The document discusses demand functions. It explains that a demand function describes the quantity demanded of a product based on its price and other factors. A general demand function is written as Q = f(P, A, Y, Pr) where Q is quantity, P is price, A is advertising, Y is income, and Pr is the price of a related product. The document provides an example demand function for coffee and shows how it can be used to derive the demand curve and determine how quantity demanded changes with price. It also discusses inverse demand functions and how to interpret the coefficients in a linear demand function.
The document discusses demand functions. It explains that a demand function describes the quantity demanded of a product based on its price and other factors. A general demand function is written as Q = f(P, A, Y, Pr) where Q is quantity, P is price, A is advertising, Y is income, and Pr is the price of a related product. The document provides an example demand function for coffee and shows how it can be used to derive the demand curve and determine how quantity demanded changes with price. It also discusses inverse demand functions and how to interpret the coefficients in a linear demand function.
The document discusses demand functions. It explains that a demand function describes the quantity demanded of a product based on its price and other factors. A general demand function is written as Q = f(P, A, Y, Pr) where Q is quantity, P is price, A is advertising, Y is income, and Pr is the price of a related product. The document provides an example demand function for coffee and shows how it can be used to derive the demand curve and determine how quantity demanded changes with price. It also discusses inverse demand functions and how to interpret the coefficients in a linear demand function.
The document discusses demand functions. It explains that a demand function describes the quantity demanded of a product based on its price and other factors. A general demand function is written as Q = f(P, A, Y, Pr) where Q is quantity, P is price, A is advertising, Y is income, and Pr is the price of a related product. The document provides an example demand function for coffee and shows how it can be used to derive the demand curve and determine how quantity demanded changes with price. It also discusses inverse demand functions and how to interpret the coefficients in a linear demand function.
Aarushi Amity Business School Demand Function • A product’s demand function describes amount of product that is demanded for each possible combination of its price and other factors. • The general form of the demand function in terms of price and quantity demanded is: Q = f(P) • Including other variables it can also be written as: Q = f(P, A, Y, Pr), • where A represents advertising expenditure, Y represents average income of the market and Pr represents the price of a related product.
AARUSHI I MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS 2
Demand Function • For example, we could specify the demand for coffee as a function of the price of coffee (P), income (Y), the price of sugar (Ps), holding all other factors constant, the demand function will be: Q = f(P, Ps, Y) • This expression shows how the quantity of coffee demanded varies with the price of coffee, the price of sugar and the income of consumers. • The estimated demand function has a linear form – Q = 8.56 - P - 0.3Ps + 0.1Y where Q is the quantity of coffee in millions of tons per year, P is the price of coffee in dollars per pound, Ps is the price of sugar in dollars per pound, and Y is the average annual household income in high- income countries in thousands of dollars. AARUSHI I MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS 3 Demand Function • When we draw the demand curve, we set Ps and Y at specific values, say, Ps = $0.20 per pound and Y = $35 thousand per year. • By substituting these values for Ps and Y in the equation, we can express the quantity demanded as a function of only the price of coffee: Q = 8.56 - P - 0.3Ps + 0.1Y Q = 8.56 - P - (0.3 × 0.2) + (0.1 × 35) Q = 12 – P • The demand function corresponds to linear demand curve. • The constant term (12) is the quantity demanded if the price is zero. • i.e. Q = 12, where demand curve hits the quantity axis—when price is zero.
AARUSHI I MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS 4
How quantity demanded varies with change in price? • Using demand function, Q = 12 – P • If the price falls from P1 to P2, the change in price, ∆P = P2 - P1 • Quantity demanded changes from Q1 to Q2, ∆Q = Q2 - Q1 • The change in the quantity demanded, in response to the price change is – ∆Q = Q2 - Q1 = f(P2) - f(P1) = (12 - P2) - (12 - P1) = - (P2 - P1) = - ∆P • Thus, the change in the quantity demanded, ∆Q, is - ∆P, indicating inverse relation between quantity demanded and price. AARUSHI I MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS 5 Inverse • As we usually graph this relation with the price of the good on the vertical axis, it is Demand useful to represent the demand function with price on the left-hand side and Function everything else on the right-hand side. This relation is called an inverse demand function. We know that • It reveals how much consumers are willing equation of a straight and able to pay for each additional unit of line is – good X. y = mx + c • Example, if demand function is – Where m is the slope Qd = 6060 – 3P and c is the y- • Then, inverse demand function would be – intercept. 1 P = 2020 - Qd 3 • Here, the y-intercept is 2020 and the slope is -1/3. AARUSHI I MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS 6 Deriving slope of the demand curve • Given the demand function for coffee, Q = 12 - P, • the derivative of the demand function with respect to price is 𝒅𝑸 = -1 𝒅𝑷 • Therefore, the slope of the demand curve, which is 𝒅𝑷 𝟏 = 𝒅𝑸 = -1 𝒅𝑸 𝒅𝑷 • The Law of Demand states that the derivative of the demand function with respect to price is negative, 𝒅𝑸 <0 𝒅𝑷
AARUSHI I MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS 7
Demand Function Interpretations • Consider the following linear demand function – Qdx = α0 + αxPx + αyPy + αMM • By the law of demand, an increase in Px leads to a decrease in the quantity demanded of good X. This means that αx < 0. • The sign of αy will be positive or negative, depending on whether goods X and Y are substitutes or complements. • If αy is a positive number, an increase in the price of good Y will lead to an increase in the consumption of good X; therefore, good X is a substitute for good Y. • If αy is a negative number, an increase in the price of good Y will lead to a decrease in the consumption of good X; hence, good X is a complement to good Y.
AARUSHI I MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS 8
Demand Function Interpretations • Consider the following linear demand function – Qdx = α0 + αxPx + αyPy + αMM • The sign of αM also can be positive or negative depending on whether X is a normal or an inferior good. • If αM is a positive number, an increase in income (M) will lead to an increase in the consumption of good X, and good X is a normal good. • If αM is a negative number, an increase in income will lead to a decrease in the consumption of good X, and good X is an inferior good
AARUSHI I MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS 9
Reference: Thomas, C. R., & Maurice, S. C. (2016). Managerial economics: Foundations of Business Analysis and Strategy. 12th ed. McGraw-Hill Education.