Het 4

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 21

Chapter Four: Marxist Economics

Introduction

Marxist economics is a school of economic thought based on the works of Karl Marx. It is a
critical theory of capitalism that seeks to explain the exploitation and oppression of workers
under capitalism. Marxist economics is a critical theory of capitalism that argues that it is
inherently exploitative and unstable. It is based on the labor theory of value, which states that
the value of a commodity is determined by the amount of socially necessary labor required to
produce it. Surplus value, the difference between the value of the goods that workers produce
and the wages that they are paid, is appropriated by capitalists in the form of profits. Capital
accumulation, the process by which capitalists reinvest their profits in order to expand their
businesses and increase their profits, leads to overproduction, underconsumption, and a
falling rate of profit, which can lead to periodic crises. Marxist economists argue that the only
way to achieve a just and equitable society is to overthrow capitalism and establish socialism
or communism.

4.1. Marx and the Labor Theory of Value

Karl Marx

The career of Karl Marx (1818-1883)—an economist, but also a philosopher, sociologist,
prophet, and revolutionist—is proof of the importance of economic ideas. Karl Marx
advocated for fundamental change in society and the economy. He is best known for his
theories about capitalism, socialism, and communism. Marx's most important works include
The Communist Manifesto (1848), which he co-wrote with Friedrich Engels, and Das Kapital
(1867-1894). In Das Kapital, Marx develops his theory of capitalism, which he sees as a
system that is inherently exploitative and unsustainable. He argues that capitalism is based on
the exploitation of workers by capitalists, and that this exploitation leads to a number of social
problems, such as poverty, inequality, and alienation. His economic theory is an application
of his theory of history to the capitalist economy. He wanted to lay bare the laws of the
dynamics of capitalism, and he focused on the dynamic process of change rather than the
static equilibrium of the economy. Marxian economics is useful for understanding the forces
underlying the market, whereas standard classical analysis is useful for organizing and
operating a socialist economy. Marxian and orthodox economic analysis should be looked
upon as complementary rather than mutually exclusive.

Marx's work has had a profound impact on modern intellectual, economic, and political
history. His ideas and theories, collectively known as Marxism, have been used to justify and
guide revolutions and social movements around the world. Marx also developed a theory of
history, known as historical materialism, which he used to explain the development of
capitalism and other social systems. Historical materialism argues that the economic base of
society determines its political and cultural superstructure. In other words, the way that a
society produces and distributes goods and services determines its political and social
institutions. In discussing growth, Marx emphasized the deterministic role of technology and
increasing returns. He argued that firms would get bigger and bigger for technological
reasons. In this emphasis he anticipated work by modern endogenous growth theorists, who
have returned modern economics to a focus on growth and increasing returns. While Marx’s
discussion was broader and more far-reaching than this modern work, it focused on the same
issues—the importance of technology in determining the working of the economy, and the
implications of increasing returns.

Marx's ideas have been both praised and criticized. His critics argue that his theories are
outdated and that they do not accurately reflect the way that the world works today. His
supporters argue that his ideas are still relevant and that they can be used to understand and
challenge the problems of contemporary capitalism. Despite the criticisms, Marx's work
remains an important influence on many fields of thought, including economics, sociology,
political science, and history. His ideas continue to be debated and discussed by scholars and
activists around the world.

The labor theory of value

The labor theory of value is a central concept in Karl Marx's economic theory. In developing a
theory of relative prices, or the quantitative relationship between things or commodities, Marx
essentially used Ricardo’s theory of value. Commodities manifest in their prices certain
quantitative relationships, and this means, according to Marx, that all commodities must
contain one element in common that must exist in certain measurable quantities. Marx
considered use value, or utility, as a common element but rejected this possibility. He then
turned to labor as the common element and concluded that it is the amount of labor time
necessary to produce commodities that governs their relative prices. It states that the value of
a commodity is determined by the amount of socially necessary labor required to produce it.
Socially necessary labor is the amount of time that it takes a typical worker to produce a good
using the prevailing technology and social conditions. To Marx, the only social cost of
producing commodities was labor. At the highest level of abstraction, Marx disregarded the
differing skills of labor and conceived of the total labor available to society for commodity
production as a homogeneous quantity, which he called abstract labor. The production of any
commodity requires the use of a part of the total supply of abstract labor. The relative prices
of commodities reflect the amounts of this abstract supply of labor, measured in clock hours,
necessary to produce the goods. This raises what we have called the skilled labor problem,
namely, that labor with varying skills will have varying outputs. Marx then reduced the level
of abstraction and met this issue by measuring the amount of labor required to produce a
commodity by the socially necessary labor time, which is defined as the time taken by a
worker with the average degree of skill possessed by labor at the time. Labor with skill
greater than the average is reduced to the average by measuring its greater productivity and
making an appropriate adjustment.

Marx argued that labor is the only source of value because it is the only thing that can create
new value. Land and capital, on the other hand, are simply stored-up labor. For example, a
machine that is used to produce shoes is simply the product of previous labor. It is the labor of
the workers who built the machine that creates its value.

He also argued that the value of a commodity is not the same as its price. Price is determined
by supply and demand, while value is determined by the amount of labor required to produce
it. Marx used the labor theory of value to explain the exploitation of workers under
capitalism. He argued that capitalists are able to extract surplus value from workers because
they pay workers less than the value of the goods that the workers produce. The surplus value
that is extracted from workers is the source of capitalist profits. The labor theory of value is a
controversial concept, and there has been much debate about its validity. However, it remains
an important concept in Marxist economics and in critical political economy.
If, for example, a given laborer, because of greater natural ability, produced 100 percent more
than a laborer with average skills, each hour of the superior labor would count as two hours of
average labor. In this manner, all labor time is reduced to socially necessary labor time. We
saw that Smith became involved in circular reasoning by measuring differences in labor skills
by wages paid to labor. Marx sidestepped the entire issue by assuming that differences in
labor skills are measured not by wages but by differences in physical productivity.

Another problem raised by a labor theory of value is how to account for the influence of
capital goods on relative prices. Marx used Ricardo’s solution to this problem, maintaining
that capital is stored-up labor. The labor time required to produce a commodity is, then, the
number of hours of labor immediately applied plus the number of hours required to produce
the capital destroyed in the process. Marx’s solution, like Ricardo’s, is not completely
satisfactory, because it fails to allow for the fact that where capital is used, interest may be
paid on the funds used to pay the indirect labor stored in the capital from the time of the
payment of the indirect labor until the sale of the product.

A labor theory of value must also address the issues raised by differing fertilities of land.
Equal amounts of labor time will produce varying outputs when applied to land of different
fertilities. The labor theory of value that Marx developed in the first two volumes of Capital
completely neglects this problem, but later he met the question by adopting Ricardo’s theory
of differential rent: the greater productivity of labor on land of superior fertility is absorbed
by the landlord as a differential rent. Competition will cause the rent on superior grades of
land to rise until the rates of profit on all grades of land are equal. Rent, then, is price-
determined, not price-determining.

A final difficulty inherent in a labor theory of value derives from the influence of profits on
prices. One of the crucial aspects of this problem involves labor- capital ratios in various
industries. Industries that are highly capital-intensive will produce goods whose profits are a
larger proportion of final price than industries of lesser capital intensity. Because of his close
study of Ricardo, Marx was fully aware of this problem, but throughout the first two volumes
of Capital he avoided the issue by assuming that all industries and firms have the same capital
intensity.
How the labor theory of value might be applied:

Suppose it takes two hours of labor to produce a bushel of wheat and four hours of labor to
produce a pair of shoes. Under the labor theory of value, the exchange ratio between wheat
and shoes would be two bushels of wheat for one pair of shoes. This is because the two
goods embody the same amount of socially necessary labor. However, in practice, the
exchange ratio between wheat and shoes might be different from this. For example, if there
is a high demand for shoes and a low demand for wheat, the price of shoes might be higher
than the price of wheat. This is because the price of a commodity is determined by supply
and demand, not just by its value. Despite its limitations, the labor theory of value is a
useful tool for understanding the nature of capitalism and the exploitation of workers. It
also provides a basis for a more just and equitable economic system.

Implications of the labor theory of value:

Capitalism is inherently exploitative. Under capitalism, workers are paid less than the
value of the goods that they produce. The difference between the value of what
workers produce and what they are paid is called surplus value, and it is the source of
capitalist profits.

Workers are the only source of value. All other factors of production, such as land and
capital, are simply stored-up labor. This means that workers are the only ones who
create value, but they do not receive all of the value that they create.

Prices are determined by supply and demand, but value is determined by labor. This
means that the price of a commodity may be higher or lower than its value, depending
on the forces of supply and demand. However, in the long term, prices tend to
gravitate towards the values of commodities.

The labor theory of value provides a basis for a more just and equitable economic
system. In a socialist system, workers would own and control the means of
production, and they would receive the full value of the goods that they produce. This
would eliminate the exploitation that is inherent in capitalism.

The labor theory of value is a complex and controversial concept, but it is an important part
of Marxist economics. It provides a framework for understanding the nature of capitalism
and the exploitation of workers. It also provides a basis for a more just and equitable
economic system.

Socialism and Communism

The terms socialism and communism have no exact meaning as they are used today, but in the
Marxian system they refer to stages that will occur in the historical process. One of the chief
characteristics of capitalism, he said, is that the means of production, capital, are not owned
or controlled by the proletariat. The major change that occurs in the transition from capitalism
to socialism is that the expropriators are expropriated—the proletariat now owns the means of
production. However, under socialism, a remaining vestige of capitalism is that economic
activity is still basically organized through the use of incentive systems: rewards must still be
given in order to induce people to labor. In the Marxian system, socialism is a set of relations
of production that will follow capitalism. It contains some vestiges of capitalism, such as the
use of incentive systems to induce people to labor. Under socialism, the means of production
are owned by the proletariat, but economic activity is still basically organized through the
market. Communism is a classless society in which the state has withered away and people
are motivated to work by their own sense of duty and responsibility to the community, rather
than by monetary reward. Marxian economics regards human beings as perfectible and
human goodness as suppressed and distorted by existing society. It believes that a
communistic society will reveal that humans are basically good.

There are two levels at which one can analyze Marxian economics: philosophical and
practical. The philosophical level asks whether it is a correct reading of human nature to see
the market as inherently alienating and whether a communistic society will reveal that
humans are basically good. The practical level asks whether there is a practical alternative to
the market, even if it is alienating. One appealing facet of Marxism is the view that humans
are basically good and that undesirable behavior is a result of the institutional environment.

Critics of Marx's dialectic argue that it is teleological, meaning that it is directed towards a
specific end, namely communism. They argue that this is not realistic, because there will
always be contradictions within society, regardless of the economic system. Modern Marxists
such as Richard Wolff and Stephen Resnick have reinterpreted Marx's dialectic as
overdeterminism, which means that there can be many possible paths. This interpretation is
more realistic, because it acknowledges that there is no single inevitable path to communism.
The recent collapse of the Soviet Union and the dramatic changes occurring in Eastern
Europe have led to a questioning of socialism and communism throughout the world. Even
China, the last major communist country, is now embracing private property and markets.
These developments suggest that there is no one-size-fits-all approach to socialism or
communism. Each country must find its own path to a more just and equitable society.

There are two main arguments for and against Marxian economics in light of recent
developments.

Against Marxian economics: The collapse of the Soviet Union and the dramatic
changes in Eastern Europe suggest that society is not on a direct path to
communism. Additionally, some modern Marxists argue that even socialism was not
truly tried in these countries, because the so-called communists simply became
oppressors.

For Marxian economics: Some argue that markets do alienate and that this
contradiction in capitalist society will ultimately lead to its overthrow and the
institution of a non-alienating economic system. Additionally, some argue that Marx's
use of class was a simplifying device that can change as social division changes, and
that he was wrong in his prediction that class divisions under capitalism would
increase.

4.2. Marx's theory of money

Marx's theory of money is based on his labor theory of value. Marx’s theory of money, which
represents one of his most original intellectual contributions, offers a superior framework for
the analysis of contemporary monetary issues and processes. In contradistinction to other
economic schools, Marx has no notion of a dichotomy between the real and the monetary side
of the economy. The commodity, his point of departure for the study of capitalism, has a
natural, physical form (“use value”) and a social form (“exchange value”) which exists in the
form of money. The different functions of money derive from different movements in the
exchange of commodities and capital, with interest-bearing capital (“capital as capital”) itself
constituting a commodity. Different types of exchanges require different forms of money. The
latter are historically specific, yet unable to alter the essential functions of money or the socio-
economic basis for its existence which derives from the nature of commodity production.
Hence, a key feature of Marx’s theory of money is that it aims to explain the socio-economic
basis for the existence of money by treating its essential properties and functions as
independent from its concrete historical forms. Marx’s theory of money is not a commodity
theory of money; neither is it a non-commodity theory of money. What underlies the
continued relevance of this theory is that its essence is independent of the concrete forms
money takes—gold, leather, paper, tin, or electronic entries on a bank account. Starting with
an analysis of key aspects of Marx’s theory of money, this paper examines their significance
in the light of important monetary phenomena, such as the rush to liquidity during financial
and commercial crises, the nature of hoarding, and the attempts at man aging the different
forms of money via monetary policy. He argued that money is a commodity that is used to
measure the value of other commodities. The value of money is determined by the amount of
socially necessary labor required to produce it.

According to Marx, money has five main functions. Marx argued that these five functions of
money are essential for capitalism to function. Without money, it would be impossible to have
a division of labor, specialization of production, or accumulation of capital.

1. Measure of value: Money is used to measure the value of all other commodities. This
means that money provides a common unit of account that allows us to compare the
values of different goods and services. Marx argued that the value of a commodity is
determined by the amount of socially necessary labor required to produce it. Money
acts as a measure of value by providing a common unit of account that allows us to
compare the values of different commodities. For example, we can say that a loaf of
bread is worth $1.00 and a gallon of milk is worth $3.00. This means that the socially
necessary labor required to produce a gallon of milk is three times greater than the
socially necessary labor required to produce a loaf of bread.

2. Medium of exchange: Money is used to facilitate the exchange of goods and


services. Without money, we would have to rely on barter, which is a much less
efficient system of exchange. Without money, we would have to rely on barter to
exchange goods and services. Barter is a very inefficient system of exchange because
it requires both parties to have something that the other party wants. For example, if
we want a haircut, we would need to find a barber who wants something that we have,
such as food or clothing. Money solves this problem by acting as a medium of
exchange. We can sell my food or clothing to someone who wants it, and then use the
money to buy a haircut from the barber. The barber can then use the money to buy
whatever he wants.

3. Means of hoarding: Money can be hoarded as a store of value. This means that we
can save money for future use, or we can use it to purchase goods and services at a
later date. Money can be hoarded as a store of value. This means that we can save
money for future use, or we can use it to purchase goods and services at a later date.
This is important because it allows us to provide for our future needs and to take
advantage of opportunities that may arise in the future.

4. Means of payment: Money can be used to pay debts. This means that we can use
money to settle our obligations to others, regardless of whether we are buying goods
and services or repaying a loan. Money can be used to pay debts. This means that we
can use money to settle our obligations to others, regardless of whether we are buying
goods and services or repaying a loan. This is important because it allows us to engage
in complex economic transactions without having to worry about swapping goods and
services directly.

5. Universal currency: Money is universally accepted as a means of payment. This


means that we can use money to purchase goods and services all over the world.
Money is universally accepted as a means of payment. This means that we can use
money to purchase goods and services all over the world. This is important because it
allows us to trade with people from all over the world, which can lead to economic
growth and prosperity.

Money is a commodity that is used to measure the value of other commodities.The value of
money is determined by the amount of socially necessary labor required to produce it. Marx
argued that money is not just a neutral medium of exchange. It is also a social power that can
be used to exploit and oppress workers. For example, capitalists can use their money to buy
the means of production and then hire workers to produce goods for them. The capitalists then
sell the goods for a profit, while the workers receive only a portion of the value that they
create. It is also a social power that can be used to exploit and oppress workers. Money plays
a central role in the development of capitalism. The accumulation of money is the driving
force behind capitalism. Capitalists are constantly striving to accumulate more money, and
they do this by exploiting workers and extracting surplus value from them. A worker sells
their labor power to a capitalist for a wage. The worker is paid less than the value of the goods
that they produce, and the difference is appropriated by the capitalist in the form of profit. A
capitalist uses their money to buy the means of production, such as a factory and
machinery. The capitalist then hires workers to produce goods using the means of
production. The capitalist then sells the goods for a profit, while the workers receive only a
portion of the value that they create. A consumer buys a good from a store using money. The
money is then used by the store owner to pay their suppliers and employees.

Marx's theory of money is a complex and sophisticated theory. It has been criticized by some
economists, but it remains an important influence on Marxist economics and critical political
economy.

1.3. Marx on distribution

Marx on distribution is a complex topic, but it is essential to understanding his critique of


capitalism. Marx argued that the distribution of income and wealth in capitalist society is
unjust and exploitative. He believed that workers are the only ones who create value, but
they receive only a fraction of the value that they create. The rest of the value is
appropriated by capitalists in the form of profit.

Marx explained the distribution of income and wealth in capitalism using his labor theory
of value. He argued that the value of a commodity is determined by the amount of socially
necessary labor required to produce it. Socially necessary labor is the amount of time that it
takes a typical worker to produce a good using the prevailing technology and social
conditions.

Marx argued that capitalists are able to appropriate surplus value because they own the
means of production, such as factories and machines. Workers are forced to sell their labor
power to capitalists in order to survive. The capitalists then use the workers' labor power to
produce goods, which they sell for a profit. The profit that capitalists make is the difference
between the value of the goods that the workers produce and the wages that the workers are
paid. Marx argued that this profit is stolen from the workers, and that it is the source of all
inequality and exploitation in capitalist society.

Marx believed that the only way to achieve a just and equitable distribution of income and
wealth is to overthrow capitalism and establish socialism. In a socialist society, the means
of production would be owned and controlled by the workers, and the workers would
receive the full value of the goods that they produce.

The key implications of Marx's theory of distribution: The distribution of income and
wealth in capitalist society is unjust and exploitative. Workers are paid less than the value
that they create, and the rest of the value is appropriated by capitalists in the form of profit.
Profit is stolen from workers. Profit is the difference between the value of the goods that
workers produce and the wages that they are paid. Marx argued that this profit is stolen
from the workers, and that it is the source of all inequality and exploitation in capitalist
society. The only way to achieve a just and equitable distribution of income and wealth is to
overthrow capitalism and establish socialism. In a socialist society, the means of production
would be owned and controlled by the workers, and the workers would receive the full
value of the goods that they produce. Marx's theory of distribution has been influential in
the development of socialist and communist thought. It has also been used to justify and
guide revolutions and social movements around the world.

The Concentration and Centralization of Capital

Marx's law of the concentration and centralization of capital predicts that capitalism will
eventually evolve into a system dominated by large corporations with monopoly power. This
is because larger firms can achieve economies of scale and produce at lower costs than
smaller firms. As a result, larger firms will drive smaller firms out of the market, leading to a
concentration of capital in fewer and fewer hands. This concentration of capital will also be
facilitated by the growth of credit markets and the corporate form of business organization.

Marx believed that the growth of monopoly power would lead to a number of undesirable
social consequences, including a new aristocracy of finance, increased speculation, and a
separation of ownership and control. He also argued that the concentration and centralization
of capital was another example of the contradictions within capitalism that would ultimately
lead to its destruction.
Marx's prediction of the rise of large corporations with monopoly power has been largely
borne out. In many industries today, a small number of large firms dominate the market. This
concentration of market power has been associated with a number of negative consequences,
including higher prices, less innovation, and reduced economic growth. However, it is
important to note that Marx did not fully develop an explanation of the forces that would
bring about the growth of the corporation and monopoly power. As a result, his law of the
concentration and centralization of capital is somewhat vague and difficult to test.

Increasing Misery of the Proletariat

Marx called another contradiction of capitalism that will lead to its collapse the increasing
misery of the proletariat. Marx's doctrine of the increasing misery of the proletariat can be
interpreted in three different ways:

1. Absolute increasing misery: The real income of the mass of society decreases with
the development of capitalism. This interpretation has been disproven by history, as
real incomes have increased in developed countries.

2. Relative increasing misery: The proletariat's share of the national income declines
over time. This interpretation is also questionable, as historical evidence shows that
wages have constituted a relatively constant proportion of national income over time.

3. Non-economic increasing misery: The quality of life declines as people become


chained to the industrial process. This interpretation is more difficult to assess, but it is
certainly true that many people find the alienation and exploitation of capitalism to be
dehumanizing.

It is clear that Marx's prediction of increasing misery has not come to pass in the way that
he expected. However, his analysis of capitalism still has much to offer, and the concepts of
surplus and exploitation are still relevant today.

Marx's doctrine of increasing misery predicts that the quality of life for the proletariat will
decline, regardless of whether their income rises or falls. This is because capitalism is an
exploitative system that dehumanizes workers. Marx believed that the only way to improve
the quality of life for the proletariat is to overthrow capitalism and establish a socialist
society. This prediction is difficult to test because there is no accepted measure of the
quality of life. However, it is worth noting that many people find the alienation and
exploitation of capitalism to be dehumanizing. Additionally, a number of economists have
questioned whether rising per capita income must be associated with the development of a
good society. Marx subscribed to all three doctrines of increasing misery at one time or
another, but eventually abandoned the first one. He argued that the relative income position
of the proletariat would fall over time, even though its real income would rise. He also
believed that one of the most undesirable consequences of capitalism is a deterioration of
the quality of life.

Surplus and Exploitation

Marx's labor theory of value divides production into two parts: the cost of production, which
is the labor time spent on producing the good, and the surplus value, which is the difference
between the good's price and its cost of production. Marx's message is that any economy will
produce more goods and services than are needed to pay all the real social costs of
production. This residual surplus value can be used to improve the lives of workers, invest in
new technologies, or fund other social programs. However, Marx also argued that capitalism
is an exploitative system because the capitalists (who own the means of production) keep the
surplus value for themselves, while the workers (who produce the goods and services) only
receive a small fraction of it. This exploitation is the source of all social problems under
capitalism, such as poverty, inequality, and environmental degradation.

Marx's concept of surplus value is similar to the physiocrats' concept of net product. It is the
difference between total yearly output and the real costs that must be paid to produce that
output. Marx argued that surplus value is created by labor, but that it is taken away from
workers by capitalists who own the means of production. This exploitation is the source of all
social problems under capitalism. However, economists today, Marxist or mainstream, do not
see economic theory as proving the existence or the nonexistence of exploitation. In other
words, Marx's claim that surplus value is "taken from" labor is not a scientific fact, but rather
a philosophical or ideological position. Marx's concepts of surplus and exploitation are still
used today, but most economists have given up the labor theory of value. The concept of
surplus is useful for thinking about the equitable distribution of income, but the concept of
exploitation is more controversial. Marx used it in a pejorative sense to describe the unfair
income distribution at the time, but most modern economists see it as going beyond the role
of economists to make such judgments. Some economists argue that human nature is
generally exploitative and that the market is based on the concept of mutual exploitation.
They see the labor theory of value as providing a justification for this exploitation. However,
other economists argue that there is no need for the labor theory of value to justify the
existence of surplus or exploitation. They argue that these phenomena can be explained by
other factors, such as market power or the need to invest in new technologies. Ultimately,
whether or not the concepts of surplus and exploitation are useful is a matter of debate.
However, they are still widely used in discussions about economics and social justice.

1.4. Marx 's Theory of Capital Accumulation and Crises

Marx's theory of capital accumulation and crises is a complex and sophisticated theory that
explains the dynamics of capitalism and its inherent tendency to experience crises.

Marx argued that capitalism is a system that is driven by the accumulation of capital.
Capitalists are constantly reinvesting their profits in order to expand their businesses and
increase their profits. Marx identified two main sources of capital accumulation:

Surplus value: Surplus value is the difference between the value of the goods and
services produced by workers and the wages that they are paid. Capitalists are able to
extract surplus value from workers because they own the means of production and can
dictate the terms of employment.
Dispossession: Dispossession is the process by which capitalists acquire the means of
production and other resources from others, often through force or coercion. This can
include things like land enclosures, colonialism, and slavery.

Marx argued that capital accumulation is a necessary condition for the growth of capitalism,
but it is also a process that is inherently unstable. As capitalists reinvest their profits in order
to expand their businesses, they are constantly increasing the demand for labor. This can lead
to inflation and higher wages, which can erode the profits of capitalists.

In addition, Marx argued that the process of capital accumulation leads to a growing
concentration of wealth and power in the hands of a few capitalists. This can lead to
inequality, social unrest, and even revolution. Capital accumulation is the process of
increasing the stock of capital goods and financial assets in an economy. It is a key driver of
economic growth and development. Capital goods are the physical assets that businesses use
to produce goods and services, such as machinery, equipment, and buildings. Financial assets
are claims to future income or wealth, such as stocks, bonds, and loans.

The process of capital accumulation can be divided into two main stages:

A. Production of surplus value: This is the first stage of capital accumulation, and it
involves the production of goods and services that are worth more than the wages paid
to the workers who produce them. The difference between the value of the goods and
services produced and the wages paid to the workers is called surplus value.
B. Realization of surplus value: This is the second stage of capital accumulation, and it
involves selling the goods and services produced in the first stage and converting the
proceeds back into capital. This can be done in two main ways:
✓ Reinvestment: The capitalist can reinvest the proceeds from the sale of goods
and services into new capital goods, such as machinery, equipment, and
buildings. This will allow the capitalist to produce more goods and services in
the future, and therefore generate more surplus value.
✓ Consumption: The capitalist can also consume the proceeds from the sale of
goods and services. This includes things like buying luxury goods and
services, or investing in financial assets such as stocks and bonds.

The process of capital accumulation is a continuous one. As the capitalist reinvests its profits,
the stock of capital goods in the economy grows. This allows the capitalist to produce more
goods and services, and therefore generate more surplus value. The cycle then repeats itself.

Overaccumulation occurs when there is too much capital and too few consumers. This can
happen for a number of reasons, such as:

Rising inequality: When the rich get richer and the poor get poorer, there is
less money available for consumption.
Technological unemployment: As technology advances, it can lead to job
displacement, which reduces the number of people with money to spend.
Debt-driven growth: When the economy is growing on the basis of debt, it can
lead to a bubble that eventually bursts, leading to a crisis.
This process of capital accumulation leads to a number of problems, including:

Overproduction: As capitalists expand their businesses, they produce more goods than
consumers can afford to buy. This leads to overproduction and a fall in prices.
Underconsumption: As workers are paid less than the value of the goods that they
produce, they do not have enough money to buy all of the goods that are produced.
This leads to underconsumption and a further fall in prices.
Falling rate of profit: As capitalists reinvest their profits in order to expand their
businesses, they need to buy more machinery and equipment. This machinery and
equipment becomes more expensive over time, which reduces the rate of profit. These
problems lead to crises in capitalism which characterized by a sharp decline in
economic activity, a rise in unemployment, and a fall in profits.

Marx argued that crises are not accidental events. They are a necessary part of the capitalist
system. Crises serve to clear away the surplus capital and labor that has accumulated during
the expansionary phase of the capitalist cycle. This allows capitalism to enter a new phase of
expansion, but the cycle of accumulation and crises is inevitably repeated.

Suppose there is a capitalist who owns a factory that produces shoes. The capitalist reinvests
their profits in order to expand the factory and increase production. This leads to
overproduction of shoes and a fall in prices. As a result of the fall in prices, the capitalist
makes less profit. The capitalist then tries to cut costs by reducing wages and laying off
workers. This leads to underconsumption and a further fall in prices. The capitalist is now in a
difficult position. They have too much inventory and they are not making enough profit. This
leads to a crisis in the capitalist's business. The crisis may force the capitalist to sell off some
of their assets or even to close their business. This will lead to job losses and economic
hardship for the workers. However, the crisis will also clear away some of the surplus capital
and labor that has accumulated.

Marx identified a number of counteracting tendencies that can offset the falling rate of profit.
These include:

Increases in the rate of exploitation: Capitalists can try to increase the rate of
exploitation by working their workers longer hours for lower wages.
Technological innovation: Technological innovation can lead to increases in
productivity, which can offset the falling rate of profit.
Expansion into new markets: Capitalists can expand into new markets to find new
sources of profit.
Foreign investment: Capitalists can invest in foreign countries where wages are lower
and the rate of profit is higher.

But, Marx's theory of capital accumulation is exploitive and a central concept in his
economic theory. It explains how capitalism expands and develops over time. Marx argued
that capitalism is a system that is driven by the accumulation of capital. Capitalists are
constantly reinvesting their profits in order to expand their businesses and increase their
profits. This process of capital accumulation leads to a number of important developments,
including:

The growth of the means of production: As capitalists reinvest their profits in their
businesses, they invest in new machinery, equipment, and buildings. This leads to an
increase in the size and productivity of the means of production.
The concentration of capital: As capitalists reinvest their profits, they also tend to acquire
more capital. This leads to a concentration of capital in the hands of a few large
capitalists.
The internationalization of capital: As capitalists seek to expand their businesses, they
often invest in foreign countries. This leads to the internationalization of capital and the
development of a global capitalist economy.

Marx argued that the process of capital accumulation is inherently exploitative. Capitalists are
able to accumulate capital by paying workers less than the value of the goods that they
produce. This difference between the value of what workers produce and what they are paid is
called surplus value, and it is the source of capitalist profits.

Marx also argued that the process of capital accumulation is inherently unstable. As capitalists
expand their businesses and invest in new machinery and equipment, they also increase the
supply of goods on the market. This can lead to overproduction and a fall in prices. When
prices fall, capitalists make less profit, and they may be forced to cut wages or lay off
workers. This can lead to a downward spiral in the economy, known as a crisis.
Marx's theory of capital accumulation has been influential in the development of socialist and
communist thought. It has also been used to justify and guide revolutions and social
movements around the world.

The Falling Rate of Profit and Business Crises

The falling rate of profit is a theory developed by Karl Marx in his book Capital: Volume 1. It
states that the rate of profit, which is the ratio of surplus value to capital, tends to fall over
time in capitalism. Marx argued that the falling rate of profit occurs because of the increasing
organic composition of capital. The organic composition of capital is the ratio of constant
capital (machinery, equipment, and buildings) to variable capital (wages). As capitalists invest
more in constant capital in order to increase productivity, the organic composition of capital
rises. This means that each unit of labor produces more value, but the rate of profit declines.

Marx integrated his law of the falling rate of profit into these two theories. Thus, his theories
that depressions result when technology fails to develop smoothly, that disproportionality
crises will occur because overproduction in one industry can adversely affect the rest of the
economy, and that the rate of profit will steadily decline, are all facets of a single integrated
view that capitalism will fail to provide stable levels of economic activity at a full utilization
of resources.

Marx had another explanation for depressions — or crises, as he called them— that is unusual
in that it accepts Say’s Law. He said that even if we make all the necessary assumptions so
that Say’s Law holds, capitalism will still fail because of inherent contradictions that will
bring about business crises. In the Marxian model, a capitalist economy clearly depends on
the behavior of the capitalist, whose reactions to changing rates of profits and changing
expectations of profits are a central part of the explanation of business crises. Marx used his
law of the long-run, continual fall in the rate of profits to explain short-run fluctuations in
economic activity, asserting that in their search for greater profits, the capitalists increase
capital spending and thereby cause the rate of profit to fall. The capitalists will periodically
react to this fall in profit rates by reducing investment spending, causing fluctuations in
economic activity, which will engender crises. Thus, Marx deduced crises even in a model
that accepts Say’s Law.
Marx argued that crises are not simply temporary disruptions to the capitalist system, but
rather are an essential feature of capitalism. He believed that crises would eventually lead to
the overthrow of capitalism and the establishment of a socialist system. Marx's theory of
crises has been influential among both economists and Marxists. However, it has also been
criticized for a number of reasons. One criticism is that Marx's theory is too deterministic, and
does not allow for the possibility of government intervention to prevent crises. Another
criticism is that Marx's theory does not adequately explain why crises occur at some times and
not others.

Cyclically Recurring Fluctuations

One model of economic fluctuation suggested by Marx is a recurring cycle. Impressed by the
dramatic growth of the textile industry in England, he hypothesized that a burst of
technological change could generate a business cycle. A technological burst will produce
increased capital accumulation and an increased demand for labor. The size of the reserve
army will fall, wages will rise, surplus value will fall, the rate of surplus value will fall, and
the rate of profit will decrease. The falling rate of profit will result in decreased capital
accumulation as the economy spirals downward into depression. But depression, according to
Marx, contains elements that will sooner or later generate a new expansion in economic
activity. As total output falls, the size of the reserve army of the unemployed is enlarged.

The competitive pressure of this unemployed labor will bring down wages and thus provide
greater profit opportunities. These larger profits will stimulate more capital accumulation, and
economic activity will increase as the upward stage of the cycle begins. Marx suggested that
another self-corrective aspect of depressions was their destruction of capital values. Because
profit is a money calculation, businesses that were not profitable because of the inflated value
of their capital assets carried over from the prosperity phase of the cycle become profitable as
asset values are lowered during the depression. A cycle started by a technological burst may
generate further cycles in the future as capital equipment wears out. If all plants and
equipment were replaced evenly over time, there would be a constant level of investment to
replace worn-out capital goods. A replacement cycle can be generated, however, when the
capital goods put into place during the technological burst suddenly require immediate
replacement.
The Origin of Business Crises

Marx argued that the capitalist economy is fundamentally different from a simple barter
economy. In a barter economy, production and consumption are synchronized, and money
is simply a medium of exchange. In a capitalist economy, however, production is oriented
towards the production of exchange values and profits, rather than use values. This means
that capitalists will continue to produce goods even if there is no demand for them, which
can lead to overproduction and crises.

Marx's critique of Say's Law is based on this distinction between barter and capitalist
economies. Say's Law states that supply creates its own demand, meaning that the
production of goods and services will automatically generate the income necessary to
purchase them. However, Marx argued that this law does not hold true in a capitalist
economy, because capitalists are not motivated by the production of use values, but by the
pursuit of profits. If there is no demand for the goods that capitalists produce, they will still
produce them in order to make profits. This can lead to overproduction and crises, as there
will not be enough income to purchase all of the goods that have been produced.

Marx's view of the capitalist economy as inherently unstable and prone to crises is a
significant departure from the classical economic model. Classical economists believed that
the capitalist economy was naturally self-correcting, and that any crises that did occur
would be temporary. Marx, on the other hand, argued that crises are an inherent part of the
capitalist system, and that they will continue to occur until the system is overthrown.

Marx argued that capitalism is a system oriented towards the production of exchange values
and profits, rather than use values. This means that capitalists are motivated to produce
goods even if there is no demand for them, which can lead to overproduction and crises.
Marx also argued that the rate of profit is a key factor that determines investment spending,
and that changes in the rate of profit will lead to fluctuations in the total level of economic
activity. Marx's analysis of capitalism is significant because it challenges the classical
economic view that the capitalist system is naturally self-correcting. Marx argued that
crises are an inherent part of the capitalist system, and that they will continue to occur until
the system is overthrown.
Disproportionality Crises

Once an economy moves from the barter stage to a high degree of labor specialization and the
use of money and markets, there may be difficulty in coordinating the levels of output of its
various sectors. Under capitalism the market mechanism performs this function, but Marx
questioned the ability of the market to reallocate resources smoothly. Suppose there is an
increase in the demand for the products of industry A and a decrease in demand for the
commodities produced in industry B. In a smoothly functioning capitalist economy, prices
and profits in industry A would increase, and prices and profits in industry B would decline.
In reaction to these changing profits, capitalists would move resources from the contracting to
the expanding industry. The excess supply or overproduction of industry B would thus be of
short duration and would have no perceptible influence on the general level of economic
activity. Overproduction in one industry, what Ricardo called a partial glut, would not spread
to the rest of the economy and cause a general decline in economic activity, or a depression.

Marx contended that supply and demand will not always mesh this perfectly in an economy’s
various submarkets and that the entire process of resource reallocation therefore will not work
as smoothly as in the classical model. His theory is that the unemployment created in industry
B as demand decreased could spread to the rest of the economy and result in a general decline
in economic activity, a view that is directly opposed to the orientation of the orthodox
classical theorists. Classical theory looks to the market to solve problems of resource
allocation. It stresses equilibrium, maintaining that positions of disequilibrium are of short
duration and that a smooth transition occurs between equilibria. Marx assumed disharmony in
the system and looked for basic contradictions in the workings of market forces. Orthodox
theory has not paid much attention to Marx’s disproportionality crises theory, arguing that an
individual industry is so small relative to the entire economy that the spread of
overproduction from one industry to produce a general decline is unlikely. They also argue
that the mobility of resources is much greater than Marx admitted. Overproduction in a major
industry such as automobiles, however, might conceivably spread to the rest of the economy.

You might also like