Dokumen - Pub Geopolitics and Democracy The Western Liberal Order From Foundation To Fracture 0197535402 9780197535400
Dokumen - Pub Geopolitics and Democracy The Western Liberal Order From Foundation To Fracture 0197535402 9780197535400
Dokumen - Pub Geopolitics and Democracy The Western Liberal Order From Foundation To Fracture 0197535402 9780197535400
“In this tour de force, Trubowitz and Burgoon offer a new and compelling
portrait of the shifting and fraught domestic foundations of Western de-
mocracy and its postwar leadership of the liberal world order. Beautifully
written and deeply researched, Geopolitics and Democracy chronicles the
decades-in-the-making erosion of support for liberal internationalism in
Western societies—and points to ways in which liberal democracies might
once again bring their ambitions and capacities back into line.”
—G. John Ikenberry, Albert G. Milbank Professor of Politics and
International Affairs, Princeton University
P E T E R T RU B OW I T Z A N D B R IA N BU R G O O N
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers
the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education
by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University
Press in the UK and certain other countries.
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780197535400.001.0001
List of Figures xi
Preface and Acknowledgments xv
Appendices 139
Notes 183
References 207
Index 233
Figures
War has given Western democracies a renewed sense of unity and purpose.
In response to Vladimir Putin’s invasion of Ukraine, Western governments
have imposed tough economic sanctions on Moscow, sent weapons and aid
to Kyiv, ratcheted up military spending, strengthened their security ties,
and thrown open their doors to millions of Ukrainian refugees. The speed,
breadth, and vigor of the West’s response have raised hopes that Putin’s brutal
war marks a turning point for a liberal international order whose rules and
norms have been badly battered and weakened by the forces of autocracy and
nationalism. Whether the liberal order gains a new lease on life will depend
on more than Western democracies’ resolve in the current international
crisis, however. The liberal order’s future will be determined by the push and
pull of domestic politics as well as by geopolitics.
Geopolitics and Democracy is about how international and domestic pol-
itics have shaped and reshaped the liberal world order from its postwar
origins through the height of the Cold War to the present era. For decades,
the liberal order’s political foundations were sturdy and strong. Geopolitics
and social democracy were self-reinforcing, the one buttressing and forti-
fying the other. Today, the liberal order’s foundations are fractured, riven by
anti-globalist and populist insurgencies and democratic backsliding. We ex-
plain how this happened and consider what might be done to restore do-
mestic support for the liberal order. In telling this story, we draw on ideas and
concepts that will be familiar to scholars of international relations, compara-
tive politics, and political economy, combining and testing them in new ways.
What emerges is an account that traces today’s disorder and discontent
back to choices and missteps that Western leaders made at the height of
liberal triumphalism after the Cold War. Chief among them was Western
governments’ failure to balance the pressures to rapidly globalize markets
and pool national sovereignty at the supranational level against the demands
for greater social protections and economic security at home. Western
democracies succeeded in expanding the liberal order, but the resulting im-
balance between foreign and domestic policy came at the cost of mounting
public disillusionment and political division at home. In short, Western
xvi Preface and Acknowledgments
governments’ efforts to globalize the liberal order exceeded what their do-
mestic politics would allow.
Closing this gap will be critical if Western leaders hope to put the liberal
order on solid domestic footing again in their nations. In one democracy after
another, the turn to globalism has weakened the political center and fueled
ideological extremism. As we show, this has proven costly internationally as
well as domestically. As Western democracies have become more internally
fragmented, the pace of globalization and international institution-building
they have long set has slowed. Meanwhile, Western party democracy, once
a source of Western attraction, has lost much of its international luster and
appeal. If Western democracies hope to reverse these international trends,
understanding how they got themselves into this political fix is an essential
first step. In writing Geopolitics and Democracy, we have tried to keep this
goal front and center.
We began this collaborative journey in 2015 as part of the Dahrendorf
Forum on Europe’s future, a joint initiative by the Hertie School in Berlin and
the London School of Economics and Political Science, funded by Stiftung
Mercator. After co-authoring a couple of articles on the erosion of domestic
support for the liberal order in the US, European, and other Western democ-
racies, we decided to deepen and expand the argument in a book. We began
working on the project in earnest shortly before the COVID-19 pandemic
struck, traveling back and forth between Amsterdam and London and
then, like so many others, meeting over Zoom. For both of us, it was a labor
of love as the book engages issues that touch core themes of our research
interests. It was also an opportunity to rekindle and deepen an old friendship
forged many years before when teaching and studying at UCSD in La Jolla,
California.
At various stages of the project, we have benefited from the comments,
suggestions, and insights of colleagues and friends at LSE and the University
of Amsterdam, as well as from seminars and conferences at Columbia
University, the Hertie School, Princeton University, Université de Genève,
the University of Konstanz, and the University of Tokyo where we have
presented parts of the argument and analysis. We are especially grateful to
Catherine Boone, Alexander Trubowitz, Wolfgang Wagner, and three anon-
ymous reviewers for extremely helpful suggestions on how to improve the
book. At Oxford University Press, we wish to thank Dave McBride for his
sound advice and encouragement. The book has also benefited from Alexcee
Bechthold’s attention to detail during the production process. We would also
Preface and Acknowledgments xvii
like to thank Stella Canessa and Beatriz Da Silva for their expert research
assistance.
We have accumulated many debts in writing this book, but none is greater
than the ones we owe to our respective families. They have been a source of
inspiration and support, especially in the face of the many challenges that
COVID-19 presented for work and family life while this book was being
researched and drafted. Peter thanks Catherine, Joshua, and Alexander for
their constant encouragement and many insights about this research and the
immense challenges facing liberal democracies today. Brian thanks Nicole,
Max, and David for their support and wisdom on the project (and on life out-
side the project). We dedicate this book to them.
1
The Solvency Gap
Geopolitics and Democracy. Peter Trubowitz and Brian Burgoon, Oxford University Press.
© Oxford University Press 2023. DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780197535400.003.0001
2 Geopolitics and Democracy
countries. This too is part of the Western-led liberal order’s long trajectory
stretching from the postwar era to the present.
We are also mindful that there is a long arc of writings about the West’s
woes. Like the greatly exaggerated reports of Mark Twain’s demise,
historians, political scientists, and commentators have been predicting the
West’s death since Oswald Spengler published The Decline of the West after
World War I.8 Geopolitics and Democracy is not another monograph about
the West’s inexorable decline. Our purpose is different. In the pages that
follow, we argue that Western democracies’ foreign policies have overrun
their political foundations, but that it is within their power to bring inter-
national ends and domestic means back into balance. To do so, a necessary
first step is to correctly diagnose how the West got itself into this fix. As we
show, today’s anti-globalist pressures in Western democracies owe more to
the breakdown of their commitment to social democracy at home than the
headlong pursuit of democracy promotion abroad, however checkered the
history of the latter. It is here, in Western efforts to build an open, institu-
tionalized order, that the gap between international ambition and domestic
politics is greatest. If Western leaders hope to rebuild domestic support for
international engagement, this is where they must concentrate their efforts,
and their governments’ resources.
In the rest of this introductory chapter, we sketch out the theoretical
framework, research design, and methods we use to track Western democ-
racies’ foreign policies, and domestic support for them, over the past
seventy-five years. We begin by developing a typology that distinguishes
between four basic foreign policy strategies: globalism, liberal internation-
alism, isolationism, and nationalism. We then provide an overview of our
argument about how Western governments’ foreign policies changed in the
1990s, and why they overran their domestic foundations. We turn next to
how we develop and test our argument empirically, and describe how our
argument differs from other explanations for the rise of anti-globalism and
the causes of Western overreach. Finally, we summarize the book’s three
empirical chapters, along with the book’s concluding chapter on possible
strategies for bringing international ends and domestic means back into bal-
ance. Our principal aim in this book is to explain the widening gap between
Western governments and their publics over foreign policy. Yet our analysis
of Western foreign policy does point to a number of “dos” and “don’ts” for
those hoping to bridge the gap and make the liberal order more solvent.
6 Geopolitics and Democracy
VARIETIES OF STATECRAFT
In making these and related arguments about the Western liberal system’s evolu-
tion since World War II, we model Western statecraft along two separate foreign
policy dimensions that we call “power” and “partnership.” These are depicted in
Figure 1.1. By power, we mean military power, one of statecraft’s oldest tools and
a key indicator of a foreign policy strategy’s ambition and cost. International re-
lations scholars and defense analysts measure military power in different ways,
though most agree that the percentage of GDP a country invests in building up
and maintaining its military power is a good barometer of how much weight or
value its leaders and citizens attach to military might and defense preparedness
as part of their nation’s overall foreign policy strategy.10 Nations that are located
on the right end of the horizontal axis strongly favor investing in building up
national militaries and national defense capabilities and maintaining military
preparedness. Those located at the opposite end of the horizontal axis strongly
oppose investing a large share of gross domestic product.
The Solvency Gap 7
More international
partnership
More
military
power
Where states lie on this continuum thus tells us something about the rel-
ative weight they attach to military strength, balance of power, and power
projection in foreign policy. There is an extensive literature by international
relations scholars on how, why, and when states come to occupy different
points or positions on this power continuum. Motivations can vary from
protecting national sovereignty, to checking the expansionist ambitions of
other states in the international system, to establishing spheres of influence.
Where states land on this continuum also depends on pressures within states,
from economic interests (e.g., industrialists, merchants) seeking private gain
from militarism and war-making, to peace movements that seek to reduce
the impetus toward war through disarmament, collective security, or inter-
national federation.11
The position of each state on the power continuum also offers a rough
sense of their international and domestic spending priorities.12 This is be-
cause states’ resources are limited. As the American strategist Bernard Brodie
famously put it, “Strategy wears a dollar sign.”13 Political leaders must decide
how much military power is enough to meet their foreign policy objectives,
and whether to favor foreign policy strategies that make fewer demands on
the government’s resources and national wealth.14 Political leaders must also
consider whether and how those decisions might affect what they hope to
8 Geopolitics and Democracy
More international
partnership
Support for economic integration
and institutionalized cooperation
Globalism
Liberal inter-
nationalism
More
military
power
Nationalism
Isolationism
an exhaustive list of foreign policy approaches that fit into these quadrants,
and the relative weight that different governments, parties, or voters attach
to each of these dimensions—power and partnership—can also vary within
quadrants.29 We describe each of these four foreign policy approaches, be-
ginning with globalism in quadrant 1.
Globalism
Globalism favors partnership over power. Globalists consider national sov-
ereignty to be the root cause of international instability and war, and look
to economic integration and institutionalized cooperation as remedies.30
While viewing a common defense and foreign policy as indispensable for
settling disputes and guaranteeing collective external security, they see
political and economic union as essential prerequisites to overcoming the
frictions caused by self-interested sovereign states. In the 1940s, this diag-
nosis of sovereignty’s pernicious effects was shared by leading American,
British, and European public intellectuals of varying political persuasions.
They argued that international federation, of one form or another, offered
the most promising path to removing the barriers of national economies,
improving economic and social well-being, and reducing the risk of inter-
national conflict among self-interested sovereign states.31 Today’s suprana-
tional European Union, which pools sovereignty and guarantees the free
movement of goods, capital, services, and people across borders, arguably
stands as the fullest expression of this midcentury globalist vision, albeit on
a regional scale.32
Globalists give pride of place to economic integration and institutional-
ized cooperation, but they are not opposed to investing in or using military
power under all conditions.33 In general, though, globalists favor investing
relatively few resources in peacetime militaries and, importantly, see military
power as a means for collective self-defense and enforcing international laws
rather than as a tool for maintaining international order through balance of
power. This view of when, how, and to what end military power should be
used in international affairs is not wholly different from Woodrow Wilson’s
vision of a “community of power.” For Wilson and other supporters of the
League of Nations, the purpose was not only to guarantee peace through the
threat of collective action against aggressors, but also importantly, to grad-
ually transcend traditional raison d’état and balance of power politics by
transforming “how states and peoples thought about rights and obligations
and the imperatives to uphold them.”34
12 Geopolitics and Democracy
Liberal internationalism
If globalists favor partnership over power, liberal internationalists (quadrant
2) see both as essential and complementary.35 Liberal internationalists also
see international openness, institutionalized cooperation, and multilater-
alism as means to foster a more peaceful and prosperous world. However,
they worry more about the sovereignty costs of institutionalized cooperation
than do globalists. They also think that international order and peace de-
pend on balance of power politics and the willingness to use military power
to uphold it. In a world of sovereign states, liberal internationalists do not
think the Hobbesian problem of anarchy can be solved through interna-
tional institutions and laws, but they think those challenges can be managed
and lessened if partnership is buttressed by a heavy investment in military
power. This very intuition lies at the core of the liberal international order
that Western democracies built after World War II, and in the thinking of its
chief architect, Franklin Delano Roosevelt.36
Liberal internationalism and globalism are often conflated. It is easy to
see why. Like globalism, liberal internationalism entails a commitment to
economic integration and institutionalized cooperation. Yet the liberal in-
ternationalism championed by Roosevelt and his successors in the United
States and elsewhere differs from globalism in two important ways. First,
unlike globalists, who view international federation as a substitute and
remedy for domestic interventionism, liberal internationalists see govern-
ment intervention as a means to correct for international market failures
and to respond to domestic demands for social justice. In schematic terms,
liberal internationalists are thus located lower on the vertical axis in Figure
1.2 than are globalists, even if both liberal internationalists and globalists
are more favorably disposed to international openness and multilateralism
than isolationists and nationalists (see below). Second, unlike globalists who
look to international law and institutions to restrain the dogs of war, liberal
internationalists also rely on power politics to guarantee security, even as
they try to devise institutional arrangements to manage great power rival-
ries, armament races, and destabilizing technologies. Where globalists focus
on the promise of a world free of balance of power, spheres of influence, and
militarism, liberal internationalists see wisdom in realist adages of “peace
through strength” and “weakness invites aggression.”
Isolationism
In contrast to globalism and liberal internationalism, isolationism (quadrant
3) attaches comparatively little weight to international institutions, preferring
The Solvency Gap 13
Nationalism
Nationalists (quadrant 4) share isolationists’ strong aversion to trade liber-
alization, international institutions, and multilateral governance. At best,
they see international institutions as a temporary expedient to leverage
power advantages or export their nation’s socioeconomic model; at worst,
they consider institutionalized cooperation, especially security coopera-
tion, to be a source of moral hazard and strategic entrapment. However,
14 Geopolitics and Democracy
For roughly half a century after World War II, liberal internationalism was the
West’s lodestar. A strategy of international order-building that was at once lib-
eral and realist, postwar liberal internationalism relied on international part-
nership and military power. Forged in the shadow of the Cold War, the West’s
liberal internationalist strategy was organized around two great regional
axes, with the United States at the center. One was an Atlantic axis binding
North America and Western Europe; the other, a Pacific axis tying Japan and
other non-communist Asian nations to the United States. Together, they de-
fined the geographic core of the Western system and the dense networks of
military, economic, and diplomatic ties that made the whole greater than
the sum of its parts. Sometimes described as Pax Americana, the Western
system was dominated by the United States. However, it was not a distinc-
tively American system, or unilaterally imposed by Washington. European
and Asian democracies also saw benefits in foreign policies that offered pro-
tection from Soviet geopolitical ambitions and delivered high rates of eco-
nomic growth.
To be sure, the Western system fell short of the universal liberal world order
that Franklin Delano Roosevelt and other Western leaders envisioned as
World War II was coming to a close. Even within the West, the level of support
for liberal internationalism varied, as did the precise mix of power and part-
nership that member states favored. And economic nationalists in the emer-
ging postwar “Third World” were often penalized or undercut. Nevertheless,
the system achieved a level of international openness, economic interde-
pendence, and political integration that exceeded what postwar planners
thought possible, and that set the West apart from the rest—something the
empirical analysis in Chapter 2 lays bare. Trade, foreign investment, and
monetary cooperation grew rapidly along the system’s Atlantic and Pacific
axes. Western democracies’ commitment to the common defense deepened.
So, too, did the West’s commitment to party democracy. In sharp contrast to
16 Geopolitics and Democracy
the interwar years, when ideological extremism ruled in much of Europe and
Asia, the postwar era was one of domestic consensus and coalition-building
across party lines. Socialists and conservatives, Christian Democrats, and
secular liberals found common ground in liberal internationalism.
During the Cold War, the Western liberal international order benefited
from what political scientist Robert Dahl called a “surplus of consensus.”44
Mainstream parties dominated the electoral landscape and controlled the
machinery of national government. Their dominance did not guarantee do-
mestic consensus over foreign policy across the board. Public support for
partnership often sagged during economic downturns. When fears of nu-
clear Armageddon dwarfed concerns about Soviet ambition, public support
for military spending softened too. Yet for most of the Cold War, Western
governments’ foreign policies enjoyed broad and consistent domestic sup-
port. At the same time, Western governments’ commitment to liberal inter-
nationalism provided grounds for consensus within Western democracies.
Western leaders could advance liberal internationalist policies, confident
that those policies would garner the support of a broad cross section of po-
litical parties representing the majority of voters in their countries. What
was good for liberal internationalism was good for mainstream parties, and
vice versa.
This virtuous cycle between foreign policy and party democracy in
Western democracies did not last. The first cracks in liberal internationalism’s
domestic foundations appeared in the 1970s, but it was not until the Cold War
ended that the virtuous cycle between foreign policy and party democracy
broke down. In the 1990s, Western governments shifted from a strategy of
liberal internationalism that combined power with partnership to a strategy
of globalism that relied increasingly on partnership, and a particular market-
oriented variant thereof. Military spending declined. International markets
and institutionalized cooperation expanded. Trade and investment boomed.
New international bodies were formed and older ones were enlarged, many
promoting the expansion of global markets. Countries that once languished
on the edges of the liberal world order, or that the Cold War had effectively
locked out, were suddenly in play as destinations for Western investment. In
the 1990s, the Western system was globalized.
Domestic support did not keep stride, however. We show that, even be-
fore the 1990s were out, popular support for liberalized trade, institution-
alized cooperation, and multilateral governance was declining in Western
democracies. The erosion of domestic support was starkest in the European
The Solvency Gap 17
How did Western foreign policy ends become so disconnected from do-
mestic political means? What explains this widening gap between Western
18 Geopolitics and Democracy
governments and their publics? In the chapters that follow, we argue that
popular support for the Western-led liberal order was contingent on a
particular configuration of geopolitical pressures and domestic bargains.
Geopolitically, the Soviet challenge was a defining reality for Western leaders
and voters. For over half a century, worries about communist expansion
on the Eurasian landmass and the associated danger of nuclear war pushed
Western leaders toward liberal internationalist foreign policies. Soviet power
and the nuclear arms race made most Western voters skeptical of foreign pol-
icies that were too trusting or too belligerent. For the “median voter,” a liberal
internationalist strategy that balanced liberalism with realism was far prefer-
able to globalism, nationalism, or isolationism, especially if waging Cold War
did not require sacrificing butter for guns.
Cold War constraints gave Western leaders and voters strong incentives
to support liberal internationalism. So did the practical realities of domestic
coalition-building in what Peter Mair calls the “age of party democracy.”46
For most of the second half of the twentieth century, political parties had to
build cross-class coalitions to win power. This led Western leaders to pursue
mixed-economy growth strategies at home, combining state intervention
and free-market policies. In foreign policy, this meant striking a balance
between international openness and social protection, and between insti-
tutionalized cooperation and national sovereignty. International openness
and multilateral institutions were needed to promote and sustain growth;
national autonomy and social protection were needed to correct for interna-
tional market forces and ensure working-class voters’ support. This was the
compromise of embedded liberalism that balanced international openness
with domestic policy objectives—full employment, economic equity, unem-
ployment insurance, and social welfare, at least for labor market insiders.
For thirty remarkable years—les trente glorieuses—Western democra-
cies’ commitment to the liberal world order deepened. It was not until the
1970s and 1980s that the first cracks in liberal internationalism’s domestic
foundation appeared. This is when Western leaders, led by Ronald Reagan
and Margaret Thatcher, began “liberalizing” the Western system by shifting
the balance between international openness and social protection in favor
of markets. The West’s turn toward neoliberalism set in motion forces that
would ultimately come back to haunt mainstream parties by weakening
public support for the liberal order and opening the door to political parties
advancing anti-globalist platforms. However, it was not until the Cold War
ended, and Western governments fully embraced an agenda of international
The Solvency Gap 19
market expansion and welfare state “reform,” that a clear gap emerged be-
tween political leaders and their domestic publics.
In the 1990s, globalization became the West’s new elixir. Those who argued
that too much economic integration would trigger a political backlash were
dismissed as Cassandras. At the height of Western triumphalism over “win-
ning” the Cold War, political leaders doubled down on international partner-
ship, driving economic integration and international rule to new heights. The
new supranational European Union and World Trade Organization pooled
sovereignty far more extensively than their forerunners—the European
Community and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT).
With the lifting of the Iron Curtain, West European industries moved pro-
duction to low-cost East European countries and, soon, opened their doors
to workers from Eastern Europe. American and Western investment in
China accelerated. At the same time, Western leaders, including center-left
politicians like Bill Clinton, Tony Blair, and Gerhard Schröder, continued
to liberalize domestic economies and loosen social protections. In the early
2000s, Japan’s Koizumi Junichiro followed suit.
For Western leaders, globalization’s promise of greater national wealth
and security served as a substitute for Cold War imperatives—a new way to
sustain the Western system in the absence of a common threat. However,
domestic support for foreign policies to promote greater international open-
ness and multilateral cooperation had never depended on geopolitics alone.
This support also rested on social guarantees to Western workers, especially
those who formed much of the backbone of the mainstream parties. And
therein lay the problem. After a decade of market liberalization and priva-
tization at home, Western leaders had less and less domestic political room
to maneuver in foreign policy. Public opinion was shifting against the new
orthodoxy. We show that, by expanding the global liberal order through the
European Union, the WTO, and other global initiatives in the 1990s, but
doing so without also expanding social protection at home, Western leaders
set in motion the anti-global political dynamics we see today. While for-
eign policies that resulted in greater access to low-wage markets in Asia and
Eastern Europe appealed to many middle-class voters who benefited from
cheaper goods and low-cost immigrant labor, those same policies fueled
working-class discontent and anti-globalist politics.
In the chapters that follow, we document how the end of the Cold War and
the growing reliance on globalism combined to make liberal international
order-building less attractive to Western electorates. While the electoral
20 Geopolitics and Democracy
strategizing of parties on the far left is part of the story, we show that it is the
parties on the radical right that have been particularly adept at converting
anti-globalist policies and platforms into electoral support. Once champions
of traditional values and laissez-faire economic orthodoxy, far-right parties
adopted nationalist and nativist foreign policies while moving their do-
mestic economic policy agendas to the left. This made radical-right parties
more appealing to the swelling ranks of disaffected working-class voters. It
also put mainstream parties on the center-right on the political defensive.
Western governments’ failure to uphold the postwar social bargains they had
struck with their citizens does not fully explain the hollowing out of the lib-
eral order’s domestic foundation, but we show that it has contributed signif-
icantly to the fragmentation of Western party systems and to the political
divisions over the purposes of foreign policy that we see today.
Most international relations scholars and foreign policy analysts agree that
the liberal world order has fallen on hard times.56 Yet there is considerable
disagreement about how and why liberal internationalism lost its way, and
debate over what steps Western democracies should take to rebuild inter-
national and domestic support for the liberal order. Our analysis starts from
the assumption that there is much to be gained by viewing the current anti-
globalist backlash against a larger historical canvas—that is, by tracking the
ebb and flow of domestic support for liberal international order-building
across many Western democracies, different issue areas, and over many
decades. Adopting such a comparative, historical approach reveals many
things about the liberal international order’s trajectory, but perhaps the most
essential is that the anti-globalist backlash we see across the West today has
deep roots. As we show, anti-globalist domestic pressures have been steadily
The Solvency Gap 23
building in Western democracies, large and small, old and new, for over three
decades.
Establishing when the West’s retreat from liberal internationalism began is
important for several reasons. For one thing, it helps us understand why early,
highly influential prognostications about the post–Cold War world were so
far off the mark. In the 1990s, Western commentators were proclaiming the
“end of history” and the arrival of the “unipolar moment.”57 The end of the
Cold War, they argued, represented the permanent victory of liberal democ-
racy and capitalism over the forces of illiberalism and nationalism. America’s
unparalleled power put it in a position to ensure liberal democracy’s triumph
by consolidating, protecting, and extending the liberal international order.
As we show, these arguments sorely underestimated the risks of Western
overreach because they rested on mistaken assumptions about the sources
of popular support for liberal internationalism during the Cold War. They
assumed that Western leaders’ success in winning cross-partisan support for
their foreign policy was due to voters’ commitment to liberalizing the world
order, and thus that it would continue after the Cold War. In fact, Western
leaders’ success was contingent on geopolitical imperatives and social guar-
antees that would soon disappear and weaken.
If many observers underestimated the risk that Western ambition would
outstrip its domestic supports, others have misread how ends and means
became so misaligned in the ensuing years. The most popular explanation
for Western overreach attributes it to political leaders’ overreliance on mil-
itary power and democracy promotion in the Middle East and elsewhere.58
That the West’s misguided pursuit of overly expansive liberal goals like de-
mocracy promotion in the Middle East contributed to voter disillusionment
seems clear. Yet, as we show in Geopolitics and Democracy, domestic disen-
chantment with the liberal order set in well before Western efforts to spread
democracy to the Middle East, the former republics of the Soviet Union,
and elsewhere. The evidence in this book makes clear that it was Western
governments’ unbridled pursuit of trade liberalization, institutionalized co-
operation, and multilateral governance after the Cold War, rather than their
failed military ventures (e.g., the Iraq War) or their strategic gambits (e.g., the
effort to expand democracy to Ukraine on Russia’s doorstep), that put these
governments at odds with their publics over foreign policy.
Explanations that attribute the anti-globalist backlash to globalization
itself are closer to the mark. Many cross-national and country-specific
studies indicate that anti-globalist parties have gained national vote share by
24 Geopolitics and Democracy
In the chapters that follow, we explore how and why Western democra-
cies overreached, and what their political leaders can do to set things right.
We begin in Chapter 2 by focusing on the widening gap between Western
governments and their voting publics over foreign policy. Using the two-
dimensional model described above, we show that, starting in the 1990s,
Western governments began turning away from the Cold War strategy com-
bining partnership and power (liberal internationalism) to one that relied
increasingly on partnership as opposed to power (globalism). We show that
The Solvency Gap 25
this was true of Western democracies in general, but it was also true of the
West’s preeminent power: the United States. America’s commitment to inter-
national partnership also increased, albeit less conspicuously and less fully
than did Europe’s, Japan’s, and other OECD nations. The West’s commit-
ment to globalism also deepened in the 2000s, through the war on terrorism
and the 2008 financial crisis. Western voters did not keep pace with their
governments, however. We show that, as Western governments shifted from
liberal internationalism to globalism, their foreign policies grew increasingly
out of step with what their electorates were willing to support. Anti-globalist
sentiment spread.
Chapter 3 picks up where Chapter 2 leaves off by focusing on the sources
of Western overreach and the anti-globalist backlash. We argue that Western
governments’ turn toward globalism led to a domestic backlash because it
was shorn of many of the social guarantees and protections that liberal inter-
nationalism originally entailed and that Cold War strategic exigencies rein-
forced. We show how sensitive Western domestic support for international
partnership and military power is to the level of international threat facing
Western democracies and to their governments’ commitment to economic
security for their citizens. In the absence of a “clear and present danger” to
Western interests and softening government support for social protection,
efforts to expand international markets and supernationalism were all but
guaranteed to provoke a backlash. We conclude this chapter by considering
why, in the face of these anti-globalist pressures, Western leaders did not
alter course, by trimming their internationalist sails or providing greater so-
cial compensation.
Chapter 4 considers the consequences of the anti-globalist backlash for
Western democracies and the liberal order. We show that, while mainstream
party support for liberal internationalism has not collapsed, it has weakened
in the face of declining voter support for trade liberalization and multilateral
institutions. It has also contributed to the process of political fragmentation
that has been unfolding in Western democracies for the past three decades.
In contrast to the Cold War, when liberal internationalism strengthened the
mainstream parties’ hold on national electorates, Western governments’ turn
toward globalism cost parties on the center-left and the center-right at the
polls. We show that, since the 1990s, the more mainstream parties promoted
economic integration and multilateral governance the more fragmented
Western party systems became. Parties running on anti-globalist platforms,
especially on the far right, steadily increased their share of the national vote
26 Geopolitics and Democracy
Writing two decades ago, Robert Kagan famously challenged the idea that
the countries of the West still shared a common approach to international
order-building. “On major strategic and international questions today,”
Kagan wrote about the post–Cold War world, “Americans are from Mars and
Europeans are from Venus: They agree on little and understand one another
less and less. . . . When it comes to setting national priorities, determining
threats, defining challenges, and fashioning and implementing foreign and
defense policies, the United States and Europe have parted ways.”1 Since the
Cold War, Americans, Kagan argued, had been more apt to rely on power
and coercion to promote international order and stability. By contrast,
Europeans preferred diplomacy, negotiation, and partnership to manage in-
ternational conflict and strengthen the international order. Ever since, inter-
national relations scholars and foreign policy analysts have debated how best
to characterize these differences over foreign policy—as a clash of ideas, or
interests, or, as Kagan suggested, values.2 But they did not contest the core as-
sertion itself. The idea that Western democracies’ foreign policy differences
were more significant than their similarities became an article of faith in aca-
demic and policy circles.
In this chapter, we show that Western democracies’ approaches to for-
eign policy today are far more similar than such accounts assume. Indeed,
one reason that so many Western democracies today are experiencing anti-
globalist backlashes is that their governments made essentially the same for-
eign policy bet a quarter of a century ago. In the 1990s, Western governments
turned from the Cold War strategy of liberal internationalism that had bal-
anced international openness and social protection to a strategy of globalism
that put greater emphasis on market-driven economic integration and in-
stitutionalized cooperation. This shift in strategy proved costly for Western
governments: as we show, it set in motion political forces that have weak-
ened the liberal order’s domestic supports. In this chapter, we take the first
step in explaining how and why Western domestic support for the liberal
order has declined by tracking Western government and voter support for
Geopolitics and Democracy. Peter Trubowitz and Brian Burgoon, Oxford University Press.
© Oxford University Press 2023. DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780197535400.003.0002
28 Geopolitics and Democracy
For roughly half a century after World War II, the West embraced a strategy of
liberal internationalism. After a decade of global depression and war, Western
democracies converged on a strategy that relied on international partner-
ship and military power to guarantee security and prosperity. The resulting
Western-led liberal order fell far short of the “one world” liberal internation-
alist vision that Franklin Delano Roosevelt and others were advancing as
World War II came to a close.3 Global institutions like the United Nations
(1945) and Bretton Woods (1944) championed by Roosevelt remained, but
the exigencies of the Cold War led Western leaders to adopt a system that
was less universal in ambition. Regional initiatives and programs such as
the Marshall Plan (1947), the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (1949),
and the European Economic Community (1957), backed up by a substan-
tial American military presence and nuclear security guarantees, assumed a
much larger role in promoting economic recovery and guaranteeing security
than postwar planners had originally envisioned.
The United States was the dominant power in the Western liberal order, but
it was not a solely American system. European and Japanese leaders saw
30 Geopolitics and Democracy
200
KOF index of globalization policies
Globalism Liberal internationalism
FRG
NLD
BEL SWE
LUX CHE DNK
150
FRA
ITA NOR GBR
FIN
AUT ESP USA
CAN GRC
100 IRL AUS PRT Sample
JPN NZL median
KOR
50
Sample
median
Isolationism Nationalism
0
In the 1970s, the Western liberal order’s capitalist foundations were shaken.
Growth in the advanced Western democracies suddenly slowed, dropping
in the 1970s to half its postwar rate.27 Unemployment doubled, and then
34 Geopolitics and Democracy
tripled. Inflation surged. The price of oil fueling Western economies soared
from three to thirty dollars a barrel as a result of crises in the Middle East.
Currencies fluctuated wildly, following the collapse of the Bretton Woods re-
gime and the end of capital controls. Political consensus in Western democ-
racies over the proper mix of internationalism and nationalism buckled
under the weight of mounting, conflicting demands for fiscal solvency, social
redress, and global financial liberalization. Surveying the political landscape,
one highly influential analysis of the period concluded that Western democ-
racies were suffering from a “governability crisis.”28 Western governments,
it argued, were struggling to cope with the escalating demands for public
goods and services being placed on them. Something had to give.
For many, the deepening crisis in the West evoked disquieting comparisons
to the onset of the Great Depression and the sudden breakdown of that era’s
international order. The causes of the laissez-faire international order’s col-
lapse in the interwar years were different, of course. The interwar interna-
tional system had put too much faith in markets and business.29 The question
now was whether the reverse was true—whether Western democracies had
come to rely too heavily on the state as a provider of goods and services for the
public. Many political elites, business leaders, and academic scholars thought
so.30 They argued that Western governments’ commitment to full employ-
ment and social protection had “overloaded” Western governments and sty-
mied the full development of global markets. Labor unions, workers, and
their elected representatives strongly disagreed. They urged Western officials
to maintain distributive and redistributive policies and strengthen national
control and regulation of their economies. At the time, the implications of
all this for Western democracies’ foreign policies were not immediately clear.
One reason is that the crisis of the Western economic order coincided and
intersected with unanticipated developments in the geopolitical realm.
In the late 1960s, cracks opened up on both sides of the Cold War di-
vide. In the East, a growing rift between Moscow and Beijing led to military
encounters in 1969 along the border separating the two communist powers.
Compounding matters, Eastern Europe had grown increasingly restive
under Soviet control. In 1968, the Soviet economic and political model was
challenged in Czechoslovakia. Moscow crushed the Czechs’ experiment in
A Widening Gyre 35
200
Globalism
150
AUT ESP USA
CAN PRT
IRL AUS GRC
JPN NZL
100 Sample
median
KOR
50
Sample
median
Isolationism Nationalism
0
AGE OF GLOBALISM
The surge in globalism that started in the 1990s is often equated with the
rapid global expansion of economic activity of the late nineteenth and early
twentieth centuries. There are similarities, to be sure. However, the globalism
of the 1990s and 2000s owed far more to Western governments’ efforts to
actively promote the cross-border flow of goods, capital, and services and to
shield that activity from vicissitudes of domestic politics by encasing them
in supranational institutions.41 During the 1990s, Washington, Paris, Berlin,
and other Western capitals launched new institutional projects to deepen
their economic ties as well as their reliance on international institutions.
In Europe, the Maastricht treaty of 1993 formally established the European
Union, including a new European Central Bank and a new common cur-
rency, the euro.42 In North America, the Canada-US Free Trade Agreement
was expanded to include Mexico, resulting in the 1994 North American
Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). In Asia, APEC expanded its goals, calling
for free and open trade in the Asia-Pacific by 2010 for the region’s more ad-
vanced economies and 2020 for its developing economies.
As the Western-led liberal order became more integrated internally, it also
expanded outwardly into new markets. In the 1990s, countries that were on
the periphery of the liberal order, by Western fiat or by choice, were sud-
denly in play as destinations for Western investment. Already, many coun-
tries in Asia, Latin America, and Africa had started reducing government
involvement in their domestic markets and opening up their economies to
cross-border flows of capital as well as expanded trade.43 In the 1990s, the
former Warsaw Pact countries and Soviet republics of Central and Eastern
Europe followed suit. This gave them access to Western markets and capital.
However, in most cases access came at a price: a commitment to the very
A Widening Gyre 39
$170 billion, while United States, Japanese, and other foreign investors
poured billions into China each year.50 However, it was not until the late
1990s that Washington led a concerted effort to institutionalize China’s inte-
gration into the world economy by normalizing trade relations with Beijing,
paving the way for China’s entry into the WTO. The idea was to encourage
China to become a “strategic partner,” as the Clinton administration put it.51
The United States, and the West more generally, would benefit from China’s
integration into the rapidly globalizing world economy. China would benefit
too, the thinking went. As its people began to reap the rewards of trade and
economic growth, onlookers believed that there would be domestic pressure
for social liberalization and bottom-up political change.52
In the 1990s, Western leaders also began reshaping and updating the
Western liberal order’s security architecture in Europe and Asia.53 In Europe,
this involved the unification of Germany and the integration of the former
Warsaw Pact states and Soviet Baltic republics into NATO, along with their
incorporation into the European Union. Poland, Hungary, and the Czech
Republic joined the sixteen-member military and political alliance in 1999.
Three years later, at NATO’s Prague Summit, Bulgaria, Estonia, Latvia,
Lithuania, Romania, Slovakia, and Slovenia were invited to join the security
pact. In Asia, Washington and Tokyo reaffirmed their alliance commitments.
Worries about Beijing’s ambitions in East Asia following the 1996 Taiwan
Strait missile crisis and North Korea’s ballistic missile tests over Japan led
Washington to commit to keeping 100,000 troops in East Asia. Tokyo sig-
naled greater resolve, too, by broadening the role of its Self Defense Forces
(SDF) from its traditional mission of territorial defense to regional and
global multilateral operations and peacekeeping.54
As Western democracies’ conception of security broadened, so did the
range of missions they were prepared to support.55 Democratic enlargement,
democracy promotion, humanitarian intervention, and the Responsibility to
Protect increasingly vied with more traditional conceptions of national in-
terest and international security such as balance of power, collective security,
and extended deterrence. Western governments worked to strengthen inter-
national laws to hold governments and their leaders more accountable for
how they treated their populations, and began funding nongovernmental or-
ganizations with the hope of building civil society within states transitioning
to democracy.56 In the wake of the international community’s failure to re-
spond to the Rwandan genocide and Srebrenica massacre in Bosnia, Western
governments also displayed a greater willingness to use coercion and force
A Widening Gyre 41
to achieve these goals. This was perhaps clearest in the case of the Balkans in
1999, when NATO pressured Yugoslav President Slobodan Milosevic to ac-
cept Kosovo’s de facto independence.
On security as well as economic issues, the West relied increasingly on insti-
tutionalized cooperation. The West also continued to invest in military power.
However, in the absence of a Cold War–style geopolitical rival, large outlays
for defense were harder for governments to justify and sell to publics after a
half-century of vigilance and, for many families, sacrifice.57 Talk of a “peace
dividend” was rife. In the 1990s, military expenditures as percentage of GDP
fell in every NATO nation, including the United States.58 In the wake of the
September 11 attacks and with the onset of the war in Afghanistan, the United
States, the United Kingdom, and France increased the share of GDP they
invested in defense, but they were the exceptions. As Figure 2.3 makes clear, be-
tween 1992 and 2017, the center of gravity in the West shifted from liberal in-
ternationalism toward globalism. Every Western democracy moved left along
the horizontal axis (power) and, notably, upward on the vertical axis (partner-
ship).59 The West was not alone. Now the vast majority of non-Western coun-
tries also clustered above the horizontal axis, signifying increased support for
trade liberalization, institutionalized cooperation, and multilateral govern-
ance. In the age of globalism, the West and the rest were converging.
The ensuing years were not trouble-free years for the West, of course. The
US-led war in Iraq in 2003 triggered the most significant rift in transatlantic
relations since the Vietnam War. The debate over the war exposed European
reservations about American power and the George W. Bush administration’s
willingness to flout liberal norms of sovereignty, multilateralism, and inter-
national law to overturn Saddam Hussein’s Iraqi regime. Many Americans
were put off by Europe’s hand-wringing and second-guessing. It fueled
suspicions that European capitals were no longer reliable allies or willing to
make the tough choices thought to be necessary to keep citizens safe in the
post-9/11 world. Speculation about the “end of the West” was widespread.60
However, as Figure 2.3 makes clear, the war did not drive the West apart.
The political storms over the Atlantic soon calmed. Western governments,
most under new leadership, moved on. Despite their differences over Iraq,
the United States and Europe remained committed to globalism.
42 Geopolitics and Democracy
200
Globalism AUT DEU GBR
150
JPN KOR
BIH
Sample
100
median
50
Sample
median
Isolationism Nationalism
0
In the 2000s, the event that arguably posed the greatest test of Western sol-
idarity and the liberal order’s durability was the 2008 global financial crisis.
The scale and timing of the crisis, and the recession that followed, varied
from country to country, but the crisis sent shockwaves across the OECD
and beyond. Indeed, none of the 104 countries tracked by the WTO were
spared its effects.61 As the crisis cascaded across the globe, international
trade plummeted. Unemployment spiked. International banks and financial
institutions’ asset values dropped sharply. In desperation, banks turned to
their home countries’ governments to be bailed out. By April 2009, the IMF
concluded that the recession was the deepest economic downturn on record
since the Great Depression.62 After years of being told that markets free of
domestic regulations are more efficient, national taxpayers, particularly in
the United States, were now being asked to intervene to stabilize their econ-
omies, rescue the banks, and put an end to a crisis that sprang from their
governments’ increased reliance on market liberalization.
Much has been written about the effect of the 2008 economic crisis on
Western support for international openness and global governance. On the
surface, this key dimension of the liberal order appeared to be under threat
during the first year of the crisis. Western and other governments initially
responded by imposing “micro-protectionist” measures (e.g., local content
requirements, export taxes and quotas, public procurement discrimination
A Widening Gyre 43
against foreign firms), often skirting the letter of WTO rules.63 Even so, the
beggar-thy-neighbor downward spiral in international trade many feared
did not materialize. After the immediate shock, the surge in protectionism
receded and cross-border capital flows rebounded, even if they remained
below the 2007 highs for some time.64 The initial drop in industrial output
was steep, of course. Yet here, too, the rebound exceeded what many analysts
had predicted in the early stages of the financial crisis.65 Within four years of
the recession’s onset, global industrial output was 10 percent higher than be-
fore its start, partly because capital flows did not dry up.66
In the aftermath of the 2008 crisis, global trade, investment, and output
resumed sooner and more forcefully than they had in the wake of the Great
Depression of 1929. As a number of scholars have pointed out, one impor-
tant reason for this is that the existing international institutional architecture
proved to be more robust than one might have expected, given the severity of
the crisis.67 Existing global institutions such as the IMF and World Bank were
arguably strengthened, not weakened. As the crisis deepened, the Group of
20 (G20) was transformed into a major forum for policy deliberation and
coordination between the advanced industrialized countries of the West and
the developing economies of the Global South.68 In the area of international
trade, the WTO was able to prevent or at least limit many forms of trade
policy backsliding.69 In short, the supranational architecture that Western
democracies had invested in so heavily over the preceding decades helped
them weather 2008’s strong economic headwinds.
If globalism promoted the diffusion of the financial crisis, it also gave
Western governments strong incentives to stick with the system rather than
decouple from it.70 It also arguably brought Western governments closer to-
gether. Evidence for this can be seen in Figures 2.4 and 2.5. Figure 2.4 tracks
government support in the EU-15, Japan, and the United States for partner-
ship and power from 1970 through 2018.71 We see that, over the entire time
period, there is very little distance between the EU-15 and the United States
over international partnership (vertical dimension) and that, as EU support
for international openness and cooperation increases, so does US support.
By contrast, the distance between the EU-15 and the United States on the
horizontal dimension (military power) narrows over time. Overall, though,
the EU and the United States follow the same general pattern. In the 1990s,
Western governments move away from liberal internationalism toward
globalism, and this process continues through the 2000s and into the 2010s.
While the United States never fully embraces globalism, it does follow a path
44 Geopolitics and Democracy
180
2018
160
2010 2008 1982
2004 2006 1980 1990 United States
1978
2002 200019901974 1976
140 1986
Japan 1998 1972
1996 1970 1988
1994 1992 1978 1976 1984
1986 1984 EU-15 1980
1990 1982 1982
1974
120
Sample
median
2016 2002 1998
1976
100
that is strikingly similar to the EU’s. Indeed, if there is an outlier in Figure 2.4,
it is Japan.
Japan’s path toward globalism is clearly different from America’s and
Europe’s. Not surprisingly, Japanese investment in power is low by Western
standards. Japanese defense spending averaged 0.94 percent of GDP during
the 1990s through 2000s. This is not significantly different from Japan’s de-
fense burden during the 1970s and 1980s, when it averaged 0.90 percent of
GDP.72 Yet like the EU-15 and the United States, Japan’s investment in in-
ternational partnership increased over time, and substantially so during the
1990s and especially, 2000s. This was a very active period of Japanese di-
plomacy. In the 2000s, Japan signed free trade agreements with Singapore
(2002) and Mexico (2004). Similar trade negotiations were launched with the
Philippines, Thailand, and Malaysia, among other countries in the region.73
Tokyo also expanded its level of participation in multilateral peacekeeping
and non-lethal international security missions.74 In short, as Japan invested
more heavily in international partnership, its foreign policy priorities more
closely aligned with America’s and Europe’s.
The convergence of the United States, EU, and Japan in Figure 2.4 raises
questions about the West, more generally. Did Western governments’ for-
eign policy preferences also become more similar over time? The short an-
swer is, yes. Figure 2.5 tracks Western government support for partnership
and power from 1970 through 2018.75 The dark-shaded areas in the figure
A Widening Gyre 45
Partnership
Power
6
Military spending (% GDP)
4
2
0
represent the bottom twenty-fifth and top seventy-fifth percentile of the in-
terquartile distribution. The median value for the twenty-four OECD coun-
tries in our sample is denoted by white horizontal lines in the shaded areas.
The “whiskers” in the plots represent the maximum and minimum value
among Western countries in any given year. We see Figure 2.5a that policy
differences among Western governments over trade liberalization and in-
stitutionalized cooperation have narrowed considerably over time. We see
a similar trend in the case of defense spending and military preparedness in
the bottom panel. Here, the relative defense burden shouldered by Western
governments narrows considerably between 1970 and 2000. It expands
46 Geopolitics and Democracy
slightly after 2001 due to the spike in US defense spending for the wars in
Afghanistan and Iraq, before narrowing again. In short, the post–Cold
War decades were a time of increasing policy convergence, not divergence,
among Western governments. The same could not be said about Western
governments and their publics, however.
GLOBALISM’S DISCONTENTS
In the aftermath of the 2008 economic crisis, it is not hard to see why
some Western political analysts concluded that “the system worked.” The
worst was avoided: the West and the rest did not plunge headfirst into an-
other Great Depression. The Great Recession did not lead to rapid “de-
globalization.” Yet if Western democracies were able to avoid the worst,
the notion that the system worked overlooks, or downplays, just how un-
popular globalism had become within Western democracies by 2008. Signs
that there was trouble ahead on the domestic front were evident as early as
the late 1990s. In the wake of the 1999 Seattle protests, Peter Sutherland,
the former head of the WTO, observed that the protests reflected “a fun-
damental deficit in effective political support for the WTO.”76 The deci-
sive battles were not on the streets, but at the ballot box. It was there that
Western voters began registering in ever-increasing numbers their opposi-
tion to their governments’ deepening commitment to market liberalization
and global governance.77
End of consensus
That few Western leaders saw it coming is not surprising. For decades
after World War II, Western voters had backed liberal internationalist pol-
icies, giving policymakers substantial “decision latitude” on foreign policy
matters.78 In most Western democracies, public support for international
partnership kept pace with government efforts to expand international
markets and promote multilateral cooperation. Scholars wrote of a “permis-
sive mood” or “permissive consensus,” where citizens deferred to political
elites on matters of economic integration and international governance.79
Public support for investing in military power was more variable and vol-
uble, due largely to worries about nuclear war (see below). Yet, for the most
A Widening Gyre 47
1996 US '76-'91
1996
2
2012
'50-'75 1994 2012 2000
EU15 Sample
2008 '76-'91 2014 median
1992
Japan EU-15 2014
1
2004
2012 1994 2000
Japan 1996 2006
1996 1998
2008 2010
0
Sample
median
Isolationism Nationalism
–.5
Figure 2.6 Voter support for international partnership and military power by
EU, Japan, and United States, 1950–2017
48 Geopolitics and Democracy
180
KOF index of globalization policies
30
Manifesto index of voter support
Government
support
160
20 25
140
15
Voter
support
120
10
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020
20
3
support
2.5
15
2
10
Government
support
1.5
Figure 2.7 Government and voter support for international partnership and
military power in Western democracies, 1970–2017
200
30
KOF index of globalization policies
180
25
160
20
Voter
140
15
support
120
10
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020
Voter
10
Military spending (% GDP)
2.5
2
5
1.5
Government
support
0
1
Government
support
100
160
80
140
60
Voter
support
120
40
Figure 2.8 Government and voter support for international partnership and
military power in the EU, Japan, and United States, 1970–2017
US support for power
150
8
7
support
100
6
5
50
4
Government
support
3
0
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020
40
160
Government
KOF index of globalization policies
30
140
20
120
Voter
support
100
10
80
Government
10
support
Manifesto index of voter support
Military spending (% GDP)
.95
0
.9
Voter
support
.85
−10
.8
−20
.75
after the September 11 attacks.87 Continuing voter support for pooling na-
tional sovereignty over defense as a means to keep guns-versus-butter trade-
offs in check was a factor for many in the EU.88 In Japan, mounting concerns
about China’s military buildup and North Korean hostility led to growing
support for amending constitutional prohibitions against militarization and
expanding the SDF’s role to include national security (as well as disaster re-
lief, humanitarian aid, and domestic security).89 Yet as we show in Chapter 4,
the resurgence of voter support for military power also reflects the growing
number and strength of anti-globalist, nationalist parties since the Cold
War. As these parties gained political strength, the gap between Western
governments and voters that took shape in the 1990s widened.
In the 1990s, few Western leaders spoke more eloquently about globalism’s
promise than President Bill Clinton. Speaking before the UN General
Assembly in September 1997, Clinton declared: “At the dawn of a new millen-
nium, we can envision a new era that escapes the twentieth century’s darkest
moments” and “fulfills its most brilliant possibilities.” “The forces of global
integration are a great tide inexorably wearing away the established order of
things.”90 Clinton’s optimism about globalism as a bridge to a twenty-first
century free of geopolitics and the narrow nationalisms of the past was easily
shared by many world leaders sitting in the audience that day, especially
those representing the advanced industrialized economies of the West. In the
absence of a shared security agenda after the fall of the Soviet Union, Western
elites found common purpose in a global agenda calling for the freer move-
ment of capital, goods, and services across national boundaries and greater
reliance on multilateral institutions and governance.
The West’s turn to globalism would prove a bridge too far. Clinton was
right about one thing, though: at the level of government policy, globalism
did function as a unifying force in the West. On the one hand, cooperation
between Western democracies on trade, security, and other matters con-
tinued, and as we have seen, rapidly expanded into new policy domains such
as the environment and human rights. On the other hand, Western public
support did not keep step with their leaders’ efforts to liberalize their econ-
omies, delegate more discretionary authority to supranational institutions,
and incorporate nations on the periphery of the world economy into their
54 Geopolitics and Democracy
countries’ manufacturing supply chains. As we will see, the fact that Western
leaders’ efforts to promote globalization usually went hand-in-hand with
commitments to reform and scale back the welfare state only compounded
matters by making it easier for anti-globalists on the left and right to appeal
to voters who worried they were being sold a bridge to nowhere.
It would take time before the gap between Western governments and
their publics would reach critical proportions, but as we have seen, anti-
globalist nationalist sentiment was spreading in the democracies even before
the decade of the 1990s was out. The moral of the story is not that domestic
politics matter now. As we show in Chapters 3 and 4, domestic politics have
shaped the political possibilities for liberal international order-building in
Western democracies since the very beginning of the postwar era. Forged
in an era of superpower rivalry, the postwar liberal order benefited from the
backing of Western leaders who saw electoral advantage in a foreign policy
strategy that combined partnership and power and that struck a delicate
balance between international openness and social protection. That voters
backed their governments’ foreign policies as long as they did was due in
no small part to the depth of Western political leaders’ commitment to bal-
ancing these conflicting demands and pressures in their national political
economies. In the 1990s, this too would change.
3
Roots of Insolvency
Geopolitics and Democracy. Peter Trubowitz and Brian Burgoon, Oxford University Press.
© Oxford University Press 2023. DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780197535400.003.0003
56 Geopolitics and Democracy
parties and voters. This is why political support in Western democracies for
the liberal international order ran so strong during the Cold War, and why it
has weakened considerably since.
In developing our explanation for the decline of Western support for the
liberal order, we focus considerable attention on the collapse of the Soviet
Union and its implications for the liberal order. Little has been written about
how this international development impacted the internal politics of the two
dozen Western democracies who were locked in Cold War with it for nearly
half a century. This is not surprising, given the triumphalism that has per-
meated the topic in Western commentary. However, as we show, the Cold
War strengthened national cohesion in Western democracies. It also contrib-
uted to the expansion of the welfare state. This matters because the social
protections that postwar Western leaders and mainstream parties guaran-
teed workers were essential to winning their votes. Social protection drew
voters into the liberal internationalist fold. Cold War imperatives helped
keep them there.
The chapter is organized into three sections. The first section focuses on
the relationship between economic openness and social protection. We show
that domestic support for liberal internationalism in Western democracies
depends in part on the level of social protection they guarantee their citizens.
The erosion of social protections in Western democracies since the 1990s
helps explain the widening gap between Western governments and voters
over foreign policy that we described in Chapter 2.2 In the second section,
we show that geopolitical imperatives reinforced Western governments and
mainstream parties’ commitment to liberal internationalism during the
Cold War. The corollary to this argument is that, in the absence of Cold War
pressures, Western domestic support for liberal internationalism weakened.
In the third section, we consider why Western governments and leaders did
not do more to close the resulting gap with their publics over foreign policy.
Was it simply a case of hubris and triumphalism, as some have charged, or
does it owe more to changes in the political economies of the advanced in-
dustrial nations?3 We consider several explanations.
POLANYI’S REVENGE
In the postwar era, Western leaders sought to strike precisely this balance
between market and state.5 Constructing a liberal international trade and fi-
nancial order would have to allow governments a substantial degree of social
protection in the domestic realm. International openness would have to be
harmonized with national autonomy. To be sure, a robust social safety net
would not guarantee international order and stability in an anarchical world
of states. However, it could cushion the market’s most disruptive effects while
allowing industrialists, farmers, and workers to reap the rewards of potential
export markets and cheaper imports. By taking the hard edge off capitalism,
the postwar welfare state could also help strengthen support for liberal in-
ternationalism more broadly, among Western publics, and make competing
foreign policy strategies of nationalism and isolationism less attractive.
To Western leaders, liberal internationalism and the welfare state were
thus mutually supportive.6 For most voters, the ensuing postwar eco-
nomic boom was proof enough that the basic formula worked. Across the
West, expanded trade drove economic growth, making it easier for Western
governments to expand social protections and boost real wages and giving
Western voters reason to support closer economic ties within the West. This,
in turn, gave Western leaders more latitude to press forward with liberal in-
ternationalist policies.7 Leftist arguments about the evils of capitalism and
58 Geopolitics and Democracy
2
Support for liberal internationalism
United States
Greece
United Kingdom
1
France
Portugal
Netherlands Finland
Sweden Germany
Australia SpainDenmark Italy
Canada Norway Belgium
0
Switzerland Austria
New Zealand
Japan Luxembourg
−1
Ireland
6 10 15 20
Social security transfers (% GDP)
the American-led postwar order rang hollow at a time when the vast ma-
jority of Western workers were benefiting from high rates of growth and
much higher unionization rates than today. Right-wing arguments that
Western governments harbored wild-eyed “one world” schemes of global
government also fell flat politically. Such claims strained credibility in an era
when Western leaders turned a blind eye to the many ambitious plans and
designs for international federation being advanced by leading international
scientists, economists, and public intellectuals.8
For decades Western governments maintained this delicate balance be-
tween international openness and social protection.9 Western leaders viewed
investing in social protection as an investment in liberal internationalism
and international stability. Systematic analysis at the country, party, and
voter levels of analysis indicates that they were close to the mark. Starting
at the country level, Figures 3.1 and 3.2 show that a country’s level of social
protection is positively correlated with partnership and power, individually,
and in most cases, our proxy for liberal internationalism: partnership and
power combined (partnership +power).10 Figure 3.1 provides a descriptive
snapshot of the relationship between social protection and liberal interna-
tionalism (partnership +power) from 1970 through 2017 for our sample
of Western countries.11 The solid lines in these and similar figures indicate
the direction of the relationship between the variables: in this case, between
social transfers and liberal internationalism. The broken lines refer to the
tightness of the association, or fit, between the variables. These are set at the
Roots of Insolvency 59
95 percent confidence intervals. If we see that both the upper and lower con-
fidence intervals are positive throughout the distribution, as we do here, then
we know with 95 percent confidence that the correlation between the two
variables in the figure tends to be positive. In Figure 3.1, we see that on av-
erage the higher a country’s spending on social protection, the more its gov-
ernment tends to support liberal internationalism.12
Figure 3.2 summarizes the results of more systematic analysis of these
relationships at the country-year level. Here we consider whether spending
on social protection spurs government support for liberal internationalism.
We analyze the full country-year variation, with the baseline results focused
Partnership (KOF
globalization policies)
Partnership+power
(std. sum of policies)
3 8 13 18 23
Social security transfers (% GDP)
on our twenty-four OECD countries. The top panel in the figure summarizes
the regression result, where our measure of welfare effort predicts increased
government support for liberal internationalism and its component parts,
partnership and power.13 The results for partnership and partnership +power
are statistically significant and substantively meaningful. The full country-
year variation in the West’s social security transfers predicts an 8 percent in-
crease in partnership, and a 9 percent increase in partnership +power. The
bottom panel in Figure 3.2 draws out this connection, focusing on the sub-
stantive pattern for partnership +power. We see clearly that government
spending on social protection is positively associated with increased govern-
ment support for liberal internationalism.14
The effects of spending on social protection on Western support for liberal
internationalism are also visible when we move to the party level. Figure 3.3
summarizes the results for a range of models measuring the effect of social
protection in a given country on a given political party’s support for partner-
ship, power, and partnership +power. We rely on the same party manifesto
data used in Chapter 2, though here, we focus on party-year, which is a more
fine-grained unit of analysis. The models are OLS estimates with decade
and country fixed effects, and include substantive controls for the effect of
globalization flows, level of democracy, unemployment rate, union density,
and real GDP growth, as well as individual parties’ vote share and left-to-
right ideological orientation.15 These party influences are particularly im-
portant to control for here because it is necessary to separate out and isolate
the sources of parties’ positions on partnership and power from the many
other policy stances they take in their electoral manifestos.16 The top panel
in Figure 3.3 reports results averaged across all party families. The bottom
panel summarizes the effects of social protection on support for partnership
+ power (liberal internationalism) by party family.17
The patterns we see in Figure 3.3 are consistent with our expectations. We
see that across the party family spectrum, government spending on social
protection is associated with high party support for partnership and power,
and with liberal internationalism (partnership +power) more generally. The
correlation between social protection and partnership here is consistent with
a large body of research stretching back to Ruggie’s “embedded liberalism”
reformulation of Polanyi’s argument about the need to balance international
markets and social protection. As Ruggie suggested, greater levels of social
protection and compensation in the form of unemployment insurance, so-
cial services (e.g., health care, housing assistance, child care support), and
Roots of Insolvency 61
2
Partnership
1
Power
0
−1
5 10 15 20 25
Social security transfers (% GDP)
other payments improve the chances that citizens, and their elected repre-
sentatives, will support international openness and economic integration.
This finding is consistent with previous research, including our own.18
However, the analysis here goes beyond Ruggie’s original formulation
and intuition in two important ways. First, we see that the relationship be-
tween social protection and liberal internationalism is especially consistent
for parties on the left (Social Democrats and radical-left parties), where the
confidence intervals do not cross zero. This is striking because one might ex-
pect parties of the left, whose working-class voters disproportionately benefit
62 Geopolitics and Democracy
40
30
Partnership
20
Power
10
0
−10
5 10 15 20 25
Social security transfers (% GDP)
Figure 3.4 Relationship between social protection and voter support for liberal
internationalism in Western democracies, 1960–2017
10
Social transfers
Social security transfers normalized
Social security transfers (% GDP)
(% GDP)
14
by unemployment rate
8
12
6
10
Social transfers
normalized
2
8
Figure 3.5 Western government investment in social protection for labor force
adjusted by economic risk, 1960–2017
66 Geopolitics and Democracy
and Medicare programs and promised to replace the Affordable Care Act—
Obamacare—with a universal health insurance system. Trump’s “one-two”
combo was effective, especially in the traditional Democratic strongholds of
Michigan, Pennsylvania, and Wisconsin, whose industries and workers had
been worn down by years of outsourcing and offshoring to China, Mexico,
and other destinations for low-cost production, assembly, and supply.45
In case after case, the pattern was the same. Parties on the far right
campaigned against globalism’s costs in economic insecurity and national
sovereignty. They urged governments to do more to compensate those
harmed by trade liberalization and supranationalism. This, of course, was
also true of many parties on the far left. Most rejected the right’s incendiary
anti-
immigration message, but far- left parties also campaigned against
hyperglobalization and for expanding compensation and assistance to hard-
hit workers, sectors, and communities.46 The fact that voters rewarded these
parties with an increasing share of the national vote revealed just how much
the postwar bargain had frayed in Western democracies. Yet, as we have seen,
the story of anti-globalism’s rise is not only one of popular resentment and
grievance bubbling up from below. Political entrepreneurs and parties on the
fringes of Western party systems successfully tapped and mobilized this dis-
content to increase their vote share. That parties on the far left and far right
seized on anti-globalism after the Cold War ended is no coincidence.
Shortly before the Soviet Union fell, Georgi Arbatov, the éminence grise of
Moscow’s foreign policy establishment, warned an American audience: “We
are going to do a terrible thing to you. We are going to deprive you of an
enemy.” Arbatov was a seasoned observer of the Western political scene and
surely knew that Western unity was not due solely to fears of Soviet com-
munism. Still, Arbatov’s claim contained a kernel of truth. For nearly half a
century, widespread worries about Soviet communism and the risk of nu-
clear war made liberal internationalism the strategy of choice in the West’s
corridors of power and in its courts of public opinion. With the end of the
Cold War, these external pressures and influences on domestic politics eased
considerably. Security concerns no longer weighed as heavily on voters’
minds. Western political leaders and policymakers had more latitude in de-
fining their nation’s international interests. So, however, did parties on the
Roots of Insolvency 69
far left and far right. As Cold War tensions dissipated, the room for political
maneuver in Western democracies expanded.
Geopolitics cast a long shadow over the West’s politics during the Cold War.
Suspicions of Soviet intentions in Europe, Asia, and elsewhere made Western
leaders skeptical of schemes for global disarmament and neutralism that
were popular on the far left. They were considered too idealistic, too imprac-
tical, and too risky. Calls from the far right to “roll back” the Soviet pres-
ence in Eastern Europe and rely on nuclear brinksmanship to keep the peace
were also rejected as unrealistic or, worse, reckless in a bipolar world where
both sides had “the bomb.”47 Isolationism was also a non-starter. American
politicians like Senator Arthur Vandenberg, who had advocated it in the
face of German and Japanese expansionism in the run up to World War II,
now kept the discredited strategy at arm’s length. The fear of being second-
guessed by political opponents for failing to do enough to contain the spread
of communism or, alternatively, being dubbed “trigger happy,” forced most
politicians into the middle lane. The Cold War thus exerted centripetal pres-
sure on the West’s politics.
In the United States, Cold War imperatives pushed Democrats and
Republicans toward the bipartisan liberal internationalist center. The two
parties often disagreed over how much of the federal purse was needed to
contain or balance against Soviet power and what steps needed to be taken
to avoid the risk of accidental or inadvertent nuclear war. For example, the
Truman, Kennedy, Johnson, and Reagan administrations boosted national
defense spending. The Eisenhower, Nixon, and early Carter administrations
looked for ways to trim the Pentagon’s budget.48 Yet every administration
from Truman’s through Reagan’s steered clear of strategies that were overly
reliant on idealism or realism. Investing in both partnership and power gave
them additional leverage against Moscow and limited their political exposure
domestically to charges of weakness or recklessness. Presidential hopefuls
who strayed too far to the left or to the right—as did George McGovern on
the left and Barry Goldwater on the right—paid dearly at the polls.
Geopolitics had a similar effect on West European politics. To be sure,
most politicians and parties on the far left and far right flatly rejected lib-
eral internationalism, arguing that it was little more than a stalking horse
70 Geopolitics and Democracy
unhappy end in the late 1970s and early 1980s. A confluence of events—from
Moscow’s decision to deploy a new generation of nuclear-tipped missiles in
Europe, to the spread of Marxist governments in the Middle East and Africa,
to the Soviet military invasion of Afghanistan in December 1979—forced
a reckoning. Western voters grew more apprehensive about national secu-
rity.56 Western party leaders became more concerned about the credibility
of Western security commitments. At a time of heightened anxiety about the
possibility of nuclear war and fiscal belt-tightening, there was also political
resistance to military build-up. In the late 1970s and 1980s, fears of nuclear
war and guns-versus-butter trade-offs figured prominently in party debates
about how best to strengthen Western security: should this be done through
arms control treaties and confidence-building measures, or by building up
the West’s offensive nuclear and conventional military capabilities?57
It was not until the 1990s, that the strategic imperatives dominating
Western political life for over half a century truly disappeared. Without
Soviet communism and nuclear Armageddon hanging knifelike over
Western polities, Western leaders found themselves with more room to ma-
neuver in foreign affairs, but also with less clarity about which foreign policy
strategy—which combination of partnership and power—to place their bets
on. When Bill Clinton gushed, “Gosh, I miss the Cold War,” he said out loud
what many Western leaders at the time were thinking. In a world defined by
bipolar superpower rivalry, the international rules of the road were clearer
and the task of coalition-building in democracies easier. In the absence of
a Soviet-style threat, investing in military power at Cold War levels was less
necessary to guarantee security. Defense spending as a percentage of GDP
dropped from an average of 2.7 percent in the 1980s to 2 percent in the 1990s,
where it would remain for the next twenty years. Defense spending in the
United States, UK, and France did edge back up in the 2000s. Yet even in
these countries, the share of GDP spent on defense would not return to Cold
War levels.
The end of the Cold War also helps explain why the West doubled down on
multilateralism. In the 1990s, the prevailing view in Western foreign policy
circles was that the international institutions forged in the crucible of the
Cold War had worked and could be repurposed to bring other nations and
regions into the liberal world order.58 The initial impulse in America, and
Europe too, was to expand existing regional and global institutions in both
security and economic cooperation, or use them to devise new ones. In the
security realm, NATO was expanded eastward and the role of the Conference
72 Geopolitics and Democracy
We have argued that fears of Soviet communism and nuclear war bolstered
Western support for liberal internationalism. They gave most governments,
most parties, and most voters reason to support investing in power as well as
partnership. To test this argument, we explored whether geopolitical threat
correlates positively with government, party, and voter support for liberal
internationalism. Our models below rely on the same outcome variables,
estimators, and specifications that we used earlier to measure the possible
effects of social protection. However, now we consider the relationship be-
tween geopolitical threat and support for partnership, power, and partnership
+ power. To measure the scope and intensity of geopolitical threat, we created
a composite index based upon seven different measures of the international
security environment for each of the twenty-four OECD countries in our
sample.65 This gives us a scale that runs from low to high for each country.66
The individual measures that make up this composite index capture different
features of a state’s “geopolitical threat environment,” including how stable its
74 Geopolitics and Democracy
borders and regions are, how territorial or ideological the challenge is, and
so on.67
The descriptive results for this composite threat measure are summa-
rized in Figure 3.6. It tracks the level of geopolitical threat facing the West
in general between 1950 and 2011 (top panel), and for the EU-15, Japan, and
the United States individually (bottom panel). Four key patterns stand out
in the data. First, we see that there is a secular decline in the level of threat
over time, with the average threat level for the full sample of our twenty-
four OECD countries falling below zero following the collapse of the Soviet
Union, and remaining below that level down to the present era. Second, the
.5
Geopolitical threat index
0 −.5
Japan
United States
Geopolitical threat index
0 −.5 .5
EU−15
United States
United Kingdom
France
1
Greece
Portugal
S. Korea
Finland Australia
Denmark Netherlands
Norway Italy
Sweden
0
Belgium Canada
New Zealand
Japan
−1
Ireland
−1 −.5 0 .5 1
Geopolitical threat index
Figure 3.7 Geopolitical threat and Western government support for liberal
internationalism by country, 1960–2011
76 Geopolitics and Democracy
faces on the horizontal axis and its government’s support for liberal inter-
nationalism (partnership +power) on the vertical axis. The positive corre-
lation, which is statistically significant, is in line with what our argument
predicts: that Western democracies’ commitment to liberal internationalism
was driven, in no small part, by the challenge that Soviet power and ambition
posed to their security and interests.
The descriptive results reported in Figure 3.7 are based on cross-country
averages. To test our argument in a more controlled and systematic way, we
expanded the analysis to the country-year level. The regression results are
summarized in Figures 3.8 through 3.10.70 Overall, the analysis provides
a good deal of support for our argument. As expected, we see that higher
Partnership (KOF
globalization policies)
Partnership+power
(std. sum of policies)
−.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4
1.5
Govt support for liberal internationalism
1
.5
0
Partnership+Power
2
Partnership
1
Power
0
−1
−1 0 1 2
Geopolitical threat index
earlier (Figures 3.2–3.3).71 However, the overall tenor and direction of geo-
political threat’s association with Western government and party support are
similar.
By contrast, our argument about geopolitical threats gets much less
traction when it comes to voters. In Figure 3.10, we see that the level of
international security has no significant correlation with voter-weighted
party platforms (although geopolitical threat almost reaches standard
levels of statistical significance for power).72 One possible explanation for
this is that government officials and party leaders are more attuned to ge-
opolitics than are voters.73 Certainly, heads of government have strong
electoral incentives to hedge against the risk of foreign policy failure—
that is, the risk of being blamed by their partisan rivals for failing to cor-
rectly read the international security environment.74 As we have seen,
during the Cold War such concerns weighed on political leaders in the
United States, Germany, Japan, and other Western democracies. Another
possible reason is that our geopolitical threat scale does not fully capture
well-documented public anxieties during the Cold War about the risk of
catastrophic nuclear war.75 The various threat measures that make up this
scale focus on geopolitical risk (e.g., territorial expansion), as opposed to
existential risk (e.g., public fears of “nuclear winter” in the 1980s). While
the two are related, they are not the same. As we showed in Chapter 2
(Figures 2.7 and 2.8), public support for defense outlays during the Cold
War rose sharply during periods, like the late 1970s, of heightened concern
Voter support for liberal internationalism
45
Partnership+Power
35
25
15
Partnership Power
5
−5
Figure 3.10 Relationship between geopolitical threat and voter support for
liberal internationalism in Western democracies, 1960–2017
Roots of Insolvency 79
FAILURE TO ADJUST
Much has been written about globalization and its economic, political,
and social consequences. Much less has been written about why political
leaders did not do more for those that globalization was leaving behind.76
In the face of a mounting anti-globalist backlash, one might have expected
Western leaders to trim their international sails, expand social safety nets,
and redesign international institutions to make them more responsive to the
demands of national electorates. As we discuss in Chapter 4, there was some
movement by Western governments along these lines. The breakneck pace
of trade liberalization and multilateral cooperation began to slow even be-
fore the 2008 economic crisis. In some OECD countries (e.g., Ireland, Italy,
Norway), welfare generosity and other social protections also increased. Yet
Western leaders did not actively look for programmatic ways to close the
ends-means gap. Western government efforts to liberalize trade and capital
markets continued to outpace Cold War levels and, in most cases, govern-
ment support for social protection or other measures of social policy gener-
osity stalled or declined, as it did in Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands,
and Sweden.
Some theories
Why didn’t Western leaders do more to close the gap over globalism? Why
didn’t they take steps to address the concerns of populists before the anger
and resentment over globalism reached crisis proportions? Some scholars
and analysts attribute the failure to political arrogance, elitism, and “group-
think.” These factors may help explain why Western leaders embraced glob-
alization and supranationalism in the 1990s, but they are less helpful in
explaining why, in the face of mounting political resistance, self-interested
elected leaders did not balance their support for globalization and multi-
lateralism with greater investments in social protection and compensation.
Fortunately, existing theories of international and comparative politics
80 Geopolitics and Democracy
on financial and business interests, and political leaders aligned with them.
Between 1980s and 2010, average OECD union density—a standard measure
of union political strength based on union workers as a proportion of civilian
employment—dropped by more than ten percentage points.82
To gauge the weight of these possible explanations for why Western govern-
ment policies’ have consistently outstripped voter support since the end of
the Cold War, we empirically explored several possible predictors of the gap.
To assess the impact of international financial interests and supranational
institutions on Western policymaking, we rely on the KOF Swiss Institute’s
indices for de facto globalization. These include de facto economic globali-
zation, political globalization, and KOF’s composite all globalization index.83
We measure union strength using a standard measure of union density: union
members as a proportion of civilian employment. We control for democratic
representativeness (Polity-IV democracy score and voter turnout), political
orientation (left-right platform position and right-party percentage of cabinet
posts), and economic performance (unemployment rate and GDP growth).84
The outcome variable (government-voter gap) measures the extent to which a
given Western government and its voters converge (diverge) in their support
for international partnership between 1970 and 2017.85 We focus here on in-
ternational partnership because, as we showed in Chapter 2, this is where
Western governments have consistently run ahead of voters since the end of
the Cold War.86
Figure 3.11 summarizes the key results.87 We see that our three measures
of de facto globalization, which plausibly capture the size and influence of in-
ternational business and financial interests in Western capitals and Western
leaders growing reliance on supranational institutions, tend to be positively
and significantly associated with our outcome of interest: the gap between
governments and voters over international partnership. Figure 3.11 captures
the substantive size of these associations: the outcome variable (government-
voter gap) is always on the same scale and the panels display the full-sample
variation for each KOF de facto globalization measure.88 The broadest con-
ception of globalization (all globalization; top panel) has the strongest asso-
ciation with the solvency gap. Economic globalization (middle panel) and
political globalization (bottom panel) have more modest associations, though
1.5
Govt−voter gap on partnership
0 .5 −.5 1
50 60 70 80 90
KOF index of de facto globalization (all de facto indices)
1.5
Govt−voter gap on partnership
0 .5 −.5 1
20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90
KOF index of de facto economic globalization
1.5
Govt−voter gap on partnership
0 .5 −.51
50 60 70 80 90 100
KOF index of de facto political globalization
It took time for the West’s turn to globalism to produce a backlash. Looking
back, it is also clear there was also no single defining moment when the tide
of Western political support for the liberal order turned. The 2003 invasion
of Iraq, the 2008 financial crash, and the 2015 Syrian refugee crisis are often
singled out as inflection points. Certainly, each contributed to the widening
democratic solvency gap between Western governments and their publics
over international openness and cooperation. However, the downward spiral
in domestic support began well before the Iraq War, and it has continued to
widen with each passing year since then. And it did not occur on its own.
Since the 1990s, populist and nationalist politicians have actively mobilized
globalism’s discontents by speaking to Western publics’ fears and interests.
Mainstream political leaders did remarkably little materially to offset and
counteract those attacks.
The failure of Western democracies to close this ends-means gap sheds
new light on how and why the liberal international order fractured. Writing
in the early 1990s, many international relations scholars and foreign policy
analysts predicted that in the absence of geopolitical imperatives, the West
would quickly divide and splinter over security and economic issues.91
Without a common enemy to unite them, Western democracies strategic and
commercial interests would diverge. This did not happen. The liberal order
did not devolve into rival trading blocs. NATO did not collapse. Friends did
not become foes. What did happen is that Western foreign and domestic
policy diverged. This has proved enormously costly for Western democra-
cies, internationally as well as domestically. We turn to these issues now.
4
Reaping the Whirlwind
In 1949, historian and New Dealer Arthur Schlesinger Jr. published The
Vital Center, a best-selling call to arms. Writing in the shadow of the Cold
War, Schlesinger saw a vibrant liberal political center as the West’s best de-
fense against the spread of Soviet-style communism or a possible resur-
gence of the laissez-faire capitalism that could result in depression and war.
Though writing principally for an American audience, Schlesinger’s assess-
ment of the international predicament and domestic challenges facing the
United States in the late 1940s echoed public fears and anxieties in Britain,
France, Germany, and other Western democracies. With memories of war
and democracy’s failings in the interwar years still rife, Western voters
from all strata of society and every class favored political moderation and
consensus-building over ideological fervor, economic volatility, and political
extremism. For the vast majority of Western voters, mainstream parties—
Christian Democratic and Social Democratic, Conservative and Liberal—
offered the best hope for guaranteeing protection from Soviet ambitions and
market forces.
For much of the past seventy-five years, mainstream political parties were
the bedrock of the Western liberal international order. As the vital center,
they were not only a bulwark against political extremism from the political
left and political right during the Cold War. Mainstream parties were also
the building blocks upon which the West’s shared commitment to the lib-
eral international order rested. Western leaders could advance internation-
alist policies, knowing that those policies rested on sturdy foundations in
national party systems. This is no longer the case. While most mainstream
parties continue to back the liberal order, their political capacity to support
and promote it has weakened considerably. Over the past thirty years, in-
surgent parties have made inroads on both right and left in one democracy
after another. Political authority has fragmented and coalition-building has
become more difficult. Even in two-party systems like the United States and
Britain, anti-globalist movements have made it harder for leaders to govern
Geopolitics and Democracy. Peter Trubowitz and Brian Burgoon, Oxford University Press.
© Oxford University Press 2023. DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780197535400.003.0004
86 Geopolitics and Democracy
That support took different forms in different countries and party systems.
In America’s two-party system, liberal internationalism was backed by
both of the country’s two major parties and by major segments of business,
labor, and agriculture.2 Democrats’ and Republicans’ shared power base in
postwar America’s internationally competitive industrial financial centers of
the urban Northeast gave them a strong incentive to work together to re-
build the world economy and defend it against potential military and po-
litical threats in Europe and Asia. Democrats from the agrarian South and
trans-Mississippi Republican West, whose commodity producers stood to
benefit from freer trade, also favored liberal internationalism. To be sure,
partisan politics did not stop at the water’s edge. Democrats and Republicans
frequently disagreed over the size of the defense budget and the amount of
foreign aid. Yet these partisan divisions were sporadic and transitory. On the
core features of liberal internationalism—the need for freer trade, the impor-
tance of security alliances, the role of international institutions—bipartisan
consensus was the norm in the United States during the Cold War.3
In Europe’s multiparty democracies, liberal internationalism garnered
support from both sides of the left-right ideological divide. Under the leader-
ship of Christian Democrats and Conservatives, who largely dominated party
politics in the 1950s, Western European countries joined NATO, rearmed
88 Geopolitics and Democracy
militarily, and took the first steps toward political confederation and an inte-
grated common market.4 Some center-left parties like West Germany’s Social
Democratic Party (SPD) and Italy’s Socialist Party (PSI) initially opposed the
center-right’s liberal internationalist agenda. However, by the early 1960s
they too had come around to supporting European integration and NATO
membership, even if military rearmament remained an issue for many on the
center-left.5 Conservatives in Britain and France who worried about liberal
internationalism’s sovereignty costs sought to assert some control or impose
limits, but did not reject it outright. French Conservatives sought to impose
control by making a Paris-Bonn axis the central coordinate of any move to-
ward European unity. British Conservatives approved European unity so
long as it did not require Britain to be “in Europe” or jeopardize the UK’s nas-
cent “special relationship” with the United States.6
In Japan, the ruling Liberal Democratic Party (LDP) favored what might
be characterized as liberal internationalism lite.7 Guided by the skillful lead-
ership of Shigeru Yoshida, postwar Japan adopted a Western-oriented for-
eign policy that relied on US security guarantees, homeland defense, and
foreign markets. The LDP rejected substantial military rearmament in favor
of cheaper Self-Defense Forces (SDF) and relied on state-led development
of the civilian economy instead of the market. Under the so-called Yoshida
Doctrine, successive Japanese governments accepted infringements on na-
tional sovereignty, most notably in the form of continued American military
bases and forces on Japanese soil. Japan’s status as a “semi-sovereign nation”
was a price that most members of the LDP were willing to pay if it meant
greater access to US markets and technology, and did not require the party
to sacrifice its support coalition of industry and farmers—the so-called coa-
lition of “steel and rice”—on the altar of free trade.8 To bolster broader public
support for aligning with America in the East-West struggle, mainstream
conservatives committed to forgoing nuclear weapons and arms exports and
to a narrowly prescribed regional security role for Japanese military forces.
Western support for liberal internationalism did not mean unanimity, of
course. In the United States, progressive Democrats initially favored closer
cooperation with Moscow and opposed military spending and the use of
military force in distant lands.9 In the early postwar years, Republicans on
the far right—Fortress America and America-First regionalists—opposed
strengthening transatlantic ties. In Western Europe, Atlanticism also sparked
fierce resistance on the fringes of French, German, and Italian party politics,
and debate over East-West neutrality was a staple of party politics in smaller
Reaping the Whirlwind 89
Liberal internationalism
4
Globalism
−2 0
Sample
median
Isolationism Nationalism
−4
−4 −2 0 2 4
Party support for power
Mainstream parties Radical Left parties Radical Right parties
Mainstream mean Radical Left mean Radical Right mean
Social Dem mean Liberal mean Christian Dem mean
Conservative mean
Figure 4.1 Party support for international partnership and military power in
Western democracies, 1950–1975
plots in this chapter) using the full sample medians on each dimension from
1950 through 2018. These median values roughly correspond to the values
demarcating the four quadrants in Figure 1.2 in Chapter 1: globalism (high
partnership, low power); liberal internationalism (high partnership, high
power); isolationism (low partnership, low power); and nationalism (low
partnership, high power).20
As we see in Figure 4.1, mainstream parties were liberal internationalism’s
staunchest supporters in the postwar era; parties on the far left and far right,
dedicated opponents. Most mainstream parties ran on party platforms advo-
cating liberal internationalism and, as a result, we see that the means for
each of the mainstream party families are located in, or in the case of Social
Democrats and Conservatives, close to, quadrant 2. Mainstream parties show
comparatively little support for strategies of isolationism (quadrant 3) or na-
tionalism (quadrant 4). As one might expect, Social Democratic parties are
less supportive of defense spending, military preparedness, and the use of
force than Conservative parties. As a result, there is a fair amount of disper-
sion along the horizontal axis (military power) among mainstream parties
in the liberal internationalist quadrant. There is less dispersion or variation
among mainstream parties along the vertical (international partnership)
axis—that is, on matters having to do with international trade, European in-
tegration, and multilateral cooperation.
Reaping the Whirlwind 91
Most radical-left parties cluster on the left side of the space and, espe-
cially, in the lower-left quadrant (isolationism). Radical-right parties are
concentrated on the right side of the space. Most are located in the bottom-
right nationalist quadrant, though some are in the upper-right, liberal in-
ternationalist quadrant. These alignments are not surprising. Parties on the
far-left championed disarmament and generally opposed European inte-
gration.21 Radical-right parties were more divided than the far left on the
issue of European integration: for some parties on the right, some form of
European confederation was preferable to US hegemony. Some far-right
parties also supported trade liberalization. However, most ultra-right parties
ran on party platforms that strongly favored containing the Soviet Union and
investing in national military power; hence, their location on the right side
of the figure. Last, we see in Figure 4.1 that there were relatively few radical-
right parties, as most reactionary movements from the interwar years had
collapsed.
In Western democracies, the level of mainstream party support for liberal
internationalism was impressively strong. It also proved resilient, despite
repeated challenges. The most serious of these was the crisis of the 1970s,
when the postwar compromises between left and right frayed. While parties
on the center-left urged governments to double down on Keynesianism
by expanding government spending and market regulation, parties on the
center-right called for political retrenchment, privatization, and market lib-
eralization, or what came to be known as “neoliberalism.” At first, the political
fight tilted in the center-left’s favor. Center-left parties held or gained ground
in national elections in Austria (1975), Britain (1974), the Netherlands
(1972), and West Germany (1976).22 In time, however, the balance of power
shifted to the center-right. Popular dissatisfaction with the status quo and
pressure from powerful business interests propelled Conservatives to vic-
tory in Britain (1979), the United States (1980), and Germany (1983). As
Margaret Thatcher, Ronald Reagan, and Helmut Kohl began experimenting
with different combinations of neoliberal economic policies, competitive
pressure on other Western governments to follow suit intensified. Even
France’s François Mitterrand’s socialist government (1981–1995) found it
necessary to pivot toward greater market liberalization.
For all the churn in Western party systems during the 1970s and 1980s,
mainstream parties continued to dominate the political landscape. As Figure
4.2 indicates, they also remained firmly in the liberal internationalist camp.
92 Geopolitics and Democracy
4
Party support for partnership
2
Sample
median
−2 0
Sample
median
Isolationism Nationalism
−4
−4 −2 0 2 4
Party support for power
Mainstream parties Radical Left parties Radical Right parties
Mainstream mean Radical Left mean Radical Right mean
Social Dem mean Liberal mean Christian Dem mean
Conservative mean
Figure 4.2 Party support for international partnership and military power in
Western democracies, 1976–1991
During the Cold War, the mainstream parties that made up Schlesinger’s
vital center were the liberal order’s custodians. Lying between voters and
governments, they acted as critical intermediaries, shaping and aggregating
voters’ foreign policy preferences in the electoral arena and translating that
support into programmatic policy. The relative strength of center-left and
Reaping the Whirlwind 93
Net Mainstream
vote share
−.004 −.002 0 .002 .004
Mainstream vote
share
Net Mainstream
vote share
−.03 −.02 −.01 0 .01
Figure 4.3 Effect of party vote share on government support for international
partnership and military power in Western democracies, 1970–2017
Reaping the Whirlwind 95
radical-left vote share, and combined radical vote share are all strongly nega-
tively correlated with government support for each of our outcome variables.
Figure 4.4 summarizes what these patterns mean substantively. Each panel
displays the counterfactual predicted levels of government policy support for
partnership +power as a function of the full sample variation of (a) main-
stream party vote shares (top panel) and (b) all radical-left and radical-right
party vote shares (bottom panel). The vertical axis for both models is the
same.29 Again, the solid lines in the figures refer to the direction of the re-
gression line capturing the two-way association between the variables on
.75
Govt support for liberal internationalism
.5
.25
0
−.25
−.5
−.75
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90
Mainstream party vote share
.75
Govt support for liberal internationalism
.5
.25
0
−.25
−.5
−.75
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55
Radical left and radical right party vote share
Figure 4.4 Relationship between mainstream and radical party strength and
government support for liberal internationalism in Western democracies,
1950–2017
96 Geopolitics and Democracy
the horizontal and vertical axes. The broken lines refer to the consistency or
tightness of the fit between these two variables with 95 percent confidence.
As the top panel makes clear, the larger the mainstream parties’ national vote
share, the more likely Western governments are to invest in partnership and
power—that is, in liberal internationalism. In the bottom panel, we see that
the greater the radical parties’ vote share, the less likely Western governments
are to invest in liberal internationalism. Notably, the positive effect of main-
stream party strength is marginally smaller than the negative effect of rad-
ical party strength. This is captured in Figure 4.4, where we see that the full
sample variation of mainstream vote share predicts a smaller swath of vari-
ation in liberal internationalism (top panel) than does the sample variation
in radical party vote share (bottom panel). These are substantial associations.
The variation in radical party vote shares predicts between 20 and 30 percent
of the variation in government policies of partnership +power.30
The West’s double commitment to partnership and power distinguished
liberal internationalism from other foreign policy strategies on offer, and
mainstream parties from their competitors on the far left and far right.
However, as the analyses in Figures 4.3 and 4.4 make clear, it was mainstream
parties’ strength at the ballot box during the Cold War, especially relative to
the radical parties, that enabled Western leaders to put liberal internation-
alism on a stable footing as the West’s strategy of choice.31 This point is often
forgotten or glossed over in accounts of the liberal order’s formation after
World War II and its subsequent amplification and elaboration in the decades
that followed. It was a time when party politics in Western democracies was
remarkably stable or “frozen,” as Seymour Lipset and Stein Rokkan put it
in their classic 1967 cross-national study of party democracy.32 A hidden
source of Western strength during the Cold War, the party alignments that
Lipset and Rokkan identified would remain in place until it ended.
In the 1990s, Western party systems began to unwind. Parties on the center-
left and center-right started losing vote share at a slow but accelerating pace
to insurgent parties on the far left and far right. Scholars of comparative pol-
itics have written extensively about the decomposition of the West’s postwar
party systems and its implications for democratic governance. Much less has
been written about how the West’s turn to globalism in the post-Cold War
Reaping the Whirlwind 97
Working-class blues
When the Cold War ended, the parties that made up the vital center con-
tinued to dwarf their rivals. Mainstream parties continued to win the lion’s
share of the national vote and, as a result, retained control of the pivotal
foreign policymaking positions in national governments. Between 1976
and 1991, mainstream parties captured nearly 80 percent of the popular
vote, on average; lower than the share they received during the postwar
era, but not significantly so. As Figure 4.5 indicates, thirty years later, the
situation looks quite different. Since the Cold War, mainstream parties’
share of the national vote has dropped by a full 15 percent of the total
vote—averaging only around 65 percent of the vote by the late 2010s.
In some countries, the drop was sharper still. For example, in the 1990
German election, Social Democrats and Christian Democrats received
85
6
75
4
70
2
65
over 70 percent of the vote. In the 2021 election, together they received
just under 50 percent.33
Mainstream parties have not only lost vote share. Over the past thirty
years, Western government majorities have become smaller and Western
electorates have become more disjointed and volatile.34 The erosion of the
mainstream parties’ dominance in Western governing majorities is evident
in the data. Since 1991 the percentage of cabinet portfolios held by main-
stream parties dropped from a Cold War average of almost 50 percent to just
30 percent during the 2010s.35 As shared governments have become more
commonplace in the West, the process of putting them together and keeping
them together has become more complex and taxing. A two-party system
like America’s is spared the trials and tribulations of coalition government,
but worsening polarization in the United States has also made it more diffi-
cult for Republicans or Democrats to build winning coalitions to enact na-
tional legislation. Twenty years ago, Congress passed 225 laws in a year. In
2020, it passed only twenty-eight laws.36
Many factors have contributed to the electoral decline of mainstream
parties, from technological change, to secularization, to generational change,
to mass immigration, to income inequality.37 However, a strong case can be
made that Western governments’ turn toward globalism after the Cold War
played a decisive role. In the heady days of Western triumphalism over cap-
italism and open economies, Western leaders on the center-left did not only
see globalization as a strategy to expand the liberal order, internationally.
They also saw it as a means to boost their parties’ political fortunes, after a
decade or longer languishing in the political wilderness while center-right
parties set the policy agenda. Bill Clinton’s New Democratic agenda, Tony
Blair’s “New Labour,” Lionel Jospin’s réalisme de gauche (left realism), and
Gerhard Schröder’s “Agenda 2010” were cut from the same neoliberal cloth,
and under the influence of globalization, driven by the same political imper-
ative to make the center-left more competitive electorally.
During the Cold War, center-left leaders relied on the support of working-
class voters to win elections. The viability of that electoral strategy depended
greatly on the manufacturing sector’s vitality in Western economies. For
decades, that was a safe bet. However, over time center-left leaders found it
increasingly difficult to win national office relying principally on blue-collar
votes.38 The secular decline of the manufacturing sector in Western econo-
mies, and the concomitant rise of the service sector, led Social Democratic
leaders in the 1990s to adopt more pro-globalization policies in hopes of
Reaping the Whirlwind 99
winning over service-sector voters who benefited from cheaper goods and
services increasingly provided by imports and low-wage immigrant labor.39
In effect, center-left leaders began trading a large part of their traditional
older working-class political base that was being hurt by hyperglobalization
to win over younger, educated, middle-class voters who benefited from
market liberalization and supported multilateral cooperation. By one esti-
mate, in 1980 Social Democratic parties mobilized roughly twice as many
working-class voters as middle-class voters. By 2010, the proportions were
roughly the reverse.40
In Europe, Social Democratic and socialist leaders had already begun
changing course when they agreed to the creation of a single market in the
1980s. In the 1990s, they abandoned what remained of their long-standing
commitment to independent, national roads to social democracy by
embracing economic and monetary union.41 The 1992 Maastricht treaty, for-
mally establishing the European Central Bank and a common European cur-
rency, ruled out the kind of national autonomy that center-left parties once
insisted upon to protect their working-class constituencies from market
forces. Britain’s Labour Party, at most a reluctant supporter of earlier efforts
to promote European economic integration, set aside its “ancient enmity” to-
ward market liberalization and threw in its lot with the new European Union.
As Donald Sassoon puts it in his magisterial history of the European Left,
Maastricht “decreed that inflation, and not unemployment, was the main
enemy. This was now fully accepted by the Labour Party and by all other
European socialist parties.”42
In the United States, Clinton and other New Democrats broke with
Democrats from the aging Rust Belt cities of the Northeast on globalization
as well as on welfare policy, and aligned with conservative Republicans.43
Clinton embraced trade liberalization and pushed for the NAFTA regional
trade pact (1994), the GATT agreement creating the WTO (1994), and
granting permanent normal trade relations (PNTR) to China (2000). These
agreements angered labor and other Democratic constituencies (e.g., envi-
ronmental groups, human rights NGOs), and put Clinton at odds with many
traditional Democrats in Congress.44 But free trade deals helped Clinton and
the New Democrats earn the support of fast-growing high-tech and service
sectors, as well as their voters.45 These sectors were not strongly attached
to the Republican Party, and they were a huge potential source of votes and
money. Liberal, redistributive Democratic programs could not win over
this new class of voters and investors. What could help move them into the
100 Geopolitics and Democracy
Democratic column were cheaper imports and the promise of greater access
to foreign markets and investment opportunities.46
In Japan, globalization also weakened old party alignments and led to new
domestic alliances. In the early 1990s, the coalition of “steel and rice” frac-
tured, sending the conservative LDP to its first electoral defeat in nearly four
decades. While the LDP soon regained power, its defeat ushered in a host
of institutional reforms that led to a more competitive, fluid party system.47
Urban and middle-class voters previously frozen out of party politics by the
dominant LDP’s fealty to farmers were now an object of political mobiliza-
tion drives. In 2001, Junichiro Koizumi, a political maverick, captured the
LDP’s presidency and Japan’s premiership, campaigning on a neoliberal plat-
form targeting these voters.48 Koizumi’s platform of “reform, with no sacred
cows” took aim at the protection of inefficient sectors like agriculture while
offering neoliberal policies like lower taxes, privatization (e.g., postal ser-
vice), and cuts in pork barrel spending to woo new voters.49 Stealing a page
out of the US and EU playbook, Koizumi sought to strengthen Japan’s eco-
nomic ties to other countries in the region through “open regionalism.”50
In the 1990s, center-left as well as center-right parties in Western democ-
racies saw political advantage in promoting globalization and its domestic
corollaries: lower corporate taxes, tighter fiscal policy, fewer government
regulations, trimmed down welfare states, and weaker trade unions. This
trend continued though the 2000s as the balance of power in America, France,
Germany, and other Western democracies shifted from the center-left to the
center-right.51 Under Germany’s Angela Merkel, France’s Nicolas Sarkozy,
and America’s George W. Bush, multilateralism and intergovernmentalism
remained the preferred mode for global economic cooperation. The same
was true of the Democratic Party of Japan (DPJ), which came to power in
2009, and the LDP’s Shinzo Abe, who returned to power in 2012.52 Both con-
tinued to pursue FTAs with other nations and backed the multilateral negoti-
ations that culminated in the 2016 Trans-Pacific Partnership Treaty (TPP).53
Figure 4.6 summarizes the party alignments in Western democracies over
foreign policy during these years. We see that most center-left and center-
right parties continue to cluster in quadrant two (liberal internationalism).
However, many mainstream parties also now cluster in quadrant one (glob-
alism). When compared to Figures 4.1 and 4.2, the most significant change
in the behavior of mainstream parties is their movement up the vertical axis,
indicating greater support for economic integration and institutionalized
cooperation. Center-left and center-right parties are now on average more
Reaping the Whirlwind 101
4
Globalism Liberal internationalism
−2 0
Sample
median
Isolationism Nationalism
−4
−4 −2 0 2 4
Party support for power
Mainstream parties Radical Left parties Radical Right parties
Mainstream mean Radical Left mean Radical Right mean
Social Dem mean Liberal mean Christian Dem mean
Conservative mean
Figure 4.6 Party support for international partnership and military power in
Western democracies, 1992–2018
deeply committed to partnership than they were during the Cold War (and
far more than parties on the radical left and, especially, the radical right). By
contrast, there is little sustained change in mainstream party family support
for military power. As during the Cold War, the more conservative the main-
stream party family, the more likely it is to urge increased military spending
and preparedness.
The shift in mainstream parties’ support for globalization is easier to see
in Figure 4.7. It tracks the mean position of each mainstream party family,
as well as the mean location of radical-left and radical-right parties from
1950 through 2017. In the case of mainstream parties, we see gradual move-
ment up the vertical axis. This is clearest in the case of Social Democrats,
but we see the same upward drift in the mean position of Conservatives and
Liberals (though not Christian Democrats). To be sure, the upward shift in
overall mainstream party support for market liberalization and institutional-
ized cooperation is not as dramatic as the overall movement toward market-
favoring change in Western government foreign policy that we described
in Chapter 2. This is not surprising, however. Party manifestos can tell us
something important about what parties promise voters, but they are an im-
perfect guide to what their leaders actually do once in office. As the anal-
ysis in Chapter 3 showed, one important reason for the divergence between
government policy and party platforms on trade liberalization and interna-
tional institutions is that Western leaders have become overly responsive to
102 Geopolitics and Democracy
2
Globalism SD Liberal Internationalism
L M ’92−’17
1.5
Radical left (RL) M ’76−’91
Radical right (RR) C Sample
Social Dem (SD) M ’50−’75 median
1 Liberal (L)
Christian Dem (CD)
Conservative (C) RR ’50−’75
.5
RL ’92−’17 RR ’76−’91
Sample
median
0
RL ’76−’92
−.5
RR ’92−’17
RL ’50−’75 Isolationism Nationalism
−2 −1 0 1 2
Party support for power
Figure 4.7 Average party family support for international partnership and
military power in Western democracies, 1950–2017
in Figures 4.6 and 4.7 that parties on the far right now clustered heavily in
the bottom-right nationalist quadrant. Older radical-right parties such as
France’s FN and the Denmark’s DPP, which sometimes aligned with lib-
eral internationalist parties in the past, were now squarely in the nationalist
fold.62 So were newer far-right parties like Britain’s UKIP and Germany’s
AfD.63 Still vociferous backers of military power and strength, after the
Cold War radical-right parties also became ardent foes of international
partnership.
They also became deft practitioners of wedge politics. As discussed in
Chapter 3, radical-right parties were actively using anti-globalism as early
as the 1990s to mobilize voters no longer strongly aligned with Social
Democratic parties and to put Conservative and Christian Democratic
parties on the political defensive.64 By the 2010s, campaigning against trade
liberalization and supranational institutions had become an effective strategy
for winning over working-class voters, especially in regions that were se-
verely impacted by globalization and falling behind economically.65 In the
run-up to the Brexit referendum, UKIP’s Nigel Farage made gains with the
so-called “left behind” in Northern and Eastern England’s aging Rust Belt
cities and towns by fusing the explosive issue of immigration with opposition
to EU membership. In 2017, Marine Le Pen ran for the French presidency
merging the FN’s long-standing opposition to mass immigration with a new
“strategic plan for reindustrialization” aimed directly at regions of France’s
north and east hard-hit by globalization.66
Their efforts did not catapult them into national government, but they did
succeed in putting mainstream parties on the defensive and, importantly,
capturing a larger share of the electorate. Indeed, the more issues of trade
liberalization and supranationalism were debated, the more radical-right
parties stood to benefit. Evidence for this can be found in more detailed
quantitative analysis of whether a given party’s platform position on inter-
national partnership and military power before a national election improves
or hurts its performance (vote share) in the election. Our baseline models
in Figures 4.8 and 4.9 pool all parties, countries, and years in the Manifesto
Project data (1950–2017), and control for all party families, decades, and
country fixed effects. We also control for a given party’s other manifesto
positions on a left-versus-right ideological scale to better isolate the possible
electoral effects of its stance on partnership and power.67 We expected that,
all things being equal (e.g., in the absence of a corollary commitment to ex-
pand social protections), parties that were more supportive of international
15.6
15.41%
15.4
Party’s vote share
15.2
15
14.9%
14.8
15.35%
Party’s vote share
15.2
15
14.9%
14.8
−6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6
Party platform support for liberal internationalism
−4 −2 0 2 4
Party platform support for international partnership
15.6
−4 −2 0 2 4
Party platform support for military power
16
−5 0 5
Party platform support for partnership+power
Figure 4.9 Relationship between social protection, foreign policy, and party
vote share in Western democracies, 1950–2017
Reaping the Whirlwind 107
partnership would be punished at the ballot box, while parties more opposed
to partnership would be rewarded.
This is, in fact, what we see in Figure 4.8. While there is low correlation
between a given party’s support for military spending and preparedness
(power; middle panel) and that party’s share of the national vote (party vote
share) in the ensuing election, a party’s support for trade, international
institutions, and multilateralism (partnership; top panel) correlates signifi-
cantly and negatively with its subsequent electoral performance. In general,
parties supporting partnership lose votes. By contrast, opposing partnership
increases their vote share. This pattern applies for the entire 1950–2017 time
period, but, notably, the electoral rewards for parties opposing partnership
have increased since the end of the Cold War.68 This same pattern is evident
for liberal internationalism (partnership +power; bottom panel), but does
not hold up for party support of power.
Figure 4.9 takes things a step further by considering how sensitive the
correlations reported in Figure 4.8 are to the presence or absence of social
protection. In Chapter 2, we showed that voters are more inclined to sup-
port liberal internationalism when social protections are robust, as they were
during the Cold War in the advanced industrialized economies. Here, we
consider whether this commitment to social democracy made voters more
likely to vote for parties supporting liberal internationalism. To answer
this question, we interacted social protection with liberal internationalism
(partnership +power; bottom panel) and partnership (top panel) and power
(middle panel), separately.69 The model is based on the same specifications
as the models in Figure 4.8, though now we add these interactive terms.
Figure 4.9 compares the counterfactual results, with two schedules in each
of the three panels: a light-shaded schedule, where the level of social pro-
tection is modest (at the sample’s 10th percentile of social protection); and a
dark-shaded schedule, where social protection is strong (at the sample’s 90th
percentile).70
The results we see in Figure 4.9 are clear-cut. In countries where social
protection is robust, parties running on platforms favoring partnership and
power do not pay an electoral price. Indeed, parties calling for increased
military spending and preparedness gain vote share, provided strong social
protections are in place. By contrast, in countries where social protection is
modest, a party running on the same liberal internationalist platform can ex-
pect to experience a sharp decline in its vote share, all else equal. These results
are consistent with an extensive literature in comparative and international
108 Geopolitics and Democracy
political economy that shows that governments and parties that act to miti-
gate the uneven distributional effects of economic openness are rewarded by
voters, while those that do not are punished at the ballot box.71 However, the
results in Figure 4.9, show that this holds for military spending as well. This
suggests that voters are sensitive to guns-versus-butter trade-offs, and that all
things being equal, prefer both. More broadly, the analysis here indicates that
political parties investing in partnership or power will suffer at the polls un-
less liberal order-building and social protection go hand-in-hand.
It is here, at the intersection of international and domestic politics, that
Western governments, and the mainstream parties leading them, lost their
way and opened the door to populist and nationalist parties once on the
fringes of party democracy. To be sure, the factors mentioned earlier, such as
automation, mass migration, economic inequality, have also contributed to
the rise of radical-right parties and the decline of mainstream parties. A case
can be made that many of these are having effects picked up in our meas-
ures. It is also important to bear in mind that while statistically significant,
the negative correlation between partnership (and partnership +power) and
party vote share are modest, with the full sample variation in Figures 4.8 and
4.9 predicting no more than a 0.7 percent shift in vote share. All of that said,
the results reported in Figures 4.8 and 4.9 are robust to a number of model
specifications.72 The results are also consistent with country-level aggregate
analyses that show that the size of the gaps between governments and voters
over foreign policy correlate positively with radical parties’ electoral success
and negatively with mainstream party performance at the polls.73 Minimally,
what these results tell us is that liberal order-building no longer affords main-
stream parties the electoral advantages it once did, and that radical-right
parties have found a powerful weapon in anti-globalism to challenge the au-
thority of Western democracies’ vital center.
A DECLINING ASSET
had much less to say about how changes in the distribution of political au-
thority and power within countries affect the possibilities for cooperation be-
tween them. Political polarization and democratic backsliding in the West
has exposed the limits of viewing the liberal order as though it is suspended
above domestic politics. As we have shown, party democracy has shaped the
possibilities of international cooperation between Western governments
since the inception of the postwar liberal order. In this section, we consider
how the erosion of political authority in Western democracies is impacting
the liberal order today.
During the Cold War, party democracy was a force multiplier for Western
governments in international politics. The stability, legitimacy, and effective-
ness of the mainstream parties that made up the vital center was a source
of Western strength and international influence. Western leaders had little
reason to worry that party and party-coalition turnover in the two dozen
democracies that formed the core of the liberal order would lead those
governments to renege on international commitments undertaken by their
predecessors, or at least far less than they do today. This did not mean that
mainstream parties within Western democracies were always in agreement
with one another, or that elections never produced foreign policy reversals.
Social Democrats emphasized liberal internationalism’s commitment to
partnership; Conservatives, put the accent on power. But in general, alter-
nation in power between the mainstream parties did not bring radical shifts
in governments’ commitments to partnership and power. Indeed, scholars
have argued that the robustness of foreign policy commitments to demo-
cratic deliberation and party turnover within Western democracies was a
critical source of their international credibility.75 At a time of great anxiety
about Soviet ambitions and the risk of nuclear war, party democracy was a
foreign policy asset, bolstering Western collective purpose and resolve and
strengthening the liberal order’s domestic foundations.
Western democracies did not always see eye-to-eye, of course, and liberal
order-building did not move in a straight line. There were setbacks and incon-
sistencies (e.g., high tariffs on agricultural goods, France’s 1966 decision to
opt out of NATO’s integrated military command). Fears of American dom-
ination and abandonment were never very far from the surface in Europe
110 Geopolitics and Democracy
International openness
Figure 4.10 tracks the level of international openness based on KOF’s most
comprehensive measure of globalization. It measures actual economic, polit-
ical, and sociocultural globalization flows at the country level for our sample
of twenty-four OECD nations from 1970 through 2018. We see clearly that
globalization steadily increased from the early 1970s until the mid-2000s,
when it slowed and leveled off. The trend here closely parallels the steady
112 Geopolitics and Democracy
80
KOF index of de facto globalization
60 65 70 75
78
KOF index of de facto globalization
76
74
72
70
68
Global governance
If globalization has slowed in the face of Western domestic fragmentation,
efforts to expand multilateral governance have stalled outright. Figure 4.12
tracks the growth of international authority from 1950 through 2019 for
twenty-five international organizations where Western democracies are ac-
tive members.83 We use the MIA database’s three scales to capture differences
in the scope, form, and level of authority states lodge in international gov-
ernmental institutions.84 These include the extent to which states delegate
authority to international institutions, jointly pool authority in international
organizations, and international bodies have the authority to resolve or settle
disputes among their member states. We see in Figure 4.12 that, after a rela-
tively brief increase in the 1990s, the amount of international authority in two
of the three indicators levels off in the 2000s, with little subsequent growth in
international intergovernmental authority over the next two decades.
In estimating the association between party- system fragmentation
and international authority, we focus on how strongly an international
institution’s authority in a given year correlates with its authority in the pre-
ceding year.85 The results of the time series analysis are summarized in the
top panel in Figure 4.13.86 They offer considerable support for our argu-
ment. The more Western party systems fragment in a given year, the less au-
thority Western governments are willing to delegate or pool in international
institutions, on average. The relationship between party-system fragmenta-
tion and international dispute settlement is also negative. However, it is not
114 Geopolitics and Democracy
.36
.4
IO delegation and settlement scales
Dispute
.35
settlement
.34
Pooling
.3
.33
.32
.25
Delegating
.31
.2
.29 .3
.15
Party−system fragmentation
(annual first-difference) and ...
Delegation
Pooled
sovereignty
Dispute−
settlement
International
authority com-
posite index
−1 −.5 0
IO delegation & pooled sovereignty*
.005
Delegation
score
0
Pooled sovereignty
score
−.005
.9
−1.4
Similarity
score
−1.6
.8
−1.8
.7
Agreement
score
.6
−2
−2.2
.5
Figure 4.14 tracks the level of voting similarity between Western and non-
Western states between 1950 and 2020 using two separate but related meas-
ures: “voting agreement” and “ideal-point similarity.”88 The first is simply the
share of all votes cast by our sample of twenty-four Western states that are in
agreement with non-Western states.89 The “ideal-point similarity” index is
based on a model of similarity of broader voting patterns in a given year (here
recalculated for similarity between Western and non-Western states). We see
that ideal-point similarity between Western and non-Western countries has
increased considerably since a low point in the 1970s and 1980s. The trend
is more stable over time when using the voting agreement measure, though
here, too, since the 1990s the level of voting agreement between the West
and the rest is above the historic norm dating back to the 1950s. However,
by either standard we see a marked softening in voting “likeness” between
Western and non-Western states since the 1990s. The pattern is evident by
the early 1990s in the voting agreement index, and by the mid-2000s using
the ideal-point similarity measure.90
Did political fragmentation within Western democracies contribute to
this leveling off in voting likeness between the West and the rest? In Figure
4.15, we summarize the results of a regression analysis of the relationship be-
tween party fragmentation and UN voting similarity between Western and
non-Western states.91 We expect the pattern of voting agreement and ideal-
point similarity to be negatively correlated with party fragmentation, even
Reaping the Whirlwind 117
.8
Voting agreement with West
Chance that any non-Western
.75
country votes with a given
Western country
.7
.65
after controlling for the influence of other factors.92 The top panel shows the
results for the basic “voting agreement” scores. We see that higher party frag-
mentation does, in fact, result in lower rates of agreement between Western
and non-Western countries. The correlation is statistically significant, and
the substantive associations are quite substantial. The full sample variation
in fragmentation “explains” roughly 35 percent of the variation in UN voting
agreement (from the roughly 25th to 60th percentiles in the sample distribu-
tion of non-Western agreement). In the bottom panel, we see the same nega-
tive pattern for ideal-point similarity, even if it is less significant, statistically
118 Geopolitics and Democracy
The 1990s were a high-water mark for the West’s confidence in itself. Many
commentators viewed the collapse of the Soviet Union and communism in
Eastern Europe as a victory for liberalism and open economies.94 The end of
the Cold War, they argued, represented the permanent victory of liberal de-
mocracy and capitalism over the forces of illiberalism and nationalism. Great
hopes were pinned on the new European Union’s communitarian spirit,
the promise of a more open, integrated world order that included China,
the former communist countries of Central and Eastern Europe, and other
emerging economies, and America’s capacity to consolidate, protect, and ex-
tend democracy and markets across the globe.
Today, those Western visions of the future look dated and off-target.
Western prognosticators significantly underestimated the extent to which
nations outside the Western-led system would resist efforts to globalize lib-
eral norms, laws, and institutions. They also greatly overestimated Western
democracies’ political capacity to support such a far-reaching global agenda.
In the absence of a renewed commitment to social democracy, Western
governments’ turn toward globalism after the Cold War weakened the lib-
eral order’s vital center by giving insurgent parties and movements a potent
Reaping the Whirlwind 119
wedge issue to peel off disillusioned voters and put mainstream parties on
the political defensive. As support for the vital center declined, and Western
democracies became more fragmented, disjointed, and volatile, the liberal
order itself has fractured.
New fault lines have emerged over how best to tame the disruptive forces
of globalization and to guarantee international security in a world rapidly
devolving into competing power centers. Western political fragmentation
and volatility have also exposed new vulnerabilities, as illiberal states have
sought to capitalize on these divisions by stoking nationalism and fomenting
unrest within the West. Once mutually reinforcing, party politics and lib-
eral order are now pulling Western democracies in opposite directions.
This brings us to the West’s current predicament. Given the intensity of the
domestic pressures now confronting Western democracies, any hope of
bringing international ends and domestic means back into balance must
start from within. The West must find ways to renew the liberal order’s do-
mestic purposes and legitimacy. We take up this issue in the next chapter.
5
Bridging the Gap
Writing in the midst of World War II, Walter Lippmann argued that the key
to successful international statecraft involves keeping ends and means in
balance. “In foreign relations,” Lippmann wrote, “a nation must maintain its
objectives and its power in equilibrium, its purposes within its means and
its means equal to its purposes.” When nations fail to balance international
commitments and national capabilities, Lippmann added, they “will follow
a course that leads to disaster.”1 International relations scholars and foreign
policy analysts often equate Lippmann’s means to military and economic
capabilities, but as Lippmann himself argued, a country’s political “solvency”
is often more critical to effective statecraft than its material means.
Today, Western democracies are suffering from a “Lippmann gap.”2
A large gulf has opened up between Western governments’ internationalist
ambitions and their domestic political capacity to support them. Donald
Trump’s presidency, Britain’s decision to leave the European Union, and the
spread of anti-globalist parties and movements in Europe are the most visible
signs of this gap. Yet, as we have shown in this book, today’s anti-globalist
backlash represents an intensification of a process that has been gathering
strength in Western democracies for three decades now, unbowed by ter-
rorism, pandemic, or war. The many commentators who view Russia’s inva-
sion of Ukraine as a watershed moment in the reaffirmation of the Western
alliance may be proven right in time, but if so, it will be because Western
leaders capitalized on the moment by rebuilding the domestic foundations of
the liberal international order.
As we have seen, the erosion of domestic support for the liberal order in
Western democratic polities took shape in the aftermath of the Cold War,
and at the height of Western optimism about the future. In the ensuing years,
as Western leaders deepened their nations’ commitment to economic inte-
gration and institutionalized cooperation while loosening long-standing so-
cial protections, domestic support for these foreign policies weakened. Once
a wellspring of domestic consensus and coalition-building, foreign policy
became a source of political disruption and fragmentation within the West.
Geopolitics and Democracy. Peter Trubowitz and Brian Burgoon, Oxford University Press.
© Oxford University Press 2023. DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780197535400.003.0005
Bridging the Gap 121
Mainstream parties lost ground to parties on the far left and especially to the
anti-globalist right. The gap between Western governments and voters over
foreign policy continued to widen. Today, the domestic political foundations
of the Western liberal international order are a pale shadow of what they
were at the height of the Cold War. The West overreached.
The West’s failure to keep international ends and domestic means in bal-
ance is not a classic case of imperial overreach. The anti-globalism roiling the
advanced democracies is not a backlash against far-flung empires, bloated
military establishments, or endless wars on the periphery. It has more to
do with Western leaders’ overreliance on global markets and international
institutions than with war and military expansion. As we have shown, since
the end of the Cold War, Western governments failed to maintain high levels
of social protection to compensate for the disruptive effects of capitalist
growth in an era of hyperglobalization. This eroded public confidence in the
liberal order and created opportunities for new politicians and new parties
to win over disaffected and angry voters. Freed of Cold War imperatives,
nationalist parties in Western countries turned liberalized trade, European
integration, and national sovereignty into potent wedge issues against main-
stream political leaders and parties.
This has proved costly for the West, domestically as well as internationally.
Domestically, the fragmentation of Western party systems made it harder for
Western governments to marshal the political power and authority required
to deliver on issues their citizens care most about. This fuels voter dissatisfac-
tion which, in turn, leads to greater fragmentation, paralysis, and dysfunc-
tion. Internationally, domestic fragmentation has slowed the pace of liberal
order-building and eroded confidence in the West. China and Russia have
been quick to seize on the erosion of support for Western international lead-
ership to promote alternative, illiberal visions of politics and society and to
test Western resolve. Many factors contributed to Putin’s invasion of Ukraine,
but one was surely the belief that Western democracies were too internally
divided and polarized to respond collectively and programmatically.
In this concluding chapter, we discuss the implications of Western over-
reach, and the strategies now on offer to bring ends and means back into
balance. We begin by summarizing our main findings on how Western
governments’ approach to international order-building has changed over the
past seventy-five years and how this resulted in the anti-globalist backlash we
see across the West today. We compare and contrast our analysis of Western
overreach, anti-globalism, and political fragmentation to other explanations.
122 Geopolitics and Democracy
All foreign policy strategies involve choices. Leaders must decide how much
to rely on partnership, and how heavily to invest in power. They must decide
how much to subordinate national autonomy to international markets and
pooled sovereignty, and how much to spend on military power (guns) versus
on domestically oriented policies and programs (butter). International rela-
tions scholars and foreign policy analysts writing about world politics and
foreign policy typically focus on one dimension or the other: on partnership,
or on power. There are obvious economies in doing so. Yet, as we have shown,
widening the field of vision to include both of these key dimensions of inter-
national statecraft in a single framework offers real payoffs. We have used
this framework to track the evolution of the liberal order from its postwar
inception to the current crisis, and to test our arguments about the origins,
timing, and extent of Western overreach across twenty-four OECD countries
and four hundred political parties.
The Western-led liberal order has changed in far-reaching ways since its in-
ception seventy-five years ago. During the Cold War era, the United States,
Europe, and most of the rest of the OECD shared a vision of international
order-building that rested on a robust commitment to both international
partnership and military power. At once liberal and realist, the Western-
led order balanced the demands of geopolitics and social democracy, and
international openness and national autonomy. The social democrats,
liberals, Christian democrats, and conservatives that dominated Western
governments advanced liberal internationalist policies knowing that
those policies would enjoy broad public support and, in turn, pay electoral
dividends for them. For over half a century, what was good for liberal inter-
nationalism was good for party democracy, and vice versa.
Bridging the Gap 123
The Western liberal order that took form in the postwar era was not a mon-
olith, of course. Western democracies did not move in lockstep. At any given
time, there was significant cross-national variation in levels of government
support for partnership and power along the liberal order’s Atlantic and
Pacific axes, and across party families within the liberal order’s many democ-
racies. Western leaders combined partnership and power in varying ways,
and to varying degrees, due to differences in their country’s geopolitical, do-
mestic, and historical circumstances. Yet to an extent that even the most opti-
mistic postwar planners did not anticipate, the Western liberal order became
more open, integrated, and institutionalized. America, Britain, France, West
Germany, and most other Western democracies all came to display a level of
commitment to partnership and power that sharply distinguished the West
from the rest, and that would endure through the Cold War.
What seemed to many like a virtuous cycle between foreign policy and
party democracy in Western democracies did not last. The first cracks in lib-
eral internationalism’s domestic foundations appeared in the 1980s, when
Western governments’ turn to neoliberalism in response to the crisis of
the 1970s set in motion forces that would weaken the liberal order’s party
foundations. However, it was not until the Cold War ended that the virtuous
cycle between foreign policy and party democracy broke down. In the 1990s,
Western governments shifted from a strategy of liberal internationalism that
combined power with partnership, to a strategy of globalism that relied in-
creasingly on market forces without corresponding investments in social
protections and economic security for their citizens.
Domestic support did not keep stride, however. As we have seen, that
support has eroded most starkly in the European democracies, but similar
patterns emerged in America, Japan, and in most OECD countries. Across
the West, a gap opened up between governments and voters over globalism.
Anti-globalist parties successfully exploited these gaps. Support for radical
left and radical right parties grew steadily in the 2000s, and then swelled in
the wake of the 2008 financial crisis. At the same time, globalism became a
source of contestation and division within mainstream parties themselves.
The Tea Party faction of the Republican party in the United States and the
Brexit faction within Britain’s Conservative party broke with the majority
over foreign policy.
By the time Donald Trump launched his campaign for the presidency
in 2015, the virtuous cycle between foreign policy and party democ-
racy in Western democracies had broken down. Parties and candidates
124 Geopolitics and Democracy
partnership and power was not only considered wise statecraft, it was good
politics too. A foreign policy strategy that relied solely on one or the other
risked alienating center left or center right voters. In short, liberal interna-
tionalism was a Goldilocks solution: just the right mix of liberalism and re-
alism, integration and autonomy, and partnership and power.
Cold War imperatives gave Western governments and voters reason to
support liberal internationalism. So did the generous social protections
that were part and parcel of the postwar welfare state. The nature of these
social protections and welfare provisions varied across the OECD, but the
different types of welfare models—social democratic, Christian democratic,
and liberal—shared common values of full employment, social security, and
increasing social equality. The idea that governments were responsible for
balancing free markets and economic security was widely accepted, as was
the principle that wealth should be redistributed from those that benefited
the most from greater economic growth to those who did not. These social
bargains limited how far Western governments could open up their econ-
omies to trade and capital flows, or transfer decision-making authority to
international bodies. They also helped cushion the free market’s disruptive
effects, while allowing industry, workers, and farmers to reap the benefits of
increased exports and imports. Mainstream parties’ commitment to these
social bargains and understandings secured the votes of critical working-
class voters during the Cold War who might otherwise have backed parties
on the far left.
Consensus did not mean unanimity within or between the liberal order’s
members, and every crisis generated new predictions of imminent Western
decline. During the Cold War, the most serious test of Western democra-
cies’ commitment to liberal internationalism was the crisis that unfolded
in the 1970s. The end of the postwar boom and the rise of US-Soviet stra-
tegic parity raised new doubts at the elite and mass levels about the postwar
liberal order’s ability to continue delivering prosperity and security. A rift
opened between center left and center right parties over its causes and how
best to restore growth and enhance security. The crisis was ultimately re-
solved in the 1980s on terms favorable to the center right. Center left parties
began shifting course, moving toward the right. International markets were
liberalized, security alliances were strengthened, and social protections
were reined in. Political allegiances and alignments that had defined
Western party democracy for decades frayed, but they did not unravel. The
center held.
126 Geopolitics and Democracy
key elements of the far left and far right’s agenda. Center left parties have be-
come increasingly Green in hopes of winning over younger, educated voters.
Center right parties have become more nationalist and nativist, and in many
cases more protectionist. At the height of the Cold War, parties on the center
left and center right had more in common with each other than they did with
the parties further toward the political extremes. Today, in many cases, this
is no longer true.
Sources of fragmentation
of the Cold War weakened mainstream parties’ support for social protec-
tion, and for the welfare state more generally, in Western democracies.7 For
much of the Cold War, the rivalry between the capitalist West and the Soviet
bloc encouraged both sides of the East-West divide to spend unprecedented
sums on social welfare to demonstrate the superiority of their “system” and
to gain popular support and legitimacy in the struggle. With the end of the
Cold War, an important strategic impetus for Western welfare state growth
disappeared.
The analysis also sheds new light on the fragmentation of Western party
systems. Much of the current debate among scholars specializing in com-
parative party politics is focused on whether economic or cultural causes
best explain the decline of mainstream parties and the concomitant rise of
populist and nationalist parties. This analytic distinction has its limits. The
differences between explanations that stress the consequences of globaliza-
tion, technological change, and economic inequality on those “left behind”
and “cultural backlash” theories that emphasize parochialism, nationalism,
and nativism as drivers are often overdrawn. Both explanations point to
voters’ feelings of social marginalization and their resentment against polit-
ical elites, government bureaucracies, and “foreigners.”8 Moreover, political
discontent does not find its fullest political expression on its own. The story
of anti-globalism’s rise since the end of the Cold War is not only one of pop-
ular demands for social redress. It is also about how political entrepreneurs
and parties on the fringes of Western party systems successfully tapped and
mobilized popular discontent.9
The politics of anti-globalism can be read as a textbook case of how parties
and party leaders actively try to mobilize and demobilize voters to gain and
hold on to power. As the ties between mainstream parties and working-
class voters frayed in the 1990s, parties on the far left and especially the far
right sought to capitalize on this opening by using anti-globalism to reach
out to these newly unattached voters. In the case of radical right parties, it
meant abandoning long-held laissez-faire platform positions concerning
international trade in favor of economic nationalism and protectionism.
Meanwhile, in a world where the West faced no peer challenger, voters were
more open and amenable to radical parties’ foreign policy appeals. In hind-
sight, it is clear that Western leaders seriously misjudged this electoral threat.
By doubling down on globalization while they were putting the brakes on the
growth of the welfare state and eliminating legislation favorable to unions,
political leaders fed a slow-burning fire. Western democracies have paid a
Bridging the Gap 131
heavy price for the failure of their leaders to keep international ends and do-
mestic means in balance.
DRIFT OR MASTERY
Can Western leaders bring foreign and domestic policy back into balance?
Is it possible for Western governments to renew their commitment to the
liberal order without fueling further division within their societies? In this
concluding section, we consider three strategies for easing this tension and
bridging the gap between international ends and domestic means. Discussion
around these choices is already underway. One option is for Western democ-
racies to scale back international commitments to keep the West’s interna-
tional expectations in line with what domestic politics will currently allow.
A second approach is to use Great Power confrontation with China and
Russia to rekindle Western solidarity and revive domestic support for liberal
internationalism. A third strategy is to attack the ends-means problem from
the domestic side by investing in a strategy of economic renewal, and thereby
gird the West for the return of geopolitics.
Strategic retrenchment
The idea that Western democracies can bring international ends and do-
mestic means back into equilibrium through strategic retrenchment is an al-
luring one. The argument is especially well-rehearsed in the United States,
where an entire school of thought—the “restraint” school—calls on America
to reduce its international commitments in Europe, Asia, and elsewhere.10
Made up of conservative libertarians, anti-imperialist progressives, and
balance-of-power realists, the restraint coalition claims that the mainstream
foreign policy establishment’s preoccupation with promoting “liberal he-
gemony” has led America astray. Under the guise of liberal order, Democratic
and Republican presidents alike have invested far too much blood and
treasure in parts of the world that are not vital to America’s core national
interests. This encourages wealthy allies to free ride on US military might
and engage in “reckless driving.”11 It also fuels insecurity among states who
are suspicious of US and Western motives. “Restrainers” argue that Putin’s
invasion of Ukraine was the direct result of American and European efforts
132 Geopolitics and Democracy
to expand NATO into Russia’s Near Abroad.12 The United States, restrainers
argue, would be better served by a strategy of “off-shore balancing,” where
American power is reserved for rare occasions when regional balances of
power fail and an onshore US military presence is needed to check an ag-
gressor and restore stability.13
A strategy dedicated to reeling in US security commitments is guaranteed
to set off alarm bells among America’s allies in Asia and Europe. Restrainers
acknowledge this, but they contend that weaning allies off the “American
pacifier” will force them to take more responsibility for their own security.
Meanwhile, restrainers argue that it will reduce the risk that Washington is in-
advertently drawn into regional disputes that have little bearing on America’s
national security, and provide cost savings that might be invested in butter or
used for debt reduction. Many American strategists disagree, arguing that a
strategy of restraint is neither safer nor cheaper, and risks throwing the baby
out with the bathwater. They argue that America’s strategic alliances and
forward presence in Europe and Asia strengthen regional stability, and are
cheaper to maintain than to rebuild once dismantled.14
Whatever its geopolitical advantages, a strategy of restraint stands little
chance of success domestically. One takeaway from our comparative analysis
of Western democracies’ foreign policies since World War II is that grand
strategies are only as stable and durable as the domestic political foundations
they rest on. “Ends-against-the-middle” ideological coalitions like the re-
straint coalition, which straddle positions on the far left and the far right, are
inherently unstable and invariably short-lived.15 Indeed, such coalitions are
rare in Western democracies, and rarer still in two-party systems. Trump’s
America First strategy, which crudely aped many of the restrainers’ core stra-
tegic arguments, failed to win broad-based support not only because of pres-
idential incompetence. It also ran up against the limits of security policies
that appeal only to ideological extremes. Bipartisan consensus may not be a
political prerequisite for programmatic foreign policy change in the United
States, but foreign policies that appeal to a broad cross section of voters are a
prerequisite for durable, programmatic shifts.16
Practical politics aside, restrainers have also misdiagnosed America’s
ailments. As we have shown, the erosion of domestic support for the liberal
order is not unique to America, or due to its overreliance on military power,
however misguided. It stems from the abandonment of managed trade, the
fraying of the social safety net, and overreliance on multilateral governance.
Like their Western counterparts, America’s leaders began betting too heavily
Bridging the Gap 133
Domestic renewal
and losers in Western societies, and heightened the distinction between tra-
ditional blue-collar workers and the rapidly expanding pool of immigrant
labor joining the labor force. In short, rising economic insecurity and ine-
quality eroded the liberal order’s legitimacy within Western democracies.
If Western governments want to restore the liberal order’s social purposes,
renewal’s proponents argue, they must revitalize their commitment to social
democracy.
Our analysis provides empirical support for this interpretation of the pre-
dicament Western democracies now find themselves in. As we have shown,
as government support for social protection weakened, so did domestic sup-
port for liberal order. Yet our analysis has also highlighted the pivotal role that
parties have played as intermediaries in this process, from brokering the in-
itial compromise of embedded liberalism, to its subsequent breakdown over
the turn to neoliberalism and globalism in the 1980s and 1990s, to the anti-
globalist backlash roiling Western democracies today. By bringing political
parties into the analytic frame, we have underscored the extent to which the
social bargain underlying the liberal order is contingent on party democracy.
As mainstream parties’ willingness to support social protection and eco-
nomic inclusiveness wavered, so too did voters’ enthusiasm for international
openness, institutionalized cooperation, and multilateral governance. Once
dismissed as a problem of little strategic significance, the widening chasm
between Western governments and their voters is now a source of Western
international weakness and vulnerability.
Geopolitics can help bridge this ends-means gap, as it did during the long
Cold War. But alone it cannot restore the liberal order’s legitimacy. If Western
leaders hope to rebuild popular support for the liberal order, they must attack
this ends-means problem “from the inside out”—that is, from the domestic
rather than the international side.27 In eras like the present, when traditional
foreign policy remedies (e.g., trade liberalization) have fallen into disfavor
and the domestic coalitions long associated with those foreign policies have
fragmented, political leaders must find new arguments about the necessity of
international openness and institutionalized cooperation and forge new do-
mestic bargains and political alliances to support them. Policy requires pol-
itics. This is the crucial takeaway from our analysis of seventy-five years of
liberal order-building by Western democracies. Today, as in earlier periods
of intense debate and conflict in Western democracies over the proper bal-
ance between foreign and domestic policy, these struggles will be shaped and
influenced by political parties competing for electoral advantage.28
Bridging the Gap 137
What precise shape these political arguments and party alliances might
take is unclear. Much will depend on the ability of political leaders to reim-
agine the relationship between foreign and domestic policy and reconnect
policies in the international realm to recognizable benefits at home. Western
democracies cannot return to the early decades of the postwar liberal order,
but they can look for new ways to renew and update their commitment to
inclusive growth and economic security for their citizens. This will require
innovation in domestic growth regimes centering on strategic localization of
productive activities, investment in human capital, quality-of-life supports,
and environmental sustainability. Some of these processes are already un-
derway in some progressive internationalist policy initiatives within the
OECD. Yet given the depth of the anti-globalist backlash, far more is needed
if Western democracies hope to close the solvency gap. By rebuilding support
for the liberal order from the inside out, such a strategy of renewal would also
put Western democracies on a stronger footing to compete geopolitically in
a world where international power and authority are increasingly contested.
To paraphrase Lippmann, Western democracies’ international purposes
would once again be within their domestic means, and their means equal to
their purposes.
Appendices
APPENDIX A
Summary statistics for country-year and party-year analyses.
(continued)
140 Appendices
Table B.1 Government support for international partnership and military power as a function of social security transfers and geopolitical threat in Western
democracies, 1970−2017 (summarized in main text, Figure 3.2 and Figure 3.8).
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Govt. support Govt. support Govt. support Govt. support Govt. support Govt. support
for partnership for power for partnership + for partnership for power for partnership +
power power
(1) and (4) DV =Government policy support for international partnership (KOF index of globalization policies)
(2) and (5) DV =Government policy support for military power (military spending, % GDP)
(3) and (6) DV =Government policy support for partnership +power (standardized sum of government policy support for partnership and for power)
Models (1)–(3) are OLS coefficients and robust-cluster standard errors (in parentheses) clustered by country. Models (4)–(6) are seemingly unrelated regression with OLS
coefficients and robust-cluster standard errors (in parentheses) clustered by country. Decade and country fixed effects included but not shown.
*** p<0.001, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1 (two-tailed)
Table B.2 Party platform support for international partnership and military power as a function of social security transfers in Western democracies, 1960–
2017 (summarized in main text, Figure 3.3).
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Party Platform Party Platform Party Platform Party platform Party platform Party Platform
partnership power partnership +power partnership power partnership + power
Social security transfers 0.043* 0.053* 0.096** 0.043 0.017 0.059
(0.019) (0.024) (0.029) (0.028) (0.031) (0.048)
Radical-left (RL) −1.12*** −0.9*** −2.02*** −0.981* −2.20*** −3.18***
(0.152) (0.199) (0.256) (0.457) (0.395) (0.676)
Social Democratic (SD) 0.396 −0.121 0.275 0.025 −0.448 −0.423
(0.192) (0.163) (0.296) (0.455) (0.501) (0.66)
Liberal (L) 0.73*** 0.382* 1.112*** 0.539 0.196 0.735
(0.171) (0.143) (0.211) (0.444) (0.292) (0.512)
Christian Democratic (CD) 0.709** 0.421** 1.13*** 0.847 −0.057 0.79
(0.194) (0.138) (0.252) (0.521) (0.477) (0.765)
Conservative (C) 0.544* 0.782*** 1.326** 0.411 0.354 0.765
(0.249) (0.178) (0.38) (0.596) (0.417) (0.832)
Radical-right (RR) −1.039** 0.981*** −0.058 0.043 −0.224 −0.181
(0.273) (0.146) (0.349) (0.819) (0.524) (0.807)
Social security × RL −0.01 0.097** 0.087
(0.034) (0.029) (0.048)
Social security × SD 0.03 0.024 0.053
(0.028) (0.035) (0.045)
Social security × L 0.015 0.014 0.029
(0.034) (0.02) (0.04)
Social security × CD −0.01 0.035 0.025
(0.041) (0.031) (0.055)
Social security × C 0.01 0.032 0.043
(0.048) (0.031) (0.07)
Social security × RR −0.076 0.087* 0.011
(0.06) (0.039) (0.055)
Democracy level 0.115 0.156 0.27 0.119 0.144 0.263
(0.092) (0.092) (0.166) (0.095) (0.09) (0.167)
Trade openness 0.005 0.008** 0.013** 0.005 0.008*** 0.014**
(0.004) (0.002) (0.004) (0.004) (0.002) (0.004)
Unemployment rate −0.016 −0.044** −0.06* −0.013 −0.043* −0.057*
(0.017) (0.015) (0.022) (0.016) (0.016) (0.022)
Avg. vote share 0.006 0.018*** 0.025** 0.006 0.018*** 0.025**
(0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.007) (0.004) (0.008)
Left-right platform −0.014*** 0.01** −0.005 −0.015*** 0.01** −0.005
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
Constant −0.847 −2.595* −3.442* −0.892 −2.004 −2.896
(0.912) (0.979) (1.579) (1.026) (0.996) (1.692)
Country dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Decade dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R-squared 0.397 0.462 0.461 0.401 0.47 0.463
Observations 6935 6935 6935 6935 6935 6935
(1) and (4) DV =Manifesto index of voter support for international partnership
(2) and (5) DV =Manifesto index of voter support for military power
(3) and (6) DV =Manifesto index of voter support for partnership + power
Models are OLS coefficients and robust-cluster standard errors (in parentheses) clustered by country. Decade and country fixed effects included but not shown.
*** p<0.001, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05
Table B.4 Party platform support for international partnership and military power as a function of geopolitical threat in Western democracies, 1960–2015
(summarized in main text, Figure 3.9).
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Party platform: Party Party platform: Party platform: Party platform: Party platform:
partnership platform: power partnership +power partnership power partnership +power
Geopolitical threat 0.156 0.42** 0.576** 0.34 0.328 0.667*
(0.137) (0.115) (0.167) (0.20) (0.159) (0.26)
Radical-left −1.109*** −0.971*** −2.08*** −1.143*** −0.955*** −2.098***
(0.176) (0.212) (0.276) (0.177) (0.222) (0.299)
Social Democratic 0.365 −0.199 0.166 0.311 −0.168 0.143
(0.209) (0.173) (0.319) (0.19) (0.181) (0.308)
Liberal 0.72** 0.325 1.045*** 0.758*** 0.289 1.047***
(0.2) (0.165) (0.237) (0.166) (0.185) (0.221)
Christian Democratic 0.664** 0.349* 1.013** 0.652** 0.374* 1.026**
(0.197) (0.149) (0.268) (0.188) (0.165) (0.276)
Conservative 0.583* 0.758*** 1.341** 0.565* 0.768*** 1.333**
(0.265) (0.193) (0.412) (0.243) (0.196) (0.4)
Radical-right −0.935** 0.936*** 0.001 −1.01* 1.025*** 0.015
(0.297) (0.157) (0.381) (0.403) (0.191) (0.438)
Social security × RL −0.273 0.047 −0.226
(0.171) (0.258) (0.367)
Social security × SD −0.208 0.082 −0.125
(0.173) (0.208) (0.312)
Social security × L 0.211 −0.201 0.01
(0.215) (0.282) (0.335)
Social security × CD 0.053 0.075 0.128
(0.189) (0.217) (0.314)
Social security × C −0.664** 0.351 −0.313
(0.203) (0.23) (0.345)
Social security × RR −0.233 0.298 0.065
(0.867) (0.374) (1.036)
Democracy level 0.101 0.19* 0.291* 0.099 0.191* 0.289*
(0.064) (0.077) (0.118) (0.066) (0.077) (0.114)
Trade openness 0.007 0.01* 0.017* 0.007 0.011** 0.017*
(0.007) (0.004) (0.008) (0.007) (0.004) (0.008)
Unemployment rate 0.011 −0.021 −0.01 0.012 −0.022 −0.01
(0.017) (0.019) (0.027) (0.018) (0.019) (0.028)
Avg. vote share 0.006 0.018** 0.024* 0.006 0.018** 0.024*
(0.007) (0.005) (0.009) (0.006) (0.005) (0.008)
Left-right platform −0.014*** 0.009* −0.006 −0.014*** 0.008* −0.006
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
Constant −0.357 −2.418** −2.775* −0.338 −2.43** −2.768*
(0.64) (0.816) (1.176) (0.639) (0.809) (1.113)
Country dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Decade dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R-squared 0.393 0.457 0.454 0.406 0.462 0.456
Observations 5976 5976 5976 5976 5976 5976
Table B.6 (a–e) Government support for international partnership and military power
as a function of mainstream and radical party vote share in Western democracies,
1970−2017 (summarized in main text, Figure 4.3 and Figure 4.4).
(1) DV =Government policy support for international partnership (KOF index of globalization
policies)
(2) DV =Government policy support for military power (military spending, % GDP)
(3) DV =Government policy support for partnership +power (standardized sum of government
policy support for partnership and for power)
Models are seemingly unrelated regression with OLS coefficients and robust-cluster standard errors
(in parentheses) clustered by country. Decade and country fixed effects included but not shown.
*** p<0.001, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1 (two-tailed)
Appendices 153
Table B.6b Effect of radical-right party vote share on Western government support
for international partnership and military power, 1970–2017.
(1) (2) (3)
Government Government Government
support for support for support for
partnership power partnership +
power
Radical-right vote share −0.002** −0.004* −0.015**
(0.001) (0.002) (0.006)
Past globalization 0.004** −0.004+ 0.007
(0.002) (0.002) (0.007)
Democracy level 0.012** −0.016* −0.004
(0.005) (0.008) (0.024)
Avg. vote share −0.000 0.007* 0.015
(0.002) (0.003) (0.010)
Voter turnout 0.000 0.001 0.004
(0.001) (0.003) (0.008)
Union density −0.003*** −0.001 −0.015*
(0.001) (0.002) (0.006)
Unemployment rate 0.003 0.003 0.021*
(0.002) (0.003) (0.010)
GDP growth 0.002 −0.003 0.002
(0.002) (0.008) (0.022)
Constant 5.016*** 0.000 0.473
(0.162) ( 0) (0.881)
Decade dummies Yes Yes Yes
Country dummies Yes Yes Yes
R-squared 0.866 0.904 0.863
Observations 1043 1043 1043
(1) DV =Government policy support for international partnership (KOF index of globalization
policies)
(2) DV =Government policy support for military power (military spending, % GDP)
(3) DV =Government policy support for partnership +power (standardized sum of government
policy support for partnership and for power)
Models are seemingly unrelated regression with OLS coefficients and robust-cluster standard errors
(in parentheses) clustered by country. Decade and country fixed effects included but not shown.
*** p<0.001, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1 (two-tailed)
154 Appendices
Table B.6c Effect of radical-left party vote share on Western government support
for international partnership and military power, 1970–2017.
(1) (2) (3)
Government Government Government
support for support for support for
partnership power partnership +
power
Radical-left vote share 0.000 0.005** −0.013+
(0.001) (0.002) (0.007)
Past globalization 0.004* −0.005* 0.004
(0.002) (0.002) (0.006)
Democracy level 0.014** −0.014+ 0.005
(0.004) (0.007) (0.021)
Avg. vote share −0.001 0.005+ 0.010
(0.002) (0.003) (0.010)
Voter turnout −0.000 −0.000 0.000
(0.001) (0.002) (0.008)
Union density −0.003** −0.000 −0.012*
(0.001) (0.002) (0.006)
Unemployment rate 0.002 0.003 0.020+
(0.002) (0.003) (0.010)
GDP growth 0.002 −0.002 0.007
(0.002) (0.008) (0.023)
Constant 5.048*** 0.000 0.000
(0.183) ( 0) ( 0)
Decade dummies Yes Yes Yes
Country dummies Yes Yes Yes
R-squared 0.859 0.904 0.856
Observations 1043 1043 1043
(1) DV =Government policy support for international partnership (KOF index of globalization
policies)
(2) DV =Government policy support for military power (military spending, % GDP)
(3) DV =Government policy support for partnership +power (standardized sum of government
policy support for partnership and for power)
Models are seemingly unrelated regression with OLS coefficients and robust-cluster standard errors
(in parentheses) clustered by country. Decade and country fixed effects included but not shown.
*** p<0.001, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1 (two-tailed)
Appendices 155
Table B.6d Effect of radical party vote share (radical-left plus radical-right parties)
on Western government support for international partnership and military power,
1970–2017.
(1) (2) (3)
Government Government Government
support for support for support for
partnership power partnership +power
All radical vote share −0.001* −0.004*** −0.014***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.004)
Past globalization 0.004* −0.004+ 0.006
(0.001) (0.002) (0.006)
Democracy level 0.013** −0.017* −0.004
(0.004) (0.007) (0.022)
Avg. vote share −0.001 0.006* 0.014
(0.002) (0.003) (0.010)
Voter turnout 0.000 0.001 0.004
(0.001) (0.002) (0.008)
Union density −0.003*** −0.001 −0.015**
(0.001) (0.002) (0.006)
Unemployment rate 0.003 0.003 0.021*
(0.002) (0.003) (0.010)
GDP growth 0.002 −0.003 0.004
(0.002) (0.007) (0.021)
Constant 5.041*** 1.339*** 0.0001
(0.164) (0.283) (0.001)
Decade dummies Yes Yes Yes
Country dummies Yes Yes Yes
R-squared 0.863 0.907 0.866
Observations 1043 1043 1043
(1) DV =Government policy support for international partnership (KOF index of globalization
policies)
(2) DV =Government policy support for military power (military spending, % GDP)
(3) DV =Government policy support for partnership +power (standardized sum of government
policy support for partnership and for power)
Models are seemingly unrelated regression with OLS coefficients and robust-cluster standard errors
(in parentheses) clustered by country. Decade and country fixed effects included but not shown.
*** p<0.001, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1 (two-tailed)
156 Appendices
Table B.6e Effect of net mainstream vote share (mainstream vote share minus all radical
vote share) on Western government support for international partnership and military
power, 1970−2017.
(1) (2) (3)
Government Government Government
support for support for support for
partnership power partnership +power
Net mainstream vote share 0.001* 0.001*** 0.005***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.001)
Past globalization 0.004* −0.005+ 0.005
(0.002) (0.002) (0.006)
Democracy level 0.012** −0.017* −0.005
(0.004) (0.008) (0.021)
Avg. vote share −0.001 0.006* 0.011
(0.002) (0.003) (0.011)
Voter turn out 0.000 0.000 0.002
(0.001) (0.002) (0.008)
Union density −0.003*** −0.001 −0.014*
(0.001) (0.002) (0.006)
Unemployment rate 0.003 0.004 0.023*
(0.002) (0.003) (0.010)
GDP growth 0.002 −0.003 0.002
(0.002) (0.008) (0.022)
Constant 0.000 0.000 0.368
( 0) ( 0) (0.869)
Decade dummies Yes Yes Yes
Country dummies Yes Yes Yes
R-squared 0.862 0.904 0.862
Observations 1043 1043 1043
(1) DV =Government policy support for international partnership (KOF index of globalization policies)
(2) DV =Government policy support for military power (military spending, % GDP)
(3) DV =Government policy support for partnership +power (standardized sum of government policy
support for partnership and for power)
Models are seemingly unrelated regression with OLS coefficients and robust-cluster standard errors (in
parentheses) clustered by country. Decade and country fixed effects included but not shown.
*** p<0.001, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1 (two-tailed)
Appendices 157
Table B.7 Party vote share as a function of party platform support for international
partnership and military power in Western democracies, 1960−2017 (summarized in the
main text, Figure 4.8).
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Vote share Vote share Vote share Vote share Vote share Vote share
Party platform support −0.06* −0.086**
for partnership (0.023) (0.029)
Party platform support −0.005 0.007
for power (0.023) (0.032)
Party platform support −0.034* −0.048*
for partnership +power (0.013) (0.02)
Cold War dummy −0.254** −0.159* −0.209**
(0.083) (0.074) (0.073)
Platform × Cold 0.058* −0.021 0.025+
War
period (0.031) (0.024) (0.018)
(continued)
158 Appendices
(continued)
Table B.8 Continued
DV models given by column heading. Models are OLS coefficients and robust-cluster standard errors (in parentheses) clustered by country. Decade and country fixed
effects included but not shown.
*** p<0.001, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05, +p<0.10
Table B.10 (a–c) International organization (IO) authority as a function of party-system
fragmentation in Western democracies, 1960−2018 (summarized in the main text,
Figure 4.13).
Table B.10a Time series analysis of authority measures in twenty-five IOs with strong
Western membership, 1960–2018.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
∆ Delegation ∆ Pooling ∆ Dispute- ∆ IO authority
settlement
∆ Party-system −0.137** −0.174** −0.064 −0.655**
fragmentation (0.048) (0.065) (0.12) (0.231)
Constant 0.001 0 0.002 0.005
(0.001) ( 0) (0.002) (0.005)
AR(1) 0.724** 0.323 0.611 0.736*
(0.238) (0.404) (0.653) (0.37)
MA(1) −0.472 −0.797** −0.507 −0.584
(0.27) (0.256) (0.661) (0.395)
Sigma: const. 0.003*** 0.003*** 0.008*** 0.016***
( 0) ( 0) ( 0) (0.001)
Log likelihood 240.9 250.9 200.5 251.2
Observations 57 57 57 57
Table B.10b Time series analysis of authority measures in thirty-five IOs with little
Western membership, 1960−2018.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
∆ Delegation ∆ Pooling ∆ Dispute- ∆ IO authority
settlement
∆ Party-system 0.001 0.139 −0.32 0.147
fragmentation (0.125) (0.15) (0.353) (0.743)
Constant 0.002 0 0.004* 0.007
(0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.009)
AR(1) 0.807** −0.916*** −0.813*** 0.849***
(0.25) (0.078) (0.132) (0.24)
MA(1) −0.623 1 1 −0.677
(0.355) ( 0) (104.713) (0.357)
Sigma: constant 0.005*** 0.006*** 0.011 0.029***
( 0) ( 0) (0.563) (0.002)
Log likelihood 200.9 198.9 188.5 179.2
Observations 57 57 57 57
APPENDIX C
List of parties in Western countries by party family.
Table D.1 Government support for liberal internationalism (partnership +power, categorical) as a function of social protection and geopolitical
threat in Western democracies, 1970−2015 (see discussion of Figures 3.1 and 3.2 in main text).
(1) (2) (3)
Liberal Liberal Outcome 1: Outcome 2: Outcome 3:
Internationalism Internationalism Isolationism Nationalism Globalism
relative to liberal relative to liberal relative to liberal
internationalism internationalism internationalism
Social transfers (% GDP) 0.82*** 0.985*** 0.312 −0.481** −0.721*
(0.146) (0.171) (0.399) (0.176) (0.347)
Geopolitical threat −0.324 −1.306 0.437 −2.301 −4.118
(1.173) (1.113) (1.973) (1.314) (2.106)
Democracy level 9.539** 13.424*** −1.383 −2.638*** −1.042
(3.225) (3.827) (0.992) (0.639) (1.248)
Trade openness −0.119*** −0.152*** 0.195** 0.035 0.193**
(0.029) (0.033) (0.074) (0.042) (0.073)
Avg. party vote −0.415** −0.501** −0.295 0.171 −0.303
(0.16) (0.155) (0.21) (0.112) (0.244)
Voter turnout 0.215*** 0.163* 0.019 0.15 −0.631***
(0.058) (0.066) (0.162) (0.078) (0.181)
Union density −0.172*** −0.185*** −0.075 0.061 0.229*
(0.048) (0.042) (0.097) (0.053) (0.095)
(continued)
Table D.1 Continued
Models (1) and (2): DV =Government policy support for liberal internationalism (1 =KOF globalization policies>median AND military spending>median; 0 =KOF
policies and/or military spending<median)
Model (3): DV =Government policy support for liberal internationalism in categories (1 =lower-than-median KOF policies and lower-than-median military spending;
2 =lower-than-median KOF policies and higher-than-median military spending; 3 =higher-than-median KOF policies and lower-than-median military spending;
4 =higher-than-median KOF policies and higher-than-median military spending)
Model (1) is logistic regression with country and decade dummies (not shown).
Model (2) is multi-level random intercept logistic regression with country as level 2, country-year as level 1, with decade dummies (not shown).
Model (3) is multinomial logit with baseline value being outcome 4 (liberal internationalism =high government support for partnership and high government support
for power).
Table D.2 Government support for liberal internationalism (partnership +power, categorical) as a function of net mainstream vote share in Western
democracies, 1970−2017 (relevant to Figure 4.1).
(1) (2) (3)
Liberal Liberal Outcome 1: Outcome 2: Outcome 3:
internationalism internationalism Isolationism relative Nationalism relative Globalism relative to lib.
to lib. int’lsm. to lib. int’lsm int’lsm
Net mainstream vote 0.037*** 0.045*** −0.024*** −0.029*** −0.019***
(0.01) (0.012) (0.004) (0.005) (0.004)
Democracy level 9.454* 9.888** 0.763*** −0.177 0.946***
(4.149) (3.218) (0.159) (0.093) (0.162)
Trade openness −0.143*** −0.154*** 0.011*** −0.008* 0.02***
(0.021) (0.026) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003)
Avg. party vote −0.093 −0.105* 0.014 0.064*** −0.03*
(0.05) (0.049) (0.012) (0.013) (0.014)
Voter turnout 0.2*** 0.146** −0.014 0.014 −0.02*
(0.048) (0.047) (0.008) (0.01) (0.008)
Union density −0.081* −0.082** 0.012 0.022** 0.029***
(0.032) (0.03) (0.007) (0.008) (0.007)
Unemployment rate 0.073 0.058 0.017 0.029 −0.021
(0.091) (0.091) (0.027) (0.035) (0.028)
GDP growth −0.463*** −0.561*** 0.406*** 0.056 0.221***
(0.128) (0.134) (0.058) (0.066) (0.053)
(continued)
Table D.2 Continued
Models (1) and (2): DV =Government policy support for liberal internationalism (1 =KOF globalization policies > median AND military spending > median; 0 =KOF
policies and/or military spending < median)
Model (3): DV =Government policy support for liberal internationalism in categories (1 =lower-than-median KOF policies AND military spending; 2 =lower-than-
median KOF policies AND higher-than-median military spending; 3 =higher-than-median KOF policies AND lower-than-median military spending; 4 =higher-than-
median KOF policies AND higher-than-median military spending).
Models (1) is logistic regression with country and decade dummies (not shown).
Models (2) is multi-level random intercept logistic regression with country as level 2, country-year as level 1, with decade dummies (not shown).
Model (3) is multinomial logit with outcome 4 (liberal internationalism) as baseline.
APPENDIX E
Effect of government-voter gap on party politics.
Table E.1 Government-voter gap over international partnership and military power as a function of party vote share and party-system fragmentation
in Western democracies, 1970−2018.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Radical right Radical left vote All radical vote Mainstream vote Net mainstream Party-system
vote share share share share vote share fragmentation
Government-voter 2.378* 0.523 2.902* −2.056 −4.957 2.975*
gap: partnership (0.966) (1.042) (1.348) (2.138) (3.312) (1.282)
Government-voter: −0.859 0.035 −0.824 0.046 0.869 0.027
gap: power (1.018) (1.177) (1.723) (1.387) (2.922) (0.836)
Democracy −0.485 −0.269 −0.754 1.064 1.818* −0.716*
(0.327) (0.283) (0.442) (0.53) (0.847) (0.27)
Trade openness −0.027 0.026 −0.001 −0.071 −0.069 0.016
(0.023) (0.04) (0.05) (0.057) (0.104) (0.03)
Average party vote share 0.045 −0.216 −0.171 0.327 0.498 −0.62**
(0.142) (0.109) (0.184) (0.258) (0.389) (0.19)
Voter turnout −0.093 0.217 0.123 0.19 0.066 0.094
(0.149) (0.108) (0.186) (0.122) (0.276) (0.132)
Union density 0.013 −0.009 0.005 −0.018 −0.023 −0.066
(0.1) (0.039) (0.12) (0.158) (0.245) (0.072)
Unemployment rate 0.062 0.076 0.137 −0.475 −0.613 0.168
(0.193) (0.165) (0.25) (0.402) (0.601) (0.179)
GDP growth −0.064 −0.123 −0.187 0.419 0.606 −0.058
(continued)
Table E.1 Continued
Radical right
vote share
Radical left
vote share
All radical
vote share
Mainstream
vote share
Net mainstream
vote share
Party−system
fragmentation
−10 −5 0 5
APPENDIX F
Additional figures for selected Western countries.
−1.5
Ideal−point similarity score with US
Voting agreement score with US
Similarity
.8
score
−2
.6
−2.5
Agreement
score
.4
−3
−3.5
.2
−1.2
.9
−1.4
.8
−1.6
.7
Agreement −1.8
score
.6
−2
−2.2
.5
Similarity
.9
score
Agreement score with Japan
−1.2
.8
−1.4
−1.6
Agreement
.7
score
−1.8
.6
Figure F.2 Voting agreement and ideal-point similarity by EU, Japan, and
United States in UN General Assembly, 1950–2020
Notes
Chapter 1
14. The literature here is extensive. See, for example, Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003;
Narizny, 2003; Trubowitz, 2011; Garfinkel and Skaperdas, 2012; Oatley, 2015; and
Obinger et al., 2018.
15. For a discussion of these issues, see Petersen, 2013; and Obinger et al., 2018.
16. See, for example, Cozer, 1956; Mayer, 1969; Skocpol, 1992; Giddens, 1985; and Mann,
1988. For an older but still relevant review of the literature, see Levi, 1988.
17. Obinger and Schmitt, 2011, 250.
18. This is a common strategy in peacetime as well as wartime. See, for example, Blainey,
1973; Mearsheimer, 2001; and Luttwak, 2009.
19. Petersen, 2013, 233.
20. Indeed, scholars have argued that the massive postwar expansion of the welfare state
was a byproduct of the Cold War. For a review of the relevant literature, see Obinger
and Lee, 2013; and Petersen, 2013. See also the recent histories by Westad, 2018b; and
Gerstle, 2022.
21. Obinger and Schmitt, 2011, 252.
22. On the mediating role of political parties in this process, see Trubowitz, 1998 and
2011; Narizny, 2003; Rathbun, 2004; Fordham, 2007; Hoffmann, 2013; Martill, 2019;
and Wagner, 2020.
23. The term sovereignty costs is from Moravcsik, 2000. For other work on this issue,
see Keohane and Hoffmann, 1991; Moravcsik, 1998; Woods and Narlikar, 2001; Lake,
2007; Rixen and Zangl, 2013; Hafner-Burton et al., 2015; Hooghe and Marks, 2015;
Grewal, 2018; and Börzel and Zürn, 2021.
24. Sovereignty costs also vary depending on international institutions’ architecture or
design. Some, like the Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) forum, involve
no delegation or transfer of authority by members to a collective body. In other cases,
such as the International Monetary Fund and World Bank, members pool and transfer
authority to a collective body that makes binding decisions on its members. These are
supranational institutions. For a discussion of the different forms that transfers of na-
tional authority to international institutions can take, see Lake, 2007; and Hooghe
and Marks, 2015.
25. We are interested here in liberal institutionalized cooperation, but multilater-
alism can serve illiberal ends too. In the 1930s, Italian and German fascists viewed
multilateralism as a means to export their economic models. During the Cold
War, the Soviet Union relied on the multilateral Council for Mutual Economic
Assistance, or COMECON, to promote economic planning and coordination
with its allies in Central and Eastern Europe. On these and other examples, see
Helleiner, 2019.
26. On the domestic effects of trade liberalization, see Katzenstein, 1985; Kurzer, 1993;
Rodrik, 1998; Trubowitz, 1998; Iversen and Cusack, 2000; Swank, 2002; Scheve and
Slaughter, 2004; Finseraas, 2008; Burgoon, 2009; Hays, 2009; Mau and Burkhardt,
2009; Rehm, 2009; Walter, 2010; Autor et al., 2016; Colantone and Stanig, 2018; and
Milner, 2019.
27. See Dancygier and Water, 2015; Oesch and Rennwald, 2018; Copelovitch and
Pevehouse, 2019; and Konstantinidis et al., 2019.
Notes 185
28. On the role of political parties in this process, see Boix, 1998; Garrett, 1998; Piazza,
2001; Hooghe, 2003; Swank and Betz, 2003; Marks and Steenbergen, 2004; Benoit and
Laver, 2006; Kupchan and Trubowitz, 2007; Kriesi et al., 2008; Hobolt, 2009; Hooghe
and Marks, 2009; Burgoon, 2012; Ecker-Ehrhardt, 2014; Hutter et al., 2016; Margalit,
2019; Rommel and Walter, 2018; and Zürn, 2019.
29. It is also not hard to imagine foreign policy strategies that straddle two quadrants. As
we note below, arguably Wilson’s vision of a “community of power” is an example.
30. On globalism, see Rosenboim, 2017; and Slobodian, 2018.
31. These versions of international federation differed principally in terms of the relative
weight globalists assigned to international markets versus economic planning at the
supranational level. F.A. Hayek was mostly closely identified with the former; Barbara
Wootton with the latter. Both were members of the London-based Federal Union
that championed international federation as a blueprint for the postwar order. See
Rosenboim 2017, especially 130–167.
32. On the connection between the EU and mid-twentieth century globalist thought, see
Streeck, 2017, 97–105.
33. This was true too of Hayek and Ludwig Von Mises and others in the Austrian school.
See Kjar and Anderson, 2010; and Westley et al., 2011.
34. Quoted in Ikenberry, 2020a, 132.
35. On liberal internationalism’s dual commitment to power and partnership see
Kupchan and Trubowitz, 2007. See also Hoffmann, 1995; Ikenberry, 2009; and Brooks
and Wohlforth, 2016a.
36. Wilson as quoted in Ikenberry, 2009.
37. For isolationism and related strategies (e.g., autarky, self-sufficiency), see Borchart,
1990; Nordlinger, 1996; Nichols, 2011; Kupchan, 2020; and Helleiner, 2021.
38. Nichols, 2011.
39. We use the terms radical-right (radical-left), far-right (far-left), and right-wing (left-
wing) interchangeably in the text. Chapter 4 describes these party families, and the
parties within each of them, in more detail.
40. John Mearsheimer (2011) argues that realism and nationalism are “kissing cousins,”
and there are certainly similarities. Yet, as Mearsheimer himself notes, realism is a
large church with many denominations. Indeed, different strands of realism favor dif-
ferent combinations of power and partnership, putting realists in every quadrant in
Figure 1.2 except quadrant 1 (globalism). Some realists (e.g., Brooks and Wohlforth,
2016a) explicitly embrace liberal internationalism. They favor investing in partner-
ship as well as power. Other realists are more drawn to the combination of partnership
and power that we have labeled isolationism (e.g., Gholz et al., 1997; Sapolsky et al.,
2017; and Thrall and Friedman, 2018). They are not opposed to free trade or investing
in military power, but they do not favor large peacetime military establishments or
the transfer of sovereignty to “lock in” liberal trade. This variation within the realist
school is not surprising. As Robert Gilpin argued, realism, like its counterpart lib-
eralism, is elastic and malleable and better understood as an intellectual tradition
rather than a strategy. On realism’s elasticity and malleability, see Gilpin, 1987. See
also Wohlforth, 2011.
186 Notes
41. On neo- mercantilism, see Hirschmann, 1945; Waltz, 1979; Grieco, 1988; and
Drezner, 2010.
42. Henley, 2017.
43. On Trump’s foreign policy approach, see Mead, 2017; Schweller, 2018; and
Mastanduno, 2020.
44. See Dahl, 1965, 19.
45. In 2018, Front National changed its name to Rassemblement National. We use Front
National throughout when referring to the party.
46. See Mair, 2013, 1.
47. Supporting material and links to data used in this book can be found at the authors’
webpages.
48. Our measures of international threat rely on Dreyer and Thompson, 2011; Gibler
et al., 2016; Goertz et al., 2016; Hensel et al., 2008; Kim, 2018; Markowitz and Fariss,
2018; and Palmer et al., 2021. All of our measures of social protection rely on OECD
data on social transfers and expenditures (see Chapter 3 for details).
49. The strengths and limits of this particular measurement instrument have been widely
debated. See Budge et al., 2001; Klingemann et al., 2006; and Benoit et al., 2009.
50. The coding unit in the Manifesto database is the number of sentences or sentence
fragments in party platforms that take a position (for or against) on a particular for-
eign (or domestic policy) issue. Here we focus on foreign policy issues that concern
international partnership (e.g., open markets, international cooperation) and mili-
tary power (e.g., military spending and military preparedness). These are described in
Chapter 2.
51. There are few systematic cross-national studies on public support for foreign policy,
and even fewer studies tracking public support for foreign policy spanning time-
frames as long as the one here. Most studies focus on a single nation, usually the
United States. Moreover, these cross-national studies tend to focus on specific events
or issues (e.g., the 2003 Iraq War; nuclear weapons) and thus, do not permit broad
comparisons of support for different types of foreign policy strategies (e.g., liberal
internationalism, isolationism) over time. For a recent effort to address some of these
limitations, see Gravelle et al., 2017.
52. For discussion of approaches to gauging voter support for policy issues based on
voter support for parties with systematically measured policy positions, see Kim and
Fording, 1998, 2003; and De Neve, 2011. For a discussion of the limits of this ap-
proach, see Warwick and Zakharova, 2013. Perhaps the greatest concern is that voters
do not usually vote for a party based solely on that party’s stated position on a single
issue. We address this concern in various ways, including estimating the effects of a
party’s platform position on a single issue (e.g., support for defense spending) only
after controlling for the party’s platform positions on other salient issues.
53. Voter support estimates are based on the country-year means of party platform sup-
port for international partnership and military power for any given political party,
weighted by that party’s actual electoral vote share won partly on its manifesto
positions on partnership and power. For a discussion of this and related approachs,
see Kim and Fording, 1998; De Neve, 2011; and Lindvall and Rueda, 2018. See
Notes 187
Chapter 2 for a description of the items in the Manifesto database used to create party
measures of partnership and power.
54. Previous research indicates that indirect voter-weighted manifesto measures like the
ones used here correlate significantly with direct measures of public opinion (e.g.,
Kim and Fording, 1998; McGregor, 2013; and Caughey et al., 2019). More related to
the specific focus of our study, Burgoon et al. (2019) find that manifesto positions on
the EU and trade tend to correlate with direct questions on these issues in European
Social Survey data.
55. See, for example, Acharya, 2014; Allison, 2018; Barma et al., 2007; Nye, 2019; and
Adler-Nissen and Zarakol, 2021.
56. See, for example, Mearsheimer, 2019; Cooley and Nexon, 2020; Ikenberry, 2020a; Lake
et al., 2021; Krastev and Holmes, 2020; Kornprobst and Paul, 2021; and Katzenstein
and Kirshner, 2022. Some scholars take issue with how “liberal” and “coherent” the
Western international order was, but not with the idea that Western democracies are
experiencing domestic blowback from their foreign policies. See, for example, Porter,
2020; and Barnett, 2021.
57. See Fukuyama, 1989; and Krauthammer, 1990.
58. See, for example, Posen, 2014; Mearsheimer, 2018; Porter, 2020; and Walt, 2018.
59. See, for example, Kriesi et al., 2008; Burgoon, 2009; Guiso et al., 2017; Colantone and
Stanig, 2018; Hooghe and Marks, 2018; Rommel and Walter, 2018; Dippel et al., 2015;
Pástor and Veronesi, 2018; Autor et al., 2020; Rodrik, 2021; and Caselli et al., 2021.
60. As Charles Tilly’s well-known phrase in describing the rise of states in Europe,
“War made the state and the state made war,” reminds us, it is also hardly new. Tilly,
1975, 42.
Chapter 2
10. In the 1960s, America’s allies in Asia invested 2.7 percent of GDP in defense on av-
erage, though notably Japan spent only 0.8 percent of GDP on defense (Chai, 1997;
Sandler and George, 2016). In Europe, defense spending as a share of GDP averaged
just under 4 percent during the same period, with Britain, France, and Germany
each investing more in the common defense than the West European average
(Nikolaidou, 2008).
11. Ruggie, 1982.
12. On class and industrial sector support of liberal internationalism in the United
States, see Block, 1977; Ferguson, 1984; Frieden, 1988; and Trubowitz, 1998. For
the European states, see Cameron, 1978; Katzenstein, 1978, 1985; and Eichengreen,
1996, 2007.
13. Deporte, 1979, 197.
14. Beckley et al., 2018.
15. Authors’ calculations using OECD Country Statistical Profiles (OECD, 2020).
16. Following the initial GATT round in 1947, there were five rounds between 1949 and
1967: the Annecy Round (1949); Torquay Round (1951); Geneva Round (1956);
Dillon Round (1960–1961); and the Kennedy Round (1964–1967). The Tokyo Round
began in 1973, but was not completed until 1979.
17. By 1973, multinational corporations had invested $200 billion dollars globally, with
three quarters of it going into the advanced industrial countries. Frieden, 2006, 293.
18. Again, we include the following twenty-four countries under the heading of the
“West”: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, West
Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Netherlands, New
Zealand, Norway, Portugal, South Korea, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United
Kingdom, and the United States.
19. Military spending as a share of GDP figures prominently in national election
campaigns and public debate about “burden-sharing.” We treat this as a proxy for
military preparedness and resource commitments. This measure does not provide
explicit information about actual military missions, deployments, and use of force.
But scholars and policy analysts regularly focus on this indicator to compare national
investments in military power (e.g., Sandler and George, 2016). In our inferential
analyses in Chapters 3 and 4, we also consider alternative specifications, particularly
spending per capita, yielding patterns that corroborate our baseline focus on share
of GDP.
20. KOF’s widely used and cited database includes a range of policy and flow measures
of globalization for more than 200 countries and territories over the period 1970 to
2016. Here we use only those measures representing national government policies
that enable or constrain economic and political globalization—measures that the cur-
rent version of the dataset refers to as “de jure” as opposed to “de facto” measures that
represent actual cross-border flows and actions. See Dreher, 2006; Gygli et al., 2019.
21. Our indices exclude the dataset’s economic data on actual flows of trade, foreign di-
rect investment and migration, and also measures of sociocultural globalization.
22. The KOF treaty party diversity measure refers to the degree to which a country’s in-
vestment treaties are multilateral in nature.
Notes 189
23. Our partnership measure is a weighted index of these two KOF indices from 1970
through 2017, the most recent available year. There are many ways of aggregating,
normalizing, and weighting the various components. Our baseline simply adds these
two KOF indices, providing an intuitive composite measure of global engagement
and international cooperation and the pooling (sacrificing) of national sovereignty.
24. To provide reference points, we set the axes in Figure 2.1 using the worldwide (193
countries) sample medians for all 9,408 observations on each dimension for the full
time-period (1970–2017). These median values yield rough approximations of the
four quadrants in Figures 1.1 and 1.2 in Chapter 1. We use logged values because log
transformation improves the visibility of the relative positions of the countries. Our
analysis is the same whether we use raw or logged values.
25. Greece, Portugal, and Spain did not transition to democracy until the mid-1970s.
26. One limitation of the KOF data is that few countries that were members of the former
Communist bloc appear in the data set before the 1990s. We are thus unable to plot
the Soviet Union and most other members of the Communist bloc in Figures 2.1 and
2.2. Two exceptions are China (CHN) and Hungary (HUN), which are both located
in the nationalist quadrant (quadrant 4) in Figure 2.1. After the Cold War, China and
Hungary, like many other countries, move northward on the vertical axis in support of
greater economic integration and institutionalized cooperation. See Figure 2.3 below.
27. Frieden, 2006, 363.
28. Crozier, Huntington, and Watanuki, 1975.
29. Frieden, 2006, 173–194.
30. Burnham, 1978; Scharpf, 1991; and Reid-Henry, 2019, 78–95.
31. O’Connor, 1973.
32. SIPRI, 2018. Calculations by authors.
33. In 1975, Chile imposed economic liberalization, privatization of state-owned com-
panies, and fighting inflation anticipated many of the policies. Its economic poli-
cies were a precursor to many of the steps that Reagan, Thatcher, and other Western
leaders took.
34. Gilpin, 2002, 99–103.
35. Slobodian, 2018, 257.
36. Slobodian, 2018.
37. Reid-Henry, 2019, 743.
38. Frieden, 2006, 383.
39. For accounts of this shift in Western governments’ foreign economic policies, see
Frieden, 2006; Rodrik, 2011; and Reid-Henry, 2019.
40. See, Ikenberry, 2009; Slobodian, 2018; Börzel and Zürn, 2021.
41. Reid-Henry, 2019, 312–313.
42. Britain, Denmark, and Sweden remained outside the new euro zone.
43. Irwin, 2022.
44. Simmons et al., 2008, 3.
45. Bloodgood, 2016; Börzel and Zürn, 2021.
46. Krastev and Homes, 2019.
47. Reid-Henry, 2019, 315–326.
190 Notes
75. In Figure F.1 in Appendix F, we show that the same pattern holds when the EU-15 is
disaggregated by individual countries: Austria, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Spain,
and the United Kingdom.
76. Quoted in Slobodian, 2018, 275.
77. Stephens, Huber, and Ray, 1999, 179.
78. Flynn and Rattinger, 1985, 384.
79. See Almond, 1960; and Lindberg and Scheingold, 1970, 41–42.
80. See Domke et al., 1987, 404.
81. See Chapter 1 for a description of the Manifesto Project Database. The Manifesto
coding unit is sentences or quasi-sentences (single statements) in party platforms that
take a pro-and an anti-position on issues relevant to a given issue. This allows the
analyst to gauge the level of support for, or opposition to, a given position (e.g., for or
against more open trade) by individual parties (cf. Burgoon, 2009; Lowe et al., 2011;
Milner and Judkins, 2004).
82. Our Manifesto measure of international partnership refers to the (logged) percentage
of total sentences or quasi-sentences (single statements) expressing support for ge-
neral internationalism, free trade (low trade protectionism) and the European Union
minus the (logged) percentage of (quasi-) sentences expressing opposition to each.
This net measure includes every reference to open markets, international coopera-
tion, and global governance in the Manifesto database (per107 +per108 +per407 +
.5) and (per109 +per110 +per406 +.5). Our Manifesto measure of “military power”
refers to the (logged) percentage of total sentences or quasi-sentences in favor of mil-
itary spending, preparedness, security, and defense generally minus the (logged) per-
centage of statements expressing doubt and criticism of defense spending, military
conscription, and the use of military power to solve conflict. Following Lowe et al.
(2011), we take the natural log of each component, to ensure a more normal distribu-
tion of the measures, and add .5 to avoid zeros in the calculations.
83. To compare such voter support between countries, we weight the results for a given
policy position by the average vote share in a party system (since countries with only two
choices will have higher vote shares on average than countries with many party choices).
84. The full-sample median benchmarks are based on all countries and years for which
the Manifesto project provides data since 1950. These median values yield rough
approximations of the four quadrants in Figure 2.6, comparable to quadrants in
Figures 2.1 through 2.4. When using voting support measures, it is also possible to set
the benchmark at a score of zero on each axis. This is because the zero-line demarcates
net voter support from net voter opposition on each dimension. For example, on the
vertical axis, scores greater than zero indicate voter-support levels for platforms that
are more positive than negative about international partnership. Conversely, scores
lower than zero indicate voter support for platforms that are more negative than pos-
itive about partnership. The equivalent holds for the measures of voter-support for
military power displayed on the horizontal axis. We considered both benchmarks—
the zero-lines as well as the sample-medians—in interpreting the data. For the sake of
consistency with our measures of government and party positions elsewhere in the
analysis, we use the full-sample median here.
192 Notes
85. This finding is broadly consistent with recent public opinion research on rising anti-
globalist sentiment towards trade liberalization and institutionalized cooperation.
See Bearce and Jolliff Scott, 2019; Copelovitch, et al., 2020; and De Vries, et al., 2020.
86. Western political elites were more willing to live with the threat of nuclear war than
their publics were. On this point, see Domke et al., 1987, 405.
87. Corman et al., 2015.
88. Schilde et al., 2019, 155.
89. Madison, 2019.
90. Clinton, 1997.
Chapter 3
10. To measure Western government support for partnership, power, and the two
combined (partnership +power), we use the same measures we introduced in
Chapter 2: KOF’s globalization policy measures to gauge support for international
partnership, and defense spending as a percentage of GDP to measure investment
in military power. Partnership +Power is the sum of the standardized measures of
partnership and power. This provides a rough approximation of liberal internation-
alism (partnership +power), though it smooths over which of the two components—
partnership or power—accounts for year-to-year or cross-country difference. We
explored other measurement approaches, such as categorizing values of partnership
and power into the four categories or quadrants introduced in Figure 1.1 in Chapter 1,
including the category liberal internationalism, where partnership and power are
higher than the sample medians. These specifications, which are summarized in
Appendix D, yield results similar to the baseline results in Figures 3.1 and 3.2.
11. Social protection, our explanatory variable here, is based on social security transfers
as a percentage of GDP, a widely used measure of social protection in the comparative
political economy literature. This is a particularly useful measure for our purposes.
Among the available measures of social protection, social security transfers have a
large economic impact and are thus politically salient. This measure has the added ad-
vantage of providing the most complete coverage for all of the OECD countries in our
sample from 1960 to 2017. We use country-year data from OECD, 2019. The results
reported here are also broadly supported using other measures such as social wel-
fare generosity (1970–2011) and OECD social expenditures (transfers and services)
(1980–2017).
12. The descriptive patterns are not as strong for power, and stronger for partnership, but
the positive correlation holds for both.
13. For full results, see Table B.1 in Appendix B. Controls for the country-level analyses
(where the unit of analysis is country-year) include democratic representativeness,
unemployment rate, union density, voter turnout, past trade openness, and GDP
growth. All of these control variables are lagged five-year moving averages to take
into account the time it often takes for these factors to register in government policy.
In addition to these substantive controls, the models include “dummies” (or indi-
cator variables) for each sample country and decade to control for “fixed effects” of
country-level or general conditions that do not vary over the time period.
14. This is consistent with other research that has focused more narrowly on the rela-
tionship between social safety net compensation and government support for trade
liberalization, capital mobility, and so on. See, for example, Burgoon et al., 2012;
and Ha and Tsebelis, 2010. Of course, there is also a large literature that explores
globalization’s effects on social compensation: cf. Cameron, 1978; Katzenstein, 1985;
Rodrik, 1998; and Adsera and Boix, 2002.
15. The explanatory variables capturing social protection, and geopolitical threat, as well
as the control variables, are lagged values of five-year moving averages. We use five-
year lagged moving averages to account for the time it takes political and economic
conditions to fully affect party or voter position-taking.
194 Notes
16. We calculate the party’s left-right orientation using Manifesto’s “RILE” (Right-Left)
parameter, excluding platform positions we use to generate our party platform meas-
ures of partnership and power. The “RILE” measure is a composite variable made up
of platform positions (for or against) on issues highly related to “left versus right” ide-
ological orientation, such as government regulation, social welfare, market efficiency,
and economic inequality.
17. For presentational purposes, we restrict the analysis by individual party families to
partnership +power. See Table B.2 in Appendix B for the full regression results.
18. Burgoon, 2009 and 2012; and Burgoon and Schakel, 2022.
19. See, for example, Inglot, 2008; Mishra, 1993; Obinger and Schmitt, 2011; and Obinger
and Lee, 2013. For a review of the literature, see Petersen, 2013.
20. Shantz, 2008, 798.
21. Hobsbawm, 1990, 21, cited in Obinger and Schmitt, 2011, 247.
22. Full regression results are shown in Table B.3 of Appendix B. Figure 3.4 is based on the
results in models (1) to (3). These show that the results for partnership +power, which
captures the broadest, most inclusive specification, are statistically significant.
23. In estimating these vote-weighted scores, controlling for other platform positions in
a party’s manifesto (including the party’s adjusted left-right composite of platform
positions) is important. Otherwise, one cannot be sure that the associations be-
tween social protection, geopolitical threat (below), and other explanatory variables
with vote-weighted manifesto scores (as outcome variables) reflect the influence of
a party’s position on other platform issues. Supplemental analyses (available upon
request) consider other non-foreign policy aspects of a party’s platform positioning
(e.g., welfare state provisions, environmental safety, democracy, traditional moral
values, etc.).
24. We estimate voter support by weighting a party’s platform support for international
partnership and military power by the portion of that party’s actual electoral vote
share that can be attributed to its manifesto positions on partnership and power.
These estimates are based on linear interpolation between election years for a given
party’s vote-weighted platform. See Chapter 2 for a description of the items in the
Manifesto Project Database used to create voter support estimates of partnership
and power.
25. See the discussion in Chapter 1.
26. In addition to the standard country and decade dummy variables, controls for these
models include: democratic representativeness, international openness, country’s
average vote share, unemployment rate, GDP growth, party family and party’s left-
right orientation. Controlling for party platform orientation helps zero in on how
social protection, geopolitical threat (below), and other explanatory variables cor-
relate with vote-weighted manifesto scores on partnership and power (our outcome
variables), as distinct from other party platform issues. In supplemental analyses, we
consider the “effects” of party platform positions on issues such as welfare state pro-
vision, environmental safety, democracy, and moral values. These are available upon
request.
Notes 195
27. Studies that are especially relevant to the argument here include Swank and Betz,
2003; Walter, 2010; Kersbergen and Vis, 2013; Halikiopoulou and Vlandas, 2016; Dal
Bó et al., 2018; Fetzer, 2019; Foster and Frieden, 2019; and Gingrich, 2019.
28. Scharpf, 2000; Prasad, 2006; and Thelen, 2014.
29. Rodrik, 2011; and Subramanian and Kessler, 2013.
30. Betz, 1994; Jackman and Volpert, 1996; Lubbers and Scheepers, 2000; Golder, 2003;
Swank and Betz, 2003; Jesuit and Mahler, 2004; Kessler and Freeman, 2005.
31. Knigge, 1998; Lubbers et al., 2002; Van der Brug et al., 2005; and Arzheimer and
Carter, 2006.
32. Hays et al., 2005; and Scheve and Slaughter, 2006.
33. This adjustment is important to make because when unemployment rises, more
people file for unemployment insurance benefits or fall into the income brackets that
make them eligible for means-tested benefits, or both. Since we are interested in meas-
uring public commitment to social protection or welfare effort, it is necessary to nor-
malize spending by the unemployment rate so that unemployment-induced increases
in social spending (that do not involve changes in policy) are not mischaracterized as
increases in welfare effort.
34. This process began during the later stages of the Cold War, but it accelerated in the
post–Cold War era. See Karns and Mingst, 2010.
35. Mathews, 1997.
36. Featherstone, 1994. In France, a referendum on the Maastricht treaty narrowly
passed. In Denmark, the treaty was initially rejected in a close vote. It passed in a
second referendum.
37. On the history of political opposition to multilateral institutions in the United States,
see Patrick, 2017.
38. See Chapter 2, Figure 2.7.
39. Lefkofridi and Michel, 2017; Roth, et al., 2018; and Michel, 2019.
40. Heinisch, 2003; and Höbelt, 2003, 99.
41. Hainsworth, 2004, 106.
42. Swank and Betz, 2003; and Hernández and Kriesi, 2016.
43. Farage also connected EU membership to the issue of immigration, arguing that the
best way to limit immigration was to leave the supranational institution.
44. Miller, 2016; Semuels, 2016.
45. Autor et al., 2020.
46. Ironically, many on the left also now saw multilateral institutions as a means to help
achieve this goal. By regulating social-welfare and labor standards across national
borders, international institutions could help protect vulnerable workers, businesses,
and communities from market-induced regional and global “races to the bottom.”
Following the signing of the Maastricht treaty in 1992, the call for a new “social Europe”
that would harmonize welfare and labor costs across Europe united most West European
parties on the left. Instead of using the European Union to shield international business
from domestic politics, they argued “federal Europe” should be repurposed to defend
working families from the vicissitudes of global market forces. See Sassoon, 2014, 721.
196 Notes
47. In West Germany, Italy, and elsewhere, ruling Christian Democrats also exploited
public fears about communism to shore up political support for their foreign and
domestic policies (Mazower, 1999, 292–293; and Corduwener, 2016). Similar tac-
tics were employed by political elites in the United States to silence progressive “one
worlders” on the political left and to keep isolationist and nationalist opposition to
American international leadership on the far right in check (Doenecke, 1979; and
Dudziak, 2012). In Japan, conservatives used various means, including legislation
(e.g., Subversive Activities Prevention Bill), to attack and marginalize socialists and
communists (Hayes, 2009, 88).
48. Gaddis, 2005.
49. Sassoon, 1992, 215.
50. Sassoon, 1992, 168–169.
51. Midford, 2011.
52. Rosenbluth and Thies, 2010, 60.
53. Midford, 2011, 57.
54. Samuels, 2007, 32; and Pyle, 2018, 360–361.
55. Hughes, 2017, 82.
56. Eichenberg, 1989; and Holsti, 1992.
57. Domke et al., 1987
58. Ikenberry, 2020a.
59. Talbott, 2008, 329–330, as cited in Ikenberry, 2020a, 263.
60. Ikenberry, 2020a, 259.
61. De Spiegeleire et al., 2017, v, fi
gure 1.2; and Henke and Maher, 2021.
62. Alonso and da Fonseca, 2012; Halikiopoulou et al., 2012; and Burgoon and
Schakel, 2022.
63. Autor et al., 2020.
64. Midford, 2011, 15–16; Hughes, 2017, 79; and Madison, 2019.
65. The country-year measures included in our baseline model are: Hensel et al.’s (2008)
ICOW-based territorial rivalries index; Dreyer and Thompson’s (2011) strategic
rivalries index; Palmer et al.’s (2021) and Gibler et al.’s (2016) binary Militarized
International Disputes (MIDs) measure; Goertz, et al.’s (2016) interstate peace scale
with neighbors; Kim’s (2018) categorical measure of hostile relations with neighbors;
and Markowitz and Fariss’s (2018) spatial lag measure of geopolitical competition.
The resulting scale is the standardized and equally weighted sum of the seven meas-
ures. In constructing the scale, we used casewise deletion where a country-year ob-
servation lacked any of the seven components, with a Cornbach’s alpha of .78 as a
threshold for internal consistency. In addition to our baseline model, we developed a
supplementary measure that also includes system-wide variation in the risk of nuclear
war based on the Bulletin of Atomic Scientists’ annual updating of its “Doomsday
Clock.”
66. The measures differ in how they define threats (military as opposed to economic and
political), the extent to which threats involve territorial claims, and whether the threat
entails actual hostilities.
Notes 197
67. Given that our concern is with geopolitical challenges broadly defined, aggregating
these indicators into a composite index allows us to capture the different ways inter-
national threats manifest and, importantly, to offset the substantive and methodolog-
ical limitations inherent in any particular measure.
68. Vine, 2021.
69. The analyses here start in 1960 because many of the control variables are only avail-
able from that year.
70. The regression analyses underlying these three figures, while focused on how geo-
political threat is associated with partnership and power, follow the same respective
specifications discussed above with respect to the effects of social transfers: Figure
3.8 focuses on the country-level (specification summarized in discussion of Figures
3.2 above); Figure 3.9 focuses on the party level (specification discussed for Figure 3.3
above); and Figure 3.10 focuses on the voter level (specification summarized in dis-
cussion of Figure 3.4).
71. For the full results underlying Figure 3.8, see Table B.1 in Appendix B. For the full
results underlying Figure 3.9, see Table B.4 in Appendix B.
72. See Table B.3 in Appendix B, for the full results.
73. Voters may feel better placed to pass judgment on issues like international trade
that directly impact their pocketbooks, than on “high politics” issues such as mil-
itary balances, modernization, and deployments. See McCormick et al., 1992; and
Holsti, 1978.
74. Trubowitz, 2011.
75. Nuti et al., 2015; Tompkins, 2016; Conze et al., 2017.
76. Others have recognized this too. See Broz et al., 2021.
77. See, for example, Katz and Mair, 1995; Kirshner, 2014; Hopkin and Blyth, 2019; Tooze,
2018; and Blyth, 2021.
78. See, for example, Featherstone, 1994; De Vries and McNamara, 2018; and Börzel and
Zürn, 2021.
79. Colgan and Keohane, 2017.
80. Mair, 2013, 109; Slobodian, 2018.
81. See Scheve and Slaughter, 2001; Scheve and Slaughter, 2006; and Boix, 2019.
82. Przeworski, 2019, 111.
83. KOF’s de facto economic globalization index includes trade in goods and in services,
trade partner diversity, FDI, portfolio investment, international debt, international
reserves, and international income payments. The KOF de facto political globalization
index comprises number of embassies, UN peacekeeping missions, and international
non-governmental organizations operating in country. Our de facto all globaliza-
tion index includes these de facto economic and political indices, plus KOF’s de facto
socio-cultural measures (international voice traffic, international tourism, interna-
tional students, internet bandwidth, IKEA and McDonald’s stores, international
trademarks). For details, see Gygli et al., 2019.
84. Right-party government (percentage of cabinet posts) comes from Armingeon et al.,
2020. All explanatory variables are five-year lagged moving averages, to address the
198 Notes
lag in effects and also to help isolate the direction of association—to assess our causal
inferences about statistically significant predictors. For each of our measures of de
facto globalization, we consider two specifications: without any controls; and with
substantive controls and country fixed effects. See Table B.5 in Appendix B.
85. We created a country-year government-voter gap index measuring the degree to which
OECD government and public support for liberalized trade and institutionalized co-
operation were different (similar). We rely on the KOF globalization policy indices
to measure government policy support for partnership. Voter support estimates are
based on our country-level vote-weighted indices measuring the voting public’s sup-
port of partnership. The government-voter gap measure for partnership is the adjusted
value of the difference between standardized government support for partnership
and the standardized vote-weighted party support for partnership.
86. For our baseline, we recode negative government-voter gaps—i.e., situations where
the voting public wants more trade liberalization and institutionalized cooperation
than their government currently supports—as 0. We make this adjustment because
there is no reason to assume that the voting public prefers government policies that
are more supportive of international partnership than government policy, or less so. It
is the magnitude of the overreach that we are interested in.
87. See Table B.5 in Appendix B for the full results. We considered a wide range of al-
ternative specifications, including adding further measures of partnership in party
platforms and de jure globalization (indices that go into our outcome measure).
88. The results in Figure 3.11 are based on the specification with the fullest battery of
controls. See columns 2, 4, and 6 in Table B.5, Appendix B.
89. We obtain similar results using narrower measures of economic globalization, such as
financial flows or capital openness.
90. Since these de facto measures might be affected by past de jure measures that inform
our measures of government-voter gap we also considered models that include our
measures of government support for globalization (KOF index of de jure political and
economic globalization) and average vote-weighted party support for partnership.
The results also show a significant effect of de facto all globalization.
91. For a review of these debates, see Mastanduno, 1999.
Chapter 4
power) for a given set of explanatory conditions. In doing so, we take into account
how those explanatory conditions affect each outcome in ways related to their effects
for other outcomes. In statistical terms, seemingly unrelated regression models factor
in such dependence, treating the error terms of the respective models as linked. For
a discussion, see Zellner, 1962; and Greene, 2012. The model coefficients are ordi-
nary least squares (OLS) with robust cluster standard errors (clustered by country),
including controls for level of democracy, unemployment rate, real GDP growth,
average party vote share, past openness, voting turnout, union density, along with
fixed effects for the twenty-four Western countries and decade dummies. To reduce
endogeneity and address delays in outcomes, we use lagged moving averages (five-
year) for the explanatory variables.
27. Again, partnership + power is the sum of the standardized measure of our KOF glob-
alization index (partnership) and the standardized measure of defense spending as a
share of GDP (power). This provides a rough approximation of liberal internation-
alism though it smooths over which of the two components—partnership or power—
account for year-to-year differences. We also considered alternative approaches to
standardize and combine our measures of partnership and power (e.g., creating cat-
egories for different combinations of partnership and power; developing scales using
principal component analysis). These yielded similar patterns to those reported using
our baseline measures.
28. See Appendix A for the summary statistics on these and all country-year and party-
year variables explored in this chapter.
29. Since the horizontal axes capture the full sample variation for our twenty-four OECD
countries, we can compare the substantive size of effects across party families and
government policy.
30. The results reported here are corroborated using other approaches to combining of
partnership and power. See, for example, the categorical specifications in Table D.2 of
Appendix D.
31. Mainstream parties benefited too from the fact that parties on the far left and far right
disagreed sharply over defense spending and military preparedness. Nuclear disar-
mament also made it difficult for them to find common ground on an alternative for-
eign policy strategy.
32. Lipset and Rokkan, 1967. For a recent discussion of the Lipset and Rokkan cleavage
model, see Ford and Jennings, 2020.
33. Clark, 2019; and Voce and Clarke, 2021. On the decline of mainstream party vote
share more generally, see Katz and Mair, 2018, chapter 7.
34. Golosov, 2010; Best, 2013; Pildes, 2021.
35. Computations by authors based on data from Swank, 2018.
36. Mettler and Leavitt, 2019, cited in Pildes, 2021, 146.
37. See, for example, Kitschelt, 1997; Mudde, 2007; Kriesi et al., 2008; Bolleyer and
Bytzek, 2013; Inglehart and Norris, 2017; Burgoon et al., 2019; De Vries et al., 2021;
and Mutz, 2018.
38. Przeworski and Sprague, 1986; Kitschelt, 1994; Clark and Lipset, 2001; Gingrich and
Häusermann, 2015; Boix, 2019; Hall, 2020; and Rennwald and Pontussen, 2021.
Notes 201
39. At the same time, Social Democratic parties pushed to reform social insurance sys-
tems and labor market regulations in ways that often disadvantaged traditional blue-
collar workers, while extending coverage to previously excluded groups, such as
female service-sector workers. See Häusermann, 2010.
40. Häusermann, 2017, cited in Boix, 2019, 9.
41. Denmark and the UK agreed to the treaty’s commitment to allow goods and people
to move freely across national borders, but not to the European Union’s common
currency.
42. Sassoon, 2014, 739. Center-left and center-right parties in Western Europe were
less enthusiastic about extending membership to the fledgling democracies of post-
Communist Central and Eastern European countries (CEEC). The prevailing view
was incorporating CEEC nations into NATO should take priority over EU mem-
bership. Offering NATO membership was easier and less costly, politically as well as
economically. Already, radical-right parties like France’s FN had reversed course on
the issues of economic and political integration and were attacking the idea of EU
citizenship and a single currency (Mudde, 2007). EU enlargement would come, but
for mainstream parties, it was double-edged, politically. While the vast majority of
Western European elites supported it, mass support was considerably less enthusi-
astic. In 2005, public support for the European Union among EU citizens was only
about 50 percent. Significantly, opposition was strongest among those without
degrees and workers. See McLaren, 2005, cited in Eatwell and Goodwin, 2018, 102.
43. Trubowitz, 2011.
44. Clinton understood that moving in this direction would anger liberal constituencies
within the party and, to some extent, sought to soften the blow by imposing unilateral
sanctions against European and Japanese exporters accused of dumping goods in the
US market and using the Commerce Department to actively promote US manufac-
tured exports. See Trubowitz, 2011, 122.
45. Shoch, 2001, 228–230.
46. Scheve and Slaughter, 2001; Shoch, 2001; and Hiscox, 2020.
47. Pempel, 1998; Schoppa, 2011.
48. Rosenbluth and Thies, 2010, 155, 118; Schoppa, 2011, 36–38.
49. Koizumi’s agenda was enormously popular with urban voters, but rural members of
the party attacked and sometimes defeated his policy proposals. In an effort to blunt
the political impact of those criticisms, Koizumi made annual high-profile sym-
bolic visits to the controversial Yasukuni Shrine that had “deep and special meaning
for rural voters” (Rosenbluth and Thies, 2010, 167). While these annual visits were
roundly criticized by Beijing and Seoul for being insensitive and nationalistic, the
gestures allowed Koizumi to solidify his exposed flank with conservative, rural voters.
50. Under Koizumi, Japan launched its first big surge in Economic Partnership
Agreements (FTAs) with other countries in the Pacific region. See Urata, 2009.
Historically, FTAs were considered closed-door measures. However, in the 1990s they
came to be seen as complements to WTO efforts to promote “open regionalism.” See
Drezner, 2014, 146.
51. Reid-Henry, 2019, 559–565.
202 Notes
association between a party’s support for partnership and its subsequent electoral
share was less negative, or even positive, during the Cold War.
69. Social protection is based on social security transfers as a percentage of GDP. See
Chapter 3 for a discussion.
70. See Appendix B, Table B.7, for the full results. The reported panels in Figure 4.8 corre-
spond to models 2–3 in Table B.7.
71. Studies that are especially relevant to the argument here include Swank and Betz,
2003; Walter, 2010; Kersbergen and Vis, 2013; Halikiopoulou and Vlandas, 2016; Dal
Bó et al., 2018; Fetzer, 2019; Foster and Frieden, 2019; and Gingrich, 2019.
72. The patterns hold when controlling for other economic and political conditions
(i.e., GDP per capita, economic inequality, government debt, inflation, party system,
measures of corruption). They also hold up to changes in sample size: for instance,
including the CEEC countries and other countries like Turkey and Brazil in the
models. The results also hold up to different estimators (e.g., multi-level random in-
tercept models) and alternative ways of calculating standard errors (e.g., simple ro-
bust standard errors).
73. See Appendix E for these results.
74. Well-known works in this genre include Keohane and Nye, 1971; Kindleberger, 1973;
Gilpin, 1975; Keohane, 1984; Mearsheimer, 1990; and Ikenberry, 2001.
75. Fearon, 1994; Schultz, 2001.
76. Cha, 2000; Mastanduno, 1997; and Ikenberry 2020a, 200–202.
77. Acheson, 1969, 97.
78. Simmons et al. (2008), cited in Ikenberry, 2020a, 265.
79. For a description of the KOF de facto globalization index, see Chapter 3.
80. See also Voeten, 2013; and Bailey et al., 2017.
81. Rae’s index is a straightforward measure of party fragmentation, ranging between 1
(maximal fractionalization) and 0 (minimal fractionalization). The index data comes
from Armingeon et al.’s (2020) CPDS database.org (variable rae_leg). The results
hold up to related measures such as the effective number of parties in party systems
(Laakso and Taagepera, 1979), as well as different methods of calculating fragmenta-
tion in party systems.
82. Table B.9 in Appendix B provides the full regression results. Model 1 shows the result
that is the basis for Figure 4.11.
83. These include the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), Benelux Union, Central
Commission for Navigation on the Rhine (CCNR), European Organization for
Nuclear Research (CERN), Council of Europe (COE), European Economic Area
(EEA), European Free Trade Association (EFTA), European Space Agency (ESA),
European Union (EU), International Bank for Reconstruction and Development
(IBRD), International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO), International Labor
Organization (ILO), International Monetary Fund (IMF), International Maritime
Organization (IMO), International Criminal Police Organization (INTERPOL),
International Telecommunication Union (ITU), International Whaling Commission
(IWC), North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), North Atlantic Treaty
Organization (NATO), Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
204 Notes
92. Hence, the regression analyses include lagged moving-averages not only of our
fragmentation measure, but also the same battery of controls described above (see
Figure 4.11).
93. Lincoln was referring to anti-war Democrats in the North who threatened the Union
cause against the Confederacy.
94. See, for example, Fukuyama, 1989; and Krauthammer, 1990.
Chapter 5
Abdelal, Rawi, and Jonathan Kirshner (1999). “Strategy, Economic Relations, and the
Definition of National Interests.” Security Studies 9, no. 1–2: 119–156.
Acharya, Amitav (2014). “Global International Relations (IR) and Regional Worlds: A New
Agenda for International Studies.” International Studies Quarterly 58, no. 4: 647–659.
Acheson, Dean (1969). Present at the Creation: My Years at the State Department.
New York: W.W. Norton.
Adler-Nissen, Rebecca, and Ayşe Zarakol (2021). “Struggles for Recognition: The Liberal
International Order and the Merger of Its Discontents.” International Organization 75,
no. 2: 611–634.
Adsera, Alicia, and Carles Boix (2002). “Trade, Democracy, and the Size of the Public
Sector: The Political Underpinnings of Openness.” International Organization 56, no.
2: 229–262.
Allison, Graham (2018). “The Myth of the Liberal Order: From Historical Accident to
Conventional Wisdom.” Foreign Affairs 97, no. 4: 124–133.
Alonso, Sonia, and Sara Claro da Fonseca (2012). “Immigration, Left and Right.” Party
Politics 18, no. 6: 865–884.
Anderson, Jeffrey, G., John Ikenberry, and Thomas Risse, eds. (2008). The End of the West?
Crisis and Change in the Atlantic Order. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Anderson, Nicholas D. (2017). “Anarchic Threats and Hegemonic Assurances: Japan’s
Security Production in the Postwar Era.” International Relations of the Asia-Pacific 17,
no. 1: 101–135.
Archibugi, Daniele, and David Held (1995). Cosmopolitan Democracy: An Agenda for a
New World Order. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Archibugi, Daniele, and David Held (2011). “Cosmopolitan Democracy: Paths and
Agents.” Ethics & International Affairs 25, no. 4: 433–461.
Arias, Eric, James R. Hollyer, and B. Peter Rosendorff (2018). “Cooperative
Autocracies: Leader Survival, Creditworthiness, and Bilateral Investment Treaties.”
American Journal of Political Science 62, no. 4: 905–921.
Armingeon, Klaus, Sarah Engler, and Lucas Leemann (2020). Comparative Political Data
Set 1960–2018. Zurich: Institute of Political Science, University of Zurich.
Arts, Wil, and John Gelissen (2002). “Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism or More?
A State-of-the-Art Report.” Journal of European Social Policy 12, no. 2: 137–158.
Arzheimer, Kai, and Elisabeth Carter (2006). “Political Opportunity Structures and
Right-wing Extremist Party Success.” European Journal of Political Research 45, no.
3: 419–443.
Aspalter, Christian (2006). “The East Asian Welfare Model.” International Journal of Social
Welfare 15, no. 4: 290–301.
Autor, David, David Dorn, Gordon Hanson, and Kaveh Majlesi (2020). “Importing
Political Polarization? The Electoral Consequences of Rising Trade Exposure.”
American Economic Review 110, no. 10: 3139–3183.
208 References
Autor, David H., David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson (2016). “The China Shock: Learning
from Labor- Market Adjustment to Large Changes in Trade.” Annual Review of
Economics 8: 205–240.
Autor, David, David Mindell, and Elisabeth Reynolds (2020). “The Work of the
Future: Building Better Jobs in an Age of Intelligent Machines.” MIT Task Force on the
Work of the Future. https://workofthefuture.mit.edu/research-post/the-work-of-the-
future-building-better-jobs-in-an-age-of-intelligent-machines/.
Bacevitch, Andrew (2002). American Empire: The Realities and Consequences of U.S.
Diplomacy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Bafumi, Joseph, and Joseph M. Parent (2012). “International Polarity and America’s
Polarization.” International Politics 49, no. 1: 1–35.
Bailey, Michael A., Anton Strezhnev, and Erik Voeten (2017). “Estimating Dynamic State
Preferences from United Nations Voting Data.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 61, no.
2: 430–456.
Bailey, Thomas A. (1943). “Review of U. S. Foreign Policy: Shield of the Republic, by Walter
Lippmann.” Political Science Quarterly 58, no. 3: 429–431.
Baldwin, Richard E., and Philippe Martin (1999). “Two Waves of Globalisation: Superficial
Similarities, Fundamental Differences.” NBER Working Paper w6904: 1–30.
Bale, Tim (2018). “Who Leads and Who Follows? The Symbiotic Relationship between UKIP
and the Conservatives—and Populism and Euroscepticism.” Politics 38, no. 3: 263–277.
Barma, Naazneen, Ely Ratner, and Steven Weber (2007). “A World Without the West.”
National Interest, no. 90: 23–30.
Barnett, Michael (2021). “International Progress, International Order, and the Liberal
International Order.” Chinese Journal of International Politics 14, no. 1: 1–22.
Bearce, David H., and Brandy J. Jolliff Scott (2019). “Popular Non- support for
International Organizations: How Extensive and What Does This Represent?” The
Review of International Organizations 14, no. 2: 1–30.
Beckley, Michael (2022). “Enemies of My Enemy: How Fear of China is Forging a New
World Order.” Foreign Affairs 101, no. 2: 68–85.
Beckley, Michael, Yusaku Horiuchi, and Jennifer M. Miller (2018). “America’s Role in the
Making of Japan’s Economic Miracle.” Journal of East Asian Studies 18, no. 1: 1–21.
Benoit, Kenneth, and Michael Laver (2006). Party Policy in Modern Democracies.
London: Routledge.
Benson, Brett V., Adam Meirowitz, and Kristopher W. Ramsay (2014). “Inducing
Deterrence through Moral Hazard in Alliance Contracts.” Journal of Conflict Resolution
58, no. 2: 307–335.
Beramendi, Pablo, Silja Häusermann, Herbert Kitschelt, and Hanspeter Kriesi, eds.
(2015). The Politics of Advanced Capitalism. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Best, Robin E. (2013). “How Party System Fragmentation Has Altered Political Opposition
in Established Democracies.” Government and Opposition 48, no. 3: 314–342.
Betz, Hans-Georg (1994). Radical Right-wing Populism in Western Europe. New York: St.
Martin’s Press, 1994.
Blainey, Geoffrey (1974). The Causes of War. London: Macmillan.
Block, Fred L. (1977). The Origins of International Economic Disorder: A Study of
United States International Monetary Policy from World War II to the Present.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Bloodgood, Elizabeth (2016). “The Yearbook of International Organizations and
Quantitative Non-State Actor Research.” In The Ashgate Research Companion to Non-
State Actors, edited by Bob Reinalda, 31–46. London: Routledge.
References 209
Blyth, Mark (2021). “The End of Social Purpose? Great Transformations of American
Order.” In The Downfall of the American Order: Liberalism’s End, edited by Peter
Katzenstein and Jonathan Kirshner, 35–53. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Bogdanor, Vernon (2020). Britain and Europe in a Troubled World. New Haven: Yale
University Press.
Boix, Carles (1998). Political Parties, Growth and Equality: Conservative and Social
Democratic Economic Strategies in the World Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Boix, Carles (2019). Democratic Capitalism at the Crossroads: Technological Change and
the Future of Politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Bolleyer, Nicole, and Evelyn Bytzek (2013). “Origins of Party Formation and New
Party Success in Advanced Democracies.” European Journal of Political Research 52,
no. 6: 773–796.
Bomberg, E. (2002). “The Europeanisation of Green Parties: Exploring the EU’s Impact.”
West European Politics 25, no. 3: 29–50.
Bordo, Michael D., Alan M. Taylor, and Jeffrey G. Williamson, eds. (2007). Globalization
in Historical Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Börzel, Tanja A., and Michael Zürn (2021). “Contestations of the Liberal International
Order: From Liberal Multilateralism to Postnational Liberalism.” International
Organization 75, no. 2: 282–305.
Brady, David, and Hang Young Lee (2014). “The Rise and Fall of Government Spending in
Affluent Democracies, 1971–2008.” Journal of European Social Policy 24, no. 1: 56–79.
Brands, Hal (2021). “Why Containment Can Stop the China Threat.” The National Interest April
23. https://nationalinterest.org/feature/why-containment-can-stop-china-threat-183423.
Braun, Daniela, Sebastian Adrian Popa, and Hermann Schmitt (2019). “Responding
to the Crisis: Eurosceptic Parties of the Left and Right and Their Changing Position
towards the European Union.” European Journal of Political Research 58, no.
3: 797–819.
Brodie, Bernard (1965). Strategy in the Missile Age. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Brooks, David (2019). “How China Brings Us Together: An Existential Threat for the 21st
Century.” New York Times, 14 February. https://www.nytimes.com/2019/02/14/opin
ion/china-economy.html.
Brooks, Stephen G., and William C. Wohlforth (2016a). America Abroad: The United
States’ Global Role in the 21st Century. New York: Oxford University Press.
Brooks, Stephen G., and William C. Wohlforth (2016b). “The Rise and Fall of the Great
Powers in the Twenty-First Century: China’s Rise and the Fate of America’s Global
Position.” International Security 40, no. 3: 7–53.
Brown, Garrett W., and David Held (2010). The Cosmopolitanism Reader.
Cambridge: Polity.
Broz, J. Lawrence, Jeffry Frieden, and Stephen Weymouth (2021). “Populism in Place: The
Economic Geography of the Globalization Backlash.” International Organization 75,
no. 2: 464–494.
Brummer, Klaus, and Kai Oppermann (2016). “Germany’s Foreign Policy after the End
of the Cold War: ‘Becoming Normal?’” Oxford Handbooks Online: Political Science,
April: 1–30.
Budge, Ian, and Michael Laver (1992). Party Policy and Government Coalitions.
London: St. Martin’s Press.
Burgoon, Brian (2001). “Globalization and Welfare Compensation: Disentangling the
Ties That Bind.” International Organization 55, no. 3: 509–551.
210 References
Conze, Eckart, Martin Klimke, and Jeremy Varon, eds. (2017). Nuclear Threats, Nuclear
Fear, and the Cold War of the 1980s. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cooley, Alexander, and Daniel H. Nexon (2020). Exit From Hegemony: The Unraveling of
the American Global Order. NewYork: Oxford University Press.
Cooper, Robert (2000). “The Post-Modern State and the World Order.” London: Demos.
Copelovitch, Mark, Sara B. Hobolt, and Stefanie Walter (2020). “Challenges to the
Contemporary Global Order: Cause for Pessimism or Optimism?” Journal of European
Public Policy 27, no. 7: 1114–1125.
Copelovitch, Mark, and Jon C.W. Pevehouse (2019). “International Organizations in
a New Era of Populist Nationalism.” Review of International Organizations 14, no.
2: 169–1286.
Corduwener, Pepijn (2016). “Democracy as a Contested Concept in Post-War Western
Europe: A Comparative Study of Political Debates in France, West Germany, and Italy.”
Historical Journal 59, no. 1: 197–220.
Corman, Juliane, Kim Harris, David Levin, Jeffrey Schulte, and Brittany Shanks. (2015).
“Support for Defense and Military Spending.” Public Opinion Quarterly 79, no.
1: 166–180.
Coser, Lewis A. (1956). The Functions of Social Conflict. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
Cox, Michael, John Ikenberry, and Takashi Inoguchi (2000). American Democracy
Promotion: Impulses, Strategies, and Impacts. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Crozier, Michel J., Samuel P. Huntington, and Joji Watanuki (1975). “The Crisis of
Democracy: Report on the Government of Democracies to the Trilateral Commission.”
New York: New York University Press.
Dahl, Robert A. (1965). “Reflections on Opposition in Western Democracies.”
Government and Opposition 1, no. 1: 7–24.
Dal Bó, Ernesto, Frederico Finan, Olle Folke, Torsten Persson, and Johanna Rickne
(2018). “Economic Losers and Political Winners: Sweden’s Radical Right.” Unpublished
manuscript.
Dancygier, Rafaela, and Stefanie Walter (2015). “Globalization, Labor Market Risks,
and Class Cleavages.” In The Politics of Advanced Capitalism, edited by Hanspeter
Kriesi, Herbert Kitschelt, Pablo Beramendi, and Silja Häusermann, 133–156.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Davis, Christina L. (2019). “Japan: Interest Group Politics, Foreign Policy Linkages, and
the TPP.” In Megaregulation Contested: Global Economic Ordering After TPP, edited
by Benedict Kingsbury, David M. Malone, Paul Mertenskötter, Richard B. Stewart,
Thomas Streinz, and Atsushi Sunami, 573–591. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
De Mesquita, Bruce Bueno, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. Siverson, and James D. Morrow
(2003). The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.
De Neve, Jan-Emmanuel (2011). “The Median Voter Data Set: Voter Preferences Across
50 Democracies.” Electoral Studies 30, no. 4: 865–871.
De Spiegeleire, Stephan, Clarissa Skinner, and Tim Sweijs (2017). “The Rise of Populist
Sovereignism: What it is, Where it Comes from, and What it Means for International
Security and Defense.” Hague Centre for Strategic Studies.
De Vries, Catherine E., and Sara Hobolt (2019). Political Entrepreneurs: The Rise of
Challenger Parties in Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
De Vries, Catherine E., Sara Hobolt, and Stefanie Walter (2021). “Politicizing International
Cooperation: The Mass Public, Political Entrepreneurs, and Political Opportunity
Structures.” International Organization 75, no. 2: 306–332.
212 References
De Vries, Catherine E., and Kathleen R. McNamara (2018). “How Choice Can Save
Europe: The EU Needs Less Technocracy and More Democracy.” Foreign Affairs.
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/europe/2018-05-14/how-choice-can-save-
europe.
DeLong, J. Bradford (1997). “America’s Peacetime Inflation: The 1970s.” In Reducing
Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, edited by Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer,
247–280. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Deporte, Anton William (1979). Europe between the Superpowers: The Enduring Balance.
New Haven: Yale University Press.
Desch, Michael C. (2007). “America’s Liberal Illiberalism: The Ideological Origins of
Overreaction in U.S. Foreign Policy.” International Security 32, no. 3: 7–43.
Deudney, Daniel, and G. John Ikenberry (2021). “Misplaced Restraint: The Quincy
Coalition versus Liberal Internationalism.” Survival 63, no. 4: 7–32.
Di Bella, Gabriel, and Francesco Grigoli (2019). “Optimism, Pessimism, and Short-term
Fluctuations.” Journal of Macroeconomics 60: 79–96.
Dippel, Christian, Robert Gold, and Stephan Heblich (2015). “Globalization and Its (Dis-
)Content: Trade Shocks and Voting Behavior.” NBER Working Paper. Cambridge,
MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/
nbrnberwo/21812.htm.
Doenecke, Justus D. (1979). Not to the Swift: The Old Isolationists in the Cold War Era.
Lewisburg: Bucknell University Press.
Dolezal, Martin (2008). “Austria: Transformation Driven by an Established Party.” In West
European Politics in the Age of Globalization, edited by Hanspeter Kriesi, Edgar Grande,
Romain Lachat, Martin Dolezal, Simon Bornschier, and Timotheos Frey, 105–129.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Domke, William K., Richard C. Eichenberg, and Catherine M. Kelleher (1987).
“Consensus Lost?: Domestic Politics and the ‘Crisis’ in NATO.” World Politics 39, no.
3: 382–407.
Dorman, Andrew M., and Joyce P. Kaufman, eds. (2011). The Future of Transatlantic
Relations: Perceptions, Policy, and Practice. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Dreher, Axel (2006). “Does Globalization Affect Growth? Evidence from a New Index of
Globalization.” Applied Economics 38, no. 10: 1091–1110.
Dreyer, David, and William R. Thompson (2011). Handbook of International Rivalries. 1st
ed. Washington, DC: CQ Press.
Drezner, Daniel W. (2010). “Mercantilist and Realist Perspectives on the Global Political
Economy.” Oxford Research Encyclopedias: International Studies. https://oxfordre.com/
internationalstudies/display/10.1093/acrefore/9780190846626.001.0001/acrefore-
9780190846626-e-260.
Drezner, Daniel W. (2014). “The System Worked: Global Economic Governance during
the Great Recession.” World Politics 66, no. 1: 123–164.
Dudziak, Mary L. (2012). War Time: An Idea, Its History, Its Consequences.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Dupuy, Kendra, James Ron, and Aseem Prakash (2016). “Hands Off My Regime!
Governments’ Restrictions on Foreign Aid to Non-Governmental Organizations in
Poor and Middle-Income Countries.” World Development 84: 299–311.
Eatwell, Roger, and Matthew Goodwin (2018). National Populism: The Revolt Against
Liberal Democracy. London: Pelican.
References 213
Gidron, Noam, and Daniel Ziblatt (2019). “Center-Right Political Parties in Advanced
Democracies.” Annual Review of Political Science 22, no. 1: 17–35.
Gilens, Martin (2014). Affluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and Political Power in
America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Gilmore, Jonathan (2015). The Cosmopolitan Military: Armed Forces and Human Security
in the 21st Century. New Security Challenges Series. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Gilpin, Robert (1975). U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political
Economy of Foreign Direct Investment. New York: Basic Books.
Gilpin, Robert (1987). The Political Economy of International Relations.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Gilpin, Robert (2002). The Challenge of Global Capitalism: The World Economy in the 21st
Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Gingrich, Jane (2019). “Did State Responses to Automation Matter for Voters?” Research
& Politics 6, no. 1: 1–9.
Gingrich, Jane, and Silja Häusermann (2015). “The Decline of the Working-Class Vote,
the Reconfiguration of the Welfare Support Coalition and Consequences for the
Welfare State.” Journal of European Social Policy 25, no. 1: 50–75.
Glanville, Luke (2014). Sovereignty and the Responsibility to Protect: A New History.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Goertz, Gary, Paul F. Diehl, and Alexandru Balas (2016). The Puzzle of Peace: The Evolution
of Peace in the International System. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Golder, Matt (2003). “Explaining Variation in the Success of Extreme Right Parties in
Western Europe.” Comparative Political Studies 36, no. 4: 432–466.
Golosov, Grigorii (2010). “The Effective Number of Parties: A New Approach.” Party
Politics 16, no. 2: 171–192.
Goodman, Sara Wallace, and Thomas B. Pepinsky (2021). “The Exclusionary Foundations
of Embedded Liberalism.” International Organization 75, no. 2: 411–439.
Gourevitch, Peter (1986). Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International
Economic Crises. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Gourevitch, Peter Alexis (1977). “International Trade, Domestic Coalitions, and
Liberty: Comparative Responses to the Crisis of 1873–1896.” Journal of Interdisciplinary
History 8, no. 2: 281–313.
Grajewski, Marcin (2021). “The EU Strategic Autonomy Debate [What Think Tanks Are
Thinking].” European Parliament, March 30, 2021.
Gravelle, Timothy B., Jason Reifler, and Thomas J. Scotto (2017). “The Structure of
Foreign Policy Attitudes in Transatlantic Perspective: Comparing the United States,
United Kingdom, France and Germany.” European Journal of Political Research 56, no.
4: 757–776.
Greene, William E. (2012). Econometric Analysis. 7th ed. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.
Greider, William (2018). “American Hubris, or, How Globalization Brought Us Donald
Trump.” Nation, April 19. https://www.thenation.com/article/archive/american-hub
ris-or-how-globalization-brought-us-donald-trump/
Grewal, David S. (2018). “Three Theses on the Current Crisis of International Liberalism.”
Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies 25, no. 2: 595–621.
Grieco, Joseph M. (1988). “Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique
of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism.” International Organization 42, no. 3: 485–507.
Griffith, Robert (1979). “Old Progressives and the Cold War.” Journal of American History
66, no. 2: 334–347.
216 References
Guiso, Luigi, Helios Herrera, Massimo Morelli, and Tommaso Sonno (2017). “Demand
and Supply of Populism.” EIEF Working Papers Series. Einaudi Institute for Economics
and Finance (EIEF). https://ideas.repec.org/p/eie/wpaper/1703.html.
Gygli, Savina, Florian Haelg, Niklas Potrafke, and Jan-Egbert Sturm (2019). “The KOF
Globalisation Index—Revisited.” Review of International Organizations 14, no.
3: 543–574.
Ha, Eunyoung, and George Tsebelis (2010). “Globalization and Welfare: Which Causes
Which?” APSA Meeting Paper. https://ssrn.com/abstract=1657519.
Hafner-Burton, Emilie M., Edward D. Mansfield, and Jon C. W. Pevehouse (2015).
“Human Rights Institutions, Sovereignty Costs and Democratization.” British Journal
of Political Science 45, no. 1: 1–27.
Hainsworth, Paul (2004). “The Extreme Right in France: The Rise and Rise of Jean-Marie
Le Pen’s Front National.” Representation 40, no. 2: 101–114.
Halikiopoulou, Daphne, Kyriaki Nanou, and Sofia Vasilopoulou (2012). “The Paradox
of Nationalism: The Common Denominator of Radical Right and Radical Left
Euroscepticism.” European Journal of Political Research 51, no. 4: 504–539.
Halikiopoulou, Daphne, and Tim Vlandas (2016). “Risks, Costs and Labour
Markets: Explaining Cross-National Patterns of Far Right Party Success in European
Parliament Elections.” Journal of Common Market Studies 54, no. 3: 636–655.
Hall, Peter A. (2018). “How Growth Strategies Evolve in the Developed Democracies.”
In Growth and Welfare in Advanced Capitalist Economies, edited by Anke Hassel and
Bruno Palier, 57–97. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hall, Peter A. (2020). “The Electoral Politics of Growth Regimes.” Perspectives on Politics
18, no. 1: 185–199.
Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice (2001). Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional
Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Halliday, Fred (1983). “The New Cold War.” Bulletin of Peace Proposals 14, no. 2: 125–129.
Hanrieder, Wolfram F. (1989). Germany, America, and Europe: Forty Years of German
Foreign Policy. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Harteveld, Eelco (2016). “Winning the ‘Losers’ but Losing the ‘Winners’? The Electoral
Consequences of the Radical Right Moving to the Economic Left.” Electoral Studies
44: 225–234.
Hass, Ryan (2021). “Playing the China Card.” Noēma Magazine. May 20. https://www.
noemamag.com/playing-the-china-card/.
Häusermann, Silja (2010). Politics of Welfare State Reform in Continental
Europe: Modernization in Hard Times. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Hayes, Louis D. (2009). Introduction to Japanese Politics. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Hays, Jude (2009). Globalization and the New Politics of Embedded Liberalism.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Hays, Jude C., Sean D. Ehrlich, and Clint Peinhardt (2005). “Government Spending and
Public Support for Trade in the OECD: An Empirical Test of the Embedded Liberalism
Thesis.” International Organization 59, no. 2: 473–494.
Heginbotham, Eric, and Richard J. Samuels (2018). “Active Denial: Redesigning Japan’s
Response to China’s Military Challenge.” International Security 42, no. 4: 128–169.
Heinisch, Reinhard (2003). “Success in Opposition –Failure in Government: Explaining
the Performance of Right-wing Populist Parties in Public Office.” West European
Politics 26, no. 3: 91–130.
References 217
Helleiner, Eric. (2021). “The Diversity of Economic Nationalism.” New Political Economy
26, no. 2: 229–238.
Held, David (1995). Democracy and the Global Order: From the Modern State to
Cosmopolitan Governance. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Hemerijck, Anton (2012). Changing Welfare States. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hemerijck, Anton, ed. (2017). The Uses of Social Investment. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Hemmer, Christopher, and Peter J. Katzenstein (2002). “Why Is There No NATO in Asia?
Collective Identity, Regionalism, and the Origins of Multilateralism.” International
Organization 56, no. 3: 575–607.
Henke, Marina, and Richard Maher (2021). “The Populist Challenge to European
Defense.” Journal of European Public Policy 28, no. 3: 389–406.
Henley, Jon (2017). “Marine Le Pen Promises Liberation from the EU with France-First
Policies.” Guardian, February 5. https://www.theguardian.com/world/2017/feb/05/
marine-le-pen-promises-liberation-from-the-eu-with-france-first-policies.
Hensel, Paul R., Sara McLaughlin Mitchell, Thomas E. Sowers, and Clayton L. Thyne
(2008). “Bones of Contention: Comparing Territorial, Maritime, and River Issues.”
Journal of Conflict Resolution 52, no. 1: 117–143.
Hernández, Enrique, and Hanspeter Kriesi (2016). “The Electoral Consequences of the
Financial and Economic Crisis in Europe.” European Journal of Political Research 55,
no. 2: 203–224.
Hirschman, Albert O. (1945). National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Hiscox, Michael J. (2020). International Trade and Political Conflict. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Höbelt, Lothar (2003). Defiant Populist Jörg Haider and the Politics of Austria.
Indiana: Purdue University Press.
Hix, Simon (1999). The Political System of the European Union. European Union Series.
Palgrave Macmillan.
Hobolt, Sara Binzer (2009). Europe in Question: Referendums on European Integration.
Europe in Question. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hobsbawm, Eric J. (1990). “Goodbye to All That.” Marxism Today, October: 18–23.
Hoffmann, Stanley (1995). “The Crisis of Liberal Internationalism.” Foreign Policy, no.
98: 159–77.
Hoffmann, Stephanie, C. (2013). European Security in NATO’s Shadow: Party Ideologies
and Institution Building. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Holmes, Michael, and Simon Lightfoot (2007). “The Europeanisation of Left Political
Parties: Limits to Adaptation and Consensus.” Capital & Class 31, no. 3: 141–158.
Holsti, Kal J. (1978). “A New International Politics? Diplomacy in Complex
Interdependence.” International Organization 32, no. 2: 513–530.
Holsti, O.R. (1992). “Public Opinion and Foreign Policy: Challenges to the Almond-
Lippmann Consensus.” International Studies Quarterly 36, no. 4: 439–466.
Holsti, Ole R., and James N. Rosenau (1996). “Liberals, Populists, Libertarians, and
Conservatives: The Link between Domestic and International Affairs.” International
Political Science Review 17, no. 1: 29–54.
Hooghe, Liesbet (2003). “Europe Divided?: Elites vs. Public Opinion on European
Integration.” European Union Politics 4, no. 3: 281–304.
218 References
Hooghe, Liesbet, Tobias Lenz, and Gary Marks (2019a). A Theory of International
Organization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hooghe, Liesbet, Tobias Lenz, and Gary Marks (2019b). “Contested World Order: The
Delegitimation of International Governance.” Review of International Organizations
14, no. 4: 731–743.
Hooghe, Liesbet, and Gary Marks (2009). “A Postfunctionalist Theory of European
Integration: From Permissive Consensus to Constraining Dissensus.” British Journal of
Political Science 39, no. 1: 1–23.
Hooghe, Liesbet, and Gary Marks (2015). “Delegation and Pooling in International
Organizations.” Review of International Organizations 10, no. 3: 305–328.
Hooghe, Liesbet, and Gary Marks (2018). “Cleavage Theory Meets Europe’s Crises: Lipset,
Rokkan, and the Transnational Cleavage.” Journal of European Public Policy 25, no.
1: 109–135.
Hooghe, Liesbet, Gary Marks, and Carole J. Wilson (2002). “Does Left/Right Structure
Party Positions on European Integration?” Comparative Political Studies 35, no.
8: 965–989.
Hooghe, Liesbet, Gary Marks, Tobias Lenz, Jeanine Bezuijen, Besir Ceka, Svet Derderyan
(2017). Measuring International Authority. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hopkin, Jonathan (2020). Anti-System Politics: The Crisis of Market Liberalism in Rich
Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hopkin, Jonathan, and Mark Blyth (2019). “The Global Economics of European
Populism: Growth Regimes and Party System Change in Europe.” Government and
Opposition 54, no. 2: 193–225.
Huber, John, and Ronald Inglehart (1995). “Expert Interpretations of Party Space and
Party Locations in 42 Societies.” Party Politics 1, no. 1: 73–111.
Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, and Euijin Jung (2016). “Why Has Trade Stopped Growing? Not
Much Liberalization and Lots of Micro-Protection.” Peterson Institute for International
Economics, March 23, 2016. https://www.piie.com/blogs/trade-investment-policy-
watch/why-has-trade-stopped-growing-not-much-liberalization-and-lots.
Hughes, Christopher W. (2017). “Japan’s Grand Strategic Shift: From the Yoshida Doctrine
to an Abe Doctrine?” In Strategic Asia 2017–18: Power, Ideas, and Military Strategy in
the Asia-Pacific, edited by Ashley J. Tellis, Alison Szalwinski, and Michael Wills, 73–
105. Washington, DC: National Bureau of Asian Research.
Huntington, Samuel P. (1987/1988). “Coping with the Lippmann Gap.” Foreign Affairs 66,
no. 3: 453–477.
Huntington, Samuel P. (1988). “The U.S.: Decline or Renewal?” Foreign Affairs 67, no.
2: 76–96.
Huntington, Samuel P. (1993). “The Clash of Civilizations?” Foreign Affairs 72, no.
3: 22–49.
Hutter, Swen, Edgar Grande, and Hanspeter Kriesi, eds. (2016). Politicising
Europe: Integration and Mass Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ikenberry, G. John (2001). After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the
Rebuilding of Order after Major Wars. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Ikenberry, G. John (2009). “Liberal Internationalism 3.0: America and the Dilemmas of
Liberal World Order.” Perspectives on Politics 7, no. 1: 71–87.
Ikenberry, G. John (2019). “Reflections on After Victory.” British Journal of Politics and
International Relations 21, no. 1: 5–19.
References 219
Ikenberry, G. John (2020a). A World Safe for Democracy: Liberal Internationalism and the
Crises of Global Order. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Ikenberry, G. John (2020b). “The Light That Failed: Why the West Is Losing the Fight for
Democracy.” Foreign Affairs 14, no. 1: 133–136.
Ikenberry, G. John (2020c). “The Next Liberal Order: The Age of Contagion Demands
More Internationalism, Not Less.” Foreign Affairs 99, no. 4:133–142.
Immerwahr, Daniel (2020). How to Hide an Empire: A History of the Greater United States.
New York: Vintage.
Inglehart, Ronald, and Pippa Norris (2017). “Trump and the Populist Authoritarian
Parties: The Silent Revolution in Reverse.” Perspectives on Politics 15, no. 2: 443–454.
Inglot, Tomasz (2008). Welfare States in East Central Europe, 1919– 2004.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2009). “World Economic Outlook: Crisis and
Recovery.” World Economic and Financial Surveys. https://www.imf.org/en/Publicati
ons/WEO/Issues/2016/12/31/Crisis-and-Recovery.
Irwin, Douglas A. (1993). “Multilateral and bilateral trade policies in the world trading
system: an historical perspective.” New Dimensions in Regional Integration 90: 90–119.
Iversen, Torben (2005). Capitalism, Democracy, and Welfare. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Iversen, Torben, and Thomas R. Cusack (2000). “The Causes of Welfare State
Expansion: Deindustrialization or Globalization?” World Politics 52, no. 3: 313–349.
Jackman, Robert W., and Karin Volpert (1996). “Conditions Favoring Parties of the
Extreme Right in Western Europe.” British Journal of Political Science 26, no. 4: 501–521.
Jacobs, Lawrence R., and Benjamin I. Page (2005). “Who Influences U.S. Foreign Policy?”
American Political Science Review 99, no. 1: 107–123.
Jamitzky, Ulli (2015). “Diffusion of Japanese Preferential Trade Agreements: Why Is No
Evaluation Underway?” Japanese Economy 41, no. 1–2: 1–13.
Jenson, Jane (2010). “Diffusing Ideas for After Neoliberalism: The Social Investment
Perspective in Europe and Latin America.” Global Social Policy 10, no. 1: 59–84.
Jesuit, David, and Vincent Mahler (2004). “Electoral Support for Extreme Right-Wing
Parties: A Subnational Analysis of Western European Elections in the 1990s.” LIS
Working Paper Series, no. 391. Luxembourg Income Study (LIS), Luxembourg.
Johnston, Alastair Iain (2019). “The Failures of the ‘Failure of Engagement’ with China.”
Washington Quarterly 42, no. 2: 99–114.
Judt, Tony (2005). Postwar: A History of Europe since 1945. London: Vintage.
Kafura, Craig, and Dina Smeltz (2021). “Republicans and Democrats Split on China
Policy.” The Chicago Council on Global Affairs. December 10. https://www.thechicago
council.org/research/public-opinion-survey/republicans-and-democrats-split-china-
policy.
Kagan, Robert (2003). Paradise and Power: America and Europe in the New World Order.
New York: Alfred A. Knopf.
Kahl, Colin, and Thomas Wright (2021). Aftershocks: Pandemic Politics and the End of the
Old International Order. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Kahler, Miles (2013). “Economic Crisis and Global Governance: The Stability of a
Globalized World.” Procedia—Social and Behavioral Sciences 77: 55–64.
Kaldor, Mary (2000). “Civilising Globalisation? The Implications of the ‘Battle in Seattle.’”
Millennium 29, no. 1: 105–114.
220 References
Kjar, Scott A., and William L. Anderson (2010). “War and the Austrian School: Applying
the Economics of the Founders.” Economics of Peace and Security Journal 5, no. 1: 6–11.
Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, and Andrea Volkens, Ian Budge, Judith Bara, and Michael
D. McDonald (2006). Mapping Policy Preferences II: Estimates for Parties, Electors,
and Governments in Eastern Europe, European Union and OECD 1990– 2003.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Knigge, Pia (1998). “The Ecological Correlates of Right-wing Extremism in Western
Europe.” European Journal of Political Research 34, no. 2: 249–279.
Konstantinidis, Nikitas, Matakos Konstantinos, and Mutlu-Eren Hande (2019). “ ‘Take
Back Control’? The Effects of Supranational Integration on Party-System Polarization.”
Review of International Organizations 14, no. 2: 297–333.
Koopmans, Ruud, and Michael Zürn (2019). “Cosmopolitanism and
Communitarianism—How Globalization Is Reshaping Politics in the Twenty-First
Century.” In The Struggle Over Borders: Cosmopolitanism and Communitarianism, ed-
ited by Michael Zürn, Oliver Strijbis, Pieter de Wilde, Ruud Koopmans, and Wolfgang
Merkel, 1–34. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Kornprobst, Markus, and T.V. Paul (2021). “Globalization, Deglobalization and the
Liberal International Order.” International Affairs (London) 97, no. 5: 1305–1316.
Korpi, Walter, and Joakim Palme (1998). “The Paradox of Redistribution and Strategies of
Equality: Welfare State Institutions, Inequality, and Poverty in the Western Countries.”
American Sociological Review 63, no. 5: 661–687.
Korpi, Walter, and Joakim Palme (2003). “New Politics and Class Politics in the Context
of Austerity and Globalization: Welfare State Regress in 18 Countries, 1975–95.”
American Political Science Review 97, no. 3: 425–446.
Krastev, Ivan, and Stephen Holmes (2019). “How Liberalism Became ‘the God That Failed’
in Eastern Europe.” Guardian, October 24, sec. World news. https://www.theguardian.
com/world/2019/oct/24/western-liberalism-failed-post-communist-eastern-europe.
Krastev, Ivan, and Stephen Holmes (2020). The Light That Failed: A Reckoning.
London: Penguin Books.
Krauthammer, Charles (1990). “The Unipolar Moment.” Foreign Affairs 70, no. 1: 23–33.
Kriesi, Hanspeter, Edgar Grande, Romain Lachat, Martin Dolezal, Simon Bornschier,
and Timotheos Frey (2008). West European Politics in the Age of Globalization.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Kupchan, Charles A. (2020). Isolationism: A History of America’s Efforts to Shield Itself
from the World. New York: Oxford University Press.
Kupchan, Charles A., and Peter L. Trubowitz (2007). “Dead Center: The Demise of Liberal
Internationalism in the United States.” International Security 32, no. 2: 7–44.
Kupchan, Charles A., and Peter L. Trubowitz (2021). “The Home Front: Why an
Internationalist Foreign Policy Needs a Stronger Domestic Foundation.” Foreign
Affairs 100, no. 3: 92–101.
Kurth, James R. (1979). “The Political Consequences of the Product Cycle: Industrial
History and Political Outcomes.” International Organization 33, no. 1: 1–34.
Kurzer, Paulette (1993). Business and Banking: Political Change and Economic Integration
in Western Europe. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Laakso, Markku, and Rein Taagepera (1979). “‘Effective’ Number of Parties: A Measure
with Application to West Europe.” Comparative Political Studies 12, no. 1: 3–27.
Lake, David A. (2007). “Delegating Divisible Sovereignty: Sweeping a Conceptual
Minefield.” Review of International Organizations 2, no. 3: 219–237.
222 References
Lake, David A. (2018). “International Legitimacy Lost? Rule and Resistance When
America Is First.” Perspectives on Politics 16, no. 1: 6–21.
Lake, David A., Lisa L. Martin, and Thomas Risse (2021). “Challenges to the Liberal
Order: Reflections on International Organization.” International Organization 75, no.
2: 225–257.
Lascurettes, Kyle M. (2020). Orders of Exclusion: Great Powers and the Strategic Sources
of Foundational Rules in International Relations. New York: Oxford University Press.
Layne, Christopher (1993). “The Unipolar Illusion: Why New Great Powers Will Rise.”
International Security 17, no. 4: 5–51.
Layne, Christopher (1997). “From Preponderance to Offshore Balancing: America’s
Future Grand Strategy.” International Security 22, no. 1: 86–124.
Leali, Giorgio (2021). “EU-China Deal Spells Trouble for Macron at Home.” Politico. March
18. https://www.politico.eu/article/eu-china-deal-spells-trouble-for-macron-at-home/
Leffler, Melvyn P. (2019). “China Isn’t the Soviet Union: Confusing the Two Is Dangerous.”
The Atlantic, December 2. https://www.theatlantic.com/ideas/archive/2019/12/cold-
war-china-purely-optional/601969/.
Lefkofridi, Zoe, and Elie Michel (2017). “The Electoral Politics of Solidarity: The Welfare
Agendas of Radical Right Parties.” In The Strains of Commitment: The Political Sources
of Solidarity in Diverse Societies, edited by Keith Banting and Will Kymlicka, 233–267.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Levi, Margaret (1988). Of Rule and Revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Liff, Adam P. (2015). “Japan’s Defense Policy: Abe the Evolutionary.” Washington
Quarterly 38, no. 2: 79–99.
Lim, Sijeong, and Brian Burgoon (2020). “Globalization and Support for Unemployment
Spending in Asia: Do Asian Citizens Want to Embed Liberalism?” Socio-Economic
Review 18, no. 2: 519–553.
Lind, Jennifer M. (2004). “Pacifism or Passing the Buck? Testing Theories of Japanese
Security Policy.” International Security 29, no. 1: 92–121.
Lind, Jennifer M., and William C. Wohlforth (2019). “The Future of the Liberal Order Is
Conservative: A Strategy to Save the System.” Foreign Affairs 98, no. 2: 70–80.
Lind, Michael (2018). “U.S. & China Relations: Cold War II.” National Review, May 10.
https://w ww.nationalreview.com/magazine/2018/05/28/us-china-relations-cold-
war-ii/.
Lindberg, Leon N., and Stuart A. Scheingold (1970). Europe’s Would-Be Polity: Patterns of
Change in the European Community. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall.
Lindberg, Tod, ed. (2005). Beyond Paradise and Power: Europe, America, and the Future of
a Troubled Partnership. New York: Routledge.
Lindert, Peter H. (2004). Growing Public: Social Spending and Economic Growth since the
Eighteenth Century: Volume 1: The Story. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lindsay, James M. (2000). “The New Apathy: How an Uninterested Public Is Reshaping
Foreign Policy.” Foreign Affairs 79, no. 5: 2–8.
Lindvall, Johannes, and David Rueda (2018). “Public Opinion, Party Politics, and the
Welfare State.” In Welfare Democracies and Party Politics: Explaining Electoral Dynamics
in Times of Changing Welfare Capitalism, edited by Philip Manow, Bruno Palier, and
Hanna Schwander, 89–118. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Lippmann, Walter (1943). U.S. Foreign Policy: Shield of the Republic. Boston: Little, Brown.
Lipset, Seymour M., and Stein Rokkan (1967). Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross-
National Perspectives. New York: Free Press.
References 223
Lowe, Will, Kenneth Benoit, Slava Mikhaylov, and Michael Laver (2011). “Scaling
Policy Preferences from Coded Political Texts.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 36, no.
1: 123–155.
Lubbers, Marcel, Mérove Gijsberts, and Peer Scheepers (2002). “Extreme Right-wing
Voting in Western Europe.” European Journal of Political Research 41, no. 3: 345–378.
Lubbers, Marcel, and Peer Scheepers (2000). “Individual and Contextual Characteristics
of the German Extreme Right-Wing Vote in the 1990s. A Test of Complementary
Theories.” European Journal of Political Research 38, no. 1: 63–94.
Lundestad, Geir (1986). “Empire by Invitation? The United States and Western Europe,
1945–1952.” Journal of Peace Research 23, no. 3: 263–277.
Luttwak, Edward (2009). The Grand Strategy of the Byzantine Empire. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
Lynch, Cecilia, M. (1999). Beyond Appeasement: Interpreting Interwar Peace Movements
in World Politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Madison, Cory (2019). “Tracking Public Support for Japan’s Remilitarization Policies: An
Examination of Elitist and Pluralist Governance.” Asian Journal of Comparative Politics
4, no. 2: 123–140.
Mair, Peter (1997). Party System Change: Approaches and Interpretations.
Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Mair, Peter (2013). Ruling the Void: The Hollowing of Western Democracy. London: Verso.
Mann, Jim (1999). About Face: A History of America’s Curious Relationship with China
from Nixon to Clinton. New York: Alfred Knopf.
Mann, Michael (1988). States, War and Capitalism: Studies in Political Sociology.
Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
March, Luke, and Cas Mudde (2005). “What’s Left of the Radical Left? The European
Radical Left After 1989: Decline and Mutation.” Comparative European Politics 3, no.
1: 23–49.
Margalit, Yotam (2019). “Economic Insecurity and the Causes of Populism, Reconsidered.”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 33, no. 4: 152–170.
Markowitz, Jonathan N., and Christopher J. Fariss (2018). “Power, Proximity, and
Democracy: Geopolitical Competition in the International System.” Journal of Peace
Research 55, no. 1: 78–93.
Marks, Gary, Tobias Lenz, Besir Ceka, and Brian Burgoon (2014). “Discovering
Cooperation: A Contractual Approach to Institutional Change in Regional
International Organizations.” EUI Working Paper, 65, Robert Schuman Centre for
Advanced Studies, Global Governance Program.
Marks, Gary, and Marco R. Steenbergen, eds. (2004). European Integration and Political
Conflict. Themes in European Governance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Marquand, David (2004). Decline of the Public: The Hollowing Out of Citizenship.
Malden: Polity Press.
Martill, Benjamin (2019). “Center of Gravity: Domestic Institutions and the Victory of
Liberal Strategy in Cold War Europe.” Security Studies 28, no. 1: 116–158.
Mastanduno, Michael (1997). “Preserving the Unipolar Moment: Realist Theories and
U.S. Grand Strategy after the Cold War.” International Security 21, no. 4: 49–80.
Mastanduno, Michael (1999). “A Realist View: Three Images of the Coming International
Order.” In International Order and the Future of World Politics, edited by Paul T. V. and
Hall John A., 19–40. London: Cambridge University Press.
Mastanduno, Michael (2020). “Trump’s Trade Revolution.” The Forum 17, no. 4: 523–548.
224 References
Mathews, Jessica T. (1997). “Power Shift.” Foreign Affairs 76, no. 1: 50–66.
Mau, Steffen, and Christoph Burkhardt (2009). “Migration and Welfare State Solidarity in
Western Europe.” Journal of European Social Policy 19, no. 3: 213–229.
Mayer, Arno J. (1969). “Internal Causes and Purposes of War in Europe, 1870–1956: A
Research Assignment.” Journal of Modern History 41, no. 3: 292–303.
Mazower, Mark (1999). Dark Continent: Europe’s Twentieth Century.
London: Penguin Books.
McCormick, James M., and Eugene R. Wittkopf (1992). “At the Water’s Edge: The Effects
of Party, Ideology, and Issues on Congressional Foreign Policy Voting, 1947 to 1988.”
American Politics Quarterly 20, no. 1: 26–53.
McGregor, R. Michael (2013). “Measuring ‘Correct Voting’ Using Comparative Manifestos
Project Data.” Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties 23, no. 1: 1–26.
McLaren, Lauren (2005). Identity, Interests and Attitudes to European Integration. Palgrave
Studies in European Union Politics. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Mead, Walter Russell (2017). “The Jacksonian Revolt: American Populism and the Liberal
Order.” Foreign Affairs 96, no. 2: 2–7.
Mearsheimer, John J. (1990). “Back to the Future: Instability in Europe after the Cold
War.” International Security 15, no. 1: 5–56.
Mearsheimer, John J. (2001). The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: Norton.
Mearsheimer, John J. (2011). “Kissing Cousins: Nationalism and Realism.” Unpublished
manuscript. http://www.sneps.net/t/images/Articles/11Mearsheimer_national
ism%20and%20realism.PDF.
Mearsheimer, John J. (2014). “Why the Ukraine Crisis Is the West’s Fault: The Liberal
Delusions That Provoked Putin.” Foreign Affairs 93, no. 5: 1–12.
Mearsheimer, John J. (2018). Great Delusion: Liberal Dreams and International Realities.
New Haven: Yale University Press.
Mearsheimer, John J. (2019). “Bound to Fail: The Rise and Fall of the Liberal International
Order.” International Security 43, no. 4: 7–50.
Mettler, Suzanne, and Claire Leavitt (2019). “Public Policy and Political Dysfunction,”
in Can America Govern Itself? edited by Frances E. Lee and Nolan McCarty, 239–71.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Michel, Elie (2019). “The Strategic Adaption of the Populist Radical Right in Western
Europe: Shifting the Party Message,” in The Oxford Handbook of Electoral Persuasion,
edited by Elizabeth Suhay, Bernard Grofman, and Alexander H. Trechsel, 838–862.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Midford, Paul (2011). Rethinking Japanese Public Opinion and Security: From Pacifism to
Realism? Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Miller, S.A. (2016). “Donald Trump Vows to Cancel Trans- Pacific Partnership as
President, Puts NAFTA on Notice.” Washington Times, June 28. https://m.washingtonti
mes.com/news/2016/jun/28/donald-trump-vows-to-cancel-trans-pacific-partners/
Milner, Helen V. (2019). “Globalisation, Populism and the Decline of the Welfare State.”
Survival 61, no. 2: 91–96.
Milner, Helen V., and Benjamin Judkins (2004). “Partisanship, Trade Policy, and
Globalization: Is There a Left-Right Divide on Trade Policy?” International Studies
Quarterly 48, no. 1: 95–119.
Mishra, Ramesh (1993). “Social Policy in the Postmodern World.” In New Perspectives on
the Welfare State in Europe, edited by Catherine Jones, 18–42. London: Routledge.
References 225
Mochizuki, Mike M. (1983). “Japan’s Search for Strategy.” International Security 8, no.
3: 152.
Moravcsik, Andrew (1998). The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from
Messina to Maastricht. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Moravcsik, Andrew (2000). “The Origins of Human Rights Regimes: Democratic
Delegation in Postwar Europe.” International Organization 54, no. 2: 217–252.
Morefield, Jeanne (2014). Empire Without Imperialism: Anglo-American Decline and
Politics of Deflection. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mudde, Cas (2007). Populist Radical Right Parties in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Mueller, John (1994). “The Catastrophe Quota: Trouble after the Cold War.” Journal of
Conflict Resolution 38, no. 3: 355–375.
Mutz, Diana C. (2018). “Status Threat, Not Economic Hardship, Explains the 2016
Presidential Vote.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 115, no. 19: 4330–4339.
Narizny, Kevin (2003). “Both Guns and Butter, or Neither: Class Interests in the Political
Economy of Rearmament.” American Political Science Review 97, no. 2: 203–220.
Nichols, Christopher McKnight (2011). Promise and Peril: America at the Dawn of a
Global Age. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Nikolaidou, Eftychia (2008). “The Demand for Military Expenditure: Evidence from the
EU15 (1961–2005).” Defence and Peace Economics 19, no. 4: 273–292.
Nordlinger, Eric (1996). Isolationism Reconfigured: American Foreign Policy for a New
Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Norris, Pippa (2000). “Global Governance and Cosmopolitan Citizens.” Governance in a
Globalizing World 155: 173–175.
North, Douglass C., John Joseph Wallis, and Barry R. Weingast (2009). Violence and
Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Nuti, Leopoldo, Frédéric Bozo, Marie- Pierre Rey, and Bernd Rother (2015). The
Euromissile Crisis and the End of the Cold War. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson
Center Press.
Nye, Joseph S. (1995). “East Asian Security: The Case for Deep Engagement.” Foreign
Affairs 74, no. 4: 90–102.
Nye, Joseph S. (2019). “The Rise and Fall of American Hegemony from Wilson to Trump.”
International Affairs 95, no. 1: 63–80.
Oatley, Thomas (2015). A Political Economy of American Hegemony: Buildups, Booms, and
Busts. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Obinger, Herbert, and Shinyong Lee (2013). “The Cold War and the Welfare State in
Divided Korea and Germany.” Journal of International and Comparative Social Policy
29, no. 3: 258–275.
Obinger, Herbert, and Klaus Petersen (2015). “Review Article: Mass Warfare and the
Welfare State—Causal Mechanisms and Effects.” British Journal of Political Science 47,
no. 1: 203–227.
Obinger, Herbert, and Carina Schmitt (2011). “Guns and Butter? Regime Competition
and the Welfare State during the Cold War.” World Politics 63, no. 2: 246–270.
Obinger, Herbert, Klaus Petersen, and Peter Starke, eds. (2018). Warfare and
Welfare: Military Conflict and Welfare State Development in Western Countries.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
226 References
O’Connor, James (1973). The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Oesch, Daniel, and Line Rennwald (2018). “Electoral Competition in Europe’s New
Tripolar Political Space: Class Voting for the Left, Centre-Right and Radical Right.”
European Journal of Political Research 57, no. 4: 783–807.
Olson, Mancur (1982). The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation,
and Social Rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Oltermann, Philip (2021). “Stand up to China and Putin? Foreign policy at heart of
Germany vote.” Guardian. May 2. https://www.theguardian.com/world/2021/may/02/
stand-up-to-china-and-putin-foreign-policy-at-heart-of-germany-vote.
Orbie, Jan, and Olufemi Babarinde (2008). “The Social Dimension of Globalization and
EU Development Policy: Promoting Core Labour Standards and Corporate Social
Responsibility.” Journal of European Integration 30, no. 3: 459–477.
Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2019). OECD
National Accounts Statistics (database). https://doi.org/10.1787/na-data-en.
Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2020). Country
Statistical Profiles: Key Tables from OECD (electronic resource). English ed. https://doi.
org/10.1787/20752288.
Palmer, Glenn, Michael R. Kenwick, Mikaela Karstens, Chase Bloch, Nick Dietrich, Kayla
Kahn, and Kellan Ritter (2021). “The MID5 Dataset, 2011–2014: Procedures, Coding
Rules, and Description.” Conflict Management and Peace Science 39, no. 4: 470–482.
Pástor, Lubos, and Pietro Veronesi (2018). “Inequality Aversion, Populism, and the
Backlash Against Globalization.” NBER Working Paper. National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://www.nber.org/papers/w24900.
Patrick, Stewart (2017). The Sovereignty Wars: Reconciling America with the World.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Pempel, T. J. (1998). Regime Shift: Comparative Dynamics of the Japanese Political
Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Petersen, Klaus (2013). “The Early Cold War and the Western Welfare State.” Journal of
International and Comparative Social Policy 29, no. 3: 226–240.
Piazza, James (2001). “De-Linking Labor: Labor Unions and Social Democratic Parties
under Globalization.” Party Politics 7, no. 4: 413–435.
Pieterse, Jan Nederveen (2006). “Emancipatory Cosmopolitanism: Towards an Agenda.”
Development and Change 37, no. 6: 1247–57.
Pildes, Richard H. (2021). “The Age of Political Fragmentation.” Journal of Democracy 32,
no. 4: 146–159.
Plehwe, Dieter, Quinn Slobodian, and Philip Mirowski, eds. (2020). Nine Lives of
Neoliberalism. London: Verso.
Polanyi, Karl (1944). The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our
Time. New York: Farrar & Rinehart.
Pontusson, Jonas (2005). Inequality and Prosperity: Social Europe vs. Liberal America.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Porter, Patrick (2020). The False Promise of Liberal Order: Nostalgia, Delusion and the Rise
of Trump. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Posen, Barry (2014). Restraint: A New Foundation for U.S. Grand Strategy. Ithaca: Cornell
University Press.
Prasad, Monica (2006). The Politics of Free Markets: The Rise of Neoliberal Economic Policies
in Britain, France, Germany, and the United States. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
References 227
Pring, Hayley (2021). “Does Populism Affect Trade? How Audience Costs Affect the
Design of Preferential Trade Agreements.” PEIO Draft. https://www.peio.me/wp-cont
ent/uploads/2021/papers/PEIOo21_paper_86.pdf.
Przeworski, Adam (2019). Crises of Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Przeworski, Adam, and John Sprague (1986). Paper Stones: A History of Electoral
Socialism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Pyle, Kenneth B. (2018). Japan in the American Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Rathbun, Brian C. (2004). Partisan Interventions: European Party Politics and Peace
Enforcement in the Balkans. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Rehm, Philipp (2009). “Risks and Redistribution: An Individual- Level Analysis.”
Comparative Political Studies 42, no. 7: 855–881.
Reid-Henry, Simon (2019). Empire of Democracy: The Remaking of the West Since the Cold
War, 1971–2017. New York: Simon & Schuster.
Rennwald, Line, and Jonas Pontusson (2021). “Paper Stones Revisited: Class Voting,
Unionization and the Electoral Decline of the Mainstream Left.” Perspectives on Politics
9, no. 1: 36–54.
Rixen, Thomas, and Bernhard Zangl (2013). “The Politicization of International
Economic Institutions in US Public Debates.” Review of International Organizations 8,
no. 3: 363–387.
Rodrik, Dani (1998). “Has Globalization Gone Too Far?” Challenge 41, no. 2: 81–94.
Rodrik, Dani (2011). The Globalization Paradox: Why Global Markets, States, and
Democracy Can’t Coexist. Oxford: Oxford University Press USA—OSO.
Rodrik, Dani (2021). “Why Does Globalization Fuel Populism? Economics, Culture, and
the Rise of Right-Wing Populism.” Annual Review of Economics 13: 133–170.
Rodrik, Dani, and Charles F. Sabel (2022). “Building a Good Jobs Economy.” In A Political
Economy of Justice, edited by Danielle Allen, Yochai Benkler, Leah Downey, Rebecca
Henderson, and Josh Simmons, 61–95. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Rommel, Tobias, and Stefanie Walter (2018). “The Electoral Consequences of
Offshoring: How the Globalization of Production Shapes Party Preferences.”
Comparative Political Studies 51, no. 5: 621–658.
Rone, Julia (2020). Contesting Austerity and Free Trade in the EU: Protest Diffusion in
Complex Media and Political Arenas. New York: Routledge.
Rooduijn, Matthijs (2018). “What Unites the Voter Bases of Populist Parties? Comparing
the Electorates of 15 Populist Parties.” European Political Science Review 10, no.
3: 351–368.
Rooduijn, Matthijs, Brian Burgoon, Erika J. van Elsas, and Herman G. van de Werfhorst
(2017). “Radical Distinction: Support for Radical Left and Radical Right Parties in
Europe.” European Union Politics 18, no. 4: 536–559.
Rooduijn, Matthijs, Stijn Van Kessel, Caterina Froio, Andrea Pirro, Sarah De Lange,
Daphne Halikiopoulou, Paul Lewis, Cas Mudde, and Paul Taggart (2019). “The
PopuList: An Overview of Populist, Far Right, Far Left and Eurosceptic Parties in
Europe.” www.popu-list.org.
Rosenbluth, Frances McCall (2012). “Japan in 2011: Cataclysmic Crisis and Chronic
Deflation.” Asian Survey 52, no. 1: 15–27.
Rosenbluth, Frances McCall, and Michael F. Thies (2010). Japan Transformed: Political
Change and Economic Restructuring. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
228 References
Rosenboim, Or (2017). The Emergence of Globalism: Visions of World Order in Britain and
the United States, 1939–1950. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Röth, Leonce, Alexandre Afonso, and Dennis C. Spies (2018). “The Impact of Populist
Radical Right Parties on Socio-Economic Policies.” European Political Science Review
10, no. 3: 325–350.
Ruggie, John Gerard (1982). “International Regimes, Transactions, and
Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order.” International
Organization 36, no. 2: 379–415.
Ruggie, John Gerard (2002). “At Home Abroad, Abroad at Home: International
Liberalization and Domestic Stability in the New World Economy.” In The Globalization
of Liberalism, edited by Eivind Hovden and Edward Keene, 99–122. London: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Rydgren, Jens (2005). “Is Extreme Right-Wing Populism Contagious? Explaining the
Emergence of a New Party Family.” European Journal of Political Research 44, no.
3: 413–437.
Samuels, Richard J. (2007). Securing Japan: Tokyo’s Grand Strategy and the Future of East
AsiaIthaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Sandler, Todd, and Justin George (2016). “Military Expenditure Trends for 1960–2014
and What They Reveal.” Global Policy 7, no. 2: 174–184.
Sapolsky, Harvey M., Benjamin H. Friedman, Eugene Gholz, and Daryl G. Press (2009).
“Restraining Order: For Strategic Modesty.” World Affairs 172, no. 2: 84–94.
Sartori, Giovanni (1976). Parties and Party Systems: A Framework for Analysis.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Sassoon, Donald (1992). “The Rise and Fall of West European Communism 1939–48.”
Contemporary European History 1, no. 2: 139–169.
Sassoon, Donald (1996). Social Democracy at the Heart of Europe. London: Institute for
Public Policy Research.
Sassoon, Donald (2014). One Hundred Years of Socialism: The West European Left in the
Twentieth Century. London: I.B. Tauris.
Scharpf, Fritz W. (1991). Crisis and Choice in European Social Democracy. Ithaca: Cornell
University Press.
Scharpf, Fritz W. (2000). “Economic Changes, Vulnerabilities, and Institutional
Capabilities.” In Welfare and Work in the Open Economy Volume I: From Vulnerability
to Competitiveness in Comparative Perspective, edited by Fritz W. Scharpf and Vivien A.
Schmidt, 21–121 Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Scheve, Kenneth F., and Matthew J. Slaughter (2001). “Labor Market Competition and
Individual Preferences over Immigration Policy.” Review of Economics and Statistics 83,
no. 1: 133–145.
Scheve, Kenneth, and Matthew J. Slaughter (2004). “Economic Insecurity and the
Globalization of Production.” American Journal of Political Science 48, no. 4: 662–674.
Scheve, Kenneth, and Matthew J. Slaughter (2006). “Public Opinion, International
Economic Integration, and the Welfare State.” In Globalization and Egalitarian
Redistribution, edited by Pranab Bardhan, Samuels Bowles, and Michael Wallerstein,
217–60. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Schilde, Kaija E., Stephanie B. Anderson, and Andrew D. Garnerb (2019). “A More Martial
Europe? Public Opinion, Permissive Consensus, and EU Defence Policy.” European
Security 28, no. 2: 153–172.
References 229
Schlesinger, Arthur M. (1949). The Vital Center: The Politics of Freedom. Boston: Houghton
Mifflin Company.
Schonhardt-Bailey, Cheryl (1998). “Parties and Interests in the ‘Marriage of Iron and Rye’.”
British Journal of Political Science 28, no. 2: 291–332.
Schoppa, Leonard J. (2011). The Evolution of Japan’s Party System: Politics and Policy in an
Era of Institutional Change. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.
Schultz, Kenneth A. (2001). Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy. Cambridge;
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Schweller, Randall (2018). “Opposite but Compatible Nationalisms: A Neoclassical
Realist Approach to the Future of US–China Relations.” Chinese Journal of International
Politics 11, no. 1: 23–48.
Semuels, Alana (2016). “TPP’s Death Won’t Help the American Middle Class.” Atlantic,
November 15. https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2016/11/tpps-death-
wont-help-the-american-middle-class/507683/.
Shantz, Jeff (2008). “Social Policy.” In Ruud van Dijk, ed., Encyclopedia of the Cold War,
vol. 2, 797–799. New York: Routledge.
Shaw, Timothy M. (2016). Comparative Regionalisms for Development in the 21st
Century: Insights from the Global South. New York: Routledge.
Sheehan, James J. (2008). Where Have All the Soldiers Gone? The Transformation of
Modern Europe. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.
Sheingate, Adam D. (2001). The Rise of the Agricultural Welfare State: Institutions and
Interest Group Power in the United States, France and Japan. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Shoch, James (2001). Trading Blows: Party Competition and U.S. Trade Policy in a
Globalizing Era. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
Sil, Rudra, and Peter J. Katzenstein (2010). “Analytic Eclecticism in the Study of World
Politics: Reconfiguring Problems and Mechanisms across Research Traditions.”
Perspectives on Politics 8, no. 2: 411–431.
Silver, Laura, Kat Devlin, and Christine Huang (2021). “Most Americans Support Tough
Stance Toward China on Human Rights, Economic Issues.” Pew Research Center, 4
March. https://www.pewresearch.org/global/2021/03/04/most-americans-support-
tough-stance-toward-china-on-human-rights-economic-issues/.
Silver, Laura, Christine Huang, and Laura Clancy (2022). “Negative Views of China Tied
to Critical Views of Its Policies on Human Rights.” Pew Research Center, July 29. https://
www.pewresearch.org/global/2022/06/29/negative-views-of-china-tied-to-critical-
views-of-its-policies-on-human-rights/.
Simmel, Georg (1955). Conflict and the Web of Group-Affiliations. New York: Free Press.
Simmons, Beth A., Frank Dobbin, and Geoffrey Garrett (2008). “Introduction: The
Diffusion of Liberalization.” In The Global Diffusion of Markets and Democracy, edited by
Beth A. Simmons, Frank Dobbin, and Geoffrey Garrett, 1–63. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Skocpol, Theda (1992). Protecting Soldiers and Mothers: The Political Origins of Social
Policy in the United States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Slobodian, Quinn (2018). Globalists: The End of Empire and the Birth of Neoliberalism.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Snyder, Jack (2019). “The Broken Bargain: How Nationalism Came Back.” Foreign Affairs
98, no. 2: 54–60.
230 References
Snyder, Jack, Robert Y. Shapiro, and Yaeli Bloch-Elkon (2009). “Free Hand Abroad, Divide
and Rule at Home.” World Politics 61, no. 1: 155–187.
Spengler, Oswald (1926). The Decline of the West, Vol.1: Form and Actuality. Translated by
C. F. Atkinson. London: George Allen and Unwin.
Sprout, Harold, and Margaret Sprout (1968). “The Dilemma of Rising Demands and
Insufficient Resources.” World Politics 20, no. 4: 660–693.
Stephens, John D., Evelyne Huber, and Leonard Ray (1999). “The Welfare State in
Hard Time.” In Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, edited by
Herbert Kitschelt, Peter Lange, Gary Marks, and John D. Stephens, 164– 193.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Stockholm International Peace Research Institute, (SIPRI), and Stockholm International
Peace Research Institute (2018). “Military Expenditures Database.” https://www.sipri.
org/databases/milex.
Strange, Susan (1997). “The Erosion of the State.” Current History 96, no. 613: 365–369.
Strange, Susan (1999). “The Westfailure System.” Review of International Studies 25, no.
3: 345–354.
Streeck, Wolfgang (2017). Buying Time: The Delayed Crisis of Democratic Capitalism.
Revised second edition. London: Verso.
Subramanian, Arvind, and Martin Kessler (2013). “The Hyperglobalization of Trade and
its Future.” Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper No. 13–6.
Swank, Duane (2002). Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy Change in
Developed Welfare States. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Swank, Duane (2018). “Comparative Political Parties Dataset: Electoral, Legislative,
and Government Strength of Political Parties by Ideological Group in 21 Capitalist
Democracies, 1950– 2015.” Electronic Database. Department of Political Science,
Marquette University. https://datafinder.qog.gu.se/dataset/sw.
Swank, Duane, and Hans-Georg Betz (2003). “Globalization, the Welfare State and Right-
Wing Populism in Western Europe.” Socio-Economic Review 1, no. 2: 215–245.
Szöcsik, Edina, and Alina Polyakova (2019). “Euroscepticism and the Electoral Success
of the Far Right: The Role of the Strategic Interaction between Center and Far Right.”
European Political Science 18, no. 3: 400–420.
Talbott, Strobe (2008). The Great Experiment: The Story of Ancient Empires, Modern States,
and the Quest for a Global Nation. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Tarrow, Sidney (2005). The New Transnational Activism. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Thelen, Kathleen (2014). Varieties of Liberalization and the New Politics of Social Solidarity.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Thrall, A. Trevor, and Benjamin H. Friedman (2018). US Grand Strategy in the 21st
Century: The Case for Restraint. London: Routledge.
Thurow, Lester C. (1992). Head to Head: The Coming Economic Battle Among Japan,
Europe, and America. New York: William Morrow & Co.
Tilly, Charles, ed. (1975). The Formation of National States in Western Europe.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Tilly, Charles (1985). “War Making and State Making as Organized Crime.” In Bringing
the State Back In, edited by Dietrich Rueschemeyer, Peter B. Evans, and Theda Skocpol,
169–91. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Tompkins, Andrew S. (2016). Better Active than Radioactive!: Anti-nuclear Protest in
1970s France and West Germany. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
References 231
Tooze, Adam (2018). “The Forgotten History of the Financial Crisis: What the World
Should Have Learned in 2008.” Foreign Affairs 97, no. 5: 199–210.
Tooze, Adam (2020). “Whose Century?” London Review of Books 42, no. 15. https://www.
lrb.co.uk/the-paper/v42/n15/adam-tooze/whose-century.
Tooze, Adam (2021). Shutdown: How Covid Shook the World’s Economy.
New York: Allen Lane.
Trubowitz, Peter (1998). Defining the National Interest: Conflict and Change in American
Foreign Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Trubowitz, Peter (2011). Politics and Strategy: Partisan Ambition and American Statecraft.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Trubowitz, Peter, and Brian Burgoon (2020). “The Retreat of the West.” Perspectives on
Politics 20, no. 1: 102–122.
Trubowitz, Peter, and Peter Harris (2019). “The End of the American Century? Slow
Erosion of the Domestic Sources of Usable Power.” International Affairs 95, no.
3: 619–639.
Trubowitz, Peter, and Jungkun Seo (2012). “The China Card: Playing Politics with Sino-
American Relations.” Political Science Quarterly 127, no. 2: 189–211.
Ulrich, Beck (2006). Cosmopolitan Vision. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Urata, Shujiro (2009). “Japan’s Free Trade Agreement Strategy.” Japanese Economy 36, no.
2: 46–77.
Van Der Brug, W., M. Fennema, and J.N. Tillie (2005). “Why Some Anti–Immigrant
Parties Fail and Others Succeed: A Two-Step Model of Aggregate Electoral Support.”
Comparative Political Studies 38, no. 5: 537–573.
Vine, David (2021). “Lists of U.S. Military Bases Abroad, 1776– 2021,” American
University Digital Research Archive.
Voce, Antonio and Seán Clarke (2021). “German election 2021: full results and analysis.”
The Guardian, September 6. https://www.theguardian.com/world/ng-interactive/
2021/sep/26/german-election-results-exit-poll-and-possible-coalitions.
Voeten, Erik (2013). “Data and Analyses of Voting in the UN General Assembly.” In
Routledge Handbook of International Organization, edited by Bob Reinalda, 54–66.
London: Routledge.
Voeten, Erik, Anton Strezhnev, and Michael Bailey (2009). “United Nations General
Assembly Voting Data.” https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/LEJUQZ, Harvard Dataverse,
V28, UNF:6:dki7hpeRB0FwTFJ00X/TCQ== [fileUNF].
Waal, Jeroen van der, and Willem de Koster (2018). “Populism and Support for
Protectionism: The Relevance of Opposition to Trade Openness for Leftist and Rightist
Populist Voting in the Netherlands.” Political Studies 66, no. 3: 560–576.
Wagner, Wolfgang (2020). The Democratic Politics of Military Interventions: Political Parties,
Contestation, and Decisions to Use Force Abroad. New York: Oxford University Press.
Wallerstein, Immanuel (1993). “The World-System after the Cold War.” Journal of Peace
Research 30, no. 1: 1–6.
Walt, Stephen M. (1987). The Origins of Alliance. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Walt, Stephen M. (2018). The Hell of Good Intentions. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
Walt, Stephen M. (2019). “The End of Hubris.” Foreign Affairs 98, no. 3: 26–35.
Walter, Stefanie (2010). “Globalization and the Welfare State: Testing the Microfoundations
of the Compensation Hypothesis.” International Studies Quarterly 54, no. 2: 403–426.
Waltz, Kenneth N. (1979). Theory of International Politics. Boston: McGraw-Hill.
232 References
For the benefit of digital users, indexed terms that span two pages (e.g., 52–53) may, on
occasion, appear on only one of those pages.
Tables and figures are indicated by t and f following the page number
73–79, 74f, 75f, 76f, 77f, 78f, 124, Lippmann, Walter, 120, 135–36, 137
142t, 146t, 149t, 157t, 159t Lipset, Seymour, 96
immigration policy and, 64 Lithuania, 40
international democracy promotion Luxembourg
and, 5, 23 liberal internationalism and, 69–70
international security institutions list of political parties in, 166
and, 61–62 partnership orientation in, 33f, 37f,
multilateral governance and, 1–2, 12, 42f, 58f
15–16, 17, 23, 25–26, 46–47, 48, 65– power orientation and military
66, 136 spending in, 33f, 33, 37f, 42f, 58f
neoliberalism’s challenge to, 18–19, 23, welfare state policies in, 58f
91, 123, 135–36
partnership orientation in, 10f, 12, Maastricht Treaty (European Union,
24–25, 32, 33f, 46–47, 50, 58f, 59f, 1993), 38, 65–66, 99, 195n.46
59–60, 61f, 62–64, 63f, 73–74, 75f, mainstream parties. See also Christian
76f, 77f, 78f, 105f, 106f, 122–23, 157t, Democratic parties; Conservative
159t, 173t parties; Liberal parties; Social
post-Cold War overconfidence Democratic parties
regarding fate of, 23, 118–19, 127 declining influence since 1990 of, 97f,
power orientation in, 10f, 12, 13–14, 98, 108, 120–21, 126–27, 128–30
24–25, 32, 33f, 46–47, 50–53, 58f, 59f, definition of, 2–3, 21, 89–90, 166
59–60, 61f, 62–64, 63f, 71, 73–74, 75f, economic crisis of 1970s and, 125
76f, 77f, 78f, 105f, 106f, 122–23, 157t, environmental policies and, 126–27
159t, 173t globalism and, 98–102, 101f, 102f,
trade liberalization and, 1–2, 3–4, 12, 126, 128–29
15–16, 17, 18–20, 23, 25, 30–32, 46– immigration policies and, 126–27
47, 48, 57, 64, 136 liberal internationalism and, 89–98,
welfare state policies and, 3–5, 19–20, 94f, 95f, 100–1, 101f, 122, 124–25,
23–24, 25, 55–62, 58f, 59f, 61f, 63f, 152t, 156t
63–65, 65f, 83, 106f, 107–8, 120–21, partnership orientation and, 90f, 92f,
123, 125–26, 127–28, 136, 142t, 145t, 100–2, 101f, 102f, 175t
146t, 149t, 157t, 159t power orientation and, 90f, 92f, 100–2,
Western democracies’ political party 101f, 102f, 175t
systems and, 2, 6, 16–17, 21–22, 55– welfare state programs and, 125,
56, 60, 61f, 77f, 85–86, 89–98, 90f, 92f, 129, 136
94f, 95f, 104–8, 105f, 106f, 136, 152t, working-class voters and, 98–99, 125,
157t, 159t 126, 130–31
Liberal parties Mair, Peter, 18
decline in power and influence of, 2–3 Malaysia, 44
liberal internationalism and, 15–16, 61f, Manifesto Project Database (MPD), 21–
77f, 85–87 22, 47
lists of, 166 Mao Tse-tung, 30
partnership orientation and, 90f, 92f, Marshall Plan, 29
102f, 145t, 146t, 149t, 157t, 159t Mathews, Jessica, 65–66
power orientation and, 90f, 92f, 102f, McGovern, George, 69
145t, 146t, 149t, 157t, 159t mercantilism, 14
welfare state policies and, 61f Merkel, Angela, 100
libertarianism, 13, 131–32 Mexico, 38, 44, 67–68
240 Index
mainstream parties and, 90f, 92f, 100–2, welfare state policies in, 58f
101f, 102f, 175t power
motivations for, 9 Christian Democratic parties and,
multilateral governance and, 9–10, 90 90f, 92f, 101f, 102f, 145t, 146t, 149t,
radical left parties and, 90f, 91–92, 92f, 157t, 159t
94f, 101f, 102f, 102–3, 126–27, 145t, common enemy and, 8
146t, 149t, 157t, 159t Conservative parties and, 90f, 90, 92f,
radical right parties and, 90f, 91, 92f, 100–1, 101f, 102f, 145t, 146t, 149t,
94f, 101f, 102f, 102, 103–4, 145t, 146t, 157t, 159t
149t, 157t, 159t definition of, 6–9, 7f
Social Democratic parties and, 90f, 92f, domestic political objectives and, 7–8
101f, 102f, 145t, 146t, 149t, 157t, 159t globalism and, 10f, 11, 24–25, 28, 37–
“sovereignty costs” and, 9 38, 41, 45f, 50, 71, 128
trade liberalization and, 9–10, 90 isolationism and, 10f, 12–13
United States and, 33f, 37f, 42f, liberal internationalism and, 10f, 12,
43–44, 44f, 47f, 48, 50, 51f, 58f, 88– 13–14, 24–25, 32, 33f, 46–47, 50–53,
89, 131–32 58f, 59f, 59–60, 61f, 62–64, 63f, 71,
voters’ preferences regarding, 9–10, 21– 73–74, 75f, 76f, 77f, 78f, 105f, 106f,
22, 27–28, 48–50, 49f 122–23, 157t, 159t, 173t
party families Liberal parties and, 90f, 92f, 102f, 145t,
composition of, 166 146t, 149t, 157t, 159t
party fragmentation. See also Western military spending and, 6–8, 20–21, 32,
democracies’ political party systems 33f, 37f, 42f
international effects of 111–18, 113f, motivations for maintaining, 7
114f, 115f, 117f, 162t, 164t–65t nationalism and, 10f, 13–14
measurement of, 111 radical left parties and, 61–62, 90f, 92f,
party systems. See Western democracies' 94f, 101f, 102f, 102–3, 126–27, 145t,
political party systems 146t, 149t, 157t, 159t
permissive consensus, 46–47. See also radical right parties and, 88–89, 90f, 91,
liberal internationalism; solvency gap 92f, 94f, 101f, 102f, 102, 145t, 146t,
Philippines, 30–31, 44, 187n.9 149t, 157t, 159t
Podemos Party (Spain), 17, 103 Social Democratic parties and, 61–62,
Poland, 34–35, 39–40 90f, 90, 92f, 101f, 102f, 145t, 146t,
Polanyi, Karl, 56–57, 60–61, 64 149t, 157t, 159t
political parties. See individual party United States and, 27, 33f, 33, 35,
families and specific countries 37f, 40–41, 42f, 43–46, 44f, 47f, 48,
populism, 2–3, 6, 28, 67, 129–30. See also 50–53, 51f, 58f, 69, 71, 74–75, 87,
nationalism; radical left parties; 88–89, 131–33
radical right parties voters’ preferences regarding, 21–22,
Portugal 27–28, 48–50, 49f
European Community accession Prague Spring (Czechoslovakia,
(1986) of, 36 1968), 34–35
geopolitical threat levels facing, 75f Preller, Ludwig, 8
liberal internationalism and, 75f Putin, Vladimir, 121, 131–32
list of political parties in, 166
partnership orientation in, 33f, 36–37, radical left parties
37f, 42f, 58f anti-globalism and, 17, 19–20, 66–67,
power orientation in, 33f, 37f, 42f, 58f 68, 86, 126–27, 128, 130–31
242 Index
power orientation and, 61–62, 90f, power orientation in, 33f, 37f, 42f, 58f
90, 92f, 101f, 102f, 145t, 146t, 149t, welfare state policies in, 58f
157t, 159t Spengler, Oswald, 5
welfare state policies Srebrenica massacre (Bosnia,
and, 61f, 61–62 1995), 40–41
Social Democratic Party (SPD, Germany Stockholm International Peace Research
and West Germany), 69–70, 87– Institute (SIPRI), 20–21
88, 97–98 Strange, Susan, 55–56
social protection, 1, 3–4, 17–21, 24–25, Sutherland, Peter, 46
55–56, 83–84, 125–27, 129–30, 135– Sweden
36. See also welfare state European Community accession of, 36
declining Western government geopolitical threat levels facing, 75f
spending on, 64–68, 65f liberal internationalism and, 75f, 88–89
liberal internationalism’s reliance on, list of political parties in, 166
55–64, 58f, 59f, 61f, 63f, 106f, 107–8, partnership orientation in, 33f, 37f,
145t, 159t, 173t 42f, 58f
measurement of, 58–59 power orientation in, 33f, 37f, 42f, 58f
Socialist Party (PSI, Italy), 69–70, 87–88 welfare state policies in, 58f, 79
solvency gap Switzerland, 33f, 37f, 42f, 58f, 88–89, 166
definition of, 2–4 Syrian refugee crisis (2015), 84
measurement of, 81 Syriza Party (Greece), 17, 103
Western leaders’ failure to close, 79–83,
82f, 150t Taiwan, 30, 40
South Korea Tea Party (Republican Party faction,
China and, 134 United States), 123
geopolitical threat levels facing, 75f Thailand, 30–31, 44, 187n.9
liberal internationalism in, 30–31, Thatcher, Margaret, 18–19, 35–36, 39,
58f, 75f 80–81, 91
partnership orientation in, 33f, 37f, trade unions, 80–81, 83, 100, 130–31
42f, 58f Transatlantic Trade and Investment
power orientation and military Program (TTIP), 103
spending in, 33f, 37f, 42f, 58f Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), 67–68,
welfare state policies in, 58f 100, 103
Soviet Union. See also Cold War Truman, Harry S., 69
collapse of, 2, 29–30, 56, 64, 74–75, 118, Trump, Donald
128, 129–30 anti-globalism and “America First”
interwar period in, 56–57 foreign policy of, 67–68, 72–73, 132
Japan and, 70, 89 nationalist orientation of, 14
Sino-Soviet split and, 34–35 solvency gap regarding foreign policy
West Germany and, 34–35 and, 1–2, 17, 120, 123–24
Spain welfare state policies and, 67–68
anti-globalism in, 17, 103
European Community accession Ukraine War (2022-), 4, 120, 121, 131–32
(1986) of, 36 United Kingdom. See Great Britain
list of political parties in, 166 United Kingdom Independence Party
partnership orientation in, 33f, 36–37, (UKIP), 67, 103–4
37f, 42f, 58f United Nations, 29
244 Index
United States globalism and, 25, 55–56, 72, 79, 86, 96–
Afghanistan War (2001-21) and, 41, 97, 100, 129, 130–31, 132–33
44–46, 128 immigrant populations and, 4–5
anti-globalism in, 72–73, 85–86, 128 liberal internationalism and, 3–5, 19–
China and, 135 20, 23–24, 25, 55–62, 58f, 59f, 61f, 63f,
election (1980) in, 91 63–65, 65f, 83, 106f, 107–8, 120–21,
geopolitical threat levels facing, 74f, 74– 123, 125–26, 127–28, 136, 142t, 145t,
75, 75f, 78–79 146t, 149t, 157t, 159t
globalism and, 24–25, 28–29, 43–44, neoliberalism’s challenge to, 18–
80–81, 98, 99–100, 132–33 19, 135–36
Iraq War (2003-12) and, 41, 44–46, 128 Western democracies
Japan and, 70, 73, 88–89 definition of, 1, 4–5
liberal internationalism and, 4, 12, 15, Western democracies’ political party
16–17, 23, 29–32, 48, 58f, 69, 87, systems
88–89, 123 Cold War and, 3, 16, 24, 25–26, 85–
partnership orientation in, 33f, 37f, 42f, 92, 122
43–44, 44f, 47f, 48, 50, 51f, 58f, 88– geopolitical threat levels and, 77f, 78–79
89, 131–32 global governance delegation and, 113–
political polarization since 2000 in, 98 14, 114f, 115f, 164t
power orientation and military international openness and, 111–12,
spending in, 27, 33f, 33, 35, 37f, 40– 112f, 113f, 162t
41, 42f, 43–46, 44f, 47f, 48, 50–53, 51f, liberal internationalism and, 2, 6, 16–
58f, 69, 71, 74–75, 87, 88–89, 131–33 17, 21–22, 55–56, 60, 61f, 77f, 85–86,
September 11 terrorist attacks (2001) in, 89–98, 90f, 92f, 94f, 95f, 104–8, 105f,
41, 50–53, 74–75 106f, 136, 152t, 157t, 159t
trade liberalization in, 35–36, 38, mainstream parties’ declining influence
64, 99–100 since 1990 and, 97f, 98, 108, 120–21,
welfare state policies in, 19, 58f, 64, 67– 126–27, 128–30
68, 132–33 Manifesto Project Database and, 21–22
military doctrine debates and, 8–9
Vandenberg, Arthur, 69 military spending debates and, 8–9,
Vietnam War, 4–5, 70 50, 70–71
voter support. See also partnership; power; political fragmentation within Western
solvency gap democracies and, 111–18, 113f, 119,
measurement of, 21–22 120–21, 126, 128–31, 162t, 177t, 179f
postwar coalition-building and, 15–
Washington Consensus economic 16, 18, 85
policies, 39 trade liberalization debates and, 9–10
welfare state. See also social protection welfare state policies and, 60–61
Bismarck and, 8 West Germany
Cold War and, 8, 56, 62, 129–30, 133–34 election (1972) in, 91
decline in Western democracies’ election (1983) in, 91
commitment to, 1, 3–4, 5, 19–20, 25, geopolitical threat levels facing, 78–79
56, 64–65, 65f, 67, 72, 83, 86, 96–97, liberal internationalism and, 69–70, 123
120–21, 123, 126, 128, 129–31, 132– Ostpolitik policies of rapprochement
33, 136 with Soviet Union and, 34–35, 70–71
Index 245
partnership orientation in, 33f, 37f, establishment (1995) of, 35–36, 71–
42f, 58f 72, 99–100
power orientation and military global economic integration and, 19
spending in, 30–31, 33f, 33, 37f, Global Financial Crisis (2008-9)
42f, 58f and, 43
welfare state policies in, 58f protests (1999) against, 46
Wilson, Woodrow, 11, 37–38, 66 supranational sovereignty and, 19
World Bank, 35–36, 39, 43 unelected bureaucrats’ power in, 23–24
World Trade Organization (WTO)
China’s accession to, 39–40 Yoshida, Shigeru, 73, 88