of the
province so that the Ombudsman can’t make cases. Interestingly, members of larger dynasties from
70
regions that have few dynasties overall aren’t as successful in preventing prosecution. It takes the
To summarize, this paper contributes to the literature on accountability by showing where anti-
corruption agencies fail. It also contributes to the literature on dynasties by showing how they cement
their power by creating a cone of silence that hinders prosecutions. Finally, this paper contributes to the
literature on corruption by creating a new public procurement measure of corruption. Next, this paper
will give an overview of how prosecutions, dynasties, and corruption work in the Philippines, and what
data is available.
Corruption prosecutions in the Philippines are handled by the office of the Ombudsman. The office of
the Ombudsman goes back to the pre-Marcos period, but it took its modern form as a dedicated anti-
corruption agency during the reforms that followed Marcos’ fall. Bolongaita (2010) notes that for the
most part, the Ombudsman was not based on any preexisting agency and not created in concert with
civil society groups. The Ombudsman predates the successful models of Hong Kong and Singapore. The
Ombudsman is empowered to prosecute cases involving corruption of almost all politicians. Only very
low-level elected officials, municipal counselors, and barangay leaders have corruption cases not
automatically handled by the Ombudsman, and those are remitted to the Ombudsman if they involve a
The Ombudsman does not have full investigatory powers. They often rely on the police, or other
investigative bodies like the Commission on Audit, to do the front-line investigating. The Office of the
Ombudsman does have investigators, but they just don’t have that many and the office doesn’t have as
much power as other anti-corruption agencies. The Ombudsman can’t wiretap; in fact, all wiretaps, save
71
for national security, are illegal in the Philippines, and they usually can’t subpoena bank records. That’s
not to say they don’t make cases, but they have a lot of limits on what they can accomplish.
The Ombudsman’s office is also vulnerable to political interference. The appointment of the
Ombudsman, and other important judicial bodies, is supposed to be safeguarded from presidential
interference, but those protections are themselves very weak. Presidents can only choose an
Ombudsman from a shortlist created by the Judicial and Bar Council. However, the president also
appoints members of the Judicial and Bar Council. There are rules about who must serve on the councils
(two people from Congress, a retired Supreme Court Justice, a professor, a retired lawyer), but the
president can still choose from amongst these. In practice, the shortlist is already a list the president will
approve of. The Ombudsman, once appointed, serves a single seven-year term and can only be removed
by impeachment. This theoretically grants them a great deal of independence but in practice they are
often very subservient to the president that appointed them. The term of an Ombudsman doesn’t
match the six-year presidential term. Presidents may have to spend several years with an Ombudsman
appointed by their predecessor. This has resulted in Ombudsman being at odds with and investigating
people close to a president. For example, when Duterte took office, he ordered the Ombudsman, who
was appointed by his predecessor and political rival Aquino, to fire a deputy Ombudsman who had
investigated Duterte. The Ombudsman, though, refused. However, when the Ombudsman’s term
expired, Duterte appointed an ally as the new Ombudsman and the deputy was fired and lost his
pension.
The law makes the Ombudsman an independent agency, but in practice it is susceptible to
presidential power. I interviewed a lawyer who had worked at the Office of the Special Prosecutor, the
prosecutorial arm of the Ombudsman. The prosecutor (Prosecutor Interview 2019) I spoke to, despite
working for the Ombudsman’s office, thought that if a president called up an Ombudsman, the
president could get the Ombudsman to back off an investigation. The prosecutor didn’t admit to
72
knowing of that happening, but he agreed that that was the way things worked. I spoke with another
senior official who had worked for the Ombudsman (Official Interview 2019) ,who spent a lot of time
telling me that he personally never engaged in corruption. The official said that he wasn’t offered bribes
because he never took meetings with those involved in cases. He suggested that even those who turned
down bribes were putting themselves in a bad situation. Implicit in this, though, was the fact that bribes
relating to the Ombudsman were not unheard of. He had to take special care to not be influenced.
Cases can originate from complaints sent to the Ombudsman. They can also come from issues
requirement that they proceed with any particular investigation, or once started that they keep going.
Most of the staff of the Office of the Ombudsman are hired through normal civil service procedures.
However, since each case had to be, eventually, reviewed by the Ombudsman, or the deputies who are
All cases brought by the Ombudsman are tried before a special anticorruption court, the
Sandiganbayan. The Sandiganbayan consists of 21 justices appointed by the president in the same
manner as the Ombudsman. The Sandiganbayan is both a trial and appeals court and decisions made
there can only be overruled by the Supreme Court. Cases are heard by panels of three justices. Virtually
all cases are held in Manila, where the Ombudsman and Sandiganbayan are also located. The
Ombudsman is the only agency that can bring cases before the Sandiganbayan. The trial and appeals
process is famously slow. Cases drag on for years or, not uncommonly, decades when appeals are
included. This makes it somewhat hard to say which Ombudsman was responsible for a case since
virtually every important case takes longer than the tenure of any Ombudsman or president.
Cases against powerful individuals are relatively rare despite the high level of corruption in the
Philippines. In addition, even when powerful people are brought to trial and convicted, the conviction
73
rarely stands up to years of appeals. In one case after a successful conviction and a denied appeal it still
took about five years for the Ombudsman to get the Sandiganbayan to actually order the convicted man
to serve his sentence. That is not to say the Ombudsman doesn’t win convictions and sometimes send
people to jail, however. The most powerful and connected are a small group. Most dynasties aren’t
anywhere near as powerful as the Marcos dynasty. Most governors and congressmen are from a
dynasty and some 30% of local office holders as well. The Ombudsman has a hard time making cases,
but it still does make cases. As we will see later, in provinces with a low concentration of dynasties,
areas with more corruption see more prosecutions. The data on prosecutions is noisy but extensive.
What hinders the prosecutors more than their lack of investigatory power is the power of dynasties.
Dynasties in the Philippines emerged out of the Spanish colonial period. Due to the huge distance
between the Philippines and Spain, the Spanish ruled by coopting and empowering local leaders. Some
dynasties can trace their roots back even further to pre-Spanish royalty. The problem is so entrenched
that the post-Marcos constitution includes an anti-dynasty provision, but one that has never been put
into law. Even the most powerful national dynasties grow from provincial roots. The Marcoses were not
one of the leading national families before Ferdinand, but they were a powerful family in their home
province of Ilocos Norte. They have roots going back to the Spanish colonial period. Today the Marcoses
are again one of the most powerful families. Ferdinand’s daughter Imee was governor until recently,
when she was replaced by her son. Ferdinand Marcos’ son, Ferdinand “Bongbong” Marcos Jr., is a
leading candidate in the 2022 presidential election. However, the Marcoses are not the only family in
Ilocos Norte. The Fariñas family has included mayors and provincial as well as national legislators in
Ilocos Norte, to name one example. While a few extremely powerful dynasties get most of the press,
74
politics in the Philippines is made up of many small dynastic families. It’s not unusual for the mayor and
vice-mayor of a town to be father and son, or brothers, often switching jobs when one is term limited.
Even these smaller dynasties enjoy huge advantages over politicians without family in office. Access to
money, to patronage networks, and even to the tools of violence all work along dynastic lines.3
Since every province has multiple dynasties, these families form shifting alliances. I spoke to a
long-time mayor from Quezon about how dynasties affected politics (Ubana Interview). He said the
relationships between dynasties were “quite transactional” and that dynasties had “no permanent
friends, only permanent interests,” to paraphrase Lord Palmerston. He said that when faced with a
corruption investigation, local officials might want to influence the decision but that it was only when
they could reach up to the national level that this was possible. While mayor, he wasn’t a member of a
dynasty (now as a state legislator his wife has replaced him as mayor), but he would work with
dynasties, trading his ability to deliver votes in his city for favors. He explained that dynasties were
driven by one overriding idea, “the protection and continuation of the dynasty.”
Dynasties have a lot of power at the local, or provincial level. For example, Sidel (1999) notes
that mayors can appoint, promote, and remove local police chiefs. Yilmaz and Venugopal (2013) explain
that under post-Marcos decentralization, local governments are also responsible for the budgets of local
courts. With so much local power and so much favor trading between dynasties, dynasties are in
position to prevent a national organization like the Ombudsman from effectively investigating,
particularly in areas where dynasties control a high concentration of the local seats. We might also
expect to find that dynasties that are the most connected to national politics, such as having a
congressman as a member of the dynasty, would be protected as well. However, as we will see, this isn’t
3
For more on dynasty origins see the paper on land and dynasty origins.
75
Theory
Based on this background on prosecutions and dynasties, I argue that dynasties are colluding
with one another to prevent prosecutions by the Ombudsman. Dynasties intimidate the public into
silence allowing corruption to go unpunished. Dynasties are not evenly distributed across the
Philippines. As examined in the previous paper, some places had histories that led to much greater
dynasty formation. When groups of dynasties control many of the elected offices in a province, they
create a culture where even while in some competition for seats, the dynasties are jointly ruling the
province and keeping the national government at bay. In places where dynasties don’t have this
strength, I expect to find that more corruption leads to more prosecutions. However, in areas where
dynasties are the most pervasive, I expect to find that the Ombudsman can’t make cases even when
Dynasties are able to prevent the Ombudsman from making cases because the Ombudsman’s
weakness means they need outside help (reports, audits, complaints, informants) to make cases. The
Ombudsman doesn’t have the resources to investigate broadly and uncover otherwise unknown cases
of corruption. This is similar to what McCubbins and Schwartz (1984) call “fire-alarm oversight.” Like
responding to a real fire alarm, the Ombudsman waits for someone to sound an alarm before taking
action. McCubbins and Schwartz distinguish this from “police-patrol oversight” where the oversight is
active and looking for violations. Fire-alarm oversight requires less resources and initiative, but is also
less broad. More effective anti-corruption agencies take many actions that could be described as like
police-patrols. The Hong Kong anti-corruption agency developed a high school curriculum that was
deployed to attempt to change the culture around corruption at the grass roots level. The Ombudsman
76
Many dynasties in the Philippines use violence and intimidation as a key way to hold onto
power. Winters (2011) writes, “At no point from the Spanish period in the nineteenth century, through
the American period in the twentieth, to the contemporary period in the twenty-first century
have oligarchs in the Philippines ever been fully disarmed. A significant segment has retained formidable
coercive capacities – ranging from standing private militias in the countryside, to bands of soldiers that
can be hired as needed from the Philippine armed forces, to motley goon squads that can be raised and
unleashed in the provinces and sometimes in Manila.” Violence today isn’t what it was in the early
republican period, but dynasties are often willing to not only use their power over the government but
force to get their way. This shouldn’t be taken to mean that anyone who criticizes those with power will
automatically be gunned down, but it’s far from unheard of. Jopson (2013) describes the situation with
the media saying, “a culture of silence by apathy, if not intimidation or ignorance, is fostered.”
Given that dynasties are willing to use force and that there are certainly instances of dynasties
using violence against one another, why do I believe that dynasties are cooperating to keep the
Ombudsman out rather than trying to use the Ombudsman against one another? Dynasties will compete
for elections, sometimes violently, but they don’t want anything that threatens the overall status quo.
Overall, the ruling group of the Philippines isn’t any one leader but the dynasties ruling as an oligarchic
whole. Quimpo (2015) writes, “In the contemporary ruling oligarchy, as in the pre-dictatorship one,
oligarchs rule collectively through institutions and norms, albeit relatively weak, and maintain a
direct hand in coercive power through their own armed groups. Their paramount objective is to
secure and maintain their wealth and power against all threats. Politicians who are part of or aligned
with the oligarchy resort to patronage and also to campaign overspending, bribery, fraud, coercion or
violence to gain or retain public office.” Quimpo goes on to note that all the dynasties work together to
77
Dynasties form shifting alliances to increase their power. Mendoza et al. (2020) explain that in
Western Samar, two of the larger dynasties-- the Tans (12 elected members) and the Uys (13 elected
members) -- were joined when Stephen James Tan married Stephany Uy. The alliance involved accepting
that the families worked together in some areas and competed in others. Mendoza et al. argue that this
alliance persisted even after Reynaldo Uy was murdered, possibly at the behest of Milagrosa Tan.
Aspinall et al. (2016) look at how alliance networks form and shift quickly saying, “local factions will
often jump ship to align with a winning presidential candidate or member of Congress who can help
direct projects towards the municipality. Some candidates we interviewed struggled to recall what party
they had been aligned with even one election ago.” In many ways the dynasties in the Philippines act
similarly to dynasties in medieval Europe. They fight with one another, but don’t continence threats to
the overall system. They might fight, but they also intimidate everyone else into silence, making the
Data
This section will describe the availability and assembly of the data used to test if dynasties can prevent
corruption investigations. In order to test this argument, I need to have data on prosecutions, dynasties,
and corruption. I examine corruption, dynasties, and prosecutions at both a provincial and local level.
The Philippines currently has 81 provinces with the number varying only slightly over the last 20 years.
Each province is led by a directly elected governor. Metro Manila doesn’t have a governor but is
administered by a department of the central government and thus is excluded from this study.
Underneath the provinces are 146 cities and 1488 municipalities. Cities and municipalities are on the
same level. Each city or municipality is led by an elected mayor who, like the governors, serves a three-
year term with a maximum of two consecutive reelections. A mayor or governor who has been out of
78
office for one term can be elected to additional terms. Underneath cities and municipalities are
barangays, which can be villages or sections of a city. There are just over 42,000 barangays in the
Philippines. Barangay elections are theoretically every three years, but recently the government has
postponed them as a money saving measure. Barangay elections are also officially non-partisan. Unlike
governors or mayors who act as patrons distributing money for votes, barangay leaders are more like
brokers. They don’t have the sort of power that makes the positions interesting for the well-connected
dynasties. There is also a paucity of data on exactly who is running in or winning the elections when they
Prosecutions for corruption do not necessarily take place when a governor or mayor is in office.
This means that the data cannot be organized as mayor-term, or governor-term, since a mayor might be
prosecuted for something he did only after his term is over. This is especially true as prosecutions in the
Philippines are notoriously slow. Instead, the data is organized by governor or mayor. A row in the data
set is one mayor or governor, however many terms he served. In the regression, I control for the
number of terms an official served as well as how much data on public procurement there is. Finally,
governors and mayors are considered separately. There is too much overlap and too many issues with
different levels for both to be in the same regression. For governors I end up with 209 observations,
while for mayors I have 2812 observations. Each observation being a single governor or mayor. For
governors I lost some observations due to name mismatches, but I have the vast majority. With about
80 provinces and five terms, the theoretical maximum number of governors is only 400 and since the
median governor served two terms, and many served three or four, I have almost all of them. Governors
who are missing should be missing at random due to issues like names from one government agency
being entered in different ways to other agencies. For governors I tried to correct all of these I could
find, but some still likely were lost. For mayors, most of the missing data is from 2004 and 2007 where
there are few entries for public procurement data. For smaller municipalities, data is missing from 2010
79
as well. In addition, I am missing some of the mayoral data from 2016 due to missing dynasty data. I
control for this by adding a variable for the number of terms for which someone was a mayor but for
Prosecution Data
I was able to get data on every case tried in the Sandiganbayan until the end of 2019. The data is
somewhat right censored. Just because someone hasn’t been charged with corruption doesn’t mean
they won’t be. Cases can take decades from start to finish. People who have entered public life more
recently are less likely to have had charges filed against them even if they are corrupt. However, as I will
show in the results sections, controlling for time in office, and using a survival model (which better
The data being right censored should make the relationship I’m looking for harder to find.
Prosecutions for corrupt acts in 2019 probably won’t come for years. The fact that I still find a
relationship between corruption and prosecutions suggests that the relationship is probably larger than
it appears in my data. There isn’t a clear relationship between the type of case and how long it takes.
The Ombudsman and the Sandiganbayan are both notoriously slow on any number of cases. Appeals are
sometimes not made or heard for years after the initial case. Even with right censored data, the data
shouldn’t be biased.
A threat to the accuracy of the data is how names are handled. To match governors and mayors
with prosecution records, I needed to make sure the names were the same. However, since families
often serve in the same position, just matching on family names isn’t enough. I matched governors and
mayors on their first names, last names, and suffix. Issues with the quality of government records mean
that I probably have some false negatives. There is no one standard across agencies, or even within an
80
agency, for how names are recorded. In some parts of the Philippines, people may have many given
names. Which one goes first can vary. Girls named Maria will often shorten it to “Ma.” followed by their
next given name. So, Maria Josefina Cruz may be Maria Cruz in one place Ma. Josefina Cruz in another,
and even possibly Josefina Cruz in a third. This isn’t a problem for every name. Maria is a particularly
problematic first name, as is Mohammed in different regions. Most names, though, are more consistent.
I tried to make sure as many of the conventions were the same across data sources as possible, for
example all “Ma.” became “Maria,” but there are almost certainly some errors. However, these should
be random errors as I was able to account for family differences by looking at suffixes. This should make
Dynasty Data
The Philippines has some of the strongest dynasties in the world but also presents an excellent case for
measuring the impact of dynasties. In the US we have political dynasties as well, but they can be harder
to measure. Not everyone named Bush from Texas is related to the former presidents. Quite a few
people related to the Kennedys are not named Kennedy. Names in the Philippines, though, have
stronger local connections. A Spanish governor in the 1840’s took a literal book of Spanish surnames,
the Catalogo de Apellidos, and tore out pages, assigning people in different provinces different
surnames. Cruz, Labonne, and Querubin (2020) explain, “Municipal officials throughout the country then
assigned a different name to each family. Since then, names have been transmitted through generations
according to well-established and enforced naming conventions. Consequently, very common family
names are not as prevalent in the Philippines as in other countries, and thus, sharing a family name is
very strongly correlated with an actual family tie.” If your surname is Ampatuan and you live in
Maguindanao it’s highly likely you are directly related to anyone else named Ampatuan, at least in that
81
province. This is less true in Manila where people have come from all over the country, but not having a
governor, Manila doesn’t appear in the data set. This naming convention creates a unique opportunity
to measure the extent of dynasties. In addition, dynasties are mostly focused on one province. Very few
families have any power outside their traditional homes. This further means that to see the extent of a
dynasty we only need to look at the offices in any given province. The governor of Leyte is not likely to
The naming convention doesn’t work perfectly. Naming conventions for women can be a
challenge. About 20% of elected politicians in the Philippines are women. Like in the US, women almost
always take their husband’s surname. This can sometimes obscure political connections. Early in her
career Imee Marcos, daughter of the dictator Ferdinand Marcos, was married to a former athlete named
Tommy Manotoc. So, while most people knew her as Imee Marcos, in congress she was Mrs. Manotoc.
Tommy Manotoc’s first wife, though, was also running for office. The Philippines is the only country,
besides the Vatican, that doesn’t recognize divorce. Tommy Manotoc’s first wife, then, was also running
as Mrs. Manotoc. However, cases like this are relatively rare. Not only do women make up a minority of
politicians, but they are also more likely to be associated with their husband’s families. Some
professional women will also hyphenate their names after marriage. In that case, I used the final part of
the hyphenated name, which is the husband's. The result is that I likely miss a few political connections,
The dynasty measure I used is based on the work of Mendoza et al. (2016). They measure “fat”
dynasties by how many people from the same dynasty are in office in the same province at the same
time. They look at a province’s governor, vice-governor, and the provincial legislature. They also look at
the mayor, vice-mayor, and the municipal legislature for every municipality and city in a province.
Finally, they also include the members of the House of Representatives of the Philippines who are
mostly elected from single member districts. The Senate is elected with a single national district and a
82
small percent of the House is elected by proportional party list voting. These legislators aren’t included
since they aren’t tied to any specific geographic area. The exact number of people considered varies
I try several different measures of the size and power of dynasties. I tried the number of seats,
either in a province or a municipality, held by a dynasty. I also try that number divided by the number of
available seats. I looked at a measure of whether a dynasty included a congressman, or for mayors a
governor. It would be interesting to see how being linked to the president affected the chance of
prosecution, but it wasn’t possible to measure that. Because of party switching, virtually every member
of congress joins the president’s coalition. The most important measure I use, though, is a measure of
dynastic concentration. This also follows the work of Mendoza et al. (2016). Specifically, they use an
economic measure of market concentration, the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI). HHI is calculated by
taking the percent of seats controlled by each dynasty, squaring it, and adding the results together. For
example, if there are three dynasties in a province, one controlling 4% of seats, one controlling 1% of
seats, and one controlling 3% of seats the HHI would be 4^2 + 1^2 + 3^2 = 26. A high HHI means that
many of the seats in a province are held by dynasties. It doesn’t necessarily mean that this is the result
As noted before, there is an emerging literature focused on measuring corruption by looking at public
procurement contracts. This is an indirect measure of corruption, but one that looks at objective data,
not simply beliefs about the extent of corruption. Underlying this is the idea that we can spot corruption
by looking at areas where public procurement contracts are worse than in other parts of the Philippines.
This may lack some accuracy because every questionable contract isn’t the result of corruption. Higher
83
rates of poor contracts, though, are more likely in more corrupt areas. However, this measure does have
precision since the measures being used are the same everywhere. Public procurement rules are
uniform across the Philippines and the last major reform to the public procurement system was in 2003.
The Philippines is unusual for a developing country in terms of how advanced its electronic public
procurement system is. Since 2000, even before the law was officially passed, the Philippines has moved
toward an online system for public procurement. PhilGEPS (Philippines Government Electronic
Procurement System) is now supposed to include all public procurements in the Philippines. While it
does not include all procurements (many of the small barangays lack the technical or language skills to
The public procurement system was created, in part, to reduce corruption but still allows a lot of
corruption to slip through. Rosa Clemente, the deputy director of PhilGEPS, said that PhilGEPS “can’t
eradicate but minimizes corruption” (Interview Clemente). I expect to find evidence of corruption in
procurement data from PhilGEPS because there is no real punishment for having contracts in the system
that fail to live up to the standards. Many contracts entered into PhilGEPS show that contracts weren’t
posted correctly, or don’t list who won the bidding. According to the law, this could result in some
punishment for the bureaucrats who oversee the system, but I was told that in practice this doesn’t
happen (Interview PhilGEPS Staff). The national auditing agency, the Commission on Audit, does
sometimes produce audits of procurements that result in legal action, but they often rely on reports of
possible corruption (Interview COA). There are too many technical violations in PhilGEPS for a relatively
small organization like the COA to investigate. So, while PhilGEPS data is public those engaging in
corruption don’t need to worry much about the trail they may be leaving.
I look at data from 2004 to 2019, which includes 9.1 million public procurements. These include federal
agencies, provincial spending, city and municipal spending, school and hospital spending, and even
procurements on the barangay level. For my work, I am looking specifically at the procurements in a
84
province or at the city/municipal level. The number of provinces and municipalities in the data set
increases over time. In 2004 only about 60 of the provincial governments were adding all contracts to
PhilGEPS but by 2007 it was more than 70. The exact numbers are a hard to pin down since PhilGEPS
doesn’t have a clear standard for when a province was added. Each province has some contracts back to
2004, but they become more complete moving forward. Similarly, in 2004 only about 500 municipalities
and cities were in PhilGEPS, but by 2010 it was virtually all of them.
What this means is that for provinces there is data back to 2004, but the number of
procurements in the system increases greatly over time. In 2004, there were only about 40,000
procurements in the system per year. By 2010, it was more than 250,000. Today, it is about 800,000 a
year. So, if I compare someone who was governor only from 2004-2007 with someone who was
governor from 2016-2019, then the second person would have many more public procurement
contracts in his term. I use controls for how many terms someone was governor and how many
contracts they had across all their terms. For municipalities, many have no data from 2004 or 2007. Any
mayor who simply has no public procurement data is dropped from the data set. For those with some
years for which there is data and some with no data, a control is used for the number of missing terms
The public procurement data itself is organized by each procurement opened. That includes
public bidding, where anyone can bid, negotiated procurement, where the contract is awarded directly,
and even shopping for small items. Very small regular items (paper and pens for example) can be bought
directly from another arm of the Department of Budget and Management and don’t show up in the data
set. Some of the data is too specific to be useful. The name of the specific item acquired is entered by
hand so even for similar items there is no uniformity. After conducting interviews and reviewing the
data with one of the directors of PhilGEPS, I identified eight factors that could be used to compare
procurements. Procurement Mode: if a contract was open to public bidding. Approved Budget of the
85
Contract: the amount of money allocated for the contract. Time to Close: how long the contract was
open for bidding. Classification: whether the contract was for a good or service. Notice Status: was the
result of the bidding entered into PhilGEPS. Contract Duration: how long the contract was for. Award
Date to Publish: how long after the contract was awarded was the notice published. Effective Date to
End Date: how long the contract actually took to finish. These eight factors, which are measured for
For each contract, I created a latent variable measure using an IRT model. Not all the factors
load heavily onto the latent variable. The IRT model uses all eight factors, but two factors, Procurement
Mode and Time to Close, do most of the work in determining the latent corruption score for each
contract. Procurement Mode is a measure of if the contract was open to public bidding or if it was
directly awarded to a company. As noted above, the importance of competitive bidding to the
cleanliness of contracts is well established in the literature. Time to Close is a measure of how long
companies had to bid on each contract. They are supposed to have at least two weeks, but contracts are
often open for less time. This violates the procurement law and provides an opportunity for corruption
as only connected companies may know of an opportunity to bid on a procurement contract. Appendix
B has more details on exactly how the latent score is measured. In the end, each contract gets a latent
variable score for how likely it is to be corrupt. These scores are relative to the other contracts. A score
of 0 means that the contract has an average likelihood of being corrupt. A score of 1 means it has 1
standard deviation more than average chance of being corrupt. A score of -1 means 1 standard
The graph below is a density plot of all 9.1 million latent corruption scores, one for each
contract. As the graph shows, it goes from about -2 to about 2, with several peaks. Each procurement
contract is used to create the measure and each contract gets a corruption score. These scores are then
averaged to create scores for each province (or municipality) and year. For each governor and mayor, I
86
also average across term. From Figure 2, below, Sulu has an average latent corruption score of about -1
during the 2004-2007 term. That means that, on average, all the contracts in Sulu from 2004-2007 were
one standard deviation less likely to be corrupt than the overall average. This is all weighted by the
So, what does the result of all this modeling look like on the provincial level? Since I am looking at
corruption for a governor or mayor, I averaged the corruption score for each contract by province or
municipality and term. The average scores for provinces varied quite a bit between provinces and in
some cases quite a bit over time as well. The graph below is five provinces with one score for each term
from 2004 to 2019. So, for Abra in 2004 to 2007, all the contracts are added and averaged. This gives a
rating for the province for the 2004 term of .03, meaning the corruption was very close to average.
However, by 2010 the rating was -.9 almost a full standard deviation less corrupt than average. The
overall range was from about 1.5 to -1.5 so a score of -.9 is good. We see Agusan Del Norte scoring
above average throughout the whole period. Eastern Samar starts with a very high corruption score,
above 1, but moves closer to average over time. I averaged for municipalities in the same way.
87
Figure 2: Corruption in Five Provinces
Finally, this is all combined into one score for each governor and mayor. So, if someone is governor of
Sulu in 2004 and then again in 2010 they get a score of around -1 for 2004 and about -.5 for 2010. That
governor’s overall corruption score would be -0.75. Figure 3, below, is a density graph of the latent score
for all the governors and mayors. Governors is the solid line and mayors the dashed line. As seen from
the graph, most governors are a bit below average on their province’s corruption score, while mayors
are well below average on corruption. This may reflect the fact that it is a relative minority of governors
and mayors who are doing most of the dirt. In other words, the mode is lower than the mean. The mode
for mayors can be much lower than zero, even as zero is by definition the average contract, because
88
Figure 3: Latent Corruption Score Mayors and Governors
Methods
This section describes the methods used to examine the data, and the controls used. From the previous
section, we can see that there is data on every governor or mayor who was prosecuted for corruption.
There is data on the size of each dynasty an elected official is part of and the overall concentration of
dynasties in their province or municipality. Finally, there is data on corruption from the quality of public
procurement contracts for each governor or mayor for their time in office compared to the national
average.
Since the dependent variable, prosecution, is a binary variable I need to use a logistic regression.
The linear predictor is straightforward: where “prosecution” is if a mayor of governor was prosecuted,
“corruption” is the quality of public procurement contract when they were in office, and “dynasty” is the
89
I expect B1 to be positive as more corruption should lead to a higher chance of prosecution. B2 should be
negative as stronger dynastic concentration should lower the chance of prosecution. Most importantly,
B3 should be negative as the effect of corruption on the chance of prosecution should go down as
dynasties become more powerful. That’s the key relationship. As dynasties become more ingrained,
even higher levels of corruption shouldn’t lead to a much greater chance of being prosecuted. The
regression in its basic form is the same for governors and mayors. The relationship between mayors or
governors and corruption should be the same overall. As noted before, in addition to the dynastic
concentration measure (HHI), I also examine if the same effect can be seen with the ratio of seats a
It is important to note that because the models include an interaction and because it is a logistic
regression, we can’t be certain from the sign and significance of a regression table if things are as they
appear. As Ai and Norton (2003) show us, in a logistic regression the link function acts to weakly interact
all the variables, so even the sign and significance can’t be taken at face value. I present a few predicted
probability plots that show the key relationship. While Ai and Norton are correct that we can’t assume
the sign and significance are correct for logistic regression, in almost all cases something like a predicted
I also show the results from a survival model. The data for both governors and mayors is right-
censored. Just because someone hasn’t been arrested for corruption doesn’t mean he won’t be. Survival
models deal with right censored data because they estimate a hazard ratio. A hazard ratio is a
combination of an unconditional failure function -- how likely mayors or governors are to be prosecuted
at a point in time -- and a survival function -- how likely mayors or governors are to not be prosecuted at
a point in time. Right censored data, that is mayors or governors who haven’t been prosecuted so far,
give information about the survival but not the failure. While this is a theoretically sounder way to deal
90
with right censored data, it does effectively reduce the degrees of freedom by discarding a lot of
information.
Finally, I will briefly cover the measurement of the controls I used in the key regressions. First, I
included a control for the total number of contracts included in the corruption measure for every
governor and mayor. My concern was that places that had more contracts entered into PhilGEPS might
simply be places that were more scrutinized in general and thus more likely to see prosecutions.
Governors oversaw orders of magnitude more contracts than mayors. The mean for governors was
15,000 contracts while for mayors it was only about 200 contracts. The provincial contracts include the
public procurement contracts for the municipalities that make up the province.
Second, I included a control for the number of terms served for a mayor or a governor. Since
each row is a single leader, some served for three or four terms while others only served for a single
term. This was somewhat covered by the number of contracts but not completely. In addition, those
who served for more terms might be more likely to have been prosecuted simply because they were
more in the public eye. This control should deal with this being an unbalanced panel. Governors and
mayors are prohibited from serving more than three consecutive terms but may return to office after
skipping an election. There are ways around this, though. Mayors, especially, have served more than
three terms by legal maneuvering. One mayor in the data set served in all five terms under
consideration.
I include three controls that are alternative ways of measuring dynasties: the number of
relatives in office in the province or municipality; if the governor is related to a mayor or congressman,
or for mayors if they are related to the governor or a congressman; and the percent of seats in a
province or municipality held by a dynasty. This shows that dynastic concentration is associated with
lower prosecutions even when considering other ways of measuring dynasties. I also included two
91
controls for both the governor and mayor data that only are measured on the provincial level. These
measures simply don’t exist on the local level for all of the Philippines. First is the state population.
While population data is available for many municipalities, it isn’t available for all of them and isn’t
updated regularly. Population ranges from 15,000 for the smallest province to above 4 million. The
second is poverty. Poverty is measured as the percent of families in a province falling below that
province’s poverty threshold. In the poorest provinces this can be well over 50%. All these controls
would be useful to have on the local level as well, but the data simply doesn’t exist to make such a thing
viable.
There is also a control for the average size of the public procurement contracts, to control for
bigger contracts having a different relationship with corruption. Finally, there are controls for whether a
governor was a former mayor and whether a governor or mayor had a family member indicted for
corruption. The idea behind this control is that once someone in your family was indicted it might be
more likely you are indicted as well. Table 1, below, shows the summary statistics for the control
variables.
92
Table 1: Controls
Provincial Procurement
Budget Average (in thousands) 5 1139 1961 2902 2947 50679
Municipal Procurement
Budget Average (in thousands) 14 1158 1835 2339 2840 27693
Governor Former Mayor? 0 0 0 0.051 0 1
Family Member Indicted
(governors) 0 1 1 0.756 1 1
Family Member Indicted
(mayors) 0 0 1 0.6475 1 1
Table 2 shows the results from the key regressions for governors. Model 1 includes all the controls but
not the interaction. The signs are all as expected, but the dynastic HHI isn’t statistically significant.
Increased corruption, though, is still statistically significantly associated with prosecution risk. In all the
models being linked to a mayor or congressman was associated with a lower chance of prosecution;
however, there is no interactive effect with corruption. Model 2 is the most important. This includes the
93
key variables as well as controls for the total number of contracts, the number of terms served by each
governor, the number of relatives they have in the province (another measure of dynasty), if they have a
link to a mayor or congressman (another measure of dynasty), the number of available seats in the
province, the percent of seats the governor’s dynasty controls (another measure of dynasty), the level of
poverty in the province, and the population in the province, the average size of public procurement
contracts, if the governor was a former mayor, and if a relative of the governor was indicted.
In Model 2, the interaction between dynasty concentration and corruption is significant at the
.10 level. Corruption is also statistically significantly correlated with a higher chance of prosecution. The
concentration of dynasties is correlated with a lower chance of prosecution. The interaction shows us
that in provinces with concentrated dynasties, higher corruption doesn’t lead to a higher chance of
prosecution but in provinces with less concentrated dynasties higher corruption does lead to a higher
chance of prosecution. This is what I expected to find. However, because of the nature of a logistic
regression we need to see a predicted probability plot to be sure these relationships exist.
Figure 4, below, is a predicted probability plot for corruption from Model 2, controlling for the
other variables. As corruption increases the chance of prosecution increases quite dramatically from
around 0% to around 40%. This also suggests that the measurement model is capturing an important
aspect of the public procurement contracts. Otherwise, it wouldn’t likely be correlated with
prosecutions. It also shows that the Ombudsman is getting at least some of the corrupt politicians.
Holding dynasties constant, having more suspicious public procurement contracts in a province is
94
Table 2: Governor Results
95
Figure 4: Governor Prosecution Change by Corruption
Figure 5 is a predicted probability plot of the effect of dynastic concentration on prosecution chance
from Model 2. As HHI goes up, and dynasties become more concentrated in a province, the chance of
prosecution drops substantially. The number of relatives a governor has in a province, however, does
not have a statistically significant relationship with prosecution chance. The link to a mayor or
congressman does have a significant relationship, but a predicted probability graph shows that the size
of the effect is small. In addition, while not shown for space, an interaction between corruption and the
96
Figure 5: Governor Prosecution Chance by HHI
Finally, Figure 6 is a margins plot which shows an example of the interaction. The red line is a province
with a low HHI, i.e., not concentrated dynasties. For such a province, as corruption increases, the chance
of prosecution increases from about 0% to around 75%. On the other hand, for a province with a high
HHI, strongly concentrated dynasties, as corruption increases the chance of prosecution remains flat.
The power of dynasties in a province determines if governors can get away with corruption. This
relationship is only significant at the .10 level but given how few observations there are the results are
still interesting.
97
Figure 6: Interaction Between Corruption and HHI
Model 3, from Table 2, interacts corruption with the percent of seats in a province a dynasty controls.
The interaction for percent of seats is not statistically significant. The same is true if the size of the
dynasty, as opposed to the percent, is used instead of the concentration of dynasties. This is an
interesting result because it shows that the size of a particular dynasty doesn’t matter, while the
concentration of dynasties overall does. Finally, Model 4 uses the same variables as Model 2 but instead
of a logistic regression, it is a Cox proportional hazards model. This survival model allows for the fact
that the data is right censored. Unfortunately, given that I have only 209 observations and a survival
model essentially discounts some of the information, the key interaction is not significant. However, the
Table 3, below, shows the key regression for the mayors data set. The number of observations is
more than ten times higher than in the governors data set. Model 1 again doesn’t include the
98
interaction. In the mayor data set the corruption measure is not statistically significant by itself, though
it is going in the expected direction for four out of five models. I believe this is because the interaction is
larger here and corruption behaves differently at different levels of dynasty HHI. Model 2 includes all the
previous controls as well as a measure of how many terms there are for which the public procurement
data is missing. 2004 and 2007 are missing much of the public procurement data on a municipal level. It
also includes a control for the number of available seats in a province and municipality, though the
As with the governor data, it is important to look at predicted probability graphs for the key
model. Figure 7, below, shows that like what we see with governors, for mayors, as dynastic HHI rises in
a province, their chance of prosecution goes down. The chance of prosecution, though, is lower overall.
This makes sense as there are many mayors, some of which are likely to be beneath the notice of the
Ombudsman with its limited resources. Figure 8 shows the interaction. Like for governors, in a province
with a low HHI, mayors who have high levels of corruption in their municipality are more likely to be
prosecuted. Mayors in provinces with a high HHI are not more likely to be prosecuted as corruption
increases.
Returning to Table 3, Model 3 is the same as Model 2 but with two provincial controls removed.
The interaction in Model 3 is significant at a .05 level. The provincial controls may be adding noise as
they are the same for many municipalities. In the end, the relationship is the same, but the confidence
intervals are a bit smaller. Model 4 uses the percent of seats held by a dynasty in a municipality. Here
the interaction is not significant. This is the same result as seen for governors. Finally, Model 5 is a
survival model. Unlike for governors, the interaction is statistically significant here, probably due to a
much larger number of observations. This suggests the right bias in the data isn’t so much biasing results
99
Table 3: Mayor Results
100
Figure 7: Mayor Prosecution Chance by HHI
101
These regression models demonstrate a few things. First, the measure of corruption is working.
Provinces and municipalities with weak dynasties and high corruption see more prosecutions than those
with low corruption. If the quality of contracts were divorced from the actions of mayors and governors,
I wouldn’t expect to see any relationship, but a relationship does exist. Second, the overall
concentration of dynasties is what matters to prosecution. While having more dynastic members might
signal power or be an electoral advantage, it doesn’t affect the chance of being prosecuted. For mayors,
having a link to a congressman or the governor is also not associated with a lower prosecution chance.
This is also true if you interact these measures with corruption. This is a surprising result. It shows that it
is the overall situation created by dynasties that hinders prosecution, not their specific disposition. It is
undeniable that some politicians can influence the Ombudsman, but this evidence suggests that those
instances are rarer one-offs while dynasties as a group change how crime is investigated in a province
such that the Ombudsman can’t make cases. How corruption affects prosecutions is dependent on the
concentration of dynasties. It’s not just that in provinces with powerful dynasties we see fewer
prosecutions; it’s that we see no change in prosecution chances as corruption goes up. These dynasties
can act to allow mayors and governors to get away with significant corruption. In provinces with small
and weak dynasties, low corruption leads to a small risk of prosecution while high corruption leads to a
Finally, the same principle holds true for mayors as well as governors. Governors are more likely
to be prosecuted overall, but mayors whose municipalities show corrupt contracts and who don’t live in
a province with large dynasties risk prosecution. Mayors, on the other hand, who live in a province with
powerful dynasties don’t see their risk of prosecution increase even as corruption worsens. For the
corrupt, it’s better to be a small fish in a very dynastically controlled province than a big fish in a
102
Conclusion
To understand the relationship between corruption, prosecution, and dynasties, I examined three key
factors. Who was prosecuted for corruption in the dedicated anti-corruption court? How much
corruption there was in different municipalities and provinces based on the quality of their public
procurement contracts? How much power do dynasties have in different provinces? Using these
measures, I showed that in places where dynasties hold many of the key offices, corruption does not
lead to more prosecutions. In places where dynasties hold few of the elected offices, corruption does
lead to more prosecutions. This works the same way for governors and mayors. The size or connections
of one dynasty are not important when controlling for the overall power and scope of dynasties in a
province. A mayor who comes from a large dynasty is not better protected than one from a small
dynasty. What matters is the overall power of dynasties in a province. Corruption can be assessed by
looking at public procurement contracts in cities and provinces. As was suggested in interviews, the
most important factor is if a contract is open to public bidding or if it is awarded directly to one
company.
More work is needed to provide evidence for exactly how dynasties are changing the
Ombudsman’s work, in particular provinces. There is also some level of political protection that exists
for powerful families. The fact that it wasn’t detected here suggests that it isn’t available widely, but it’s
possible with a more sensitive measure of the most powerful dynasties, we would be able to see when
they are protected. The next section of this dissertation will show how for those indicted for corruption,
103
Work Cited
Ai, Chunrong and Edward C. Norton (2003). “Interaction terms in logit and probit models”. In: Economics
Letters 80.1, pp. 123–129. issn: 01651765. doi: 10.1016/S0165-1765(03)00032-6.
Amundsen, Inge (2016). “Democratic dynasties? Internal party democracy in Bangladesh”. In: Party
Politics 22.1, pp. 49–58. issn: 14603683. doi: 10.1177/1354068813511378.
Anderson, C. J., & Tverdova, Y. V. (2003). Corruption, political allegiances, and attitudes toward
government in contemporary democracies. American journal of political science, 47(1), 91-109.
Ansari, Asim, Kamel Jedidi, and Laurette Dube (2002). “Heterogeneous factor analysis models: A
Bayesian approach”. In: Psychometrika 67.1, pp. 49–77. issn: 00333123. doi:
10.1007/BF02294709.
Aspinall, E., Davidson, M. W., Hicken, A., & Weiss, M. L. (2016). Local machines and vote brokerage in
the Philippines. Contemporary Southeast Asia, 38(2), 191-196.
Auriol, Emmanuelle, Stephane Straub, and Thomas Flochel (2016). “Public Procurement and Rent-
Seeking: The Case of Paraguay”. In: World Development 77, pp. 395–407.
Azfar, O., & Gurgur, T. (2006). Local-level corruption hits health service delivery in the Philippines.
Transparency International, Global Corruption Report, 37-39.
Burgess, Robin et al. (2015). “The value of democracy: evidence from road building in Kenya”. In:
American Economic Review 105.6, pp. 1817–1851.
Castillo, Nadja A. (2010). BILIRAN PROVINCE: PROBING INTO A POSSIBLE AUTOMATED CHEATING. Tech.
rep. EU-CenPEG Project 3030, p. 26.
Chen, Ting and KAI-SING JAMES Kung (2019). “BUSTING THE PRINCELINGS THE CAMPAIGN AGAINST
CORRUPTION IN CHINA’S PRIMARY LAND MARKET”. In: Quarterly Journal of Economics, pp. 185–
226. doi: 10.1093/qje/qjy027.Advance.
Coviello, Decio and Stefano Gagliarducci (2010). “Building Political Collusion: Evidence from
Procurement Auctions”. In: IZA Discussion Paper 4939.
Cruz, Cesi, Julien Labonne, and Pablo Querubin (2020). “Social Network Structures and the Politics of
Public Goods Provision: Evidence from the Philippines”. In: American Political Science Review
114.2, pp. 486–501. issn: 15375943. doi: 10.1017/S0003055419000789.
Desierto, Desiree A (2020). “Grand Corruption by Theft and Bribery”
De Sousa, L. (2010). Anti-corruption agencies: between empowerment and irrelevance. Crime, law and
social change, 53(1), 5-22.
De Speville, B. (2010). Anticorruption commissions: the “Hong Kong model” revisited. Asia-Pacific
Review, 17(1), 47-71.
Di Tella, R., & Schargrodsky, E. (2003). The role of wages and auditing during a crackdown on corruption
in the city of Buenos Aires. The Journal of Law and Economics, 46(1), 269-292.
Fazekas, M., Tóth, I. J., & King, L. P. (2016). An objective corruption risk index using public procurement
data. European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research, 22(3), 369-397.
104
Fiva, J. H., & Smith, D. M. (2018). Political dynasties and the incumbency advantage in party-centered
environments. American Political Science Review, 112(3), 706-712.
Folke, Olle, Torsten Persson, and Johanna Rickne (2017). “Dynastic Political Rents? Economic Benefits to
Relatives of Top Politicians”. In: Economic Journal 127.605, F495–F517. issn: 14680297. doi:
10.1111/ecoj.
Heilbrunn, J. R. (2004). Anti-corruption commissions: Panacea or real medicine to fight corruption.
World Bank Institute, 2.
Jopson, T. L. A. (2013). Silent Assault: Multilevel Censorship as Media Repression in the Philippines.
Philippine Social Sciences Review, 65(2).
Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. The quarterly journal of economics, 110(3), 681-712.
McCubbins, M. D., & Schwartz, T. (1984). Congressional oversight overlooked: Police patrols versus fire
alarms. American journal of political science, 165-179.
Mendoza, Ronald U. et al. (2013). “Political Dynasties and Poverty : Evidence From the Philippines”. In:
12th National Convention on Statistics 44.2, pp. 189–201.
Mendoza, Ronald U. et al. (2020). “Term limits and political dynasties in the Philippines: Unpacking the
links”. In: Asia-Pacific Social Science Review 20.4, pp. 88–99. issn: 01198386.
Mendoza, R. U., Hiwatig, J., & Banaag, M. (2020). Dynastic Political Networks: Insights from the Case of
Western Samar, Philippines.
Olken, B. A. (2007). Monitoring corruption: evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia. Journal of
political Economy, 115(2), 200-249.
Paoli, Letizia (2007). “Mafia and organized crime in Italy: The unacknowledged successes of law
enforcement”. In: West European Politics 30.4, pp. 854–880. issn: 01402382.
Quah, Jon ST. "Defying institutional failure: learning from the experiences of anti-corruption agencies in
four Asian countries." Crime, Law and Social Change 53, no. 1 (2010): 23-54.
Querubin, Pablo (2011). “Political reform and elite persistence: Term limits and political dynasties in the
Philippines”. In: Mimeo. url: http://pclt.cis.yale.edu/leitner/resources/papers/Querubin_Term_
Limits.pdf.
– (2016). “Family and politics: Dynastic persistence in the philippines”. In: Quarterly Journal of Political
Science 11.2, pp. 151–181. issn: 15540634. doi: 10.1561/100.00014182.
Quimpo, Nathan Gilbert. "Can the Philippines’ wild oligarchy be tamed?." In Routledge handbook of
Southeast Asian democratization, pp. 347-362. Routledge, 2014.
Ravanilla, Nico, Renard Sexton, and Dotan Haim (2019). “Outsiders vs . Insiders : How Local Politics
Drives Duterte ’ s War on Drugs in the Philippines”. In.
Rotberg, R I (2019). The Corruption Cure: How Citizens and Leaders Can Combat Graft. Princeton
University Press. isbn: 9780691191577. url:
https://books.google.com/books?id=d8iXDwAAQBAJ.
Szeftel, Morris (2000). “Between Governance and Under- development: Accumulation and Africa’s
’Catastrophic Corruption’”. In: Review of African Political Economy 27.84, pp. 287–306.
105
Teehankee, Julio C (2012). “Clientelism and party politics in the Philippines”. In: Party Politics in
Southeast Asia. Chap. 10, pp. 186–214.
Timberman, D. G. (2016). The Vote in the Philippines: Elite Democracy Disrupted?. Journal of
Democracy, 27(4), 135-144.
Winters, Jeffrey (2011) Oligarchy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Yilmaz, S., & Venugopal, V. (2013). Local government discretion and accountability in Philippines. Journal
of International Development, 25(2), 227-250.
106
Appendix A: Factors Measured for Public Procurement Contracts
Procurement Mode: Procurement mode is the first and most important factor I examine. This is if a
procurement is made through public bidding where anyone can submit a bid, or some form of
negotiated procurement where the winner is selected directly. There are quite a few different
categories of negotiated procurements. For example, there are negotiated procurements listed under
“Two Failed Biddings” where according to the law, the agency can skip public bidding if, for whatever
reason, that process has failed twice already. Alternatively, there is “Small Value Procurement” where
the procurement is under a certain threshold. The threshold ranges from 500,000 pesos (about $10,000)
for a city or province to about 50,000 pesos ($1,000) for the smallest municipalities.
I was advised by those who work directly on procurement reform in the Philippines (Commission
on Audit, personal communication, October 22 2019) that it was best to simply consider public
procurement meant slipping around some oversight. Most of the contracts entered into PhilGEPS are
negotiated procurements. In 2019 out of just under 800,000 procurements only about 280,000 were
open to public bidding. On the other hand, out of just under one trillion pesos in total contracts offered,
public bidding made up about 850 billion, or about 85% in terms of value.
Procurement mode is the most important factor because much of the outstanding research
shows us that when people are trying to hide corruption, they do so by awarding contracts directly. It’s
harder to hide corruption when there might be a low-cost bidder who doesn’t pay a bribe. Auriol,
Straub, and Flochel (2016) showed that in Paraguay when the government announced it would audit
hospital procurements much more closely the number of single bidder contracts fell off precipitously.
This also matches what I was told to watch for by the Commission on Audit.
107
Approved Budget of the Contract: This is the amount of Philippine’s pesos (php) that was
allocated for the contract. For some contracts, the approved budget of a single procurement may
appear more than once since contracts with multiple parts are usually listed with a single budget for all
the parts. While this does mean that some contracts appear more than once in the data set, this tends
to mostly be the case for smaller procurements. This shouldn’t bias the data as the type of contract, and
the size of the contract are also used to create the measure of corruption.
As noted above, contracts open for public bidding tend to be larger than the negotiated ones,
but there is still variation within both groups. There are more than 1.6 million contracts worth above
one million pesos. Of those about 1.5 million are public bidding while 100,000 are negotiated
procurements. In reverse, of the approximately 450,000 contracts worth less than 7,000 pesos about
It makes sense that large contracts are less associated with corruption. Desierto (2020) models
corruption in the Philippines and suggests that smaller spending is more associated with bribery and
kickbacks, which is what is likely to produce the faulty procurements I am measuring here. Larger
contracts are more subject to scrutiny. In the end the IRT model looks for levels that vary together and
are suggestive of an underlying latent variable. The fact that some budgets are more associated with
public bidding is not a problem. In fact, it makes the outliers stand out even more. If most large value
contracts are open to public bidding, and one is not, it will create a score much higher on the corruption
scale. On the other hand, if most small contracts are negotiated procurements, this would produce a
IRT models don’t allow for continuous variables, so I needed to transform the budget into an
ordinal measure. To do that I created 20 cut points with an approximately even number of contracts in
each tranche. The smallest tranche is from zero pesos to about 6,800. The 10th tranche goes from about
108
136,000 php to 168,000 php. The largest tranche is anything above 9.8 million. Creating 20 levels instead
of a continuous measure inherently loses some data, but a latent variable measure can’t contain both
continuous and binary data. You either must treat continuous data as ordinal, or nominal data as ordinal
or continuous. Treating continuous data as ordinal loses some precision but treating nominal as ordinal
Time to Close: Under the Philippines procurement law all procurement is supposed to be listed for 14
days before the period for bidding is closed. Of the 9.1 million contracts in the data set only about 2.1
million were open for the correct 14 days. The density plot below shows the distribution of the number
of days contracts were open. As is clear, the modal number is much less than 14. This was noted
look out for, as while 14 days is required by law, most contracts posted in PhilGEPS don’t follow these
rules.
Again, since IRTs don’t work with continuous data I had to transform the time into an ordinal
measure. I decided on levels with fairly even numbers of entries. Here I used four levels, 0-6 days, 6-8
days, 8-14 days, and more than 14 days. Since only the last group is following the law, I could have just
simplified it to a binary measure, but I didn’t see the need to do so, since nothing is biased with more
levels.
When localities don’t enter contracts correctly there are supposed to be penalties. I was told (PhilGEPS,
personal communication, October 27 2019) that according to the law civil servants would be denied
bonuses for problems like this, or not entering contract winners, but that in practice their supervisors
could simply allow them to have the bonuses anyway, so there is no strong incentive to make sure the
law is being followed. I believe that this helps my research. If the system were more secure, there would
be more pressure on those wishing to engage in corruption to falsify records. As it stands, no one in
109
power is checking up on how many negotiated procurements there are or when winners aren’t entered
in the system. When you see someone punished for a public procurement-related crime, the evidence
doesn’t come through PhilGEPS, but usually from some sort of informant.
Classification: PhilGEPS also includes information on how each procurement is classified. PhilGEPS
includes four classifications: Goods, Good – General Support Services, Civil Works, Consulting Services.
Of these, only 60,000 out of 9.1 million are listed as consulting services. 900,000 are civil works, and the
remaining 8 million are goods. My measure was simply, goods or not goods. I was concerned that
procurements of goods would be easier to fabricate than ones for services or projects, since overbuying
and underdelivering are key ways corruption is accomplished. One common scam described to me is an
agency placing a procurement for something like 200 chairs when they only need 100. The directed
winner only delivers 100 chairs and the payment for the other 100 is split between the official and the
110
Notice Status: While there are 9.1 million procurements between 2004 and 2019, in PhilGEPS only about
2 million of those include details on who won the procurement. There are several possible reasons for
this. It could be that the procurement offered failed and no winner was selected. It could be that they
cancelled the procurement before it got to that stage. It could be a lack of capacity on behalf of the
locality trying to enter the data. However, an official working for PhilGEPS speculated that it was in part
to dodge taxes. If you aren’t shown in the database being awarded a contract it’s harder to tax you. This
means that there are many procurements entered into the system without information on the winner
being added. In some of these cases there may not be a winner, but in an interview with the director of
PhilGEPS I was told that it was more likely that the information on the winner simply hadn’t been
entered.
This is, obviously, suspicious. Not entering the correct information can easily be another way to
avoid leaving evidence of corruption. Even though awards are more commonly entered for public bids
than for negotiated procurements, the IRT model didn’t group notice status into the same latent
measure as procurement mode. It’s possible that while not entering awards is suspicious, it just isn’t
how corruption is being hidden. The existing literature and my interviews only point to procurement
mode and time to close as key factors to look for, both of which were grouped into the same latent
variable.
Contract Duration: Contract duration is a measure for how long the contract is supposed to last. Unlike
“Effective Date to End Date,” listed below, this is the length the contract was listed as before it was
awarded. It can be zero for immediate purchases or hundreds of days for ongoing consultations. I
included this measure under the possibility that contracts that deviated from the norms might be more
likely to be corrupt. In the end this factor didn’t have much effect on the corruption measure or on the
other latent variable measure. As with previous factors I had to transform it from a continuous measure
to an ordinal one.
111
Award Date to Publish: I also included two measures that only applied to some of the procurements. The
time from a contract being awarded to the award being announced, and the time from when the work
could start to when it was finished, both rely on data that was only entered for procurements whose
award was entered. The 2 million out of 9 whose award notice was correctly entered. This isn’t a
problem for an IRT model, as a null reading on any part of the measure simply aren’t included for that
item. What it does mean, though, is that measures with an award drew on somewhat more data. This
shouldn’t bias the results, since the IRT model includes the fact some procurements had no awards, but
it does mean some parts are more precisely measured than others.
For those 2 million procurements, the date of the award and the date when the award is
notified to the public are both recorded. I heard stories about companies not knowing that they had
won a contract until they were supposed to start working on it. In addition, there are several contracts
entered where the publish date is listed as before the award date. This is more likely to be a measure of
incompetence than corruption, but it was worth including to see if it varied with the corruption
measure.
Effective Date to End Date: Finally, I included a measure of the time from when work was supposed to
start to when it was completed. While this is mostly directly a measure of efficiency or competence, it
could theoretically also be a measure of corruption, as a company might keep a project going far longer
than necessary as part of a scheme to run up the final bill. This was transformed into an ordinal measure
112
Appendix B
The eight factor measures don’t directly measure corruption. As we have seen in other work, though,
corruption can be inferred from some aspects of public procurement contracts the way Auriol, Straub,
and Flochel (2016) do in Paraguay. What’s needed is to combine them into a latent variable measure.
There are a few possible ways to measure latent variables. Factor analysis is probably the best known
but doesn’t work with binary measures. Instead, I use an IRT measure to look at how these different
Item Response Theory was developed to examine questions in standardized tests. We can
imagine each question on the test having two parameters: difficulty and discrimination. Difficulty is how
hard a question is. Discrimination is how well a question separates one student from another. So, if
there is a question about Greek grammar on a math test, it will likely have a high difficulty, but not really
help us separate one student from another. Questions don’t need to be difficult to be good. An easy
question that still separates low skill from very low skill is a useful question.
An IRT model will use the difficulty and discrimination of each question to also determine the
skill of the respondent. In a test that’s how well they score. This is how SAT scores are determined.
Applied to measuring corruption, we can think of each question as one of the eight measures of public
procurement contracts listed above. Difficulty is how much a level of a measure suggests a high
corruption score. Discrimination is how much it separates one contract from another. In the end I get a
score for each procurement in terms of the underlying latent value, corruption.
Below is an item response curve for procurement mode. The x-axis is possible scores for a
procurement on the latent trait theta which is corruption. The y-axis is the probability of procurement
being open to public bidding. So, if a procurement has a corruption score of one, the probability of that
113
procurement involving public bidding is close to 100%. This is a very useful measure for the latent
variable as it has a high discrimination. It clearly separates some procurements from others.
Next is an item curve for time to close. Here there are four curves since the variable is ordinal
with four levels. The separation isn’t quite as clear. A contract with a latent variable score of one has
about a 75% chance of being in the fourth category. To create a single measure of the latent score for
each contract, the model takes the curve for whatever category the contract is in for each measure and
combines them, in effect creating a weighted average. However, the weighting is decided by the data
itself. This ends up with something like a factor analysis, but the weighting can vary greatly. A measure
that has little effect will have a very flat curve and not impact the overall latent score much at all. Each
contract gets a score where zero is the average and one is one standard deviation higher on the latent
ability (corruption). Each score isn’t directly interpretable, but it tells us if the contract is more or less
IRT Graph 1
114
IRT Graph 2
From all eight item curves, the model calculates a latent ability score, here corruption, for each
contract. However, the model I use calculates two latent scores for each contract based on a scree plot
and a factor analysis. While a traditional factor analysis doesn’t work with binary data Ansari, Jedidi, and
Dube (2002) tell us that a heterogeneous correlation matrix will be able to approximate the correlation
matrix necessary for a factor analysis. From this I can derive the scree plot below.
115
Scree Plot
From this scree plot we can see that two factors are the most appropriate number of latent
variables to pull from this data. The result is confirmed by looking at factor loadings. The table below
shows the factor loadings. This is how much each measure affects each latent variable. I’ve highlighted
in yellow the factors that most heavily affect the latent variable, corruption. Procurement mode, time to
close, and budget, have the largest effect. This is what I would expect. Based on interviews and the
I would label factor one as the competence or efficiency with which contracts are worked. It
draws most heavily on how long the contract takes to complete but also is affected by if the contract is
correctly entered into the system and how large the budget it. Every factor, though, has some effect on
both latent variables. The model determines exactly how much affect and for what level. The two latent
variables are somewhat correlated with a Pearson’s of .65. That isn’t surprising ,since they draw on the
same underlying factors and both utilize the budget of the contract.
116
IRT Factor Table
117
Accountability for Corruption Through
Elections in the Philippines
118
Introduction
When surveyed, the vast majority of Filipinos say that corruption is one of the biggest threats facing the
country. Yet in election after election, corrupt politicians win high and low offices. If corruption matters
to voters, why don’t they reject corrupt politicians? Worldwide, there is a gap between how people
describe their hatred for corruption and corrupt politicians winning elections. It’s possible people don’t
care as much about corruption as they claim to, but that seems unlikely, given we see whole revolutions,
recently Tunisia, kicked off by issues of corruption. It also isn’t plausible that people simply have no
choice but to vote for corrupt politicians. In the upcoming presidential election in the Philippines
Ferdinand "Bongbong" Marcos Jr., son of the late dictator, is leading the field, including some reform
minded candidates, by a large margin. The Marcos family, who stole billions and have not had to return
most of their looted wealth, are some of the most corrupt leaders to ever live.
This paper examines what obstacles there are to vertical accountability. Vertical accountability is
when voters hold elected officials accountable, as opposed to horizontal accountability where one part
of the government holds another part of the government accountable. I find that when voters have
evidence that a politician is corrupt, they are less likely to support that politician. The problem is that
dynasties can suppress that evidence. This paper builds off the last chapter to examine under what
circumstances those who are indicted for corruption are punished by voters. As shown in the last paper,
in provinces with a high concentration of dynasties, as corruption increases, prosecutions stay flat and
low. This means that in those provinces where dynasties are the most concentrated, voters don’t get
information about corruption. So, voters will reject corrupt politicians, but only under circumstances.
I analyzed ten elections from 1992 to 2019 and found that for mayors there is a small but
noticeable (about 5-7%) decrease in their chance of winning an election if they have been indicted for
corruption. So, there is vertical accountability, but not a huge amount. People care, but other factors
119
have a much stronger correlation with a candidate’s chance of winning. For example, if a candidate has
more than two relatives already holding office when they run, i.e., if they’re from at least a moderately
sized dynasty, that candidate’s chance of winning is close to 100% whether or not they have been
indicted for corruption. Incumbency also provides, on average, a 40% greater chance at winning
reelection, an advantage that dwarfs any problem being indicted for corruption might cause.
For other offices, those who were indicted for corruption saw a decreased chance to win
election, but the results were not statistically significant. The corruption prosecutor, the Ombudsman,
targets mayors much more than other positions. Since the Ombudsman’s inception, there were 1,444
mayors indicted compared to only 177 vice-mayors and 115 city councilors. Only 117 governors were
prosecuted, but there are many more mayors than governors, so governors were prosecuted at a higher
rate. Still, compared to other local officials, mayors were a major target. That’s not surprising. The
structure of local governments gives the mayors disproportionate power over the local budgets and
This paper begins with an explanation of what has been written about corruption,
accountability, elections, and the Philippines and how this work fits in and expands on that. Next, this
paper includes a description of how prosecutions for corruption and elections work in the Philippines,
with a focus on how they are being undermined. Then, this paper will include details of how the data
was collected and what the limitation of this data is. Afterward, this paper has a description of the
models used and the results of those models. Finally, this paper ends with an analysis of what the data
120
Literature and Theory
Why does vertical accountability fail? Why people vote for corrupt politicians while professing to hate
corruption is one of the most important questions facing corruption scholars. One idea is that voters
may lack information on who is corrupt. Winters and Weitz-Shapiro (2013) find that voters don’t believe
they’ve voted for corrupt politicians but when presented with evidence of corruption, they were less
likely to vote for those politicians. Klasnja, Tucker, and Deegan-Krause (2014) distinguish between voting
because of a general belief in a high level of corruption and voting because of specific knowledge of
corruption. Looking at Slovakia, they also find that when there is specific evidence of corruption, or a
personal experience with corruption, voters are more likely to reject politicians. Similarly, Pavão (2018)
argues that when corruption is pervasive, voters will believe all politicians are corrupt and vote on other
issues, but when corruption is low, voters will punish corrupt politicians. Agerberg (2020) finds that
There is a disagreement in the literature, though, on how increased information affects voting
behavior. Chong et al. (2015) find that knowing more about corruption is linked to lower voter turnout
in Mexican elections. Voters may be turned off by the political process by hearing about corruption.
Banerjee et al. (2011) show that in India, increased voter information only helps challengers, not
incumbents. That may be because voters already have a clear picture of incumbents that is hard to
change. Welch and Hibbing (1997) find the opposite. Looking at US House races, they find incumbents
charged with corruption have a lower chance of reelection. Humphreys and Weinstein (2012) examine
how in Uganda, voters indicated in surveys they were very interested in information on elected officials’
performance, but they found that officials didn’t change their behavior in response and didn’t suffer
electoral consequences. Boas et al. (2019) find in Brazil, that in surveys experiments with theoretical,
corrupt mayors voters indicate they will reject them, but when asked about their actual voting behavior,
voters still vote for corrupt politicians. This could explain the difference in voting behavior suggested by
121
the different studies. Voters may say they oppose corruption, but not actually vote out corrupt
politicians in the end. Boas et al. also find that other sources of information like party of dynasties have
a larger effect on voter behavior. If they are right, we would expect evidence of corruption in the
However, Ferraz and Finan (2007) take advantage of a natural experiment in Brazil where the
results of corruption audits were released in some places, and randomly not in others, before an
election. They find that when voters have evidence of a single instance of corruption before an election,
they are 4.6% less likely to reelect the politician. They also find that corruption is only one factor that
voters look at. For otherwise very popular politicians, a 4.6% decrease is not insurmountable, though
they find the effect is larger when multiple instances of corruption are reported. That is in line with the
5-7% reduction I found for politicians who had been indicted for corruption. Boas et al. also suggest that
the difference between their findings and those of Ferraz and Finan is that Ferraz and Finan were
dealing with a clearer source of information on corruption given to voters. In Boas et al.’s study
information on corruption came mostly from other political parties. This might also explain why I find a
reduction as the Ombudsman is a more trustworthy source than political ads. Finally, De Vries & Solaz
(2017) reviewed the literature on corruption and elections and found that the key to voters punishing
There is also a debate about the relative role of horizontal and vertical accountability. Hong
Kong and Singapore’s amazing success in combating corruption through strong anti-corruption agencies
led to this horizontal model being suggested as the key to fighting corruption worldwide. Other agencies
that had less success were criticized for not following the Hong Kong or Singapore model closely enough
(Quah 2010, or de Speville 2010). Other authors have suggested that this model will fail in all but a few
circumstances (Heilbrunn 2004). Finally, some argue that this sort of horizontal accountability can work
122
to some degree (Schutte 2012). For those who believe elections (vertical accountability) to be a weak or
This paper examines how the vertical accountability of voters punishing elected officials for
corruption relies on a system of horizontal accountability (in the Philippines the office of the
Ombudsman). Even if the Ombudsman fails to win convictions, it may still have some power if voters
are less likely to vote for candidates who have been exposed as corrupt. This relationship is similar to
what Ferraz and Finan found. In that case, audits were conducted by the government, a system of
horizontal accountability, but the punishment came from announcing the result. However, this further
highlights the problem of dynasties. Since the last paper showed us that the Ombudsman isn’t working
correctly in areas with a high concentration of dynasties, politicians in those areas are escaping both
horizontal and vertical accountability. The failure of horizontal accountability leads to a failure in vertical
accountability if the literature is correct and people wait for a clear sign that a politician is personally
corrupt before taking action. This paper, then, suggests both another path for horizontal accountability
to work through, informing the people, and how even that might fail when the horizontal institution is
weak. Horizontal and vertical accountability can work together but are subject to failures on both parts.
When thinking about how evidence of corruption affects elections ,it’s also important to think
about how this works in a heavily clientelistic system. Hicken (2011) notes clientelism may cause, or
exacerbate, corruption by creating a system where it’s hard to hold politicians accountable. If people
vote not based on the ability or policy of politicians but on what the politician can deliver for them
personally and immediately, then they have little reason to care if politicians are corrupt. In fact, as
Stokes (2005) points out, in heavily clientilistic systems it’s not that voters holding politicians
accountable (what we’ve been discussing here as vertical accountability), it’s that politicians pay off
voters and then try to hold the voters accountable (what Stokes calls perverse accountability). The
Brazilian governor Adhemar de Barros was famously described as someone who stole but also got things
123
done (“rouba mas faz”). However, this doesn’t seem to be the case in practice. De Barros was defeated
in several elections, and as noted above, even with all its problems with corruption, voters in Brazil vote
Dynasties, on the other hand, have a huge effect on elections in the Philippines both directly
and indirectly. While parties in the Philippines are weak and transitory, families are a long-term source
of power. A significant majority of all congressmen, senators, and governors in the Philippines have at
least one relative in office and in some cases, it can be dozens. This phenomenon is not unique to the
Philippines. Amundsen (2013) argues that powerful dynasties make political parties in Bangladesh
weaker as well. In the Philippines, attempts to slow or stop the power of dynasties have largely failed.
Querubin (2011) shows that term limits don’t stop dynasties in the Philippines; they just switch jobs or
hand off jobs between family members. Mendoza et al. (2020) find that term limits lead to bigger
dynasties as it forces families to pull in more members as some are term-limited out. Querubin (2016)
also shows that politics in the Philippines tends towards dynasties, as when a person not from a dynasty
gets into office, a family member is much more likely to be elected soon after. Mendoza et al. (2019)
also show that the problem of dynasties is getting worse in recent years. They find that dynasties now
account for 29% of all local positions (increasing by about 1% a year) in the Philippines, and a much
Dynasties aren’t a problem limited to the Philippines. Feinstein (2010) shows that in the US
congressional candidates from dynasties have a significantly higher chance of winning elections
regardless of their level of political experience. This is especially true when parties are weak.
Thananithichot and Satidporn (2016) show an electoral advantage for dynastic candidates in Thai House
races but one that is not nearly as strong as the role of party affiliation. Daniele and Geys (2014) show in
Italy, dynastic politicians enjoy such a substantial advantage that they tend to win even over much more
qualified non-dynastic candidates. Even in a more developed state with stronger parties, dynasties give
124
members a big advantage. Smith (2012) shows that in Japan, members of dynasties “inherit” the
electoral reputation and party connections of previously elected members of the dynasty. In effect,
dynasties are reducing the quality of politicians by getting ones elected who would not have been able
I will show that having family members holding office is very strongly correlated with a higher
chance of winning an election in the Philippines, both for those indicted for corruption and those not
indicted. For mayors, if they have more than two family members in office in the previous term, their
chances of winning end up close to 100%. For those with two or fewer family members in office, there is
still a reduction in the chance of winning for those indicted for corruption, but this gets overwritten with
3 or more family members as winning is close to guaranteed. This is not the only way dynasties can
affect elections, though. As the previous paper showed, in areas with a higher concentration of
dynasties, the chance of being indicted for corruption remains low even as corruption increases. So,
politicians who come from areas with a high concentration of dynasties have less chance be being
indicted and are thus less likely suffer any political consequences. This paper adds to the work on
dynasties by showing how strongly political dynasties help members win election. This paper also shows
that while there may be some punishment for corruption, it isn’t enough to overcome the huge benefit
of being in a dynasty.
Instead of voting for corrupt politicians only so long as they are in a dynasty, it is possible that
voters may not be motivated to reject corruption at all. Klasnja and Tucker (2013) looked at responses to
corruption in Sweden, a low corruption country, and Moldova, a high corruption country. In Sweden,
they found people very willing to punish corruption while in Moldova it was only when corruption was
linked to poor economic performance that people said they would punish corruption. Bauhr and Charon
(2017) find the same thing looking across 21 European countries. They suggest that in high corruption
countries, corruption connects some voters to corrupt politicians while demobilizing those who oppose
125
corruption. Hooghe and Quintelier (2013) find corruption linked to lower voter turnout in post-Soviet
states. If corruption can reduce voter turnout, and as Bauhr and Charon suggest, turn off the voter
opposed to corruption most of all, then corruption may not only have the obvious financial benefits for
corrupt politicians but may be a viable elections strategy as well. In this case, we would expect to find
that in areas with higher corruption, and with politicians known to be corrupt, corruption would be
In the Philippines specifically, corruption has been linked to poverty (Mendoza et al. 2016), as
well as worse health outcomes, poorer education, and a general decline in public services (Azfar and
Gurgur 2008). Given these problems, it would make sense for voters to reject corrupt politicians, but
there seems to be no end to them. A scandal over the abuse of funds for local projects, the PDAF scam,
where money was directed by members of congress to nonexistent charities, has resulted in almost no
convictions or money recovered. Many involved have continued to win election after election, often
while on trial. Given these specific circumstances, the Philippines is a difficult case for voters punishing
corruption. This paper contributes to the literature on corruption and elections by examining whether
even in a very high corruption country like the Philippines, voters will still punish corruption if they have
To summarize, this paper contributes to the literatures on: the importance of information to
vertical accountability; how horizontal accountability feeds vertical accountability; how clientelism limits
vertical accountability; how dynasties weaken accountability; and whether voters will really reject
corrupt politicians. The central argument of this paper is that when presented with evidence of
corruption in the form of an indictment in the Sandiganbayan, voters in the Philippines are less likely to
vote for a politician despite the clientelistic nature of elections. However, voters are much more likely to
vote for politicians who have had a family member in office in the previous term. Politicians with several
family members in office are so likely to win an election that any indictment for corruption becomes
126
unimportant. Finally, since corruption prosecutions themselves are lower in areas with high dynastic
Before diving into the data, I will review how prosecutions work in the Philippines as well as how
elections function to give context for how these two things may interact. Prosecutions for corruption
As explained in the previous paper, the Ombudsman is tasked with investigating corruption for almost
all elected officials. Very low-level offenses can be prosecuted at the local level, but the Ombudsman
has exclusive jurisdiction to prosecute corruption-related offenses for everyone examined in this paper
except municipal councilors. Even for municipal councilors, if the amount of money involved is
significant, the Ombudsman has jurisdiction. The biggest target of the Ombudsman is mayors. There are
1,488 municipalities and 146 cities in the Philippines. These 1,634 mayors have a great deal of power.
They have more power over local spending than their city or municipal councils and usually more local
control than a far-off governor. However, they are not usually part of some big national family. They
may be part of a large local dynasty but a Marcos (or someone like that) wants to be governor or
Mayors are both shielded and potentially exposed by the national nature of the Ombudsman. A
mayor’s power is tied to the city or municipality he runs. There is no inherent reason for national
politicians to care much about local officials. Some may have powerful national connections, but not
many. Since the Ombudsman is a national institution based in Manila and with its leaders appointed by
the president, most mayors will have little chance of influencing its decisions. If, as I was told, a
president could get most Ombudsmen to back off a case, the question is when a president is likely to do
127
that. A senator or governor might have more luck in appealing to a president, but most mayors can’t
On the other hand, the gap between local and national power works to keep the Ombudsman
far removed from most municipalities. The Ombudsman doesn’t have a large staff and has weak
investigative powers. They often rely on things like informants to prove their case. Here mayors are at
an advantage since they are much closer to those who might accuse them than a prosecutor in faraway
Manila. The previous paper shows that in provinces with a high concentration of dynasties, as
corruption increases, the chances of a mayor or governor being prosecuted for corruption remains low.
In provinces with a low concentration of dynasties, as corruption increases, the chance of a mayor being
prosecuted for corruption increases. Dynasties can make it hard for the national Ombudsman to
penetrate local issues. In the end, it is mayors from provinces with a low concentration of dynasties who
preside over cities with a high level of corruption who are most likely to be indicted. And, as the rest of
this paper will show, these mayors then have a lower chance of winning elections.
Elections in the Philippines involve serious issues of clientelism, corruption, and weak parties. As noted
before, this might lead people to believe that even knowing a politician was corrupt would not be
enough to convince people to change their votes. However, even given the issues with clientelism and
weak parties, voters in the Philippines do not simply vote for whoever pays them. Policies and the ability
to govern do matter. This section of the paper will briefly explain why clientelism is such a problem in
the Philippines, how this came to be, and why it doesn’t mean that there is no hope for controlling
corruption.
128
Elections are held on a three-year cycle with local (mayor, vice-mayor, municipal or city
councilor), state (governor, vice-governor, state legislator), and House members elected to three-year
terms with a maximum of two consecutive reelections. They can be reelected after three terms if they
take a term off. In some cases, changes in the makeup of a locality have been used to let local officials
run for even more consecutive terms. Presidents are elected to a single six-year term and senators to
six-year terms with one consecutive reelection. Both presidents and senators are elected by the whole
country.
Parties, even longstanding ones, are incredibly weak. During the US colonial period in the early
20th century, the US sought to quickly build up democratic institutions but paid little attention to what
the practical outcome of a quick changeover was. Powerful local elites, often large landowners, were
able to capture the huge number of newly created political offices and found common ground with the
other elites they met in Manila (Anderson 1988). The new national bureaucracy was also the source of
considerable rents that the new political elites could get their hands on (Abinales and Amoroso 2005).
Teehankee (2012) adds that one reason parties failed to coalesce was that politicians feared being shut
out of all the spoils. This is still the structure today and explains why the Liberals can win 115 seats in the
House but then see 97 of those winners desert the party when they failed to win the presidency. In
2016, when Rodrigo Duterte won the presidency, his PDP-Laban party captured only three seats in the
House while the Liberal party, whose candidate came in second in the presidential election, captured
115 out of 297 seats, by far the most. However, with huge immediate defections, by the end of the 17th
Congress’ term, PDP-Laban held 94 seats while the Liberals only held onto 18. The Liberals easily won
the congressional election. Nevertheless, because they failed to win the presidency, their party was
decimated. Hicken and Stoll (2013) point out that when presidential elections occur simultaneously with
legislative elections, as is the case in the Philippines, legislators will “wait until after the election when
the outcome is certain and then align with the winner” (p.4).
129
The local-national divide that helps explain the issues the Ombudsman has with prosecuting is
also important when thinking about elections. Teehankee (p.191) explains the relationship between
national money and local votes: “Historically, a powerful chief executive has exercised vast control over
fiscal powers and patronage resources. Given the absence of a programmatic party system, the
president is dependent on local political bosses and clans to mobilize electoral support and implement
central government policy.” This would all seem to indicate that voting in the Philippines is little more
than a system of cash for votes, but the reality on the ground is more nuanced.
Voters might not punish corrupt politicians if those politicians are enmeshed in long standing
clientelistic networks. If voters get payouts regularly from one politician or dynasty, then they might be
likely to support them even in the face of an indictment. However, there is good evidence that vote-
buying doesn’t necessarily mean that people will vote for whoever pays them. Sometimes the
Philippines is described as an especially vulnerable case for clientelistic payouts because of the cultural
norm of “utang na loob” or debt of gratitude. The idea is that Filipinos will be more likely than other
people to give their vote after receiving a payout as opposed to just taking the money and voting for
who they please. However, this doesn’t stand up to scrutiny. Ravanilla et al. (2020) do find that there are
cases where voters are highly likely to follow through with their promise to vote after receiving a
payout, but that this depends on how likely a voter thinks his choice will be known and that he will be
sanctioned for not following through on the agreement as opposed to simply voting his cultural values.
Canare et al. (2018) find that what politicians are offering has a large effect on how likely voters
are to deliver their votes. Interestingly, cash was less likely to induce voters to vote for their patron than
things like “shirts, umbrellas, mugs” (p.79). Groceries were also less likely to win votes than these
material goods. They suggest this is because even in a place with a high degree of vote-buying, cash is
still seen as inappropriate and voters are more comfortable with things that are less directly a form of
vote-buying. They find that only about 17% of voters who take gifts change their vote. They report that
130
policies and an assessment of the candidates is much more important than gifts in deciding who to vote
for. Canare et al. suggest that the role of vote-buying might be more to build a brand or stave off
defections than to persuade voters. Poor voters, they argue, may expect some form of gifts so a
candidate giving them doesn’t necessarily win votes, but a candidate who fails to provide gifts may lose
votes.
This makes the Philippines a harder case for vertical accountability for corruption than other
countries since politicians gain favor by buying votes, but not an impossible one. Even voters who
receive gifts indicate that they examine the fitness and policies of candidates. In addition, many voters
indicate they are willing to take gifts and vote as they please as long as they are confident that they
won’t be found out. Just as vice-president Robredo suggested, voters can “accept the money, but vote
Measurement
To review, my goal is to test under what circumstances voters will reject corrupt politicians. I believe
that even though elections in the Philippines are highly clientilistic, voters will still reject corrupt
politicians if they have clear evidence of corruption. However, I believe this effect will be lessened by the
power of dynasties to get their members elected. To this end, I need data on who is being prosecuted,
who is winning elections, who is in a dynasty, and what the level of underlying corruption is like in
different municipalities. Given that the questions all revolve around winning or losing election, the data
is organized as candidate-year. This section will describe how the data was collected, how accurate it is,
Prosecutions
131
Because all corruption cases must be filed in the Sandiganbayan I was able to get a complete list
of corruption cases up to the end of 2019. Any case against any of the people included in the elections
data must be filed in the Sandiganbayan except for municipal councilors. Cases against private
individuals can be filed in the Sandiganbayan if it also involves elected officials. The only issue with the
prosecutions data is matching it to the other data. Naming conventions vary across the Philippines and
across state agencies. In addition, in some parts of the Philippines having several middle names is
common. “Hadji” a title given to a Muslim who has made a pilgrimage to Mecca is sometimes treated as
a first name on some government documents. Because some, but not all, data sets include middle
names I had to match names based on first names, last names, and suffixes (Jr., Sr., II, III, etc.). This
created a situation where sometimes a name on one list might match more than one name on another.
For example, there might be a corruption case filed against Maria Reyes and there might be two
different people named Maria Reyes who ran for office at different times and places.
When combining the prosecutions and elections data if I only matched on names about 10% of
matches had a duplicate, i.e. one name on the prosecutions list would match two names on the
elections list. If I also matched by office and province, then the number of duplicates fell to about 0.
Because I relied on matching office as well as name, someone who was indicted for corruption before
they held public office would not appear as having been indicted in that measure. I include both
measures of being indicted for corruption in the regressions below and the results are robust to either
measure.
Elections
There is no publicly accessible data set of elections in the Philippines, so I had to bring together several
data sets to get a complete picture of elections. I have data on all local and provincial elections from
1992 to 2019 except 2010 for which I only have data on mayoral elections. Small, random errors may
132
have been introduced by the need to use an optical character reader to get the data from thousands of
pages of pdfs into a usable form, but when spot-checking I found minimal errors and what errors there
are should be random instances where a character was blurry. For 2016, the data I had didn’t include
who had won the election; only how many votes each candidate had. For mayors or governors, this
wasn’t a problem, but city councilors are elected by being one of the top number of vote-getters. The
number in question varies by the size of the city. I tried to account for this, but there may be a few cases
of a winner not being counted. However, this paper doesn’t focus on city councilors, and there are only
146 cities. Finally, I can’t verify the underlying Commission on Elections data. In some cases, there are
strange results reported, such as no votes reported, or surprisingly few candidates, but these seem
uncommon.
Dynasties
Based on the work done by Mendoza et al. (2016), I define dynasties as having multiple family members
in office at the same time. Mendoza et al. also has shown that it is these “fat dynasties” that pose the
most problems. The Philippines also offers a unique opportunity to measure dynastic connections
broadly. Due to a quirk of how the Spanish assigned family names during their colonial period, two
people from the same province sharing the same family name are very likely to be related (Cruz,
Labonne, and Querubin 2020). This means that I can look at how many family members were in office
before a candidate ran for office, and how many ran with him. This doesn’t capture connections
between families, but it is highly correlated with the chance a candidate will win an election.
In addition, Davis (forthcoming) shows that in areas with a high concentration of dynasties, i.e.
many families holding many offices, as corruption increases, the chance of being prosecuted for
corruption remains flat. So, dynasties are influencing who is being indicted for corruption, and thus on
133
Corruption
While being indicted for corruption is the key independent variable in this paper, I also have a measure
for corruption itself. I collected data on some 9 million public procurement contracts from 2003 to 2019
and created a measure for how clean they seem. There are several studies (Coviello and Gagliarducci
2010, Auriol, Straub, and Flochel 2016, Burgess et al. 2015, or Olken 2005) that have shown that things
like only having a single bidder for a public procurement contract is strongly associated with corruption.
I created a measure for each contract and then for each municipality and province for how clean the
public procurement contracts appeared. As Davis (forthcoming) shows, in areas with low dynastic
concentration, as the quality of the public procurement contracts goes down, the chance that a mayor
or governor will be indicted for corruption increases. However, as shown below, as the quality of these
public procurement contracts goes down, the chance of winning an election remains flat. However,
because I only have public procurement data for the most recent years, I don’t consider corruption
Methods
In this section I will detail the models I will examine and why they make sense given the data including
what controls I use. The underlying model is straightforward, so much of what I examine is based on
alternative measurements of the data, to show that the results are robust, or alternative controls, again
to show that changes in model specification don’t disrupt the underlying relationship. I will also detail
models I looked at to answer related questions such as whether the effect of an indictment on elections
134
The central model is:
WinElection = B_1*IndictedBeforeElection + Z + e
Wherein the key controls are for having won an election previously. This is the key control because
otherwise there is a significant issue of reverse causality. Being indicted for corruption is correlated with
a higher chance of winning an election because to be indicted for corruption by the Ombudsman you
usually need to be an elected official. And having previously won office is correlated with a much higher
chance of winning office in the future. So, if the previous office isn’t controlled for, the correlation goes
in the wrong direction. I try a series of different control for previous times in office: having held the
same office before, having held any office before, the number of times a candidate has held office, and
the number of times they’ve run unsuccessfully. As will be shown below, the results are robust to any or
all of these controls. One problem, though, is that since my elections data starts in 1992, anyone who
held office before that isn’t credited. Most of the period before this was during martial law, but even
then there were some elections, of varying quality, and many appointments. This means that there are
some people winning office who already held office being treated in the regression as first-time
candidates. However, that should mean that the actual correlation between being indicted, and the
chance of winning is larger than what I find since these missing offices will drive the relationship in the
opposite direction. It’s also not surprising, given this, that the correlation is much weaker in 1995 and
Since the elections data is panel data, I can also use either time or place fixed effects. The results
are robust to either one-way fixed effects, two-way fixed effects, or no fixed effects at all. Since the data
includes both provincial and municipal elections the fixed effects are also nested in one another
suggesting the possibility of a multilevel model. Unfortunately, since there are 500,000 individual
candidates with 84 provinces (more than currently exist because some come and go over time) and
135
about 1600 cities and municipalities running a multilevel model or running fixed effects for
municipalities results in a matrix that is just too large to run. However, when an interaction for the
mayors. Afterward, I use a subset of the data which only includes mayors and a model with fixed effects
for time, province, and municipality. This model produces the same results.
I also run models to test if there is an interaction between being in a dynasty and being indicted.
I try this model with both the number of members in a candidates dynasty and the dynastic
concentration in a province. As I will discuss below, having more than a few members of a candidate’s
dynasty in office means that candidate’s chance is very high even if indicted for corruption. I also run
several models to examine specific parts of this question. I look at an interaction between being indicted
and year. The effect does vary somewhat over time as for early years there are likely more mayors who I
don’t have information on their time in office before 1992. There isn’t a strong effect. All the models run
below are logistic regressions since the dependent variable is elected or not elected.
This section will examine the result of all the models and discuss the key takeaways from the group of
regressions. Table 1 below examines all half million candidates for office between 1992 and 2019. Table
1 shows the success in using any one of three variables to control for the reverse causality caused by
136
someone who has been in office being both much more likely to win office in the future and more likely
Table 1
Model 1.1 [I refer to models by table and model number so this is Table 1, Model 1] shows the most
basic form of the regression, only considering If someone has been indicted for corruption and if they
won the election. In Model 1.1 being indicted for corruption is strongly positively associated with
winning an election. This is because of the endogeneity problem noted above. Model 1.2 includes a
control for a past win. In Model 1.2 that is any past electoral win. Having a past win is strongly
correlated with a higher chance at election, but once that is controlled for the effect of being indicted on
To show that this is not just the result of the model specification, Model 1.3 controls for having
won the same office a candidate is running for, not just any office. Again, having won is positive and
137
statistically significant and being indicted is negative and statistically significant. Model 1.4 looks at the
number of past wins and gets the same result. Model 1.5 uses controls for both having won the same
office and the number of past wins. I control for both because both being very successful and having
held the office a candidate is running for could independently affect their chances. Both are positive and
statistically significant, while being indicted is negative and statistically significant. The number of
observations drops in Models 1.2 to 1.5, because 1992 is excluded since there are no past elections to
consider. 1992 also had more candidates than subsequent years. While not reported here, the
relationship holds when adding controls for duplicate names and for past losses. This shows that the key
to dealing with endogeneity, in this case, is controlling for having held office in the past. The model is
Model 2.1 in Table 2 includes several new controls such as if the candidate has lost previous
elections or lost an election for the same office. Not surprisingly these are statistically significant and
negatively correlated with winning an election. I also include a control for the number of family
members in office in the previous term. We’ll take more of a look at this later, but for now it’s positively
correlated with winning an election. Model 2.2 is the same, but it includes fixed effects for years. For the
models based only on mayors, I will look at the interaction between year and being indicted.
138
Table 2
Model 2.3 has provincial fixed effects. This could theoretically be run with municipal fixed effects but
with 1600 municipalities and more than 400,000 observations, the matrix becomes too large to
practically compute. Model 2.4 uses two-way fixed effects. The key idea with models 2.2, 2.3, and 2.4 is
that with either unit, time, or two-way fixed effects, the relationship between being indicted for
corruption and election remains negative and statistically significant. We can see with these various
specifications of controls and fixed effects that the result is quite robust. Finally, model 2.5 includes a
control for what office the candidate is running for and an interaction between that and being indicted
139
for corruption. This isn’t included in the table because they are very hard to interpret directly and
because office is an unordered categorical variable, so the significance is relative to what it is being
compared against. Instead, a predicted probability graph is needed to see how candidates for different
Figure 1 below shows the probability of winning an election for each office when controlling for
all the variables included in Model 2.5, most importantly past office. We can see that for almost every
office being indicted for corruption (the blue bars) results in a lower chance of winning an election.
However, it is only for mayors that the results are statistically significant. Looking at the figure the
reason is clear; there is just too much noise for the results to be clear for most positions. Mayors, who as
noted above make up by far the largest group of elected officials indicted for corruption, is the only
place where the results are statistically significant. Based on this, the rest of the models only examine
the effect of being indicted on mayors. Besides focusing the discussion, this has the advantage of making
the data set smaller so things like municipal fixed effects and a multilevel model can be tried.
Figure 1
140
Table 3, below, looks at the same general models but for mayors. Model 3.1 is the same
specification as model 2.4 except limited to just mayors. As expected, being indicted for corruption is
statistically significant and negatively correlated with winning an election. The size of the effect is larger
because all the other offices, which from Figure 1 we can see didn’t have a statistically significant effect,
have been eliminated. Again, having won in the past is strongly positively associated with winning, as is
having family members in office. Models 3.2, 3.3, and 3.4 all try different fixed effects with
municipalities instead of just provinces. This model specification isn’t as good overall because we end up
with only two or three candidates per municipality per year, but it’s worth looking at these models
briefly as a robustness check. Model 3.2 only has municipal fixed effects. Model 3.3 has municipal and
year fixed effects and Model 3.4 has municipal, year, and provincial fixed effects. In all cases, the
Model 3.5 is a multilevel model organized around provinces. Again, the results are very similar
to the other models. Using municipalities here isn’t possible because there are only a few candidates per
municipality. What Table 3 shows is that for mayors we can choose a wide range of model specifications
and still get the same relationship (so long as endogeneity is controlled for). This gives us confidence
that the relationship is not being driven by any specific aspect of the model but by a real underlying
causal relationship.
141
Table 3
142
Figure 2 shows the difference between being indicted and not indicted based on Model 3.1. As
we can see while the number of past wins increases the chance of a candidate winning there is about a
Figure 2
The next figures are all based on Table 4, which takes model 3.1 and adds a series of interactions
to see how that affects the relationship between being indicted for corruption and winning an election.
Figure 3, based on model 4.1, shows the interaction between being indicted for corruption and having
family members already in office when a candidate runs for office. There is an interaction, as can be
seen also in Table 4, but really what Figure 3 shows is that being indicted matters if there are 3 or fewer
family members in office, but once you start looking at larger dynasties, the effect of being indicted
becomes small and not statistically significant. In addition, dynasty size is a strong predictor of a
candidate’s chance to win election. It’s also worth noting that there are very few candidates with more
143
Figure 3 is important because it shows that corruption is never thought of as a positive, or even
neutral thing. It could have been the case that corrupt politicians from large dynasties were thought of
as being more effective. Wade (1985) argued that poor voters in India preferred criminal politicians
because they could better look out for their interests. Figure 3 shoes that this is not the case. Voters do
prefer candidates from large dynasties, but they also prefer that they not be corrupt. It’s just the case
that if they come from a large dynasty, that helps more than corruption hurts. Figure 3 may also show
how clientilistic bargains are built into the system. Voters don’t approve of corruption, but they will vote
for dynasties that they know well. This may reflect that those dynasties are a good source of payouts
over time.
Figure 3
Figure 4, based on model 4.2, shows the interaction between year and being indicted for
corruption. 1995 and 1998 have the relationship going in the wrong direction, but as noted before I
144
suspect this is because there are more candidates who previously held office who have yet to be
indicted. For most of the rest of the years there is variation, but the overall relationship is similar. Most
interesting is how weak the relationship is by 2019. This might reflect the changeover in the
Ombudsman and a less active pursuing of cases. However, the 2019 result could also just be noise. The
absence of evidence isn’t evidence of absence after all. If the relationship continues to get weaker, that
suggests a change in the work of the Ombudsman. It’s possible given that the new Ombudsman got his
job for being a Duterte ally, not a corruption fighter. What’s key is that we can see that the relationship
between corruption indictment and chance of winning election is not being driven by one year in
particular.
Figure 4
Figure 5, based on model 4.3, shows the interaction, or lack thereof, between being indicted and
the level of corruption in a municipality. The effect looks slightly larger in very high corruption
municipalities, but the results aren’t close to being statistically significant. Part of the problem is a lack
of data. Because the corruption data draws on the online public procurement system there are only four
145
election periods when I include this data. It is possible the relationship would be stronger with more
Figure 5
Figure 6 (based on Model 4.4) shows the interaction between being indicted for corruption and
the concentration of dynasties in a province. At low levels of dynastic concentration, we see being
indicted having a negative effect on a candidate’s chance of being elected. However as dynastic
concentration increases, the difference is no longer statistically significant. However, I’m not sure how
much we can take from this result. The previous paper showed that as dynastic concentration increases,
corruption increasing no longer results in a higher chance of prosecution. Therefore, in areas with a high
concentration of dynasties, corruption prosecutions are quite rare. That’s why the standard errors
become so large in Figure 6 as dynastic concentration increases. It may be that dynastic concentration
also works to weaken vertical accountability directly, but it’s not clear from the data.
146
Figure 7 looks at dynastic concentration from another perspective. Figure 7 doesn’t look at
corruption indictment, but just the interaction between dynasty size and being indicted for corruption.
From Figure 7 we can see that in provinces with a low dynastic concentration being from a larger
dynasty is associated with a larger chance at election. However, in provinces with a high dynastic
concentration the effect of the size of the dynasty disappears. I believe the lines crossing is just an
artifact of the expanding standard errors as there are few provinces with an HHI above 150. Similar to
how the effect of being indicted for corruption seems to go down as dynastic concentration increases,
so too does the effect of a particular dynasty. I don’t think there is enough evidence here to give a clear
answer to why this is, but it could be similar to the research suggesting that people care more about
corruption when corruption is low. Maybe when dynasties become very common the effect of being
Table 4 includes the models that the above figures were drawn from. Each model has an
147
Figure 6
Figure 7
148
From all the models and figures above, we can learn five things. First, there is a relationship
between being indicted for corruption and winning office. Being indicted for corruption reduced a
candidate’s chance of winning office by about 7% (depending on which model). Second, this relationship
is robust to a wide variety of model specifications so long as those models control for endogeneity.
Third, the relationship varies somewhat over time, but that is likely due to issues with the ability to
control for endogeneity in the earlier years. Fourth, having several family members in office offers a
huge increase in a candidate’s chance to win an election that might swamp any problem created by
being indicted. Fifth, corruption and dynastic concentration, while they influence who is indicted (Davis
149
Table 4
150
Conclusion
Being indicted for corruption decreases a candidate’s chance to win an election. This is somewhat
surprising because the high levels of corruption and clientelistic nature of elections in the Philippines
might have meant that people were either numb to news of corruption or that they didn’t care as long
as they got paid. However, while other factors had a greater impact, such as having held office
previously or having family members in office, there was still a negative effect for being indicted. The
weakness in this mix of horizontal and vertical accountability is that it relies on the Ombudsman to indict
candidates. In cases where the Ombudsman fails, there doesn’t seem to be a direct connection between
the amount of corruption in an area and the chance of a candidate being elected. However, even if the
Ombudsman fails to win a conviction, there is still a price to be paid for a candidate who is indicted for
corruption. The other limitation is that having family members in office is so strongly associated with
winning an election that candidates with more than about three family members in office are almost
This paper contributes to the work being done on how voters punish corruption by showing that
even in a difficult case they do, in fact, punish corrupt politicians. This paper also contributes to the
literature on clientelism by showing the limits of these bargains. This paper also shows how anti-
corruption agencies (horizontal accountability), and elections (vertical accountability) can work together
instead of being two different options, but also what the limits of this logic are.
There is more that can be done to extend this analysis. The Philippines offers an easier ability to
test the effect of corruption prosecutions, since they are all handled by one agency, but the same thing
could be done in other countries with central anti-corruption agencies. We don’t need to limit the
examination of anti-corruption agencies to their ability to convict but can also consider how they inform
the public. In addition, with the rise of computerized public procurement data around the world, there is
151
an increasing number of countries where the quality of public procurement contracts can be assessed to
see how corruption is punished in elections as well as how that interacts with corruption prosecutions.
There is also more work to be done looking at how dynasties face challenges. The Philippines is far from
the only country with powerful political dynasties and looking at how they affect both elections and
152
Work Cited
Abinales, P., & Amoroso, D. (2005). State and Society in the Philippines (Pasig City. Anvil Publishing.
Agerberg, M. (2020). The lesser evil? Corruption voting and the importance of clean alternatives.
Comparative Political Studies, 53(2), 253-287.
Amundsen, I. (2013). Democratic dynasties? Internal party democracy in Bangladesh. Party Politics,
22(1), 49–58. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068813511378
Anderson, B. (1988). Cacique democracy and the Philippines: Origins and dreams. New Left Review, 169,
3.
Auriol, E., Straub, S., & Flochel, T. (2016). Public Procurement and Rent-Seeking: The Case of Paraguay.
World Development, 77, 395–407.
Azfar, O., & Gurgur, T. (2008). Very Preliminary, not for circulation Decentralization and Corruption in
the Philippines. Economics of Governance Volume, 9, 197–244.
Banerjee, A., Kumar, S., Pande, R., & Su, F. (2011). Do informed voters make better choices?
Experimental evidence from urban India. Unpublished manuscript.
Bauhr, M., & Charron, N. (2017). Insider or Outsider? Grand Corruption and Electoral Accountability.
Comparative Political Studies, 0010414017710258.
Boas, T. C., Hidalgo, F. D., & Melo, M. A. (2019). Norms versus action: Why voters fail to sanction
malfeasance in Brazil. American Journal of Political Science, 63(2), 385-400.
Bolongaita, E. P. (2010). An exception to the rule? Why Indonesia’s Anti-Corruption Commission succeeds
where others don’t - a comparion with the Philippines’ Ombudsman.
Burgess, R., Jedwab, R., Miguel, E., Morjaria, A., & i Miquel, G. (2015). The value of democracy: evidence
from road building in Kenya. American Economic Review, 105(6), 1817–1851.
Canare, T. A., Mendoza, R. U., & Lopez, M. A. (2018). An empirical analysis of vote buying among the
poor: Evidence from elections in the Philippines. South East Asia Research, 26(1), 58–84.
Chong, A., De La O, A. L., Karlan, D., & Wantchekon, L. (2015). Does Corruption Information Inspire the
Fight or Quash the Hope? A Field Experiment in Mexico on Voter Turnout, Choice, and Party
Identification. The Journal of Politics, 77(1), 55–71. https://doi.org/10.1086/678766
Coviello, D., & Gagliarducci, S. (2010). Building Political Collusion: Evidence from Procurement Auctions.
IZA Discussion Paper, 4939.
Cruz, C., Labonne, J., & Querubín, P. (2020). Social Network Structures and the Politics of Public Goods
Provision: Evidence from the Philippines. American Political Science Review, 114(2), 486–501.
https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055419000789
153
Daniele, G., & Geys, B. (2014). Born in the Purple, Polticial Dynasties and Politicians’ Human Capital. 1–
36. https://www.semanticscholar.org/paper/Born-in-the-Purple:-Political-Dynasties-and-Human-*-
Daniele-Geys/17368c1dfb4aa8c719aa72b04aa32036b78ee903
De Speville, B. (2010). Anticorruption commissions: the “Hong Kong model” revisited. Asia-Pacific
Review, 17(1), 47–71.
De Vries, C. E., & Solaz, H. (2017). The Electoral Consequences of Corruption. Annual Review of Political
Science, 20(1), 391–408. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-polisci-052715-111917
Feinstein, B. D. (2010). The dynasty advantage: Family ties in congressional elections. Legislative Studies
Quarterly, 35(4), 571–598. https://doi.org/10.3162/036298010793322366
Ferraz, C., & Finan, F. (2008). Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects of Brazil’s Publicly Released Audits
on Electoral Outcomes *. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 703–745.
https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2008.123.2.703
Hicken, A., & Stoll, H. (2013). Are all presidents created equal? Presidential powers and the shadow of
presidential elections. Comparative Political Studies, 46(3), 291–319.
Hooghe, M., & Quintelier, E. (2014). Political participation in European countries: The effect of
authoritarian rule, corruption, lack of good governance and economic downturn. Comparative
European Politics, 12(2), 209–232. https://doi.org/10.1057/cep.2013.3
Humphreys, M., & Weinstein, J. (2012). Policing politicians: citizen empowerment and political
accountability in Uganda preliminary analysis. Columbia Universities. Unpublished manuscript.
Klašnja, M., & Tucker, J. A. (2013). The economy, corruption, and the vote: Evidence from experiments in
Sweden and Moldova. Electoral Studies, 32(3), 536–543.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.electstud.2013.05.007
Klasnja, M., Tucker, J. A., & Deegan-Krause, K. (2014). Pocketbook vs. Sociotropic Corruption Voting.
British Journal of Political Science, 46(1), 67–94. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123414000088
Mendoza, R. U., Banaag, M. S., Hiwatig, J. D., Yusingco, M. H. L., & Yap, J. K. (2020). Term limits and
political dynasties in the Philippines: Unpacking the links. Asia-Pacific Social Science Review, 20(4),
88–99.
Mendoza, R. U., Beja Jr, E. L., Venida, V. S., & Yap, D. B. (2016). Political dynasties and poverty:
measurement and evidence of linkages in the Philippines. Oxford Development Studies, 44(2), 189–
201.
154
Mendoza, R. U., Jaminola, L. M., & Yap, J. (2019). From fat to obese: Political dynasties after the 2019
midterm elections. ATENEO SCHOOL OF GOVERNMENT WORKING PAPER SERIES, September, 13–
19.
Olken, B. A. (2005). Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment. In in Indonesia.” NBER
Working Paper# 11753.
Pavão, N. (2018). Corruption as the only option: The limits to electoral accountability. The Journal of
Politics, 80(3), 996-1010.
Quah, J. S. T. (2010). Defying institutional failure: learning from the experiences of anti-corruption
agencies in four Asian countries. Crime, Law and Social Change, 53(1), 23–54.
Querubin, P. (2011). Political reform and elite persistence: Term limits and political dynasties in the
Philippines. Mimeo. http://pclt.cis.yale.edu/leitner/resources/papers/Querubin_Term_Limits.pdf
Querubin, P. (2016). Family and politics: Dynastic persistence in the philippines. Quarterly Journal of
Political Science, 11(2), 151–181. https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00014182
Ravanilla, N., Davidson, M., & Hicken, A. (2020). Voting in Clientelistic Social Networks: Evidence from
the Philippines. Working Paper.
Schütte, S. A. (2012). Against the odds: Anti-corruption reform in Indonesia. Public Administration and
Development, 32(1), 38–48.
Smith, D. M. (2012). Succeeding in politics: dynasties in democracies. University of California, San Diego.
Stokes, S. C. (2005). Perverse accountability: A formal model of machine politics with evidence from
Argentina. American political science review, 99(3), 315-325.
Teehankee, J. C. (2012). Clientelism and party politics in the Philippines. In Party Politics in Southeast
Asia (pp. 186–214).
Thananithichot, S., & Satidporn, W. (2016). Political Dynasties in Thailand: The Recent Picture after the
2011 General Election. Asian Studies Review, 40(3), 340–359.
https://doi.org/10.1080/10357823.2016.1193473
Wade, R. (1985). Market for public office: Why the Indian state is not better at development. World
Development, 13, 467–497.
Welch, S., & Hibbing, J. R. (1997). The effects of charges of corruption on voting behavior in
congressional elections, 1982-1990. The Journal of Politics, 59(1), 226-239.
Winters, M. S., & Weitz-Shapiro, R. (2013). Lacking Information or Condoning Corruption: When Do
Voters Support Corrupt Lacking Information or Condoning Corruption When Do Voters Support
Corrupt Politicians? Comparative Politics, 45(4), 418–436.
https://doi.org/10.5129/001041513X13815259182857
155
Conclusion: What We Can Learn From
the Findings
156
Summary of Key Findings
In the last three papers, I have shown how dynasties rose in the Philippines, how they stymie
prosecutions for corruption, and how prosecutions for corruption affect a candidate’s chance at
election. I will begin with a brief summary of the key findings of all three papers and an explanation of
how these findings go together. Next, I will explain the implications of my findings for other political
scientists. While I explain in each paper how the question examined in that paper fits into the existing
literature, I will now briefly explain what the papers suggest for political science research overall. What
should someone reading this dissertation from an academic perspective take away from it? Then, I will
discuss the implications of this dissertation from a policy making perspective. It’s not enough to just
argue back and forth with other social scientists; we must also keep one eye on what these findings
mean to the larger world. What can those who want to effect change take from this? Finally, I will
examine what more work could be done both in terms of the specific issues I looked at and in terms of
The first paper shows how dynasties in the Philippines grew out of land inequality, but that it
was the choices made by the US in creating a new government that both exacerbated land inequality
and allowed those who had the most land to take the reigns of the government. These large landholders
were able to use their political power to increase their economic power. They were able to extract so
much money from their positions in control of the government that even as land faded as the most
important resource, they were able to hold onto power. These emerging political dynasties predate
many of the later problems of weak institutionalization. Dynasties were there at the beginning, keeping
the government subservient to their interests. It wasn’t that the Philippines’ problems with corruption
and poor development allowed dynasties to grow, it was that dynasties and their self-centered nature
kept the Philippines poor and corrupt. The later papers build on this idea by showing how dynasties
157
The second paper examines when dynasties can stop prosecutions for corruption. The key is
that it’s not that large dynasties can protect their members from prosecutions; it’s that when dynasties
become very concentrated in one province, all prosecutions for corruption become rare. Dynasties
intimidate people into silence, which keeps the Ombudsman, a national institution without a strong
ability to get into local issues, out of their dealings. One large dynasty may be a problem for other
reasons, but it’s not enough to shut out national oversight. In places where dynasties have saturated
political life, the accountability that should come from the national anti-corruption agency is missing.
We can see echoes of how the differences in land inequality and land titling between provinces in the
past led to differences in the concentration of dynasties today. The political culture of different
provinces ends up being quite different such that in some places there are relatively few dynasties while
in others they control a huge percent of the seats and allow corruption to go unpunished.
The third paper looks at whether those indicted for corruption are less likely to win election. I
find that mayors who have been indicted for corruption are, in fact, less likely to win election. However,
when those mayors come from even a mid-sized dynasty, three or more members, then being indicted
has a much smaller impact on their chances of winning, which are very high. This shows that voters do
punish corruption but that dynasties have a greater weight on the electoral process than corruption
indictments do. Here it’s not the concentration of dynasties that’s key but the ability of dynasties to
perpetuate themselves even in the face of being indicted for corruption. Further, this paper must be
understood in relation to the second paper which shows that provinces with a high concentration of
dynasties see fewer corruption prosecutions. This means that in provinces with a high concentration of
dynasties, officials aren’t indicted and won’t face electoral consequences. In provinces with a low
concentration, mayors might get indicted but if they are from a mid-sized dynasty, they are still likely to
win election.
158
Implications for Political Science Research
One of the key takeaways from this dissertation is that the causes of corruption are deeply rooted.
There are arguments about the deep roots of institutions, most famously Acemoglu and Robinson, but
that logic can be expanded to look at issues like corruption. It’s too easy to see corruption as a discrete
problem. Individual instances of corruption are often treated as their own particular problem. But this is
like treating each cough as a separate malady instead of looking at what sickness is producing the
coughs. Instances of corruption are part of a greater system. We don’t want to miss the forest for the
trees. If we think of corruption as part of a long running issue, we can also see why corruption is so hard
to fix. Corruption is so deeply enmeshed in the politics and economy of some countries that reducing
corruption leaves gaps. This doesn’t mean it isn’t worth reducing corruption, but it does mean we have
to think through what reducing corruption implies and how to compensate for changes. In the
Philippines, corruption is not just a weight on people's lives; it’s also a system of election financing. This
means that those who rely on corruption, like politicians, will defend the institutions that allow
corruption to flourish.
Dynasties also need to be understood not just as parasites but as part of the political system.
Dynasties keep politicians safe from corruption prosecutions, but dynasties trace their roots back more
than a hundred years. We don’t have specific evidence of them keeping themselves safe from
corruption prosecution in the 1940s but it’s not hard to imagine the same system at work. Dynasties
don’t just promote or protect crime, though; dynasties are part of political life. In the Philippines, parties
are virtually meaningless. In other countries, parties play a crucial role in informing voters about the
positions of candidates. In the US you may not know exactly what positions a Democrat or a Republican
will hold, but you have a good general idea. Without a clear party label each candidate becomes a total
unknown. It’s often not worthwhile for voters to deeply investigate every candidate. Dynasties fill in
some of that gap by providing an alternative label. A voter in the Philippines might not be able to guess
159
from a party what a candidate is for, but he can guess by what the candidate’s family name is. If a voter
is happy with the work of a candidate’s family, that tells the voter a lot about the candidate.
This isn’t a defense of dynasties, but it does showcase how big a part of the political system they
have become. If we see dynasties as part of a greater system, why they are so difficult to reduce
becomes clear. People know politicians they like who are part of dynasties. We know that the social
world is highly contingent, but more than many problems dynasties (and corruption) need to be seen as
part of the political system, not just a problem with it. Only by seeing these connections can we think
about how to deal with them. For example, if dynasties are helping people get elected by providing clear
labels, then strengthening parties could help reduce dynasties by getting good politicians elected with a
different label.
Another important implication of this research is that problems with accountability can be more
intermingled than they might appear. We often talk about accountability as vertical or horizontal, but in
this research, we see vertical accountability relying on horizontal accountability such that failures in
horizontal accountability also undermine vertical accountability. This isn’t a unique case. Criminal acts
(corruption here) are by their very nature secret. It’s difficult for the public to know about them without
an investigation. This can sometimes be done by the press, but that’s not always going to be possible.
For people to punish politicians, they may need to hear about issues with corruption from the
government. As the literature has shown, people are reticent to punish politicians just on a general
The connection between vertical and horizontal accountability flows the other way as well. The
government may not want to investigate people in power. Pressure from citizens is important to keep
systems of horizontal accountability moving forward. The government rarely wants to confront
corruption; it’s only when leaders think there will be a political price that anti-corruption moves to the
160
fore. In Indonesia, the anti-corruption agency regularly tries to build public support, knowing it will allow
them more latitude to investigate those with power. So, I think it’s important that accountability be
examined both horizontally and vertically simultaneously. Even what sounds like a purely vertical
accountability question such as, “when do voters vote for corrupt politicians,” needs to be seen in the
context of, “when does the government investigate corrupt politicians?” If we don’t have both parts, we
This dissertation also takes another step forward in the social science research on the
measurement of corruption. One of the central problems with research into corruption is how difficult it
is to measure corruption, since corruption by its very nature is secret and illicit. There is an emerging
body of work that looks at public procurement contracts to measure corruption, since they are both a
major area of corruption (since it’s where the government is giving out money) and something that must
be at least partially public (you can’t have bids for contracts without announcing them). There has been
success in measuring corruption this way, but it's still a developing method. This dissertation adds more
weight to the idea that even under less than perfect conditions you can successfully measure corruption
The measure I used shows a correlation between corruption and corruption prosecutions which
goes a long way to show that the measure is working. This measure works even without some of the
more nuanced data on exactly what is being procured or which companies are bidding that could have
made the data even better. If we can assess corruption from only a few pieces of public procurement
information there is a hope for better research into the effects of corruption, with more exact data on
where corruption is more of a problem and more cross-national research. Even though a public
procurement measure is going to be different in different countries, we can use the same principle to
look both at relative changes over time and the relative effects of policies. Right now, a lot of cross-
national corruption research relies on self reporting or perceptions of corruption. With more public
161
procurement data, we can look at how different policies affect corruption in different countries. We
might not be able to use this measure for an absolute level of corruption, but relative changes can tell us
a lot.
When thinking about what lessons can be drawn from this dissertation for policymaking, it’s important
to think about what can be achieved short of huge reforms. Those would be good, but systemic
overhauls are vanishingly rare. Instead, I’ll begin with what lessons can be drawn for smaller, more
immediate policies. The strength, tenacity, and perniciousness of dynasties are some of the major
themes of this research. The Philippines has an anti-dynasty provision in the post-Marcos constitution,
but it has never been actualized by any law. Dynasties are a problem, but we can’t just say that the
Philippines would be better off without them, because they are so entrenched. What can help limit the
power and the durability of dynasties, without needing to take them on directly, is strengthening other
institutions around representation. One of the key problems with dynasties is that they lower the quality
of the people getting elected. In the Philippines, candidates run much more on family and clientelistic
appeals than on party labels. It’s not unusual for mayors to run under different party labels in every
election. It’s common for members of congress to switch parties depending on who wins the presidency.
Since party labels give so little information dynasties fill in the gap.
Strengthening parties, and making parties a larger focus of elections, would help reduce some of
the power of dynasties without needing to confront dynasties directly. There are a few ways to increase
the power of parties: more party-list representation, giving election funding through parties based on
past performance so that parties have an interest in stating constant, making some of the clientelistic
payoffs to voters legal but only through parties. These wouldn’t eliminate dynasties, but if party labels
162
were stronger, dynasties would have less ability to get their members elected. It might also cause
dynasties in parties that didn’t do well in elections to fade rather than party hop.
I also looked at the weakness of the Ombudsman and how dynasties were able to prevent them
from bringing cases. The key lesson here is that anti-corruption agencies can work, but that they are
only as good as their specific implementation. The Ombudsman does make cases. In the second paper,
we saw that they prosecute more mayors and governors in areas with more corruption unless there is a
high concentration of dynasties. The Ombudsman has little power to investigate, prosecutes cases in an
incredibly slow-moving court, and is subject to the whims of its single leader. But the Ombudsman still
Obviously, the mass of corrupt politicians doesn’t want the Ombudsman to be any stronger, but
one advantage of institutional design is that the design can outlast the people who designed it.
Countries go through periods of high popular demand for reform. Reforming the Ombudsman, when
there is public pressure to do so, is a good option. With more investigative power, with a larger staff,
with a more responsive court, the Ombudsman could make more cases and might be able to function in
the face of powerful dynasties. Even if later governments wanted to weaken the Ombudsman, it’s
There is also the possibility of redesigning the Ombudsman to have a more limited preview and
then giving it more power. One reason politicians fear giving anti-corruption agencies power is they
don’t want to be prosecuted themselves. This was partially baked into the Ombudsman, who has no
power to investigate the military. This isn’t because there is little corruption in the military, it is because
when empowering the Ombudsman after Marcos, they didn’t want to cause a military coup. The
Ombudsman could have its focus narrowed so that it was less a threat to the politically powerful. This
would let some corruption go unpunished, but corruption among the most powerful is already going
163
unpunished. It’s possible that if the Ombudsman had a smaller scope, it might be able to get the support
Empowering the Ombudsman, though, will never fully tackle corruption. The sort of power and
size the Ombudsman would need to try and stop the pervasive corruption in the Philippines is so much
greater than what it has now, it’s hard to imagine it without a full-scale revolution, and even then, only a
part of a broader push. To tackle corruption in the Philippines what is needed is support from the
bottom up. This dissertation shows that voters will punish corruption when they know of it. Corruption
is not an inherent part of Filipino culture. Corruption is something voters hate even if it is a part of doing
business to politicians.
Real reduction in corruption can only come from popular pressure. There are several ways the
government can work to limit corruption (I suggest two above) but without a push, the government
won’t move to limit corruption. Corruption is baked into the system, part of political life. It’s only with
people getting fed up and making politicians change that things will change. Horizontal accountability is
possible, but only when the push comes vertically. If voters make it clear that they will vote for
politicians who reduce corruption, then there can be real reduction in corruption. People need to elect
reforming politicians and support them through civil society organizations to see real change. Reformers
come in all stripes. Benigno Aquino III was the sire of one of the Philippines' most prominent dynasties
and turned out to be the sincerest reformer in recent history. But wherever they come from, the
problems facing the Philippines are large enough that changes around the edges will only do so much.
It is somewhat disheartening to argue that smaller, more measured changes just aren’t enough.
Real thoroughgoing reform is rare. Corruption and dynasties feed each other. Institutions are weak
because they have been designed to be weak. Without a broad-based movement for reform, only very
164
incremental progress can be achieved. For other countries, though, this research can serve as a warning
about how some of these problems can spiral out of control. Dynasties don’t arise overnight. Taking
steps to limit their power early before they start to dominate is important. Dynasties are organized first
and foremost around replicating their power. When they amass a lot of power, they are very hard to
stop.
Better institutions can limit how bad things get as well. As noted before, a more powerful anti-
corruption agency can stop corruption from becoming endemic. Once it becomes a pillar of the political
system, it is very hard to stop corruption. It’s much easier to design good institutions before problems
arise. Similarly, a more robust public procurement system would help. It’s probably impossible to totally
eliminate corruption in public procurement, but it doesn’t need to be so easy. Even in the Philippines
PhilGEPS was a step forward as the previous system was almost totally opaque with only non-electronic
Dynasties, corruption, lack of accountability, and weak institutions are all related. That is a huge
problem when they are all an issue. They feed one another. People who benefit from one of these issues
may defend all of them. But it also means that progress in one can help another. Limiting dynasties
would take pressure off institutions and allow for more accountability and lower corruption. More
accountability through elections could result in better institutions. Reducing corruption could bring
more people into the political process and improve accountability. Policymakers in any country need to
watch that the problems don’t build on each other until they become as intractable as in the Philippines.
Work to be Done
There is more research that can be done both on the specific areas of this dissertation and the more
general questions raised here. In this section, I will briefly describe what I think are some of the
165
important next steps. Thinking about the Philippines specifically, there is still a lot more work to be done
with dynasties. I look at dynasties across provinces, but more could be done looking at dynasties over
time. There is already some debate in the literature about whether long running dynasties are better or
worse for development, but we could also test if long running dynasties are more likely to hinder
prosecution. There is also the question of when dynasties rise and fall. Can the brand of a dynasty
degrade over time if they produce poor results for the areas they represent? A more difficult topic that
would be helpful is how dynastic alliances work. The problem is that these can’t easily be seen in naming
conventions. There might be something in electoral materials or campaigning involving people from
There is also more that can be done to examine some of the mechanisms suggested by this
dissertation. I suggest the existence and conditions for dynastic cooperation, but more concrete
evidence for this would be useful. This would likely have to be local and qualitative. In a similar vein,
something like a survey would be helpful to think about how voters see dynasties and corruption. There
are problems with reported behavior vis-a-vis corruption but getting some data directly on attitudes
would be helpful with the larger quantitative data in this dissertation. For thinking about the origins of
dynasties tracing land sales and titling in one province over its history could be helpful, though it would
Thinking about issues raised by this dissertation more generally, as noted before, I believe there
is a lot more room for using public procurement data to measure corruption. For this idea to gain wider
acceptance work could be done specifically to validate it rather than examine a causal relationship.
Thinking about dynasties, there isn’t much work that looks at dynasties cross nationally. This is because
political dynasties are going to be unique to each country and in most places, they are hard to measure.
However, there are a lot of countries with long histories of families in power. Moreover, I believe there
we should look at how those in power have changed in countries that have been democratic for a long
166
time. How many elected officials in the UK have aristocratic ancestors? How many American politicians
had ancestors who were major colonial landowners? I think it’s possible we see more families in power
Finally, there is more to be done looking at when anti-corruption institutions work and when
they fail. There is too much that treats this as an all or nothing question. Very few countries are Hong
Kong or Singapore, but even weak anti-corruption agencies make some cases. The question, then, is
under what circumstances do they work and how can these circumstances be expanded? Anti-
corruption agencies have an important part to play in reducing corruption, but we need a clearer idea of
Conclusion
In this dissertation, I’ve looked at how dynasties originated in the Philippines, how they limit
prosecutions for corruption, and when those who are indicted for corruption are elected. From this, we
can see how dynasties interact with and exacerbate problems of governance. I examined these
problems in the Philippines, but the same issues exist, in part, in many countries. These problems aren’t
immutable, but they are very difficult because of how ingrained they are in the political system. With
broad based reform even in the Philippines, these problems can be lessened. Not every part of the
Philippines sees the same level of dynasties or the same problems. Hopefully, this dissertation shed
some light on the extent of the issues, how they interacted, and suggested some possible ways to help.
167