Alonso 2011

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 64

Depar tment of Economic & Social Af fairs

CDP Background Paper No. 11 (E)


ST/ESA/20011/CDP/11 (E)

December 2011

International Migration and


Development:
A review in light of the crisis
José Antonio Alonso*

ABSTRACT

Increasing international migratory flows in the last four decades is one of the most visible
manifestations of the globalization process In spite of its potential positive effect on global ef-
ficiency and well-being, little progress has been made in designing and promoting a normative
and institutional framework to allow a better global governance of international migration.
The current crisis has added new concerns in relation to migrant situation particularly in the
countries more affected by the recession. It is likely that migratory pressures continue beyond
the crisis, as international asymmetries that promote international migration have not been
overcome.

JEL Classification: F22, F24, J61, J83, K31, O15

Keywords: international migration, labour markets, mobility of labour, development,


migrants’ remittances, human capital, brain drain, immigration policy.

* José Antonio Alonso is Director of the Complutense Institute for International Studies and Professor of Applied Economics
at the Universidad Complutense of Madrid. He is a member of the Committee for Development Policy at the United Nations
Economic and Social Council, and his main research areas focus on growth and the external sector, trade specialization devel-
opment policies and international aid. He is the editor of Principios: Estudios de Economía Política. His most recent books are
Acción Colectiva y Desarrollo: El Papel de las Instituciones, coauthored with Carlos Garcimartín, and Corrupción, Cohesión
Social y Desarrollo, coedited with Carlos Mulas-Granados.
Comments may be addressed to the author by e-mail: [email protected]
TABLE OF CONTENTS

1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
2. International empirical evidence. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
2.1. Size of migration. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
2.2. Differential traits. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
3. Factors driving migration. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
3.1. Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
3.2. Income differential. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
3.3. A wider view . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
3.4. Other social factors. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
3.5. Empirical evidence.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
4. Effects of migration. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
4.1. Aggregated effects. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
4.2. Remittances. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
4.3. Emigration of qualified labour and loss of human capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32
5. Migratory policies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
5.1. National policies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
5.2. International framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
6. The effects of the crisis: A note. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
6.1. The effects of the crisis.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
6.2. The effects on migration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
6.3. Political responses. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
7. Final considerations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
Bibliography. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
Annex: Models for determining migratory flows. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60

The CDP Background Paper Series is a collection


of peer-reviewed research papers focusing on the is-
sues dealt with by the Committee for Development
Policy. The objective is to stimulate discussion on
the broad range of economic, social and environ-
mental issues. The views and opinions expressed
UNITED NATIONS
herein are those of the author and do not necessari-
Department of Economic and Social Affairs
ly reflect those of the CDP nor the United Nations
UN Secretariat, 405 East 42nd Street
Secretariat. The designations and terminology em-
New York, N.Y. 10017, USA
ployed may not conform to United Nations prac-
e-mail: [email protected]
tice and do not imply the expression of any opinion
https://www.un.org/development/desa/dpad/document_cdp/
whatsoever on the part of the Organization.
cdp-background-paper-series/
1

International migration and development:


A review in light of the crisis

José Antonio Alonso

1. Introduction

One of the most conspicuous signs of the process of globalisation is the increase in migratory flows among
countries, regions and continents. In an increasingly integrated world, people—although with significant
restrictions—move across national borders, seeking opportunities on foreign soils that are denied them in
their own countries. According to the United Nations, there were about 214 million international migrants
in 2010. In relative terms, this corresponds to over 3 per cent of the world population. The percentage does
not seem exceptionally high, especially when compared to the proportion of other cross-border transactions,
such as trade and investment. However, the social and political relevance of migration goes beyond num-
bers: migration involves people, not just production factors but the plans, dreams, frustrations, hopes, and
interests of human beings. Migrants are active forces driving new realities and corresponding social responses
both at home and in host countries.

In fact, migration has become a major force shaping international reality. Migration is a powerful
force of social change and cultural interaction in implicated countries. It provides migrants themselves with
significant opportunities to progress. It is also a factor that has diverse developmental effects on both the
home and host countries. The international community has recognised these facts in its deliberations on
migration and has accepted the need to establish a more coherent political response to the phenomenon.
The Global Commission on International Migration,1 the UN High Level Dialogue on International Migration
and Development 2 and the Global Forum on Migration and Development.3 are cases in point. Alongside these
global initiatives, there are regional initiatives such as the Alto Diálogo Iberoamericano sobre Migraciones,
la Conferencia Regional sobre Migración (the Puebla Process), the Migration Dialogue for West Africa,
the Migration Dialogue for Southern Africa, the Ministerial Consultation on Overseas Employment and
Contractual Labour for Countries of Origin and Destination in Asia (the Colombo Process), or the Bali
Process on People Smuggling, Trafficking in Persons and Related Transnational Crime (the Bali Process),
among others.

International organisations have also tackled the question of international migration and sought to
define their positions on it. In this regard, the United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs
(UN/DESA) focused the second part of its 2004 World Economic and Social Survey to study migration
(International Migration); the World Bank devoted its 2006 Global Economic Prospects to analysis of the
economic consequences of migration (Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration); the International
Labour Organization (ILO) issued a report on the effect of migration on labour markets (International
Labour Migration and Development: The ILO Perspective); and the United Nations Development Programme
1 http://www.gcim.org/en/.
2 http://www.un.org/esa/population/migration/hld/index.html.
3 http://gfmd-fmmd.org/.
2 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

(UNDP) devoted its 2009 Human Development Report to this crucial subject (Overcoming Barriers: Human
Mobility and Development). Additionally, the International Migration Organization (IMO) is issuing increas-
ingly comprehensive annual reports on international migrations and their impacts (the latest, released in
2010, entitled The Future of Migration: Building Capacities for Change)4.

Among the bilateral donors, the United Kingdom and the Netherlands stand out for the policy posi-
tions they have adopted on development aid, aiming to improve the impact of migration on development.5
In the same way, the European Commission dedicated several documents to defining its position on this
subject, one of the most revealing of which was the Council Communication of November 2006 (The Global
Approach to Migration One Year On: Towards a Comprehensive European Migration Policy).6

Despite all these initiatives, migration remains subject to restrictive legislative frameworks, which
have been reinforced due to the current economic crisis. This restrictive tone contrasts with the increasing
liberalisation of other economic flows. Private capital has become more mobile and moves across national
borders (Caselli and Feyrer, 2007; Giannone and Lenza, 2009). Barriers to trade have been reduced, al-
though obstacles remain (Bergin and Glock, 2007), and the degree of internationalisation of certain services
has grown. Nevertheless, labour mobility between countries remains constrained by severely restrictive rules
and policies. This contrast illustrates the unbalanced nature of the globalisation process currently under way.

The restrictive tone with which immigration is regulated is contrary to the need for migrant labour
in developed countries, given the countries’ stagnant demographics and ageing populations. Some developed
countries need immigrants to support growth as well as to sustain public social security schemes. However,
the gap between the needs of foreign labour and the norms regulating that demand has led to large numbers
of immigrants living irregularly in their host countries. This has costs not only for the immigrants them-
selves, but also for the functioning of the society in which they live. Undocumented immigrants are denied
the protection of the law and are thus prone to abuse, extortion, exploitation and violence. In irregular
migrant environments mafias, police corruption and crime flourish and immigrants are among the victims.

The recent economic crisis has exacerbated the vulnerable situation of immigrants. The effect has
been multiple. Firstly, in some OECD countries, the crisis has often implied a higher level of unemployment
among immigrants than among natives, not only due to the precariousness of migrant work, but also because
jobs held by immigrants were concentrated in construction and other services which were more severely hit
by the crisis than other sectors. Secondly, due to the nature and duration of their contracts, immigrants tend
to have a lower level of social protection when they become unemployed. Thirdly, strains on labour condi-
tions in host countries have slowed migratory flows and have led many governments to announce significant
reductions in their authorised immigration quotas: as a consequence, it is likely that undocumented migra-
tion will increase. Fourthly, the crisis has also affected remittances, which declined in real terms in 2009,
although forecasts point to a rapid recovery of flows in the years to come. Lastly, and most importantly,
the crisis has led to hostility against migration in certain social and political groups in host countries- mi-
grants are seen as rivals to natives in the search for jobs, or as an additional burden to public services. That
4 The range of international institutions that have studied international migration is obviously wider, including several
regional institutions (such as, for example, the Economic Commission for Latin American Countries (ECLAC), with
its 2006 study, International Migration, Human Rights and Development) or others with mandates on specific kind of
migrations (such as, for example, UNHCR in relation to refugees).
5 In the United Kingdom, for instance, the DFID produced the 2007 policy paper Moving out of Poverty, and in the
Netherlands the MFA produced the 2008 document International Migration and Development.
6 http://ec.europe.eu/development/icenter/repository/comm_pc.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 3

perception has been translated not only into a more restrictive tone in migration policy, but also into greater
discrimination and xenophobic attitudes, even in countries with consolidated democracies.

The above not withstanding, it is worth reiterating that migration, when suitably regulated, can po-
tentially improve the efficiency and well-being of the overall international economic system, as both theoreti-
cal and empirical studies have confirmed. History shows, moreover, that migration can, in certain circum-
stances, be an important force in correcting international inequalities, actually reducing international salary
differences between host and home countries (O´Rourke and Williamson, 1999; Hatton and Williamson,
2005). Aside from this global effect, migration is also an effective, although notably selective, means of
increasing the possibilities of individuals to better themselves; improving individual income, health, educa-
tion and living conditions. It is, therefore, an important development factor, especially if we consider that
people (not only countries) matter (Clemens, 2010). If people could choose their places of residence with
fewer restrictions, human freedom would be strengthened (Nussbaum, 2000).

Of course, migration can entail costs, both for the countries of origin (breaking of family structures,
destruction of emotional ties, loss of dynamic sectors of the population, waste of social capital, etc.), as well
as for the recipient countries (funding of policies for social integration of migrants, the effects deriving from
greater ethnic and cultural heterogeneity, etc). Furthermore, in certain conditions, when emigration becomes
a wide-spread and intensive phenomenon, it can feed a vicious circle which promotes a regressive dynamic
of depopulation and the abandonment of productive activities in migrants’ communities of origin. In these
cases, young people plan their future in relation to the opportunities of migration, rather than seeking work
and professional promotion in their own communities. All these costs need to be considered and, to the
extent possible, minimised, through adequate policies both in countries of origin and in host countries.

In the following sections, the present study will analyse current migratory flows by taking into
account their effects on development. The next section reviews trends in international migrations, while the
third section discusses factors driving migration and reviews the theory of migration. Section 4 examines the
effects of migration, focusing chiefly on its impact on the development of both home and host countries.
This examination is followed by analysis on regulatory responses to the phenomenon in section 5. Section 6
analyses the impact of the current economic crisis on the flow and nature of international migration, and
section 7 concludes.

2. International empirical evidence


2.1. Size of migration
This section begins by highlighting the limited reliability of data on the number of current migrants in the
world. The fact that there is no single concept of what should be understood as a migrant,7 the irregular
conditions in which many migrants live, and the shortcomings of the demographic statistics from some low-
income countries all contribute to the problems with the quality of this information. Nevertheless, in the last
few years the availability of such data has improved. Firstly, the United Nations has made an effort to present
a relatively homogeneous statistic on the total number of the world’s emigrants with data series spanning
over the last five decades. Secondly, for some years bilateral flows of emigrants have been compiled, based on

7 The two dominant concepts discussed are, firstly, that which defines a migrant as anyone born in a country different
from that in which he or she lives, and secondly that which reserves the term for those of a different nationality from
the country in which they live. In the second definition, the process of acquired citizenship leads to a difference in the
migrant population.
4 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

harmonised data from national sources, mainly drawn from Population Censuses carried out in 2000 (Parson
et al., 2007). Finally, Docquier and Marfouk (2004, 2006) have put together exacting data on education
levels of migratory flows to OECD countries, allowing more rigorous studies.8

The United Nations’ data over the last five decades shows that the trend in international migration
has been upward in keeping with the process of globalisation. For these purposes, a migrant is considered
anyone who was born in a country different from the one in which he or she currently lives. This upward
trend shows a (somewhat artificial) jump around the 1980s, as a result of the sudden migrant status ac-
quired by former USSR citizens as a consequence of living in regions different from their birthplaces (later
converted into independent countries).9 Apart from that phenomenon, even excluding the USSR and
Czechoslovakia, the upward tendency has been maintained, with a slight acceleration in the last three five-
year periods (figure 1).

As a consequence of this upward trend, in 2010 there were about 214 million migrants in the
world, about 3.1 per cent of the world’s population. This figure is most likely an underestimate of the true
magnitude of the phenomenon because undocumented immigrants are not adequately included in the data.
Tentative estimates put the ratio of undocumented migrants in a wide range of between 5 and 30 per cent of
registered migration, depending on national cases.10 In any case, if the total rate of migrants is compared to
the relative share of trade and capital movements as a proportion of economic activity there is no doubt that,
apart from its social significance, the phenomenon of emigration is relatively small in size.

Figure 1: Evolution of total emigrants


Millions of people
250

World
200

t kia
hou ova
l d wit chosl
r e
150 Wo SS Cz
UR

100

Less developed
50

Source: United
More developed Nations (UN/DESA),
Least developed
International Migrant
0 Stock. The 2008
Revision (http://esa.
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 un.org/migration).

8 In any case, still there are problems in identifying the exact number of migrants, so the official register is not always
able to estimate the number of irregular migrants.
9 A similar, though smaller, phenomenon was produced as a result of the breakups of Czechoslovakia and the former
Yugoslavia.
10 Even in the United States, it is estimated that the official calculation fails to account for at least 1 to 1.5 million people.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 5

In dynamic terms, in the 30 years between 1980 and 2010, the total number of migrants increased
by an average annual rate of 2.6 per cent. In terms of the location of emigrants, from the mid-1980s, a
noticeable change is that high-income countries have become the major destination of immigration. While
the growth rate of migrants in high-income countries is 3.3 per cent for the period, low-income countries
reached a rate of 1.7 per cent. By 2010, 60 per cent of migrants lived in a high-income country (table 1).

According to these data, the most developed regions of the world (Europe and North America)
have the highest number of migrants. Asia comes next, with a relatively similar percentage. These figures are,
however, highly dependent on the demographic size of the respective regions. This is why it is useful to look
at the relative size of immigrant communities to their host populations (table 2). From this point of view,
North America and Oceania, the two most recently populated regions, are those with the highest coefficients
(14 per cent and 16 per cent respectively). Next is Europe, a region where migrants make up 9 per cent
of the residential population. In the other regions, the immigrant population is less than 2 per cent. This
evidence confirms the greater relative importance of the migrant population in more developed countries
(10 per cent of the population) than in less developed countries (1 per cent).

Table 1: Total numbers of migrants


Millions of people
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
By region
Africa 9.1 9.4 9.9 11.0 14.0 14.4 16.3 17.9 6.5 17.0 19.2
Asia 28.5 28.2 27.8 28.0 32.1 37.2 49.9 47.2 50.3 53.3 61.3
Europe 14.2 16.6 18.8 20.1 21.9 23.4 49.3 55.2 58.2 64.1 69.8
Latin America 6.0 5.8 5.6 5.7 6.0 6.2 6.9 6.0 6.3 6.6 7.5
North America 12.5 12.7 12.9 15.3 18.1 22.1 27.6 33.5 40.3 44.5 50.0
Oceania 2.1 2.5 3.0 3.3 3.7 4.2 4.7 5.0 5.0 5.0 6.0
World 75.4 78.4 81.3 86.7 99.2 111.0 154.9 165.0 176.7 190.6 213.9
By developmental level
More developed 32.3 35.4 38.3 42.4 47.4 53.6 82.3 94.9 105.0 115.4 127.7
Less developed 43.1 43.0 42.9 44.3 51.8 57.3 72.5 70.1 71.7 75.2 86.2
Least developed 6.4 6.9 7.2 6.8 9.1 9.1 10.9 12.2 10.2 10.4 11.5
Source: United Nations (UN/DESA), International Migrant Stock. The 2008 Revision (http://esa.un.org/migration).

Table 2: Regional distribution of emigrants


As a percentage of the local population
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
By region
Africa 3.2 3.0 2.7 2.7 2.9 2.6 2.6 2.5 2.0 1.9 1.9
Asia 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.2 1.3 1.3 1.6 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.5
Europe 3.4 3.8 4.1 4.3 4.5 4.8 6.9 7.6 8.0 8.8 9.5
Latin America 2.8 2.3 2.0 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.6 1.3 1.2 1.2 1.3
North America 6.1 5.8 5.6 6.3 7.1 6.2 9.7 11.2 12.8 13.5 14.2
Oceania 13.4 14.3 15.4 15.8 16.4 17.0 17.8 17.5 16.3 15.2 16.8
World 2.5 2.4 2.2 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.9 2.9 2.9 3.0 3.1
By developmental level
More developed 3.4 3.5 3.6 3.9 4.2 4.6 7.2 8.1 8.8 9.5 10.3
Less developed 2.1 1.8 1.6 1.5 1.6 1.6 1.8 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.5
Least developed 2.6 2.5 2.3 1.9 2.3 2.0 2.1 2.0 1.5 1.4 1.3
Source: United Nations (UN/DESA), International Migrant Stock. The 2008 Revision (http://esa.un.org/migration).
6 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

The above data could suggest that problems related to receiving international immigrants almost
exclusively belong to developed countries. However, the phenomenon is more complex than that image
suggests, as becomes clear when the countries with the largest amount of immigrants are identified (figure 2).
Some developed countries stand out here, such as the United States, Germany, Canada, France and the
United Kingdom—countries that have traditionally received migrants. Spain is in eighth place, having pro-
gressed in the last few years. Nevertheless, developing countries like India, Pakistan and the Ivory Coast also
occupy leading positions. That suggests that the distinction between host, destination and transit countries
in terms of emigration is increasingly blurred. A good number of countries, particularly Mexico and India,
fall into all three categories.

Figure 3 also shows that the migratory phenomenon is global in nature. According to the Migration
Development Research Centre, in 2000, 79.7 per cent of migratory flows came from developing countries;
45.3 per cent went to developing countries and the remaining 34.4 per cent was bound for developed
countries. In turn, 16 per cent of the total emigration from developed countries went to other developed
countries, while 4.2 per cent went to developing countries. It is clear that migrant flows are not characterized
by only one-way traffic.

2.2. Differential traits


The phenomenon of massive migration is not new in history. Similar international population movements
took place in previous eras, across countries and continents. In particular, historians have documented large-
scale migratory movements between 1840 and the start of the First World War. They estimate that almost
50 million Europeans moved during that period either to America, crossing the Atlantic, or to Australia and
New Zealand. During the same period, 50 million Asians left China and India to seek their fortunes on the
southern coasts of Asia, Africa and Latin America. This was the first era of mass migration, as Hatton and
Williamson (1998) have termed it.

Figure 2: Main recipients of emigration


Thousands of people
45 000

40 000

35 000

30 000

25 000

20 000

15 000

10 000

5 000

0 Source: United
Nations (UN/DESA),
United States
of America
Russian
Federation
Germany

Saudi Arabia

Canada

France
United
Kingdom
Spain
India

Ukraine

Australia

Italy

Pakistan
United Arab
Emirates
Kazakhstan

Jordan

Israel
Hong Kong

Côte d’Ivoire

Malaysia

International Migrant
Stock. The 2008
Revision (http://esa.
un.org/migration)
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 7

Figure 3: Flows of origin and destination in 2000


Percentage

Source: Based on data from


Development Research
Centre on Migration,
16% Globalisation and Poverty
North-North and Parsons et al. (2007),
th “Quantifying International
4% Sou
- Migration: a Database
rth
No of International Migrant
Stock”, in C. Ozden and
M.Schiff (Eds), International
Migration: Economic
Development and Policy,
46% World Bank, Palgrave
South-South Macmillan.
34% Note: North includes the
South-North United States, Canada,
EU-15+EFTA, Australia,
New Zealand, Japan and
high-income countries of
Middle East; and South
Latin America, Eastern
Europe and Central Asia,
the Middle East and North
of Africa, East Asia and
Pacific, Southern Asia and
Sub-Saharan Africa.

The intensity of migration in that period was even higher than levels registered today. Taking the
United States for comparative purposes, between the end of the 19th century and the start of the 20th, new
arrivals to the country for each decade amounted to about 10 per cent of the resident population-today that
rate is around 3 per cent. In fact, between 1880 and 1920, an average of 6 million immigrants arrived in the
United States per decade, a figure that has only been exceeded during the last three decades. The liberal tone
of immigration policies in receiving countries, coupled with a desire to stimulate the population of certain
regions, facilitated the migration process, while in source countries emigration was driven by food crises and
the degradation of traditional rural structures. All this took place in the context of a notable lessening of
transportation costs due to the increasing use of steam engines on ships and the expansion of railways.

The flow of transatlantic migration fuelled the growth of host countries by providing them with
necessary human resources, while it also accelerated the transformation of Europe’s agrarian structures and
relieved pressure on its labour markets. Some segments of these migration flows filled jobs in manufacturing
and temperate agriculture in countries of limited demographic density (such as the United States, Canada,
Argentina, and Brazil). The production of these countries competed with European production and with
countries with relative high level of development. As a result, migration reduced international inequalities in
wages-historians estimate that the transatlantic migration accounted for just over 60 per cent of the process of
convergence in real wages between Europe and the United States (Lindert and Williamson, 2001; O’Rourke
and Williamson, 1999). However, this was not the case for a large part of Asian migration, which was driven
to fill jobs in agriculture and services in tropical countries such as those in the Caribbean. In this case, pro-
duction largely competed with that of other low-income countries in Asia and Africa, which had high labour
intensity and low standards of living, therefore fuelling inequalities between recipient countries and the rest
of the world (Lewis, 1969 and 1983). So, the effect of migration on international inequality depended, in
great part, of the conditions of the host country’s productive specialization in international markets.
8 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Although the countries of origin and destination have changed, every fact available seems to point
out that we are currently in a second era of mass migration. This is suggested by the intensification of migrato-
ry pressures. It is no coincidence that both periods appear to be characterised by an increase in international
openness and integration; the root of what we call globalisation. The phenomenon is, therefore, not new
and humanity experienced similar processes in previous eras. However, when compared with other historic
episodes, the present migratory flows have four distinctive traits worth highlighting:
• Firstly, the factors encouraging emigration.
In the past, the fundamental factor that stimulated transatlantic migration was not so much
the average income differential between countries but rather the opportunities for social and
economic betterment that the new world offered. In 1850, the per capita income of the United
States was only 33 per cent higher than in Italy, and Argentina’s in 1870 only 9 per cent higher
than Spain’s. Migration took place between countries with relatively similar developmental levels
and came about because it allowed poor Europeans to move from hierarchical, highly unequal
societies to countries with much greater social mobility. Inequality within countries was a more
significant factor than international inequality.
Today, however, the per-capita income differential between countries is a much more important
factor in explaining migration. The United States’ per capita income is quadruple Mexico’s,
Spain’s is five times that of Ecuador, France’s six times that of Morocco, and the United
Kingdom’s is 10 times that of Pakistan. Migration now means movement to a country whose
average level of life is much higher. Therefore, international inequality is a much more impor-
tant factor fuelling migration in this era.
• Secondly, the feminisation of emigration.
At the end of the 19th century, migratory flows were primarily composed of men (between 2/3
and 3/4). The presence of women, especially in the form of independent migration (as opposed
to being part of the family nucleus) was a relatively minor phenomenon. At the moment,
however, women make up half the total amount of emigrants; in some cases as a consequence of
family-reunion policies, but also as a result of total independent migratory strategies (figure 4).
Even so, the rate of women in migratory flows varies considerably depending on the destination
region. The proportion of women is highest in emigration to Europe, and lowest in emigration
to Asia. Although some of the factors that influence the presence of women in different migra-
tory flows are known, a full explanation of the observed differences is far from established.
Although the higher share of women in total migrants could be the result of advances in wom-
en’s empowerment, it is worthwhile pointing out that in many cases female migration seems
to be associated with activities related to traditional domestic tasks in the destination country
(domestic service, child care, care of the elderly)—a reality that reinforces traditional gender
roles, although on a transnational scale. In fact, in some cases female migration has allowed a
fresh division of domestic tasks in host countries, allowing women in host societies greater inde-
pendence. In other words, gender inequality in host societies has been corrected at the expense
of gender inequalities internationally. The increase in elderly populations in developed countries
is also contributing to the feminisation of migrant flows, as new jobs for female migrants are
created in relation to the “economy of family care”. This labour specialization has costs for the
migrant woman in terms of salary, personal promotion and employment security. In any case,
a fuller and more independent incorporation of women into migratory flows should be seen
positively, to the extent that it contributes to reduce gender inequalities in countries of origin.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 9

• Thirdly, the presence of undocumented migrants.


In the previous era of mass migration in the second half of the 19th century, the phenomenon of
undocumented migration did not exist: after a medical examination and registration, migrants
acquired the status of residents of the host country. However, since the start of the 1920s, when
U.S. legislation became more restrictive on immigration, a large number of migrants have lived
outside the law in their host country. The best estimates suggest that close to 30 per cent of
total emigrants are living informally in the United States (Passel and Cohn, 2008); while in the
European Union that share ranges between 5 per cent and 15 per cent, depending on the coun-
try (Vogel and Kovacheva, 2009). The presence of undocumented immigrants is the result of an
imbalance between the restrictive regulatory framework and the strength of migratory pressure,
sometimes fuelled by the labour needs of recipient countries.
The contrast between migratory demand and regulatory response means that for a large number
of people migration takes place without legal protection. Emigrants in this situation are stripped
of rights and made vulnerable to abuses, both during transit and following settlement in their
destination country. Undocumented migration has also contributed to the abuse of emigrants by
mafias and criminal networks. The most extreme example of this abuse is human trafficking, in
which displacement may be associated with sexual exploitation, organised crime, violent abuse,
and clear economic exploitation. Despite the seriousness of this phenomenon, its full dimension
is not known. A recent report by the U.S. Department of State11 estimates that 12.3 million
people were affected by such crime, meaning that 1.8 of every 1000 of the global population
suffered this type of abuse.

Figure 4: Percentage of women in the stock of migrants, 2010


Percentage of total
54

52

50

48

46

44

42

40
Source: United
Africa

Europe

Latin America

North America

Oceania

World

High volume

Low income

Least income
Asia

Nations (UN/DESA),
International Migrant
Stock. The 2008
Revision (http://esa.
un.org/migration)

11 US Department of State: Trafficking in Persons Report 2010, http://state.gov/g/tip/rls/tiprpt/2010/.


10 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

• Finally, a source of transnational social capital.


Advances in communications technology have meant that contact between communities
of origin and those in destination countries occurs almost on a daily basis with lower costs,
creating a range of transactions and communications. Remittances are just one part of those
transactions; other flows related to communications, tourism, transport and trade in nostalgic
products have likewise been developed. There is an entire network of communications, initia-
tives and undertakings linked to relationships between communities of origin and the diasporas
in destination countries. Feelings of national identity are strengthened in the diasporas, creating
positive phenomena of solidarity and mutual support (social remittances, for example), as well
as negative expressions of crime (such as gangs and “maras”).

3. Factors driving migration


3.1. Introduction
Almost four centuries ago, Marc Lescarbot (1907-14, I, 295) wrote: “Three things drive men to seek lands
far away and to abandon their homes. The first, the desire to find something better. The second, when a
province is full to bursting of people (…). The third, divisions, disputes and quarrels”. More recently, the
Global Commission on International Migration (2005) reached a similar conclusion, referring to three
‘Ds’ driving emigration: development, demographics and democracy.12 Relative privation generates a lack of
development; pressure on resources and employment is caused by excessive population growth; and exclusion,
persecution and violence, is caused by a lack of democratic rights. These have been the most important factors
for migration in history.

Of course, times have changed since Lescarbot wrote his History of the New France, but the problems
he highlighted remain today. It is true that during the last few decades democracy has spread across the
globe and there is a more generalised, shared recognition of human rights. The data show that elections to
choose a government are held in about 140 of the 192 countries that make up the United Nations. However,
the United Nations recognises that in 100 of those countries, there are important restrictions on civil and
political liberties; in 70, levels of corruption are demonstrably high; and in about 30 there are active armed
conflicts. As a result, more than 14 million people are refugees today; and an untold quantity of people have
emigrated from their countries to flee violence—not just political, but also religious and gender violence.

Progress has doubtless been made in democratic terms, but the differences that exist between coun-
tries in their levels of development and respective demographic dynamics have taken on huge proportions in
the current era. In particular, the gap between the richest region on the planet and the poorest was less than 3
to 1 at the beginning of the 18th century when Lescarbot wrote his book, but today that ratio is 19 to 1 (the
richest region has 19 times the per capita income of the poorest). These differences are multiplied if we look
at countries rather than regional averages: the per capita income of the United States is about 267 times that
of Zimbabwe, both expressed in PPP; the per capita income of Norway is 184 times that of the Liberia; and
that of the Netherlands is 140 times that of the Democratic Republic of the Congo, with both expressed as
purchasing power parity (PPP).

Differences in terms of demographics have also increased significantly. For instance, the population
growth rate of sub-Saharan Africa is five times that of the EU (2.7 per cent compared with 0.5 per cent).
With an ageing population, developed countries face the problem of providing sufficient human resources
12 See Global Commission on International Migration (2005): Migration in an interconnected world: New directions for
action, en www.gcim.org.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 11

in order to fuel economic growth and extend the sustainability of their respective welfare states. In the case
of developing countries, the problem is how to educate their populations and integrate a large number of
young workers into the labour market. The lack of balance between these demographic dynamics is another
powerful factor behind international migration.

In this context we should not be surprised when people try to overcome international inequalities
through personal initiatives: emigrating from places with few opportunities to destinations offering more.
If a society does not change, we change the society: individual exit emerges as an alternative when there is no
confidence in the collective voice as a means of social progress. Emigration therefore becomes a response to
striking economic and social differences in an increasingly integrated and unequal world.

That said, for people to decide to migrate, it is not enough that inequalities exist. It is necessary
that the emigrant have scenarios of both departure and reception in the new country in his mind, as well
as a vision of what opportunities might be in his future. People do not desire that which they do not know
about, nor do they demand things clearly beyond reach. Reductions in the cost of transport, development of
new communication technologies have contributed to greater integration of the international community.
Geographic barriers are pushed, distances are broken down, and alternative ways of life are shared and
presented as desirable.

Globalisation and international inequality are revealed, therefore, as the two underlying vectors
feeding migration. It can be understood that the greater the international inequality (the greater the gradi-
ent of income and living standards between countries) and the lower the costs associated with displacement
(the lower the obstacles to mobility), the greater the expected volume of emigration will be. This argument
explains the increase in migratory pressure in an era of accentuated and imbalanced globalisation. In this
context, the question is not why migratory flows are so intense but, given the huge inequalities that exist,
why there is so little migration.

To sum up, we live in a world of growing migratory pressures. This burden is neither entirely new
nor likely to be episodic, beyond the effect of stemming flows caused by the crisis. During other historical
periods, humanity underwent waves of migration that were similar, or even more intense, than what we are
experiencing now. The wave we are experiencing now is bound to remain with us, at least for some time,
as an important feature of international relations. Since the phenomenon is not new, we need to draw on
important lessons from the past. As this wave of emigration is not temporary, we need to tackle the phe-
nomenon intelligently and without alarmism. In this way, it is necessary to start to analyse the causes driving
emigration, which is what this section seeks to do.

3.2. Income differential


The causes of migration are as numerous and diverse as the kinds of migration that exist. Temporary migra-
tion as a one-off saving/investment strategy is not the same as the definitive move of a migrant to a new
country of residence; migration undertaken by an individual is not the same as migration by an entire family
nucleus; the characteristics of migration driven by migrant’s economic poverty are not the same as those of a
migration promoted by people’s desire to improve their professional qualification or their studies; and finally,
emigration aimed at obtaining a more secure and profitable job is not the same as emigration fuelled by the
desire to flee violence, persecution and discrimination. The means of emigration are as diverse as the reasons
behind each case. Despite that, when economic reasons are referred to for emigration—thereby excluding
political, religious and cultural reasons—the migration is thought to be conditioned by two opposing factors:
the opportunity for economic progress that change implies, and the cost and risk associated with the move.
12 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Economic theory at its simplest has tended to identify the cause of international migration with dif-
ferences in labour rewards between countries. In a framework of general equilibrium, migration operates like
a system of interconnected vessels, which allow balancing of the difference in wages between countries with
dissimilar productive factor endowments. It is to be expected, therefore, that in search of greater income,
the world’s population moves from economies with (cheap) abundant manpower in relative terms to places
where manpower is in relative short supply (higher-income countries). This theory seems confirmed by the
fact that almost 80 per cent of the migrant population of a developing country chooses a more developed
country as destination (UNDP, 2009).

Differences in living standards among countries are substantial enough to justify this movement.
Clemens Montenegro and Pritchett (2008) aim to estimate the benefits to citizens from developing countries
who settle in the United States. They compare data for 1.5 million workers in 42 developing countries with
that of people from the same developing countries who work in the United States, correcting the selection
bias associated with the comparison. They find that an average male worker from a developing country,
aged 35, with 9-12 years of education can earn an additional income of 10,000-15,000 dollars a year in the
United States. In other words, the average wage doubles or triples, depending on the case-a powerful factor
driving emigration.

According to the analysis, emigrants from the least developed countries are those which most
benefit from migration. The UNDP (2009) states that this type of migrant can see his or her income mul-
tiplied 15 times (15,000 dollars a year), while rates of registration in education double (from 47 per cent
to 95 per cent) and infant mortality is reduced 16 times (from 112 to 7 per thousand live births). For the
migrant, the emigration decision is therefore one with enormous potential for progress.

Despite the persuasiveness of the above theory, it comes up against one problem: the cartography of
cross-border migratory movements does not respond precisely to the gradient of labour rewards. Migration
does not necessarily originate from the poorest countries (where wages are lowest), nor are the principal des-
tinations for migratory flows always the richest countries (those with the highest wages). The mere difference
in wages or in developmental levels between countries does not seem an exhaustive explanation for migratory
flows. If it were, why then would Ecuadorean migrants choose Spain as a destination, when they could go,
for example, to the Netherlands, whose per capita GDP is 34 per cent higher than Spain’s? And why do
Ecuadoreans emigrate massively to Spain but not Haitians, whose per capita GDP is almost one-seventh of
Ecuador’s?

In fact, if the rate of migration (taken from Parson et al. 2007) is plotted against countries’ GDP
per capita (measured in PPP), no significant linear relationship is found between the two variables. Instead,
an inverted U-shape curve can be drawn, showing that migration is at its most intense from middle-income
countries (figure 5). Nevertheless, even this relationship is subject to nuances, since the size of a country also
influences the rate of migration (there being a bias in favour of the smaller countries) as well as the size of the
diasporas which, as we shall see later, reduces the costs of migration.

3.3. A wider view


If we want to deepen our explanation, we should begin by underlining—as Todaro (1969) and Harris
and Todaro (1970) did—that the important factor is not so much the dissimilarity of labour rewards at a
particular moment, but rather the differential in expected income during the life cycle. In other words, when
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 13

Figure 5: Migratory rate in relation to GDP per capita (PPP), 2000


Countries with more than 5 million inhabitants
0.25
Kazakhstan

0.2 Portugal

Belarus
AzerbaijanEl Salvador

Mali
Israel 2
0.15
y = -1E-10x + 3E-06x + 0.0458
2
Source: Based on data
R = 0.0318
Tajikistan
from Development
Research Centre
Burkina Faso
Ukraine
Bulgaria on Migration,
NicaraguaDominican Republic Mexico
Hong Kong Globalisation and
Uzbekistan Poverty and Parsons
0.1
Benin
Morocco Slovakia
Greece
et al. (2007),
Russian Federation
Haiti Paraguay “Quantifying
Guinea Algeria
Finland
United Kingdom International
Tunisia
BurundiAngola
Honduras Ecuador
Italy Austria Switzerland Migration: a Database
Poland
Mozambique
Guatemala
Ghana SriBolivia
Lanka Romania Turkey
Germany Netherlands
Belgium
of International
0.05 Nepal Philippines Colombia
Niger
Chad YemenEgypt
Hungary
Czech Republic
CanadaDenmark Migrant Stock”, in C.
Chile
RwandaViet Nam Peru Malaysia
Korea, Republic of Spain Sweden
France Ozden and M.Schiff
Cambodia
Zambia PakistanSyrian Arab Republic
Sudan South AfricaArgentina
Australia (Eds), International
Malawi
Cameroon
Thailand Venezuela Saudi Arabia
United States of America
Migration: Economic
Japan
Ethiopia Indonesia Brazil
Development and Policy,
China
0 World Bank, Palgrave
0 5000 10000 15000 20000 25000 30000 35000 40000 Macmillan.

the migrant decides to change countries, he or she is not just taking into account the difference between
wages in the countries of origin and destination at a given moment, but also considering the possibilities for
progress that one or another country might offer over his or her life cycle (or the overall period of emigra-
tion). In determining the difference in progress and salaries, other factors are also taken into account, such as
the probability of access to a stable job in one country or another, the possibilities for social and professional
promotion that each market offers, and the different level of risk associated with future income flows over
the migrant’s life cycle in each country.

This approach allows us to integrate the comparative demographic dynamic into the explanation of
the migratory phenomenon. The value of expected incomes in the country of origin will be notably reduced
with very expansive demographic dynamics, since an excess of working-age population will put downward
pressure on salaries as well as the probability of employment. On the other hand, a stagnant and ageing
population in host countries increases the demand for immigrants to occupy jobs at moments of economic
expansion, as well as to fund welfare systems, given the growing burden of this passive sector of the indig-
enous population.

Recently, the United Nations dealt with this issue in its report UN (2000) Replacement Migration:
Is it a Solution to Declining and Ageing Populations? According to demographic forecasts by the Population
Division of UN/DESA, the world population is expected to grow by 2.5 billion people by 2050 (from 6.7
to 9.2 billion). That growth will be concentrated in developing countries (growing from 5.4 to 7.9 billion),
with the developed world remaining relatively stable at 1.2 billion people. The growth will be accompanied
by a sharp ageing of the world population: the percentage of the population aged over 60 will double and the
percentage of those younger than 15 will slightly decline (table 3).
14 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Table 3: Distribution by age


Percentage
Percentage in 2005 Percentage in 2050
0-14 15-59 +60 +80 0-14 15-59 +60 +80
World 28.3 61.4 10.3 1.3 19.8 58.3 21.8 4.4
More developed 17.0 62.9 20.1 3.7 15.2 52.2 32.6 9.4
Less developed 30.9 61.0 8.1 0.8 20.6 59.3 20.1 3.6
Least developed 41.5 53.4 5.1 0.4 28.2 61.5 10.3 1.1
Other less developed 29.1 62.3 8.6 0.9 18.4 58.7 22.9 4.3
Africa 41.4 53.4 5.2 0.4 28.0 61.7 10.4 1.1
Asia 28.0 62.7 9.2 1.0 18.0 58.3 23.7 4.5
Europe 15.9 63.5 20.6 3.5 14.6 50.9 34.5 9.6
Latin America and the Caribbean 29.8 61.2 9.0 1.2 18.0 57.8 24.3 5.2
Northern America 20.5 62.7 16.7 1.5 17.1 55.6 27.3 7.8
Oceania 24.9 61.0 14.1 2.6 18.4 56.9 24.8 6.8
Source: “World Population Prospects: The 2006 Revision. Population Ageing”.

This process of ageing will be most striking in developed countries. By 2050, almost a third of the
population in developed countries will be 60 or older, while the population younger than 15 will scarcely
reach 15 per cent of the total (table 3). Those proportions are more balanced in developing countries, with
both ends of the age spectrum weighted at 20 per cent. There are, however, some variations among regions in
the developing world. In the major part of Latin America and Asia in which the ageing of the population has
already notably started, about 24 per cent of population will be 60 or older by 2050 while those under 15
years old will make up 18 per cent. In many African countries, with the ageing process behind that of other
regions, persons 60 and over will make up just 10 per cent of the population, while those younger than 15
will account for 28 per cent.

This age distribution has repercussions for the potential support ratio (PSR),13 which is expected to
fall in developed countries as a result of the ageing demographic. This ratio conditions not only the results
of the productive effort, since the working-age population has to sustain the dependent population; it also
conditions the possibilities of sustaining welfare policies based on distribution between active an non active
people. For example, the potential support ratio in Europe is about 4.5, but it is expected to fall to about 2
in 2050. This means every two members of the active population will have to support one retired person. It
is clear that, the greater the dependency on each working member, the lower the level of per capita income
generated from the same productive effort. Avoiding such a decline could be one of the motivations for
encouraging immigration in developed countries in the future.

The demographic data from the United Nations are rather similar to those related to the economi-
cally active population (EAP) that the ILO is projecting for the next few years.14 Accordingly, the world’s
EAP will rise from 3 billion in 2008 to little over 3.5 billion in 2020. Due to the stagnation of the EAP in
developed countries, all EAP growth is forecast to be in developing countries (by 446 million of people).
Again, if developed countries want to increase their economically active population, they will have to do it
through international migration.

13 Measured as the quotient between the population of 15 to 64 to the number of people over 65 (children younger than
15 are in this case not considered as passive people).
14 See http://laborsta.ilo.org/STP/.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 15

These demographic forecasts are translated by the UN (2000) in terms of migratory necessities
required to replenish the working age population. In one scenario,15 for example, the EU’s net immigration
would need to be almost 2.8 million people per year (0.75 per cent of the 2000 population) during the
period 1995-2050 to maintain the PSR at 3 in 2050.(figure 6). The total amount of immigrants needed for
1995-2050 across the whole of Europe would be 235 million people-four times the increase in immigration
experienced in the last 50 years. In other regions, such as North America, the replacement needs are smaller
(44 million people), but that still amounts to an increase of 17 per cent compared with the flows received over
the last five decades.16 To sum up, the differential in the patterns of demographic growth, when not compensated
for by differences in the rate of job creation, constitutes a relevant factor in explaining migratory flows.

One additional factor in migration is the accumulation of assets—to be displaced to the destina-
tion market—that can back a potential migrant’s decision to emigrate. Migration involves an investment
in resources, so it is not surprising that certain assets are required to undertake it. One relevant asset in this
respect is of course money amassed by the migrant, that is, personal savings (or those of the family) that
allow the migrant to pay for travel and other expenses associated with settlement in the destination country.
This is why—as we shall see later—extreme poverty acts as a restrictive element on emigration-the poorest
do not emigrate because of a lack of necessary resources. This leads to the conclusion that globalisation has
created an additional factor in social segregation by discriminating against those who lack sufficient means
even for migration (Bauman, 2003).17

Figure 6: Net annual needs for migrants per inhabitant in the period 1995-2050
in order to maintain the support ratio for over 65S at 3 in 2050
Percentage
1.6
Annual net migrants
1.4 Population 2000 (1995-2050)/

1.2

1.0

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2
Source: United Nations
(2000), Replacement
0.0 Migration: Is it a
Solution to Declining
Japan

Italy

Germany

European
Union

Europe

France

Republic
of Korea

United
Kingdom

Russian
Federation

United States
of America

and Ageing Population?,


United Nations
Publications No.
E.01.XIII.19.

15 The UN (2000) suggests six scenarios, some of which are unrealistically extreme. Among those proposed, the most
plausible is the one outlined here (being the fifth scenario).
16 As is obvious, the assumptions on which these estimates are based could be altered in accordance with productive
specialization and the nature of the technological development of those countries with greater ageing populations.
17 This is in keeping with the definition by Nussbaum (2000) that mobility is one of the basic fundamental capacities of
human beings.
16 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Apart from money, another important asset is the accumulated human capital of the migrant: his or
her skills, competencies and knowledge. In the highly competitive OECD markets, where primary and sec-
ondary education is virtually universal, the level of education of the migrant is an asset relevant to employ-
ment opportunities, and influences the decision to emigrate (Adams, 2003). The asset of education becomes
even more valuable in the case of migration to countries with selective migratory policies such as Canada or
Australia. On the other hand, education seems less relevant in the case of irregular migration, or migration
specialising in rural labour (Mora and Taylor, 2006).

In general, a migrant’s training can actuate the migratory decision as it facilitates access and inser-
tion into the labour market of the destination country. The more difficult the access to a labour market, the
greater the educational assets a migrant should possess in order to ensure success. For example, in case of mi-
gration to the U.S., the level of education of migrants from Asia or Africa is higher than those from Mexico.
The cost of not finding a job in the host country for a Mexican migrant may be seen as lower than for African
and Asian migrants, who require a higher level of human capital to reduce their risk of failure. In general,
migrants tend to have a higher level of education than the average person in their country of origin. For
example, 35 per cent of economically active migrants heading to OECD countries have tertiary education, a
rate almost six times the average population in their countries of origin (Docquier and Marfouk, 2006).

In some cases and professions this effect is so pronounced that—as we shall see further on—it drains
the pool of professionals with higher education in the country of origin, leading to what has been dubbed
brain drain. Frequently, however, the economy receiving the emigrants is incapable of making full use of the
education of the migrant population, and immigrants end up in less-skilled jobs, causing the phenomenon
called brain waste.

One of the components of human capital that can be evaluated by the destination market is the
mastery the emigrant has of the language and customs of the host country. Mastery of the language and local
culture allows the migrant, in theory, to integrate in the labour market and the social environment more
quickly, and with lower costs (Alonso and Gutiérrez, 2010). This asset is especially valued in jobs involving a
high level of communication, such as those related to customer service or personal care. This factor explains
why migrants from English-speaking countries are over-represented in the United Kingdom and the United
States, while French-speaking emigrants are over-represented in France and Belgium, and Latin Americans
in Spain. The cultural community is also a factor that can reduce a migrant’s integration costs in the host
country. This explains why six out of ten migrants head for countries with a similar religion to their own,
and four of ten go to a country with the same language (UNDP, 2009).

The comparative degree of certainty about the future flow of income in the markets of origin and
destination also influences the decision to migrate. The more unstable the market of origin and the more
stable the likelihood of progress in the destination market, the greater the migratory pressure. The stability of
the destination market influences the confidence with which the future is viewed, in terms of an intertempo-
ral choice (through the discount factor of expected income). Migration tends to take place in highly unstable
environments with episodes of prolonged stagnation or recurrent crises in the markets of origin; and it is
stimulated by the sequence of continued progress in the destination markets. This explains the effect that the
current crisis is having on reducing the attraction of some developed countries as destinations for migration.

Lastly, another factor that limits migration is the cost of transport and access to the destination markets.
Here we need to consider not just the economic cost of transportation and settling in the host country, but
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 17

also the risks and difficulties associated with the transit. This is why the bulk of international migrations take
place within regions: almost 60 per cent of emigration happens between countries belonging to the same
region (Parsons et al., 2007). In accordance, migratory pressures are increased when proximity reduces access
costs while, at the same time, the contrast between levels of living is made more evident. This is the case with
the geographical borders between the developed and developing world, where the gradients of income and
well-being that co-exist internationally are most visible and immediate. This is evident, for example, in the
3,600-kilometres border between the United States and Mexico, and in the sea that separates North Africa
(Tunisia, Libya or Morocco) from Southern Europe (Italy or Spain); also between Albania or Macedonia and
Greece or Italy, or between Indonesia and Malaysia. In all these cases, the relationship between the per capita
incomes of the contiguous countries is higher than 1 to 3 (Milanovic, 2011).

3.4. Other social factors


So far, the factors we have considered in explaining emigration have been those that most directly affect the
differential of future income in the markets of destination and origin. However, other factors, more social in
nature, also influence the decision to emigrate. Here we will focus our attention on nine of them.

Firstly, as Stark and Levhari (1982) and Katz and Stark (1984) suggest, beyond being a route to
improved income, migration can also be considered a risk-avoidance strategy by families in highly vulnerable
environments. Something presented as a personal venture can in fact be a calculated strategy for reducing
levels of family risk through diversification of the income sources of the domestic unit. To the extent that a
low co-variance exists between the evolution of income in the markets of origin and destination, the migra-
tion of a family member can prove an apt strategy to reduce the levels of risk and vulnerability of the family
nucleus. An important conclusion that can be drawn from this is that the factors determining the migration
of certain family members can also explain why, sometimes, the rest of the family decides not to migrate.

Looking at the family and community as a reference unit to analyse emigration seems to be an accept-
ably demonstrated assessment (Massey, 1987, Barham and Boucher, 1998). The presence and purpose of re-
mittances, the intensity of communication between the emigrant and his or her family, the sharing of family
obligations such as caring for children and the home by family members who remain behind, and the effort
the emigrant devotes to the processes of reuniting the family are all factors which confirm a family com-
mitment on which the decision to emigrate is largely based. Emigration redefines family relations, causing
new morphologies in the family nucleus as a result of the ties maintained despite a geographical separation
(creating so-called transnational families18). Taking this approach, as Stark and Bloom (1985) do, migration
theory is widened beyond the consideration of migration as a purely individual decision (where individuals
make the most of themselves) and is instead seen as a cooperative choice (optimisation of the whole family).
The theory moves to consider migration as a “calculated strategy” rather than as a mere “act of desperation or
limitless optimism”.

Secondly, emigration involves costs associated with transport and settling in the destination country.
These costs can be notably reduced by the presence of family networks, ethnic or linguistic ties between the
communities of origin and those of the destination of the emigrant (Massey, Goldring and Durand, 1994;
Borjas, 1992, 1994 and 1995).

18 The “chain of affection” that emigration produces is ironic, since it often results in a migrant looking after children
in the host country to make a living, leaving her own children to be looked after in the country of origin by a family
member (Hoshschild, 2001).
18 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

This element has been justly highlighted by studies on emigration that draw two interesting consid-
erations. The first has to do with the influence that the linguistic and cultural proximity between countries
of origin and destination has on emigration, an aspect highlighted by Borjas (1999); the second refers to the
effect that the social networks of the diasporas have on reducing the costs and risks of emigration (Massey et
al., 1987). Both factors contribute a partially accumulative nature to the phenomenon: as the diasporas in-
crease, further emigration from a similar origin is facilitated. Common ties and networks of trust constitute
an external force that reduces the emigrant’s cost and risk levels when settling in the host country (Bartel,
1989, and Jaeger, 2000).

A consideration of this aspect reveals the contradictory relationship of migration to the social capital
of the countries of origin and destination. Migration involves, firstly, the loss of social capital in the coun-
try of origin, as a result of the break in common ties-it causes a sort of social capital drain. Migration also
involves a similar process in the host country, since it brings with it heterogeneous elements (different values,
customs, languages and cultures) that may weaken existing relationships of trust in the destination country,
feeding xenophobic tendencies. Part of the lost social capital is re-established in the more limited sphere
of the immigrant community in the diasporas, which acts as a factor of security for the integration of new
arrivals (Schiff, 1998).

Thirdly, one variable whose effects on emigration are disputed is the level of inequality present in the
emigrant’s original society. For some authors, such as Stark (1984) and Stark and Yizhaki (1988), there is a
direct relationship between inequality and migratory pressure: the higher the level of inequality (the greater
the relative shortage, in Stark’s terms), the greater the migratory intensity for a given level of poverty. For
other authors, however, such as Clark et al. (2002), inequality approximates the differential in the rewards
of diverse levels of qualification; the greater the inequality in home countries, the lower the stimulus to
emigrate to populations with better levels of training. The first of these relationships was noted for the case
of Mexico by Stark and Taylor (1986), while the second relationship seems to fit the results of Clark et al.
(2002) who studied emigration from various regions to the United States.

In pure terms, the two interpretations are not as contradictory as they might seem, if we consider
the additional effect of social mobility. If there is sufficient social mobility, inequality would not lead to a
decision to emigrate, since social improvement could be obtained in one’s own country of origin. In this
case, the interpretation suggested by Clark et al. (2002) would be feasible. However, when mobility does
not exist (in other words, when inequality is engrained and chronic), emigration constitutes one of the few
means through which the less fortunate can improve their social status (and that of their family)-this is the
interpretation offered by Stark and Yizhaki (1988).

From a dynamic point of view, one can perceive the complexity of the relationships between the
evolution of inequality and migratory pressure. Everything seems to indicate that the relationship is not
monotonic. When the country of origin has a very unequal income distribution, an increase in inequality
will lead to a fall in the rate of emigration, perhaps because increases in extreme poverty lead to more people
lacking the resources to migrate. On the other hand, when the country of origin has a relatively fair income
distribution, an increase in inequality will increase the rate of emigration, perhaps because the number of
people who are frustrated with their expectations for progress is increased. The migration rate seems there-
fore to describe an inverted U curve: the rate grows and then falls as levels of inequality fall. However, more
investigation is needed to confirm this relationship.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 19

Fourthly, a neater relationship exists between emigration and poverty. As is recognized, migration is
not highest in either the poorest countries or the poorest sectors of society (Hatton and Williamson, 2003).
This is largely because the migratory decision itself involves an economic cost that cannot always be met
by the poorest sectors. Migration entails a minimum amount of capital to cover the costs of the journey,
payment to intermediaries for entering the destination country (fixers, those who help irregular immigrants
across the border, etc.) and money for survival until the migrant finds work. In many cases, the capital
involved is beyond the savings potential of the would-be migrants, who must borrow money either from the
formal financial sector or, more frequently, from the informal sector (usurers) or the intermediaries. Among
poor people, having a migratory experience seems to be dependent on the accumulation of assets by the
emigrant’s family in preparation for the costs of migration. This also suggests the advantage enjoyed by those
sectors of society living above the poverty line. To sum up, migration requires that an emigrant have a certain
prior economic capacity, thus many poor people are excluded from migrating (Barham and Boucher, 1998;
Taylor, 1986 and 1987; López and Schiff, 1998).

That said, we observe the fifth factor to take into consideration—if the potential migrant can access
a prior accumulation of capital (his own savings, or a loan), the question becomes: why does he not invest
that capital in his place of origin, in order to avoid emigration? One response has to do with the existence of
significant imperfections in the capital markets, making them rationed markets that are difficult to access for
people without patrimonial assets that can be given as a guarantee (Stark and Chau, 1998). As mentioned
before, emigration can be considered an investment strategy: an aim of the migratory experience is to obtain
the resources needed for the emigrant and her family to establish the foundations for a more secure and
comfortable life. If capital markets operated with perfect information, the corresponding institutions (of
credit and insurance) would be capable of identifying successful investment projects, providing the savings
and necessary assurance, thereby avoiding the migratory strategy. In this sense, the absence of those condi-
tions is what stimulates alternative savings strategies such as emigration.

Sixthly, beyond the singular elements that influence migratory decision, there are global contextual
factors that also fuel migration. Three are especially remarkable. Firstly, the worldwide spread of market
relationships, fuelled by economic growth in developed countries and by the ubiquitous presence of multi-
national companies, works to change socioeconomic and cultural conditions on the periphery. These rela-
tionships create ideological and material ties that promote migration of workers from developing countries
toward the centre of the world system (an aspect pointed out by neo-Marxist theories, such as Wallerstein,
1974; or from a different approach by Sassen, 1988). Secondly, the labour market segmentation in developed
countries promotes the consideration of some jobs as socially undesirable by native workers (the so-called
three Ds: dirty, dangerous and degrading); such jobs are set aside for immigrant workers (Piore, 1979). And,
thirdly, structural imbalances in developing countries also fuel migration, as a consequence of the widespread
expectations for consumption and ways of life inappropriate to the resources and possibilities present in most
developing countries (Portes and Walton, 1981).

The seventh factor is that the ageing process and the dissolution of the nuclear family model of
developed countries have generated an increased demand for migrant workers to carry out domestic tasks
or to care for children, sick persons, or the elderly. These kinds of tasks have created an important market
in developed countries, promoting jobs especially for migrant women. So a “chain of affection” is generated
internationally, with the consequence that the migrant offers her host family affection that she cannot offer
her own family, as they are left behind in the home country (Hoshschild, 2001). This factor is expected to
grow in importance in the future.
20 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

An eighth factor, also forecast to gain importance in future migration trends, is the effect promoted
by climate change and other environmental damages. We do not know enough about the effects of such
factors on international migration. Probably a significant part of the migration triggered by environmental
causes will occur within a given national territory, but we can not dismiss international migration as a
consequence of the severe deterioration of fragile ecological environments with abundant populations.

One final reflection is concerned with the relationship between migration and development.
According to the heuristics suggested by Hirschman (1977), migration constitutes an expression of an indi-
vidual exit, once loyalty to local institutions has been lost and there is a lack of faith around the possibilities
of the expression of a collective voice to change the society. In keeping with this explanation, it is not surpris-
ing that migratory pressures increase when situations such as the breakdown of government, institutional
fragility, social fragmentation, or a collective lack of confidence occur. In these cases, emigration becomes an
escape valve for social crises and a silent condemnation of the failure of collective response in the countries of
origin (Ellerman, 2003; Li and McHale, 2009).

This same approach may lead to a notably unsettling conclusion: in certain conditions, migration
can annul the possibilities for transformative options in a country of origin, which become unfeasible due to
the bleeding of resources that migration entails. In the terms used by Rosenstein-Rodan (1943), migration
could make it impossible for a country to obtain a high level equilibrium, condemning that country to re-
main at a low level equilibrium (remaining at the level of an underdeveloped country). Suppose, for example,
that there are complementarities between, for example, unskilled workers, human capital and physical
capital, that are necessary to take into account to reach a high level equilibrium. Unskilled workers are faced
with two options: (i) to remain in the country, trusting that the rest of the elements of the strategy will be
available and, as a result, the dynamic (or high level) equilibrium will be reachable, to the benefit of all; or,
alternatively, (ii) they can try to improve their personal state through emigration. The greater the lack of trust
in the possibilities of quality collective action in the country of origin, the more attractive the individual
option of emigration will become. The problem is that the more individuals emigrate, the lower the chances
of success for a cooperative strategy designed to achieve a high level of equilibrium. In turn, the reduction in
expectations for collective success encourages new individuals to opt for emigration, generating a process that
feeds on itself, condemning the economy in question to remain underdeveloped.

3.5. Empirical evidence


Testing all the theories mentioned in the previous sections is necessarily difficult. However, in the last few
years, advances have been made in micro- and macro-economic perspectives. Firstly, an effort has been made
to link the decision to migrate to the incentives associated with mobility, as well as to the specific character-
istics of the person or family involved. The aim in the microeconomic approach is to definitively reconstitute
the decision-making process of the emigrant (or her family), taking into account the factors that influence
the decision. Studies along these lines include those by Perloff et al. (1998), Taylor (1987, 1992), Stark and
Taylor (1989, 1991), Lucas and Stark (1985), Bardham and Boucher (1998) and Mora and Taylor (2006).
In general, these studies confirm the selective character of migration. Factors such as the accumulated wealth
of the family, the age and educational level of the people, and the existence of social support networks are
significant variables in the migratory decision.

Macroeconomic investigations have, in general, tended to be inspired by the proposals of Sjaastad


(1962) or Borjas (1994, 1999). In the first case, emigration is conceived as an investment process in which
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 21

it is necessary to consider both the benefits and the costs associated with transit and settlement in the host
country. Borjas (1994, 1999), on the other hand, sees emigration as a result of the forces of attraction and
repulsion (pull and push) that operate in the markets of origin and destination (Alonso et al., 2004). In this
way, he defines three equations of behaviour: one referred to the wage and job conditions in the host coun-
try; the other related to these conditions in the country of origin; and a third equation to consider the cost
factors associated with a change of country. The reduced functional form of these three equations is not very
far from that offered by Sjaastad (1962).

With a greater or lesser degree of sophistication, the empirical studies have taken this framework of
analysis as their starting point. Hatton and Williamson (1998) examine whether the migratory rate in the
United States is positively related to the differential of the average wage (adjusted in terms of purchasing
power parity) between the origin and destination countries, with the weight of the cohorts of the young
population in the source country and the total number of immigrants in the destination country. Alongside
these factors, Faini and Venturini (1994) add the negative effect that the level of poverty has on the possibil-
ity of emigration, by studying emigration from Southern Europe.

Using a relatively similar structure as a starting point, several authors have tried to build a more
complete model to determine migratory flows. In some cases they have tried to explain the international
emigration to a particular country: Clark et al. (2002), for instance, study emigration to the United States;
Karemera et al. (2000), emigration to the United States and Canada; Hatton (2005), emigration to the
United Kingdom; and Márquez et al. (2004), Moreno and López-Casanovas (2006), Cebrián (2009) and
Alonso (2010), studying the case of migration to Spain. Other authors, meanwhile, prefer to study bilateral
emigration involving a larger or smaller group of countries: Mayda (2007), for example, studies 14 OECD
countries; Perdersen et al. (2008), relationship to 27 countries; or Berthelémy et al. (2009), the emigration
to developed countries.

The analytical methods employed in these studies range from cross-country analysis (Clark et al.,
2002, Hatton, 2004, and Alonso, 2010, for example), to a kind of gravitational models (Berthelémy et al.,
2009, and Karemera et al., 2000), to panels of dynamic data with Generalized Method of Moments (GMM)
and Generalized Estimating Equations (GEE) procedures (Pedersen et al., 2008). The periods analysed do
not completely coincide, although most of them relate to the accelerated period of emigration in the 1990s.

A good example of these types of results is that of Clark et al. (2002) which considers the widest
range of factors in the explanation of migratory flows. The results of that model are in the Annex, applied to
the United States, while a similar approach is applied to emigration to Spain (Alonso, 2010).

4. Effects of migration
4.1. Aggregated effects
It is not unusual to find bodies of opinion that staunchly defend the advantages of free trade and free capital
movement while, at the same time, call for severe restrictions on migratory flows. Nevertheless, as stated ear-
lier, the theoretical frameworks in which the effects of one or another type of flow is analysed are, essentially,
the same. In a world of perfect competition, the mobility of both goods and services as well as other factors
such as capital and labour lead to greater total efficiency. In the case of migration, free migration allows
people to move from where they are least rewarded (because they are less productive) to areas where they
22 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

earn more (and are more productive). As a result, this is not a zero-sum game. The international system as a
whole undergoes an increase in its total level of efficiency and material well-being. Obviously, not all sectors
of society benefit from the change, but the overall result is undeniable.

It is interesting to ask how large the benefits would be in terms of efficiency gains in the hypotheti-
cal case of greater freedom of movement of people. Hamilton and Whalley (1984) undertook that task by
building a model of general equilibrium and supposing full labour mobility. The authors were aware of the
simplification of the assumptions taken as a starting point, but they were aiming to estimate the potential
benefits of free migration. The results were striking: after considering various scenarios, they evaluated the
benefits as being in a range between 4.7 and 16 billion dollars, at a time (1977) when the world’s overall
GDP was estimated at 7.82 billion dollars. In other words, the gain from allowing the free movement of
people was between 60 per cent and 204 per cent of the world’s GDP.

More recently, Moses and Letnes (2002) repeated the exercise of Hamilton and Whalley, trying to
correct some of its shortcomings and extending the estimate to 1998. In particular, Moses and Letnes had
access to better data and updated the adjustments to the economically active population, and to the compar-
ative productivity of the labour factor. Given the sensitivity of the results to the elasticity of the substitution
of factors, the estimates were carried out with various parameters, assuming the most conservative conditions
for the environment. As a result of those changes, the benefits of liberalisation were found to be more limited
than those obtained by Hamilton and Whalley, but they nevertheless remain notable: accepting an elasticity
of substitution of 1, the gains would be 7.19 billion dollars in 1977, a magnitude only slightly lower than
the total GDP for that year; while gains would reach 34 billion dollars in 1998, or 96 per cent of the GDP.
The application of the adjustments of labour efficiency between migrants and natives would considerably
reduce the estimates, but even in the most restrictive case, with the supposed elasticity of substitution, the
benefits would be equivalent to 9.4 per cent of the 1977 GDP and 12.6 per cent of the 1998 GDP.

Even though this is an intellectual exercise, the estimates confirm the potential efficiency gains that
could result from less restrictive migration policies. It is also important to note that even a small correction
to the wage differential can bring about part of the
benefits; in other words, the first phases towards Table 4: Efficiency gains from removing
restrictions on emigration
complete liberalisation—a powerful argument in Percentage of world GDP
favour of more flexible positions in the field of Elasticities of substitution
regulation of the movement of people—could real- 1.5 1.25 1 0.75 0.5
ized such benefits. Without adjustment
1977 109.5 102.7 92.7 76.4 47.6
More recently, the World Bank (2006) car- 1998 118.1 109.4 96.5 75.6 43.6
ried out a similar exercise but with a different focus. With adjustments (1)
Instead of considering full freedom of movement of 1977 28.2 26.4 23.8 20.2 14.8
1998 36.0 33.3 29.7 24.4 17.3
people, it started from a more realistic assumption:
With adjustments (2)
accepting an annual growth rate of 3 per cent of the
1977 11.6 10.6 9.4 7.9 5.9
working population in developed countries between 1998 15.5 14.2 12.6 10.7 8.3
2001 and 2025, and allowing labour needs to be Source: Own elaboration from Moses, J.W. and B. Letnes
covered, as required, by immigration.19 That would (2002): “The economic cost to international labour restrictions”,
WIDER Conference, September. Adjustments 1 and 2 referred to
involve an increase in the immigrant population the correction of the differentials of salaries in function of the
by about 14 million people in the 24 year period productivity differentials between regions.

19 The demographic forecasts for developed countries predict scant growth in the working population of those countries.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 23

(increasing from 27.8 to 42 million), assuming an annual accumulated rate of increase in the total number of
new immigrants of 1.7 per cent, which is slightly under that of the last three decades. In terms of the starting
point, this implies an increase in the total amount of immigrants by almost 50 per cent in the final year of the
period, although the rate of variation depends on the demographic characteristics of each country.20

If we take as a baseline the assumption that the proportion of immigrants that there was in 2001
is maintained, the net gains to welfare from the expansion scenario suggested above would be close to 674
million dollars, or 1.19 per cent of world GDP. If this is adjusted in function of the different costs of living
from country to country (translated into Purchasing Power Parity), the benefits would be somewhat reduced
but would still amount to 0.63 per cent of world GDP. The distribution of these benefits would be favourable
to developing countries (including to the people who emigrate) since these populations would experience an
increase in income of about 1.8 per cent, while developed countries would obtain an increase of 0.4 per cent.

The World Bank’s estimation makes an additional interesting contribution as it divides the impact
of migration between private and public consumption, on one hand, and between different sectors of society
on the other. Although the largest benefits are obtained by the people who migrate, the families that remain
behind also benefit from the process. The sector of society that is most clearly affected negatively is that of
migrants who are already settled, as they represent the main substitution factor for the new immigration.

The regional distribution of these gains is highly sensitive to differences in starting salaries. In par-
ticular, Southern Asian and Latin American natives obtain a greater relative benefit as a result of the migra-
tory phenomenon; for new communities of emigrants, the greatest benefits are concentrated in Sub-Saharan
Africa, which is the region with the lowest salaries (figure 7).

Table 5: Change in real income due to the migratory process

Real income Real income adjusted for cost of living


Private Public Total Private Public Total
Billion dollars
Natives in developed countries 0.44 -0.01 0.36 0.44 -0.01 0.36
Former migrants in developed countries -9.41 -0.02 -6.02 -9.41 -0.02 -6.02
Natives in developing countries 0.94 0.44 0.86 0.94 0.44 0.86
New immigrants 584 607 589 198 203 199
World total 1.20 1.15 1.19 0.67 0.45 0.63

Percentage change
Natives in developed countries 0.44 -0.01 0.36 0.44 -0.01 0.36
Former migrants in developed countries -9.41 -0.02 -6.02 -9.41 -0.02 -6.02
Natives in developing countries 0.94 0.44 0.86 0.94 0.44 0.86
New immigrants 584 607 589 198 203 199
World total 1.20 1.15 1.19 0.67 0.45 0.63
Source: World Bank (2006): Global Economic Prospects: Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration, Washington, D.C.,
The World Bank.

20 The simplified assumptions on which this estimate is based include the following: (i) the proportion of the population
that is qualified or unqualified is maintained in developed countries (both grow by 3 per cent); (ii) the regional origin
of the migrants remains constant; (iii) it is understood that migrant workers will bring their families to the new
country in accordance with the ratio of dependence of their own country of origin; (iv) remittances are considered to
remain constant as a proportion of the migrant’s income.
24 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Figure 7: Distribution of benefits by region


Percentage
1.2 700
Natives New migrants

600
1.0

500
0.8

New migrants
400
Natives

0.6
300

0.4
200

0.2 100

0.0 0
Source: World Bank

Sub-Saharan
Africa
Middle East and
Northern Africa
Europe and
Central Asia

Latin America
East Asia and
Pacific
Developing
countries

Southern Asia

(2006): Global
Economic Prospects:
Economic Implications
of Remittances and
Migration, Washington,
D.C., The World Bank.

The World Bank’s estimates double the benefit calculated a few years earlier by Walmsley and
Winters (2003), who took very similar assumptions, supposing more flexible regulation of temporary
migration in order to allow the labour force of developed countries to grow by about 3 per cent. Their lowest
estimate (around $150 billion) responds to a more restrictive assumption in the salary differential between
the immigrant population and the native population in the host country. Nevertheless, the World Bank
(2006) results are very close to those of Walmsley et al. (2005).

Lastly and more recently, van der Mensbrugghe and Roland-Host (2009) applied the Linkage model
to estimate the impact of migration, using a framework of computable general equilibrium models (CGE),
thereby updating the work carried out by the World Bank (2006). In particular, they corrected the growth
rates of developed countries (downwards) and developing countries (upwards) and used new PPP estimates.
With these assumptions, the authors considered the flows of migrants as exogenous and defined various
scenarios in function of the growth in the workforce in the destination countries. If 5 per cent growth in
the workforce is assumed, an increase in the world’s aggregate product is expected to be around $964 billion
($571 billion in PPP) by 2025 (in relation to the base line), or roughly equivalent to 0.9 per cent of world
GDP. Again, the new migrants capture the bulk of that benefit, and previous emigrants are negatively af-
fected, although to a lesser extent. The direction of the estimates would not change much if the growth rate
of the labour population in the destination country were 3 per cent or 8 per cent, leading to net benefits to
the world GDP of $604 billion and $1,462 billion, respectively, in relation to the base line.

The fact that migration has a positive effect on the international system in terms of aggregate ef-
ficiency does not mean that everyone affected ends up winning. As we have seen, the current immigrant and
native workers substituted by new immigrants may be negatively affected by an intensification in migratory
flows. This argument is occasionally used to justify a restrictive migration policy, highlighting the way in
which the entry of new immigrants could depress salaries in the recipient country. Empirical studies confirm
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 25

this effect, but find the salary decline to be small. For example, Borjas (2003) finds that immigration to
the United States between 1980 and 2000 caused a cumulative deterioration in average U.S. salaries by
3.2 per cent (in other words, an annual reduction of barely 0.15 per cent). An even lower rate is estimated
by Ottaviano and Peri (2008), who put the accumulated effect of immigration between 1990 and 2006 at
0.4 per cent (in other words, a 0.025 per cent fall in the average rate).

At least three additional factors should be taken into account to further evaluate the effect: (i) the
inverse effect—a rise in salaries—that is taking place in countries from which migrants originate, as Mishra
(2007) demonstrates in the case of Mexico; (ii) the reduction in the cost of certain goods and services caused
by the arrival of migrants, increasing the purchasing power of salaries in the recipient country; and (iii) the
fact that the contraction effect on salaries only occurs in the short term—in the long term, the net effect is
positive (Ottaviano and Peri, 2008). The cost of migration to the citizens of recipient countries does not,
therefore, seem a weighty argument in support of restrictive migratory policies, especially when judged in the
light of the criteria of equality.

To sum up, estimates confirm the potential efficiency gains of a less restrictive policy on migration.
These benefits, even in their most modest versions, are comparable (or superior) to those that would result
from the trade liberalisation promoted by the Doha Round and, moreover, afford a more equal distribution
of those benefits among countries. In fact, the World Bank (2006) itself decided to update the benefits that
would derive from the global reform of trade (as envisaged in Doha) for the same year as the estimate of the
migratory model. The results are clear: $155 billion of gains in the case of the trade reform, compared with
$175 in the case of migration. This confirms the development potential of international migration.

4.2. Remittances
Remittances that migrants send home are another important issue when examining the effects on develop-
ment of migratory processes. There are two aspects that need to be considered here: the size of the remit-
tances, and their effects.

a) Size
Although it has become considerably easier in recent years, it is still difficult to adequately assess the size of
remittances. Accounting registration criteria are inadequate, and the levels of hidden remittances compli-
cate the task tremendously. With regard to registration, the definition of an immigrant used by National
Accounts is far from clear. In fact, in the balance-of-payment accounts there are three related items: workers
remittances, compensation of employees, and migrant transfers. Defining these components while avoiding
overlaps, and identifying the source of each, is complicated.

Added to the difficulties of registration, there are problems stemming from the fact that many of the
transfer channels are less than transparent, causing obvious complications for the statistics. Often migrants’
savings are sent in the form of non-financial assets (consumer or household goods, for example), or transfers
are made via informal routes (trips by acquaintances or family members) that are impossible to control. Thus
only a fraction of the savings sent home by migrants is captured in statistical data, appearing in the balance
of payments. Conservative estimates put unrecorded remittances at a third or more the size of registered
remittances21, but the recent study by the World Bank (2006) increased that ratio to as high as 50 per cent.

21 Puri and Ritzema (1999) carry out an estimate of unregistered remittances in eleven countries. The margins they
obtain are very wide, ranging from 8 per cent to 85 per cent of documented remittances. The average is 36 per cent of
registered remittances according to the sample studied.
26 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

In accordance with the best estimates—those provided by the World Bank—migrant remittances
reached a little over $443 billion in 2008—the year with highest amount of remittances—$325 billion of
which went to developing countries and the remaining $118 billion to developed countries (table 6). The total
remittances doubled the total of ODA ($122 billion in that year).

Table 6: Evolution of remittances, 1990-2009


Millions of dollars
1990 1995 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Developing countries 31 56 81 95 111 137 159 192 226 278 325 307
Regions
Latin American 5.7 13.3 20.1 24.4 28.1 36.7 43.3 49.8 58.8 63.0 64.4 56.5
Southern Asia 5.6 10 17.2 19.2 24.1 30.3 28.6 33.9 42.5 54.0 71.6 75.0
Eastern Asia 3.1 8.9 15.8 20.9 27.0 32.2 40.0 50.3 57.4 71.0 85.5 85.8
Northern Africa and the Middle East 11.4 13.3 13.0 15.3 15.9 20.4 23.2 25.0 26.4 32.1 36.0 33.4
Central Europe and Central Asia 3.2 6.4 10.3 10.3 10.7 11.6 15.9 23.2 28.4 39.3 45.8 35.4
Sub-Saharan Africa 1.9 3.2 4.6 4.6 5.0 5.9 8.0 9.4 12.6 18.6 21.6 20.7
Income levels
Low income 1.4 2.2 4.1 4.5 6.0 6.9 8.1 10.0 12.9 16.6 22.0 22.7
Lower-middle income 18.4 31.2 48.8 57.6 68.7 82.9 93.5 114.2 135.8 174.8 211.0 206.3
Upper-middle income 10.9 21.8 28.3 32.7 36.1 47.4 57.6 67.4 77.5 86.8 91.9 77.9
High income 37.5 46.0 50.2 54.6 58.2 66.8 77.7 82.7 91.2 106.3 118.5 109.5
World 68.6 101.6 131.5 149.5 169.2 204.2 236.9 274.5 317.6 384.5 443.5 416.5
Source: World Bank: World Development Indicators (http://data.worldbank.org).

Viewed in perspective, the rapid growth of remittances in the last few years is surprising. In par-
ticular, officially registered remittances destined for developing countries climbed from barely $31 billion in
1990 to $325 billion in 2008. This increase became particularly notable in the past three five-year periods,
where official remittances grew at an average 5-year accumulative rate of 13 per cent. Caution is required
when interpreting these numbers due to the existence of remittances not captured by official statistics,
however the figures reveal a significant growth of remittances that has acquired increasing relevance in the
international system. In fact, during the period of 1995-2008, only foreign direct investment grew faster.
The average rate of growth of remittances in that period doubles the rate of international aid and is higher
than the rate of exports (figure 8).

The trend of remittances shows two traits which are relevant in development terms. The first is
related to the regional distribution of remittance flows, which reflects, with slight nuance, the distribution
of emigrant sources. It is not surprising that those with larger population and significant rates of migration,
such as the Asian regions, account for almost 44 per cent of the remittances sent to developing countries
(Southern Asia 18 per cent and Eastern Asia 22 per cent). Latin America follows with 21 per cent, North
Africa and the Middle East with 12 per cent, and Eastern Europe with 18 per cent. Sub-Saharan Africa
is last, with 7 per cent. By country, the main recipients of remittances coincide with the middle-income
countries, the main source of emigration flows: India, China, Mexico, the Philippines and Morocco, among
the developing countries.

The distribution of remittances in accordance with countries’ income levels is interesting for another
reason: the poorest countries do not receive the bulk of the money. More than half of remittances flows to
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 27

Figure 8: Evolution of financial flows to developing countries, 1995-2008


Annual averate rate (percentage)
16

14

12

10

Source: World Bank:


0 World Development
Foreign direct Indicators (http://data.
Exports investment Official aid Remittances worldbank.org).

developing countries (65 per cent) go to lower-middle income countries, 28 per cent go to upper-middle
income countries, and 6 per cent go to the poorest countries. However, as in the case of regional distribu-
tion, this result is highly dependent on the burden of the population (and the migration potential) of the
various aggregates. It is important, therefore, to relate these resources to the country’s other relative dimen-
sions (table 7).

The ratio of remittances to the GDP of the poorest countries is almost double that of middle-
income countries. In fact, the ratio of remittances to GDP decreases as income level goes up: 4.63 per cent
in the case of low-income countries and barely 1.18 per cent for upper-middle-income countries. This profile
explains the redistributive effect of the remittances in the international scope. Another way of expressing the
same problem is to compare remittances with other relevant macroeconomic variables (table 7). The ratio of
remittances to foreign direct investment, gross capital formation, imports, or private consumption are higher

Table 7: Relative importance of remittances


Average 2005-2008
Percentage of GDP Remittances as a percentage of
Gross
Foreign Official Foreign Official capital Private
Remittances investment aid investment aid Imports formation consume
Low income countries 4.63 2.22 9.10 208.5 50.4 12.6 20.3 5.9
Middle income countrires 1.86 2,20 0,42 84.8 436.5 6.2 6.3 3.5
Lower-middle income 2.51 2.50 0.70 100.3 356.8 7.5 6.9 5.2
Upper-middle income 1.18 1.91 0.14 62.2 819.3 4.4 5.1 2.0
High income countries 0.25 -0.89 - -0.27 - 0.8 1.1 0.4
Source: World Bank: World Development Indicators (http://data.worldbank.org).
28 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

in the low-income countries than in the other groups (middle- and high-income countries). This confirms
the key role that remittance plays as part of international financing in the poorest countries.

The second relevant characteristic of remittances is their acceptable stability over time. For example,
considering the evolution of the variables since 1990, the variation coefficient for remittances (0.23) is a little
higher than that for international aid (0.09), but it is notably lower than flows of direct investment (0.46)
or other private flows (0.43). The greater stability of remittances makes them a more predictable source of fi-
nancing than other private sources. Furthermore, remittances often demonstrate an anti-cyclical nature, with
family aid increasing during periods of greater difficulty in the country of origin, a fact verified by Kapur and
McHale (2005) through a panel of data on 14 countries. Other case studies also confirm this: the case of the
Philippines after the financial crisis of 1997 (Yang, 2005) or of Jamaica following its natural disaster (Clarke
and Wallsten, 2004).

To sum up, in relation to other private financing sources, remittances are more stable and more
equitative in their distribution. Additionally, in terms of official financing—foreign aid and other official
sources—remittances are not only larger, but also more dynamic in nature.

b) Effects
The effects of remittances on recipient societies are multiple, and not all of them produce the same result,
which explains why empirical exercises present contradictory results. While some researchers argue that remit-
tances allow families to improve their economic security and increase their ability to invest, others believe that
remittances encourage conspicuous consumption and “rentier” behaviour by recipients. Although this contro-
versy is far from resolved, the following section will try to shed some light on the available empirical evidence.

From a macroeconomic perspective, remittances provide developing countries with a means of relaxing
external constraints on their growth, helping them finance imports and preserve the balance of payments.
Remittances also complement diminished domestic savings, contributing to an increase in the investment
effort. Additionally, in some countries such as Brazil, El Salvador and Mexico, remittances are used as a
guarantee in their access to international private capital. (Ketkar and Ratha, 2001).

Of course, a large volume of remittances to a given country can have perverse macroeconomic
effects. There are two factors most frequently cited. The first has to do with the appreciation of the real
exchange rate and the subsequent loss of competitiveness for the concerned economy, through so-called
“Dutch disease”. The reality is that this effect only seems plausible in those economies (generally small in
size) that are highly dependent on remittances. In addition, the steady, gradual growth of remittances means
that any perverse effect is less pronounced than that of other international resources displaying significant
instability. In fact, Rajan and Subramanian (2005) do not find symptoms of loss of competitiveness associ-
ated with remittances. Despite this finding, however, the possibility that the Dutch disease could emerge
in countries that are highly dependent on remittances (such as Haiti, Jordan, Jamaica, Cape Verde and El
Salvador) should not be ruled out.

The second factor that is often cited is the temporary nature of remittances. Remittance flows are
expected to fall as emigrants extend their time abroad because ties to families left behind in the countries of
origin become weakened over extended periods of time. This effect can be reinforced by immigrants starting
new families in their host countries, or by family members from the country of origin being brought to the
host countries to join relatives, leading to a fall in remittances. However, this behaviour is far from certain.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 29

Indeed, what has been noted is the robustness of remittances, although their size and their evolution depends
on the type of emigration in each case (temporal or permanent, skilled or unskilled).

Translating these arguments into empirical terms leads to results that do not always match up.
Adelman and Taylor (1990), for example, identify a multiplier effect of the remittances on the Mexican
economy between $2.69 and $3.17 per dollar received (considering urban or rural environments,
respectively)22. A similar effect was obtained by Desai, Kapur and McHale (2001) in a study on India, identi-
fying a multiplier effect of remittances of between $1.5 and $2 per dollar received. Mishra (2005), meanwhile,
finds that a 1 per cent increase in the remittances to 13 Caribbean countries increases private investment by
0.6 per cent (in addition to the increase in consumption), causing a positive effect on GDP.

In contrast, other studies take a less optimistic view of the effect of remittances. Among these stud-
ies, one by the IMF (2005) stands out, observing a rather wide sample of countries over a long period (101
developing countries, between 1970 and 2003). The study does not identify robust effects of remittances on
the growth of GDP per capita, expenditure on education, or growth in investment in the reception country.

From a microeconomic perspective, remittances, unlike international aid, directly link the supplier of
resources to the receiver, without intermediation from development agencies or the attendant problems of
bureaucracy and the principal/agent relationship. Remittances produce a positive impact in various ways,
but mainly through the effect of asset accumulation in a family (Stark and Lucas, 1988), and relaxation of its
financial constraints (Faini, 2002). On the negative side, however, remittances are considered to be predomi-
nantly used for purposes other than investment, feeding consumption (even “conspicuous consumption”),
discouraging labour and saving efforts by recipient families and generating a “rentier-state” culture (Chami et
al. (2005) and Görlich et al. (2007))..

Surveys of migrant families seem to confirm these negative impacts. One survey conducted by BID
(FOMIN, 2004) on Latin American countries found the proportion of remittances dedicated to consumer
spending reached 61 per cent in Ecuador, 77 per cent in Central America, and 78 per cent in Mexico.
Compared with the share spent on basic consumption, spending on non-essential consumption was between
3 per cent and 17 per cent; spending on education, between 2 per cent and 7 per cent; the share dedicated
to savings, between 6 per cent and 8 per cent; finally, productive investments attracted the smallest share,
between 1 per cent and 8 per cent. These margins show, in any case, the variability of behaviour, which seems
dependent on the characteristics of the emigration, the circumstances of the family, and the economic condi-
tions. Nevertheless, the overall picture confirms the dominant tendency towards consumption of the remit-
tances received.

This somewhat negative image does not appear to be confirmed in the statistical and econometric
studies, however. Studies such as those on Egypt, Pakistan and Guatemala (carried out by Adams, 1998,
2005a and b), on Mexico (Taylor et al., 2005), or on the Philippines (Yang and Martínez, 2006) all point
out that remittances reduce poverty, especially non-permanent poverty, and increase family investment. Part
of the discrepancy between the statistical analyses and survey results could be due to the fact that the surveys
try to capture the direct use of the remittances, while the statistical analyses examine the effect (whether
total or marginal) that remittances have on the make-up of the total family budget. Given the fungibility of
the resources received and the endogenous nature of migration, the marginal effect of remittances on family
budget is the most relevant factor.
22 In urban environments, consumption includes a larger component of imported goods compared to rural environments.
30 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Taking these factors into account requires consideration of the effect remittances have in relation
to a relatively demanding, counter-factual scenario in which neither emigration nor remittances would have
taken place and the emigrants therefore would have continued to contribute to the family income in their
home countries. This approach could be implemented through two methods, either through a cross-country
analysis, which isolates the effect of each variable, or through a specific country study based on family budgets.
The possibility of making generalisations is greater in the first approach, although the counter-factual tends to
suppose the absence of remittances without considering alternative income from the potential migrant (which
tends to overvalue their effect). In the case of country-specific studies, this problem can be resolved more
effectually, at the expense of the capacity for generalisation and as long as the bias stemming from the selective
character of migration is corrected.

The work of the World Bank (2006) is expressive of the first approach, in which a cross-country
focus is used to analyse the impact of a cease in remittances on poverty. The results crucially depend on the
size of the remittances in question, the extent of the poverty, and potential changes in the inequality levels of
the country. When it is assumed that inequality levels remain constant, simulations of the effect of removing
remittances show an increase in poverty of between 1.2 per cent and 20.3 per cent, depending on the volume
of the remittances at present and the initial level of poverty. In average terms, the effect is an increase in
poverty by 5 per cent in those countries with low remittances, and reaches 12 per cent when remittances are
high in volume. Additionally, the impact is greater (about 70 per cent higher) if the country starts off with a
higher level of poverty. The model has some weaknesses, however, since it does not take into consideration, for
example, the potential income-loss associated with emigration, or the endogeneity of poverty and emigration.
In any case, the results match those of the IMF (2005) in its wide sample of 101 countries.

Among country-specific studies, worth highlighting is a study on Guatemala by Adams (2006).


Here the selection bias of migrant families is corrected through a Heckman-type procedure. His conclusions
suggest: (i) receiving remittances has a positive effect, not by inhibiting the existence of poverty so much
as limiting its depth and severity; (ii) migrant families spend less at the margin on consumption (including
conspicuous consumption), compared to families without migrants living outside the home country; and
(iii) families who receive remittances use those resources for investment, particularly in relation to educa-
tion. The first of these conclusions was also drawn by Yang and Martínez (2006) and Yang (2008) when they
studied data on the Philippines. They solved the problems of the endogeneity of the natural experiment of
the effect on remittances from changes to the exchange rates suffered by Asian economies in the crisis at the
end of the 1990s. In a study on Indonesia, based on a large survey of family budgets, Adams and Cuecuecha
(2010) not only confirmed the positive effect of remittances on poverty, but also found a larger impact: when
compared to the counter-factual scenario of not receiving remittances, the poverty level fell by 26.7 per cent.

The positive effect of remittances on amounts spent on education by a given family was also con-
firmed in studies by Acosta (2006) on El Salvador, Mansurini (2007) Pakistan, and López-Córdoba (2005)
and Hanson and Woodruff (2003) on Mexico, the last of which takes into consideration the educational
level of the parents. Adams and Cuecuecha (2010) could not confirm the positive impact in their study on
Indonesia but they identified the boost to consumption expenditures that remittances generate. They explain
these results by indicating the higher levels of poverty among those Indonesian families that receive remit-
tances and showing the tendency of the families to prioritise the consumption of basic products over invest-
ment goods, including education.

Some country studies allow more generalisations to be drawn, including those by Adams and Page
(2005) and by Acosta et al. (2007). The former, using data from family budgets in 71 developing economies,
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 31

confirms that an increase of 10 per cent in remittances leads to a reduction of 3.5 per cent, on average, in the
poverty rate in those countries. The latter examines eleven Latin American countries and applies the same
methodology of Adams and Page. Their results suggest that remittances have an effect on reducing levels of
poverty (an increase of 1 per cent in remittances as a proportion of GDP reduces poverty by 0.4 per cent).
The study also finds that remittances have a positive effect on education levels and health indicators. However,
the impact is weak and subject to notable heterogeneity among countries, possibly related to both the starting
income level of the recipients23 and the effect that maintaining the migrants at home has on the family income
(the counter-factual hypothesis). In any case, the aggregate impact of remittances is positive for both the
families and the recipient countries.

Less clear, however, is the effect of remittances on income inequality in the recipient country. Some
studies suggest that remittances have a levelling effect: Adelman and Taylor, 1990, for instance, looking at
Mexico, or De and Ratha, 2005, studying Sri Lanka. Other studies, however, suggest that pre-existing levels
of inequality are either sustained or increased: Adams (1998 and 2005), who studies the cases of Pakistan and
Ghana, respectively, observes that per capita remittances grow with family income levels, thereby reinforcing
existing levels of inequality. This result is in line with the fact that extreme poverty is a factor restricting emi-
gration. Nevertheless, the relationship between migrations, remittances, and inequality can vary over time. As
the network of migrants is consolidated abroad, access costs to migrate are reduced for a new migrant (Stark,
Taylor and Yitzhaki, 1986). This means that as time goes by, migration becomes possible for lower income
groups, suggesting remittances have a higher redistributive impact.

Another benefit attributed to remittances is the effect they have on stabilising the purchasing power
of families and on providing a certain degree of insurance against adversity. Remittances help families over-
come adverse shocks, contributing to a smoothing out of their expenses over time and thereby reducing their
levels of vulnerability. This effect is analysed by Lucas and Stark (1985) in relation to internal migration in
Botswana, and by Yang and Choi (2007) in the case of the Philippines.

Aside from these economic aspects, there is another that should be highlighted: the returns from
emigration received by the society of origin are not limited to remittances in the form of monetary resources.
Migration creates an international social network that promotes new activities and business which attend to
the demand of migrant communities for transport services, tourism packages, trade in nostalgic products,
transfer of money to families, and telecommunication services (“the five Ts”, Orozco 2004). In some cases,
home-town associations located in the recipient country are able to send “collective remittances” that finance
investment in social projects and public infrastructures in their home communities.

At the same time, new cultural and political relationships are forged between communities in the
diasporas and communities in countries of origin, creating a kind of transnational social capital. In some
circumstances, the communities of migrants in the diasporas became important political actors in their
home countries, giving support to certain political projects (such as assisting the political autonomy of an
ethnic minority). Finally, migrants are also carriers of new values, customs, attitudes and social relations,
which they transfer to their communities of origin through their ongoing communications, frequent visits,
and possible return. These benefits could be termed intangible remittances, affecting values, social visions,
behavioural changes, etc. It is most probable that not all these changes are useful to the development needs of
23 Differences in this aspect are very notable among countries. For example, in the case of Mexico almost 60 per cent
of emigrants come from the lowest income category, while in Peru almost 40 per cent come from the highest income
category.
32 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

the countries of origin, but some probably are, thus adding another positive factor to emigration. One good
example is the entrepreneurial capacity studied by Massey and Parrado (1998) in the case of Mexico.

4.3. Emigration of qualified labour and loss of human capital


Alongside its economic benefits, emigration can also have costs for the country of origin, largely
associated with the selective nature of migration. The assumption of homogeneity of the labour force on
which the neoclassical explanation of emigration is based is not borne out by the reality of the phenomenon.
There is a clear self-selection process in the decision to emigrate, revealing that emigrants have some traits
that clearly distinguish them from their populations of origin. Compared to their average countryman,
emigrants are relatively young, with greater capacity for initiative and self-confidence than most, and they are
more likely to take risks. Through emigration, therefore, the original society loses highly valuable groups of
its population.

Aside from these psycho-social factors, there is another trait that is extraordinarily important from a
social and economic point of view: that is, contrary to what is sometimes believed, the level of training of emi-
grants often tends to be above the average in the country of origin. In other words, through emigration, the
country loses a significant part of its limited human capital, which then feeds labour markets in destination
countries. This process, when referring to groups of highly qualified workers and acquiring certain intensity, is
called “brain drain”24, a phenomenon that should be considered in terms of its size as well as effect.

a) Size of the phenomenon


As in other fields, it is difficult to estimate the true size of the phenomenon. Neither the countries of origin
nor the recipient countries adequately register the educational levels of emigrants. The United States might
be the country with the best statistics on the subject. Using the U.S. Census of 1990, Carrington and
Detragiache (1998 and 1999) carried out an estimation of the educational levels of immigrants. Their results
showed that the average educational level of the emigrant population in the United States was significantly
high: more than half of migrants, with the exception of those from Central America and Mexico, had
tertiary education. Given the lack of availability of comparative data (to those of the U.S.), Carrington and
Detragiache (1998, 1999) assumed for all other OECD countries the educational level of the migrants was
the same as that registered for migrants in the U.S. and coming from the same countries (which overvalues
educational levels). In any case, the general panorama drawn from this information was of an immigrant
population with a manifestly higher education level than their populations of origin.

Later, Adams (2003) carried out a rigorous estimation of the educational levels of the emigrant
population from a sample of the main 24 countries that send migrants to the United States in large volume,
aiming to obtain better data with a more selective approach.25 Adams (2003) used the U.S. Population Census
for 2000, focusing his attention on the population aged over 25 who had been born abroad, with the aim of
obtaining the educational level of immigrants. His results confirm the estimates obtained by Carrington and
Detragiache (1998): 67 per cent of emigrants to the United States had a secondary or higher level of educa-
tion; and, if Mexico (which contributes almost half the number of registered immigrants) is excluded from the

24 A “brain drain” tends to be acknowledged when emigration affects more than 10 per cent of the population with
tertiary studies in the affected country.
25 All countries with remittances of more than 500 million dollars in 2000 were chosen. The selected countries were:
Albania, Armenia, Bangladesh, Brazil, P.R. China, Colombia, Croatia, Dominican R., Guatemala, Egypt, El Salvador,
India, Indonesia, Jamaica, Mexico, Morocco, Nigeria, Pakistan, Peru, the Philippines, Sri Lanka, Sudan, Tunisia and
Turkey.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 33

sample, the share of emigrants with secondary or higher level of education reaches 83 per cent. In any case,
the educational levels of the emigrants would vary notably depending on the countries of origin considered:
the share of emigrants with tertiary education would vary from 14 per cent in the case of Mexico to almost
80 per cent in the case of India. In order to estimate the level of “brain drain”, we need to discern the share
of emigrants with tertiary education as a proportion of the population in the country of origin with similar
education. In the sample selected by Adams (2003) the highest rates were those of El Salvador, Guatemala, the
Dominican Republic and Mexico, where the share of the emigrant population with tertiary education was at
least 10 per cent greater than the population with similar education in the country of origin.

In the case of the other OECD countries, Adams (2003) obtains the data from a source, Trends in
International Migration: Annual Report, 2001, which does not have as complete information as the Census.
Adams (2003) makes the same assumption as Carrington and Detragiache (1998, 1999) by accepting that the
distribution of educational levels among emigrants in the OECD is similar to those migrating to the United
States. Aside from those limitations, the proportion of emigrants with secondary or tertiary levels reaches
88 per cent of total registered immigrants. The highest proportions of tertiary education were found in im-
migration from India, Egypt, Indonesia, the Philippines and Sri Lanka.

Recent work by Docquier and Marfouk (2004, 2006) presents a new, much fuller and more reliable
estimation which, besides correcting previous figures, allows us to examine the evolution of rates of loss of
qualified populations to emigration with data from 1990 and 2000. In their study, qualified immigration
is considered to be persons 25 years and older with tertiary education who are living in an OECD country
and were born in a different country from where they are currently residing. The data is therefore limited to
emigration to OECD countries, where the bulk of qualified immigration is concentrated, with 192 indepen-
dent territories and 39 dependant territories as sending countries. Their source, however, does not contain
information on educational levels of irregular immigration and is incapable of distinguishing between those
immigrants who arrived with registered educational levels and those who acquired such levels in the destina-
tion country.

The data from the more complete database produces unequivocal results: in 2000, 34.6 per cent
of immigrants working in the OECD countries received tertiary or higher education, as compared with
11.3 per cent in the entire labour population worldwide. The immigrant population is also confirmed as
having a higher education level than the average in their countries of origin. This phenomenon appears to
be increasing over time, since in 1990 the ratio of qualified workers was 29.8 per cent of the total number of
immigrants-almost 5 percentage points less than in 2000.

The difference between the percentage of qualified workers in the emigrant population and those in
the country of origin tends to be smaller in high-income countries (figure 9). In high-income countries, the
qualified population amounts to 30 per cent among residents in the country of origin and 38 per cent among
emigrants from those countries; these shares are 3.5 per cent and 45.1 per cent, respectively, in the case of low-
income countries. In other words, the poorer the country, the greater the differential between the qualification
levels of immigrants and their home populations.

If the loss of human capital is measured through the proportion of migrants with tertiary educa-
tion to the population with that same level of education in the sending country, the highest rates are found
in small countries near the United States, such as Guyana, Jamaica, Haiti, Grenada, St. Vincent and the
Grenadines. However, some countries further from the U.S., such as Cape Verde, Gambia, the Seychelles,
Mauritius or Sierra Leone have equally high rates—all above 50 per cent. In order to avoid the effect of
34 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Figure 9: Percentage of population with tertiary studies, 2000

50
Among residents
45
Among migrants

40

35

30

25

20 Source: Docquier,
F. and A. Marfouk
15 (2006): “International
Migration by
Education Attainment,
10 1990-2000”, in Ozden,
C. and M Schiff
5 (eds), International
Migration, Remittances
and the Brain Drain,
0 Washington, D.C.,
High income Upper- Lower- Low income UN-Least The World Bank and
middle income middle income developed Palgrave Macmillan.

Figure 10: The weight of migrants with tertiary education in relation


to the residential population with that level of qualifications
Countries with more than 5 million inhabitants (percentage)
90
Percentage of migrants with tertiary
80 studies on residents with tertiary studies

70

60

50

40

30
Source: Docquier,
20 F. and A. Marfouk
(2006): “International
Migration by
10
Education Attainment,
1990-2000”, in Ozden,
0 C. and M Schiff
(eds), International
Haiti
Ghana
Mozambique
Kenya
Lao PDR
Uganda
Angola
Somalia
El Salvador
Sri Lanka
Nicaragua
Hong Kong
Cuba
Papua NG

Rwanda
Honduras
Guatemala
Afghanistan
Dominican R.
Portugal
Malawi
Cambodia
Senegal
Cameroon
Morocco
Zambia
Slovakia
United Kingdom
Mexico
Viet Nam

Migration, Remittances
and the Brain Drain,
Washington, D.C.,
The World Bank and
Palgrave Macmillan.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 35

size, it is worthwhile to exclude small countries (those with less than 5 million residents). When the smaller
countries are excluded, Haiti, Ghana, Mozambique, Kenya, Laos, Uganda and Angola have the highest rates.
Some Central American countries, such as El Salvador and Nicaragua, also show high rates (figure 10).

Two interesting conclusions can be drawn. Firstly, although it is not generalised, the problem of the
loss of qualified workers-more than 10 per cent of the population with higher education-affects a significant
number of countries, some of them notably poor. Secondly, even in cases where the threshold for the flow
to be considered “brain drain” is not reached, migration does cause a significant loss of trained human
resources. This is clear in terms of the educational composition of the migrant population—with educational
levels above the average—as well as in the rate of migration in terms of the population with tertiary studies.

The tendency for migrants to be increasingly well-qualified seems to be influenced by various factors
(Kapur and McHale, 2005). Firstly, the bias towards greater use of advanced technology doubtlessly plays a
role. The ability to adopt new technological capacities affects not only the international competitiveness of
an economy, but also its long-term growth possibilities. This source of economic growth increases demand
for specialised labour with highly technical knowledge. Countries attempt to meet that demand by attracting
trained human resources not only from their domestic markets, but also from international markets.

Aware of this need, some countries have implemented active policies to attract specialised labour
abroad, reinforcing the phenomenon analysed here. Countries such as Canada, Australia and New Zealand,
for example, have tried to incorporate admission criteria related to the educational level and specialisation of
the applicant, while in other cases, such as in Germany and France, policies have been drawn up to attract
specialised labour in specific sectors such as telecommunications and health. In some cases, such policies
affect permanent migration while in others it refers to temporary-admission formulae (such as Germany’s
“green card” and the H-1B of the United States). Regardless of its characteristics, this type of policy is a
second factor feeding the trend of attracting qualified resources linked to the migratory phenomenon.

A third factor that is influential in this process is the growing internationalisation of higher educa-
tion. Prestigious universities in the developed world offer training programmes open to students from the
developing world. In fact, in the past decade the number of foreign students in universities in the OECD
countries has increased (figure 11), and 88 per cent of these students end up staying in the host country
to develop a significant part of his professional career. The United States has the largest number of foreign
students, followed by the United Kingdom, Germany and France (figure 12). A recent study reveals that
approximately 68 per cent of foreign doctoral students in the United States stay in the country after comple-
tion of their studies; that percentage ranges between 45 per cent and 73 per cent among the OECD coun-
tries in the case of science and engineering doctoral students (Kapur and McHale, 2005).

b) Effects of the loss of human capital


Traditionally, human capital loss was considered a cost to the development possibilities of the country of
origin. It was supposed that through migration the country of origin lost a significant part of its limited
supply of human capital, which could negatively affect its future growth prospects. The higher the externali-
ties attributed to that human capital, the greater this effect would be (Grubel and Scott, 1966, and Bhagwati
and Hamada, 1974). Those who support the theory of endogenous growth, highlighting the crucial role of
human capital in economic dynamics, have reinforced this verdict (Haque and Kim, 1995, and Wong and
Yip, 1999).
36 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Figure 11: Foreign students in national universities (thousand students)


Thousand students
4000

3500
World

3000

2500

2000

1500 OECD countries

1000

500

0
Source: OECD (2011):
Education at a Glance,
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2010, Paris.

Figure 12: Main recipient countries of foreign students in national universities

700000 90
Foreign students Percentage of no OECD origin
80
600000
70
500000
Percentage of no OECD

60
Number of students

400000 50

300000 40

30
200000
20
100000
10

0 0
United States

United Kingdom

Germany

France

Australia

Canada

Japan

Italy

Spain

New Zealand

Austria

Switzerland

Belgium

Netherlands

Sweden

Source: OECD (2011):


Education at a Glance,
2010, Paris.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 37

Given the fact that many educational processes are carried out with public budgets, emigration of
trained people presents an additional problem related to the contradiction that may exist between the private
interests of emigrants and the social interests of the country from which they come. With regard to private
interests, emigration is an opportunity to improve an individual CV, to find opportunities for professional
progress, and to improve salary. In terms of the social interest of the country of origin, emigration amounts to a
partial loss of public investment in education, limiting the returns from the collective investment. Definitively,
through this route, the paradox of “the poor subsidising the rich” can arise (Kapur and McHale, 2005).

This is the conflict that fed the debate at the end of the 1960s between Johnson (1968) and Patinkin
(1968)—a debate between the so-called “liberal cosmopolitan” position, which defended a world order
that allowed any individual to freely put her choices into action (Johnson, 1968), and the position then
dubbed “nationalistic”, associated with defending a certain social return from investments made in education
(Patinkin, 1968). It is that same contradiction that Bhagwati (Bhagwati and Dellalfar, 1973, or Bhagwati,
2003) cites to justify the imposition of a tax on the educated labour that emigrates from a country, in order
to partially compensate the social effort invested in their training.

In contrast to this perspective are those who find positive aspects of the emigration of trained
resources. The fundamental argument here is that, if returns from the educational effort are higher abroad
than in the country of origin, the possibility of emigration will increase the return on investment in human
capital and will lead to more people making an effort to become educated. This, then, is a “brain-drain-
induced-brain-gain”. Stark et al. (1997, 1998), Vidal (1998) and Mountford (1997) are among the authors
that initially developed this vision, and such approaches led to what one of their most prominent advocates
termed “the new economics of the brain drain” (Stark, 2005). In addition to the reason argued above, other
potentially positive contributions are offered from the emigration of qualified persons: (i) the asset that
experience and qualification gained through emigration can represent to the country of origin, as long as the
emigrant returns (Stark et al., 1997; Domingues Dos Santos and Postel-Vinay, 2003); (ii) the possibility of
creating networks for international business (Mesnard and Ravaillon, 2001); and (iii) the higher level of re-
mittances from this type of emigration (Cinar and Docquier, 2004). Some of these arguments are questioned
by Schiff (2006). Good surveys of this field of theory can be found in Commander et al. (2004), Docquier
and Rapoport (2004) and Clemens (2009).

Despite the importance of the question, much of the “brain-drain/brain-gain” debate has focused on
the theoretical field, with limited empirical information. Only recently could advances be made in empirical
studies, from information provided by Carrington and Detragiache (1998, 1999), Adams (2003), Docquier
and Marfouk (2004, 2005) and Dumont and Lemaitre (2005).

The effort to clarify the debate and provide empirical proofs took place through two main channels.
A first group of researchers tried to analyse the relationship between qualified emigration and the accumula-
tion of human capital in the country of origin. Their results, in general, tend to confirm the association
between this type of emigration and the shortcomings of professional personnel in the affected countries
(Chen and Boufford, 2005; Docquier and Marfouk, 2006). As is obvious, the statistical association does not
imply causality.

A second group of researchers, on the other hand, tried to analyse the causal effect of qualified mi-
gration. Their results are far from conclusive. Firstly they are inconclusive because the analysis needs to esti-
mate a counter-factual scenario in which human capital remains in the country. As a consequence, the results
38 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

vary according to the study considered. Some studies argue the benefits of qualified emigration and support
the notion of brain gain (such as Easterly and Nyarko, 2010, or Manning, 2007), but others are more scepti-
cal about the supposed benefits and condition them on factors of context and emigration thresholds (Beine
et al. 2008; Schifff, 2006; and McKenzie and Rapoport, 2006). On the whole, it seems that the effects of the
loss of qualified personnel are highly subject to the externalities attributed to the human capital, the rate of
emigration considered, and the sensitivity of educational decisions to opportunities abroad.

Although it is difficult to draw definitive conclusions from this literature, the studies might sup-
port a position somewhere between the two extremes, suggesting that: (i) probably the optimum does not
coincide with a probability of professionals emigrating equal to zero; but (ii) an excessive drain of human
capital could make the costs of the process unambiguous for sending countries. A simple modelling of the
phenomenon confirms this hypothesis, suggesting an inverted U relationship between the probability of
skilled emigration and the expected value of the income derived from that migration for sending countries
(Kapur and McHale, 2005).

In any case, the studies referred to are based on significant, simplistic assumptions. Eliminating these
assumptions leads to some interesting nuances on how to evaluate the phenomenon. Five are highlighted here:
• Firstly, the possibility of emigration affects not only the generation of human capital, but also
the type of human capital promoted, because far from being homogeneous, human capital is a
highly specific asset with a very low degree of substitution between different varieties-the loss
of human resources in one sector (health professionals, for example) cannot be compensated
for by the availability of resources in another (engineers, for instance). The stimulant effect of
the emigration of professionals on training affects various elements of human capital differ-
ently, with the greatest benefit to those with skills that can be employed internationally. This
explains why skills such as those related to telecommunications and digital technology, which
are relevant across borders, are affected by this phenomenon, while skills of a more idiosyncratic
nature, such as the knowledge of national laws, are not.
• Secondly, the loss of specialised resources through emigration increases the bargaining capac-
ity—and therefore the salaries—of the specialists that stay in their home country. To the extent
that those sectors are among the highest paid, the process will increase inequality in the country
of origin. That same social inequality is sometimes justified as a response to contain the outflow
of specialists. That is the case, for example, in Brazil, whose low loss of human capital is some-
times related to the income concentration in its high-specialisation sectors.
• Thirdly, professional sectors of society provide a significant base of taxes in any economy. Thus
if a country is shedding qualified professionals, it will also be notably reducing its taxation base.
For instance, in a study on India, Desai, Kapur and McHale (2003) estimate the fiscal loss from
the emigration of qualified human resources at between 0.24 per cent and 0.58 per cent of the
country’s GDP. This loss must be added to the loss of public investment already spent on train-
ing those people.
• Fourthly, there are certain characteristics of human capital that make it particularly important to
any economy. Most importantly, human capital carries knowledge that can be passed on to the
whole economic system. Human capital is also presented in some businesses as complementary
to other productive factors (such as physical capital). Finally, in order to promote human capital
it is necessary to keep a critical mass of migrants in the host countries to fully benefit from their
presence as a group; if the group is too small, their impacts on the host country economy will
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 39

not be significant. All these characteristics—externality, complementarity and indivisibility—


mean that the loss of human capital can have a greater effect than the mere value of the private
income associated with the return of that factor on the market.
• Lastly, human capital constitutes a basic factor in building institutions within a society (Kapur
and McHale, 2005; Alonso and Garcmartín, 2008). Although not much is known about the
dynamic of creation and change in institutions, everything suggests that the process is highly
intensive in human capital. From this perspective, a great loss of qualified human capital could
also have implications for the evolution and quality of the institutional framework available in
the country in question. Since institutions constitute a relevant factor in explaining develop-
ment, the loss of human capital could therefore affect the development possibilities.

Doubtlessly, none of the reasons above would support a policy against international mobility of
qualified workers, but they are sufficient to justify countries (both sending and net recipient countries) to try
to limit the most negative effects associated with the human capital loss from the of emigration of professional
workers. Policies that restrict cross-border flows of professional workers could include: (i) limiting developed
countries’ creation of aggressive selective migratory policies designed to attract qualified personnel; (ii) greater
attention to the labour conditions of qualified workers in their countries of origin; and (iii) policy to stimulate
the return of professionals. In any case, this is a difficult objective for any developing country to achieve.

5. Migratory policies
5.1. National policies
There is a clear contradiction between the needs of developed countries to have migrant workers to support
growth and the restrictive approaches to regulate migratory flows. The result of this contradiction is the
creation of a large population—the dimension varies depending on the case—of undocumented migrants
living outside the law in host countries. Moderate estimates suggest the share of illegal immigration could
be 25 per cent greater than the total number of registered migrants. This scenario creates uncertainty for
migrants, who often fall victim to abuse or exploitation. It also contributes to fragmentation of the labour
market, worsens both the regulatory environment and social harmony, and generates unfair competition
between employers in the host countries.

The problems associated with the presence of undocumented migration go beyond the present gen-
erations of migrants and affect their descendants as well. This second generation suffers the segmented social
assimilation that derives from the irregular situation of their parents. Their downward assimilation frequently
produces low educative performance, school drop-out, adolescent pregnancy and involvement in gangs and
illegal activities (Portes, 2008). These problems end up reinforcing social and racial stereotypes associated
with migrants and further reinforce the difficulties of the social integration of migrants in host countries.

Additionally, the fact that significant migration operates in a context outside the law makes for an
appealing situation for mafias and other illegal groups to take advantage of the vulnerability and uncertainty
that many migrants face. Such abuses are especially serious around the routes of entry to destination countries,
including transit countries and border crossings. Violence is more frequent against women, who frequently
suffer exploitation and sexual abuse. The most extreme of such abuses are related to human trafficking.

As a consequence of these manifestations of delinquency, recipient countries end up viewing migra-


tion as a security problem, focusing policies on the tightening of borders and persecution of undocumented
40 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

migrants. Terrorist threats have amplified this tendency, making migration policy more repressive in tone.
These kinds of measures can foster abuses by police and security forces, not only in recipient countries but
also in transit countries. However, experience shows that this repressive approach, taken without comple-
mentary measures, has had only limited success. The migratory cycle begin not when a foreigner tries to cross
a border, but when a person decides to look abroad in search of her prosperity. Therefore, only through the
involvement of source, transit and recipient countries can the fair and effective regulation of the migratory
process be designed.

Beyond border controls, if recipient countries are to avoid irregular migration, their governments
should estimate labour needs in a more realistic way and create routes of legal access to those jobs deemed
necessary. If the labour needs are based on medium- and long-term demand, conditions should be set
for migrants to settle legally in the destination countries. The conditions should allow the migrants to be
granted residency and, where appropriate, nationality in the host country—in reasonable time-frames and
with reasonable criteria, thus guaranteeing rewards and social rights in conditions similar to those enjoyed
by national workers. To achieve this, it is necessary to adjust estimates of annual permits, allowing visas to
be granted in a simple and transparent way. It is also important for governments to flexibly regulate migrant
mobility once emigrants are in the host country, so they can extend their visas without excessive costs. If
labour conditions so allow, and migrants can then change jobs and employers without restriction once a
determined period has expired. Furthermore, it would seem just from the human rights point of view to
establish limits to tethering, which ties the foreign worker to a sponsoring employer, thus facilitating abuses
by the unscrupulous.

Sometimes the demands of the labour market lead to temporary jobs or seasonal jobs (in tourism or
agriculture, for example), so it is important for governments to develop adequate regulatory frameworks to
make the most of seasonal or cyclical migration. In these cases, permits are associated with a defined task or
time period, although they should allow for the possibility of multiple and renewed permits over successive
seasons. The State, in any case, should guarantee that the conditions of the work, residence, and health and
security of migrant workers is up to the standard of native workers. For this kind of programme to work
properly, it is best for the authorities in the countries of origin, as well as unions from both countries, to be
involved—not just the employers. In fact, the sharing of responsibilities and obligations by source countries
(such as pre-movement screening and selection, facilitation of return, and commitments to combating
irregular migration) should be a key element of these programmes. The General Agreement on Trade in
Services (GATS), through its Mode 4, could have offered a multilateral frame to develop this kind of agree-
ment. Unfortunately, few commitments have been made on Mode 4 in the Doha Round, moving countries
to turn their attention toward bilateral and regional agreements.

The form in which recipient countries have implemented these policy recommendations is highly
variable. In 2007, the British Council and the Migration Policy Group undertook the task of developing an
index of immigrant integration (the MIPEX) in which they evaluated the quality of the migration policies of
recipient countries. They considered seven key dimensions in migratory policy:26 (i) labour mobility; (ii) the
possibilities and costs of bringing other members of the family to the host country; (iii) education; (iv) the
conditions required for long-term residency; (v) regulation encouraging the political participation of migrants;
(vi) access to nationality; and (vii) policies to fight discrimination. A wide range of experts took part in
constructing the index, which used data from 31 countries (in its third edition). It is worth mentioning that
the index did not look at regulation on temporary or cyclical migration.
26 Initially, the index had only six components: afterwards, education was added.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 41

That limitation aside, the results confirm the differences that exist in the current regulatory frame-
works in recipient countries: the range of the overall qualification goes from 83 points for Sweden to 31 in
Latvia, with the potential range being 0 (for the worst case) to 100 (for the best case) (table 8). The most
notable differences were found in the extent of political participation and in eligibility of migrants to acquire
host countries nationality, the areas where approaches by different countries most diverged. Overall, the
countries with the most favourable overall policies for integration of migrants were the Nordic countries and
the southern European countries.

5.2. International framework


Although there has been improvement in national migration policies, we must recognise that national
solutions alone are insufficient-the global phenomenon requires a global approach. As argued in the previous

Table 8: Assessment of national migratory policies (MIPEX) 2010

Labour Anti-
market Family Political Long-term Access to discrimi-
Countries mobility reunion Education participation residency nationality nation Total
Austria 56 41 44 33 58 22 40 42
Belgium 53 68 66 59 79 69 79 67
Bulgaria 40 51 15 17 57 24 80 41
Canada 81 89 71 38 63 74 89 72
Cyprus 21 39 33 25 37 32 59 35
Czech R. 55 66 44 13 65 33 44 46
Denmark 73 37 51 62 66 33 47 53
Estonia 65 65 50 28 67 16 32 46
Finland 71 70 63 87 58 57 78 69
France 49 52 29 44 46 59 77 51
Germany 77 60 43 64 24 59 48 57
Greece 50 49 42 40 56 57 50 49
Hungary 41 61 12 33 60 31 75 45
Ireland 39 34 25 79 43 58 63 49
Italy 69 74 41 50 66 63 62 60
Latvia 36 46 17 18 59 15 25 31
Lituania 46 59 17 25 57 20 55 40
Luxemburg 48 67 52 78 56 66 48 59
Malte 43 48 16 25 64 26 36 37
Netherland 85 58 51 79 68 66 68 68
Norway 73 68 63 94 61 41 59 66
Poland 48 67 29 13 65 35 36 42
Portugal 94 91 63 70 78 82 84 79
Romaria 68 65 20 8 54 29 73 45
Slovakia 21 53 24 21 50 27 59 36
Slovenia 44 75 24 28 69 33 66 48
Spain 84 85 48 56 78 39 49 63
Sweden 100 84 77 75 78 79 88 83
Swizerland 53 40 45 59 41 36 31 43
United Kingdom 55 54 58 53 31 59 86 63
United States 68 67 55 45 50 61 89 62
Source: Migration Policy Group and British Council (http://www.mipex.eu).
42 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

pages, there are reasons to believe that emigration involves a notable potential for progress for emigrants
themselves as well as both the sending and recipient countries. Migration involves not only benefits, but also
costs and risks, which should be understood, with steps taken to avoid them. This could justify the need
for the international community to establish an agreed regulation of migratory flows. The reality, however,
as UNDP (2009) pointed out, is that migration falls into an area not covered by any formal international
regime. There exists neither a globally agreed regulatory framework nor a specialised multilateral institution.
Only in the case of forced migration is it possible to recognise an international regime—a widely supported
normative framework to regulate the phenomenon (Convention Relating to the Status of Refugees, 1951)
and a specialized organization to manage it (UNHCR). Such is not the case for the labour migration we are
considering here.

Internationally, there is only one agreement aimed at regulating the rights of economic migrants and
their families, but its degree of support is very limited. This is the Convention on the Rights of Migratory
Workers and their Families (1990) (CMW), signed by only 41 countries. Other international agreements
and treaties, often related indirectly to migration, attract greater support. The above-mentioned Convention
Relating to the Status of Refugees (1951) has wide support: affecting the rights of a specific type of migrant,
it has been signed by 144 countries. The six fundamental treaties on Human Rights,27 which contain clauses
against discrimination, have been signed by 131 countries; and the Protocol on the Trafficking of People
(2000) has been signed by 129 countries.

Furthermore, unlike other international issues, migration lacks a coherent institutional framework
at the global level. There are a large number of international organisations that have mandates over issues
related to migration, but none in a specialised and comprehensive way (these include, among others, the
United Nations Population Fund, UNFPA; the United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs,
UN/DESA; the International Labour Organization, ILO; the World Trade Organization, WTO; and the
International Organization for Migration, IOM). The IOM has recently increased its membership and has
expanded its initial mandate beyond the repatriation of refugees, but it is outside the UN system and lacks
regulatory power, and its activity is mainly limited to service provision by member states on a project basis.

There is not a unanimous opinion on the need to create a supranational institution with enforceable
power to manage global migration (Bhagwati, 2003, and Hatton, 2007, as opposite opinions). The main
barriers to agreement are related to: (i) the limited interest that destination states have in joining an interna-
tional regime to facilitate migration; (ii) the limited room for reciprocal benefits among (sending and host)
countries; and (iii) the lack of leadership from major migration-destination states. There is a wider agree-
ment on the opportunities for more active international cooperation based on networks (like the numerous
regional consultative processes), dialogues (such as the Global Forum on Migration and Development), and
certain institutions (such as the IOM) (Betts, 2011; Ghosh, 2007; Trachtman, 2009; or Kolowski, 2009).
Nevertheless, it would be necessary to integrate these efforts into a more global and coherent framework. The
Global Migration Group tries to partially fulfil this aim through coordination among different UN agencies.

The reasons why a global regulatory framework on migration has not attracted greater support may
have to do with perceptions about the disparity of interests between net exporters of emigrants and net

27 This is the International Convention on economic, social and cultural rights (1966), on civil and political
rights (1966), on the elimination of all forms of racial discrimination (1966), on the elimination of all forms of
discrimination against women (1979), for the prevention of torture and other cruel, inhuman or degrading treatment
and penalties (1984), and on the rights of infancy (1989).
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 43

importers. The view is that mutual interests are limited and, as a result, this policy should be preserved as the
exclusive responsibility of the States. Political and social sensitivity surrounding migration also contribute to
the reasons governments try to maintain control over this field of international affairs.

However, this perception that the space for mutual benefit is limited is partially biased, for at least
two reasons. The first is that many countries are now sending and receiving migrants at the same time and
this characteristic is set to increase in the future, as international interdependence increases. For this reason,
setting up international rules and rights could benefit not only the foreign population entering a country,
but also the nationals who leave their native countries. Second, in order to build an adequate and efficient
migratory policy, the participation of the migrants’ countries of origin is essential. An efficient migratory
policy should address international movements of people well before a person tries to cross a border because
migration is planned much earlier, very far from the recipient country. This means both sending and receiv-
ing countries need to be involved in solutions tackling the migratory phenomenon.

The failure to face up to this task will result in ineffectiveness of migration policy and mistakenly
place its focus on restricting migratory flows and identifying “illegals”. Such ineffective policy will allow the
entire process of migration—departure from the home country, transit to another country and arrival in
the host country-to occur in non-transparent environments without legal protection. This approach leads to
repressive answers, with consequent costs to community harmony and risks to expose migrants to abuse and
criminal networks.

In fact, there is a shared opinion that potential global gains produced by international migration
can be both increased and better distributed if states can share among themselves a more coherent, liberal
set of rules at the global level. The key to achieving this purpose is to find incentives that attract both home
and host countries to take part in cooperative action. But it is difficult to find sufficient mutual rewards in
the field of migration alone. It may, therefore, be necessary to make changes in other areas of international
relations in order to create mutually beneficial development opportunities in trade, technology and finance.
International migration is a consequence of the asymmetries that exist in the international system. It is
impossible to reduce migration pressures if these asymmetries are not corrected through fairer distribution
of development opportunities. Without question, the dilemma faced by developed countries is whether to
“export opportunities for development” or to end up importing the consequences of their lack. That is an
argument for the need to improve levels of coherence in policies for development.

To sum up, it is difficult to make progress towards adequately managing migratory flows without
the participation of all those countries and regions from which the migrant populations predominantly
originate and settle in. This fact has driven the increase in a number of regional and bilateral agreements
on migration—a useful route in the face of the difficulties that frustrate the striking of more far-reaching
international deals.

In any case, regardless of the disposition of governments toward signing international treaties on
this matter, what is clear is that the starting point should be based on a double principle: (i) firstly, the
recognition that it is up to the individual States to define the ways of accessing residence, employment, and
nationality in the case of anyone coming from another country; but also (ii) acknowledgement that those
same States have an obligation to protect the basic human rights of people within their territory, whatever
their administrative status.
44 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Moreover, in the case of an emigrant who legally lives in a host country, as UNDP (2009) reiterates,
the host government should be obliged to guarantee, as a minimum, the following rights: (i) equal pay for
similar jobs, respectable labour conditions and social and health protection; (ii) collective organisation and
negotiation; (iii) not being subject to arbitrary detention or deportation without judicial process; (iv) not
suffering cruel, inhuman or degrading treatment; v) the possibility of free return to the country of origin. All
these rights should be guaranteed along with those associated with personal freedom and security.

It was on these principles that the ILO tried to define a Multilateral Framework on Labour
Migration in 2005, spelling out some recommendations to governments on migration policy.28 These recom-
mendations were aimed at compensating for the low level of support for the Convention of the Rights of
Migrant Workers and their Families. However, international comparative analysis reveals that governments are
very resistant to the application of international standards and are anxious to preserve national control.

An important aspect in migratory regulation is the question of how migrants can keep the social ben-
efits they have obtained from work in countries outside their home countries. With increasingly more intense
labour mobility across countries, it is necessary to review the territorial principle that currently defines the
right to social benefits. Otherwise, if a person has worked in several countries, but in a shorter period than the
minimum duration required in each given country to claim, say, pension benefits, he will be not entailed to
receive the old-age pension. A good way to solve this kind of problem was offered by the Convenio Multilateral
Iberoamericano de Seguridad Social29 which defines insurance coverage for migrant workers, and for their fami-
lies in the case of permanent disability, old age, labour accident, or professional disease, based on total period
worked in different countries. The international agreement assures equal treatment to any worker, whatever
his nationality; the preservation of rights obtained in each country; and the consideration of the total time
worked in proportion to the time spent in each job. This is a new legal initiative, recently put into practice (1
May 2011), forging an interesting method of cooperation in defending the social rights of migrants among
countries (such as Latin American and Spain and Portugal) with different models of social security.

Defending migrant rights is not, however, solely a task for States-labour unions and NGOs should be
involved as well. Sometimes these organisations can be more effective than public authorities in identifying
and denouncing abuses. It is equally important for migrants to organise themselves and to channel their com-
plaints institutionally. This is why it is important that governments: (i) implement easy and efficient routes for
migrants to present complaints if they are subjected to abuses; and (ii) create ways for immigrant communities
to take part in defining migratory policy.

6. The effects of the crisis: A note


6.1. The effects of the crisis
The crisis that began in 2007 is severely affecting the evolution of the international economy. Although the
origins of the instability have been traced to the turmoil of the U.S. financial markets, the contagion to the
rest of the world was instantly realised. The rapid reaction of authorities on both sides of the Atlantic avoided
the collapse of the international financial system, but it could not avoid the sinking of the world economy
into a serious, synchronised recession with severe effects on overall growth and well-being of people. The
28 ILO (2005): ILO Multilateral Framework on Labour Migration. Non-binding principles and guidelines for a right-based
approach to labour migration, Geneva.
29 This agreement was subscribed to by Argentina, Bolivia, Chile, El Salvador, Spain, Paraguay, Portugal, Venezuela and
Uruguay.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 45

destruction of wealth, the fall in production, the rise in unemployment and the increase in debt levels are
hitting both advanced economies—where the crisis originated—and, in an uneven way, some emerging and
other developing countries.

To tackle the first stages of the crisis, governments used truly exceptional measures, first to sustain
the financial system and then to stimulate demand in order to avoid recession, finally rebalancing their bud-
gets to avoid a sovereign debt crisis. The individual responses of nations were complemented by the use of a
more visible international coordination. The framework chosen to facilitate that task was the G-20, which
has since become the preferred institution for economic governance of the international system, albeit with
some reservations. The succession of Summits held during the last three years (Washington, D.C., London,
Pittsburgh, Toronto and Seoul) reveals the uneven progress of the reform initiatives. In fact, there seems
to have been a dilution of the summit progress as time passed—in terms of the degree of consensus shared
among participants attended the summit meetings as well as the significance of the agreements reached.

Aside from its origins, one consequence of the crisis has been its severe impact on growth and
employment, especially in developed countries. Although the forecasts have changed over time, the latest
ones drawn up by the IMF (table 9) can serve as a guide for judgement. Overall, it would be fair to say
that, so far, developed countries have been much worse affected by the crisis than emerging economies and
developing countries. That verdict is confirmed by the location of the epicentre of the crisis in the Western
financial system (including Japan) and the way it became a transatlantic phenomenon through the underly-
ing property bubble. Of the developed countries, it is the euro zone that seems to have suffered most severely
from the crisis, and it is the euro zone that is facing the most pessimistic forecasts (with minimal growth to
GDP in 2010 and 2011). The levels of debt reached by some countries on the periphery of Europe, and the
severity of the corrections imposed by the discipline of the Monetary Union, justify those projections.

Among the developing countries, those in Asia are the least affected, whichever sub-region is consid-
ered. Nor has Africa suffered a high impact from the crisis because of the sustained demand in raw materials
from the Asian economies, among other reasons. The effect of the crisis on Latin America has been relatively
small and has basically been felt through the contraction of trade, remittances and private investment. With
the exception of Mexico, the data points to a steep fall in national products in the first half of 2009 and a
rapid subsequent recovery which led to positive and high rates of growth in 2010. Among the emerging
and developing economies, the regions most affected by the crisis are those in Western Europe and the CIS
(including Russia). These are the economies that suffered a contraction in 2009 with falls of 3.6 per cent and
6.5 per cent, respectively, and experienced a slower recovery in 2010.

From the point of view considered here, and given the limited growth expectations for the next few
years, it is interesting to underline the rise in unemployment in the OECD countries, the main recipients of
migration. Between 2007 and 2009, all countries with the exception of Poland, Israel and Germany expe-
rienced a rise in the rate of unemployment. In some cases—Spain, the United States, Estonia, Ireland and
Iceland—the rate doubled in less than two years, and in seven of the OECD countries, the unemployment
rate reached double digits (figure 13).

The difficulties in labour markets have doubtlessly affected the migrants in those countries, as they
generally suffer higher unemployment rates than the national average. The data for 2010 confirms this: in
the OECD, the average unemployment rate among immigrants was 50 per cent higher than the unemploy-
ment rate of natives (figure 14). This figure was the case for men in 18 of the 21 countries where data exists
46 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Table 9: World economy outlook


Rates of growth (percentage)
2008 2009 2010 2011 a 2012 a
World GDP 2.8 -0.6 5.0 4.4 4.5
Advanced economies 0.2 -3.4 3.0 2.5 2.5
United States 0.0 -2.6 2.8 3.0 2.7
Euro zone 0.5 -4.1 1.8 1.5 1.7
Germany 1.0 -4.7 3.6 2.2 2.0
France 0.1 -2.5 1.6 1.6 1.8
Italy -1.3 -5.0 1.0 1.0 1.3
Spain 0.9 -3.7 -0.2 0.6 1.5
Japan -1.2 -6.3 4.3 1.6 1.8
United Kingdom -0.1 -4.9 1.7 2.0 2.3
Canada 0.5 -2.5 2.9 2.3 2.7
Other advanced countries 1.7 -1.2 5.6 3.8 3.7
Recently industrialized Asian economies 1.8 -0.9 8.2 4.7 4.3
Emerging markets and developing countries 6.0 2.5 7.1 6.5 6.5
Sub-Saharan Africa 5.5 2.8 5.0 5.5 5.8
Latin America 4.3 -1.8 5.9 4.3 4.1
Brazil 5.1 -0.2 7.5 4.5 4.1
Mexico 1.5 -6.1 5.2 4.2 4.8
CIS 5.3 -6.5 4.2 4.7 4.6
Russia 5.2 -7.9 3.7 4.5 4.4
Developing economies in Asia 7.7 7.0 9.3 8.4 8.0
China 9.6 9.2 10.3 9.6 9.5
India 6.4 5.7 9.7 8.4 8.0
ASEAN-5 6.4 1.7 6.7 5.5 5.7
Central and Eastern Europe 3.0 -3.6 4.2 3.6 3.2
Middle East and Northern Africa 5.0 1.8 3.9 4.6 4.7
Source: FMI Overview of World Economic Outlook (January 2011).
a Projections.

(the United States, Greece and Hungary being the exceptions); and for women in 19 of the 21 countries
(with the exception of the United States and Hungary).

The crisis has affected the unemployment rates of migrants in OECD countries, but the extent of
the effect is based on the circumstances of each economy. The impact has been greater in those economies
where growth was driven disproportionately by a small number of sectors—such as the construction sector—
which contains a high proportion of the migrant population. Spain is an example: although the unemploy-
ment rate rose among both natives and migrants, the unemployment rate among immigrants was almost
70 per cent higher (figure 15). This result, however, cannot be generalized. In countries such as the United
Kingdom, a certain recovery in migrant employment can be seen after the fall in 2009.

6.2. The effects on migration


In principle, the recession and the rise in unemployment are expected to affect the net inflow of immigrants
into developed countries as well as the remittances that immigrants send to their families. Although these
expectations have indeed materialized, the size of the impact seems to be smaller than \expected, especially in
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 47

Figure 13: Unemployment rate and growth in the rate, 2007-2010


Percentage
25 300.0
Unemployment Rate of increase of
rate 2010 unemployment rate, 2007-2010

250.0
20

200.0

Rate of increase, 2007-2010


Unemployment rate, 2010

15
150.0

100.0
10

50.0

5
0.0

0 -50.0
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Canada
Chile
Czech Repub.
Denmark
Estonia
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Hungary
Iceland
Ireland
Israel
Italy
Japan
Korea R.
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway
Poland
Portugal
Slovakia
Slovenia
Suiza
Spain
Sweden
Turkey
United Kingdom
United States
Source: OECD (http://
www.oecd-library.org).

Figure 14: Relationship between unemployment rates among


migrants compared to natives in oecd countries, 2009
Percentage
30
Natives Foreigners

25

20

15

10

0
Italy
Czech Rep.

Denmark

Ireland

Slovakia
Norway

United States
Sweden
Luxembourg
Austria

France

Hungary
Finland

Netherlands
Belgium

Canada

United Kingdom

Portugal
Spain

Greece
Germany

Source: OECD (http://


www.oecd-library.org).
48 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Figure 15: Employment rates among natives and (non-EU) immigrants in spain
Percentage
35

30

25

20

Natives
15
Immigrants (non-EU)

10

0
2006-I

2006-II

2006-III

2006-IV

2007-I

2007-II

2007-III

2007-IV

2008-I

2008-II

2008-III

2008-IV

2009-I

2009-II

2009-III

2009-IV

2010-I

2010-II

2010-III
Source: Instituto
Nacional de Estadística
(http://www.ine.es).

the case of remittances, which seem to have held up well in the crisis, recovering rapidly after the contraction
of 2009.

In terms of flows of emigrants, the data for the last five years (2005-2010) reveals that the rate of
evolution in the total number of migrants worldwide remained stable, but with minor changes. In fact, the
programmes put in place by some countries (both net exporters and importers of emigrants) to facilitate
the return of migrants have had only limited success so far.30 Among the reasons for the limited effect of
those programmes, three stand out: (i) the extraordinary level of inequality between the living conditions
between the countries of origin and recipient country; (ii) the temporary protection afforded by public aid to
unemployed emigrants in most OECD countries (unemployment benefits, minimum incomes); and (iii) the
restrictive access regulations to OECD countries, because migrants in their destination countries may avoid
returning to their countries of origin, out of fear of not being able to re-enter the host country afterwards. It
is possible, of course, that those countries (such as on the European periphery) are still experiencing effects of
the crisis and the impact of the crisis on the labour market prevent emigrants from returning home.

In addition to the effect of those returns, it seems clear that in the next few years, new arrivals to
certain developed countries are going to be restricted. Various Governments have announced their decision
to significantly cut the numbers of immigrants allowed to enter. It is therefore possible that those countries
will see a significant slowdown in the pace of arrivals. Moreover, their economic situation makes them less
attractive to the potential emigrant, who must take into consideration the greater difficulties to be faced in
finding a job, thereby reducing, at least, the migratory pressure. Spain could, again, serve as an example. The
rate of growth in Spain’s migrant population in 2009 fell by half compared to the previous year (reaching
30 Examples of this programmes were applied in Japan and Spain, as recipient countries, and Ecuador and Colombia, as
sending countries.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 49

7 per cent, compared to 15 per cent in 2008); and, although the statistics have not been released for 2010,
the forecasts point to another, still sharper, fall.

At the global level, it is possible that this effect will prove less significant. Firstly, this is because the
family reunion policies that operate on the previous migrant stock are less affected by the crisis. Secondly, the
crisis may bring new migrant destinations to the fore—destinations associated with emerging markets that
have a high growth potential.

In turn, remittances seem to have followed a relatively similar path. In 2009, remittances directed at
developing countries fell by 5.5 per cent, ending up at $307 billion: an appreciable fall, but still well below
the declines in direct foreign investment (40 per cent) or private financial flows (80 per cent). Remittances
are expected to recover their dynamism in 2010 and to grow by 6 per cent, to 325 billion dollars. The
forecasts point to a continuation of an upward trend for the following few years, with growth of 6.3 per cent
and 8.1 per cent in 2011 and 2012, respectively (translating to $346 and $376 billion, respectively).

Three reasons can be found to explain the ability of remittances to resist the effects of the crisis
(Ratha and Mohapatra, 2009): (i) remittances are sent by the entire migrant population accumulated over
time, and not just by those who have recently settled in host countries; (ii) not all of the businesses where
immigrants were predominantly employed were equally hit by the crisis (for example, employment related
to domestic service and personal care are among the most resistant to the effects of the crisis); and (iii) even
when migrant returns are limited, those who do return take along their accumulated savings, which are
counted as remittances.

In any case, the effect on remittances has not been the same across regions. The two regions most
affected by the crisis have been Eastern Europe and Central Asia and Latin America, which suffered falls
in remittances in 2009 of 22.7 per cent and 12 per cent, respectively. Declines in the Middle East and
Northern and Sub-Saharan Africa were smaller, at 6.3 per cent and 3.7 per cent, respectively. In other re-
gions, although the growth rate fell compared to previous years, the volume of remittances continued to ex-
pand. That will be the general pattern for 2010: all regions are expected to see an increase in the remittances
they receive. In fact, some of the regions that suffered a greater contraction (Europe and Central Asia, Latin
America, and Eastern Asia and the Pacific) are the same regions that will experience some of the highest rates
of growth in their remittances in 2011 and 2012 (table 10). Obviously these forecasts are subject, firstly, to
the risks that still exist in the economic recovery—especially in the case of the euro zone—and secondly to
the effects that international imbalances may have on the currencies in which remittances are paid.

6.3. Political responses


One of the main risks surrounding the crisis is associated with the reawakening of anti-immigration senti-
ment in very diverse countries, many of which have long traditions of accepting immigrants and consoli-
dated democratic institutions. The subject of migration has become one of the flashpoints in recent election
campaigns in many OECD countries. Some are witnessing an increase in the number of political parties
that are wary of immigration, and even an increase in xenophobic messages. Additionally, some governments
have undertaken actions that are notably aggressive towards migrants, and sometimes at the edge of what
is legally acceptable such as new laws approved in the U.S. State of Arizona, or the measures to expel illegal
immigrants from the Roma community in France and Italy.
50 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Table 10: Evolution of remittances


Millions of dollars
2007 2008 2009 2010a 2011b 2012b
Developing countries 278 325 307 325 346 374
East Asia and Pacific 71 85 86 91 98 106
Europe and Central Asia 39 46 35 37 39 43
Latin America and Caribbean 63 65 57 58 62 69
Middle East and North Africa 32 36 34 35 37 40
South Asia 54 72 75 83 87 92
Sub-Saharan Africa 19 21 21 21 22 24
Low income 17 22 22 24 26 29
Middle income 262 303 285 301 319 345
World 385 443 416 440 464 499
Source: Mohapatra, S. D. Ratha, and A. Silwal (2010). “Outlook for remittance flows: 2011-2012: recovery after crisis, but risks lie
ahead”, Migration and Development Brief, 13, World Bank.
a Estimates.
b Projections.

Aside from these individual actions, the crisis has fed a fear in the minds of national citizens about
the competition that immigrants could represent both in the labour market and in terms of access to public
services. This fear does not seem to be well-founded, but citizens perceive it as reality, identifying immigra-
tion as a potential threat to their living standards. This fear does not always show up in opinion polls,
because other threats—like those resulting directly from the economic situation—emerge more strongly
in citizens’ views. In Eurobarometer data, for instance, in 2005, 14 per cent of those surveyed in the EU
found immigration to be the most important problem; in 2010, that had fallen to 9 per cent. In Spain, those
figures were 30 per cent and 8 per cent, respectively. In both cases, this drop is due to the mounting concerns
associated with the economic situation. Nevertheless, when the survey is specialized in migration, the results
reveal a more anti-immigration sentiment. That occurs, for instance, in the survey carried out in Finland in
2007, where the share of citizens who felt that immigration should not be increased rose from 35 per cent in
2004 to 60 per cent three years later. Another recent survey carried out in Germany suggested that a third of
the population supported a policy of repatriating immigrants.

The crisis, therefore, represents more of a risk to future migratory flows than a risk to immediate
numbers. It seems to have changed the opinions of groups of citizens and the political spectrum in recipient
countries towards more restrictive positions on immigration. Some of these positions—and this is worth
reiterating—do not coincide with the objective need of those societies in employment terms to stimulate
immigration in order to sustain their own welfare systems.

7. Final considerations

A number of general considerations can be put forward, which will serve as a reminder of the main ideas
examined in this document. These ten final considerations are expressed briefly here..

1. We are not in a new historical period in terms of international migratory pressures. While the
current crisis tends to slow down migration flows, it is reasonable to assume that migratory pressures will
continue to be part of the contemporary world. Other contributing factors include: (i) the persistence of
notable inequalities in salaries between countries; (ii) the disparity between the demographic dynamic of the
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 51

developed world (with stable and increasingly ageing populations) and that of the developing world (which
has a more dynamic demographic); and (iii) lifestyles and consumption styles of the developed world are
easily and quickly spread to the developing world, making migration an attractive option, along with the fall
in the costs of displacement and international transportation. In sum, migration will continue because we
live in an increasingly interdependent, but highly unequal, world.

2. International migration may be a powerful factor in the development process for both recipient and
destination countries and opens up significant opportunities for the emigrants. In fact, emigrants are the
ones who benefit most from the process. When people are able to choose their place of residence with fewer
restrictions, their human freedoms are increased and they are allowed access, albeit selectively, to better living
conditions. In this sense, emigration is not a zero-sum game; adequately regulated, it can be the source of
shared benefits for all those involved. Studies confirm these effects. Of course, emigration can also involve
costs, which need to be considered and, to the extent possible, minimized but, on the whole, emigration is
an important factor in the development of people and their societies. Governments in countries of origin
and recipient countries must, therefore, make the most of the opportunities that emigration offers, aiming at
taking full advantage of its positive impacts while attenuating its negative effect. To achieve this objective it is
necessary:
• Firstly, that migrants sending countries understand that emigration cannot be conceived as a
substitute for a development strategy since only through a solid and solvent development policy
can the positive effects of emigration be properly exploited;
• Secondly, that recipient countries of emigrants understand that meeting their labour needs
through the use of foreign labour requires offering emigrants the protection of the law and a
recognition of workers’ social rights, along with their right to work without discrimination.

3. Despite the potential benefits of international migration, the laws governing this process are notably
restrictive. There is, therefore, a clear contradiction between the needs of developed countries for migrant
workers to support growth and the restrictive rules with which the same countries are creating to regulate
immigration. The result of this contradiction is the presence of a large group of undocumented immigrants
living outside the law in their destination countries. Thus many people migrate from one country to another
without the protection of the law, leaving them vulnerable to abuse and allowing mafias and criminal behav-
iour to flourish around illegal immigration. In order to avoid this outcome, recipient countries must better
balance their need for a migrant population with rules and regulation that allow migrant workers to obtain
residence (and citizenship, where appropriate) as well as employment.

4. In relation to migration laws, all countries have the right to define the rules around entry into their
territories, access to residency and citizenship, and integration by foreigners into labour markets. However,
such regulation should be drawn up bearing in mind:
• Firstly, migratory regulation must be sensitive to the conditions of the poorest peoples and
societies while identifying the potential of emigration as a source of progress for those involved.
• Secondly, the nature of the times at present with markets and countries increasingly integrated
beyond national borders. It would seem incoherent to seek freedoms governing trade and capital
while excluding the movement of people.

If states have the right to regulate conditions of access of non-nationals to their countries, they also have
the obligation to protect and respect the basic rights of everyone in their territory, regardless of his or her
52 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

administrative status. Migrants constitute a particularly vulnerable sector of society, which obliges states
(whether countries of origin, destination or transit) to redouble their efforts in fighting against the abuse and
exploitation, xenophobia, exclusion and marginalization of the emigrant, as well as the illegal trafficking of
humans.

5. In an increasingly integrated world, national solutions are insufficient. It is difficult to effectively


manage migratory flows without a concerted international effort; the participation of sending countries of
migrants, recipient countries, and the countries through which emigrants pass en route to their destina-
tions. Policies that address migrants crossing national borders as the major issue tend to treat the migration
problem as if it were simply a question of controlling entry flows. On the contrary, the migratory process
begins much earlier than border crossing and involves all those factors that drive a person to decide to search
for possibilities denied by his home country in distant lands. That is why fair and efficient regulation of the
migratory processes can only be tackled with the involvement of countries of origin, destination and transit.
Therefore, regulation should support the international instances of dialogue and cooperation currently in
effect (such as the Regional Consultative Processes on Migration, or RCPs), backing their secretariats to
prepare and monitor their agenda, promoting more active participation by civil society and the private sec-
tor, and encouraging, when appropriate, a tighter link with the process of regional integration. The process
of negotiation between countries could take place at two levels.
• Firstly, through the setting of minimum rules and standards on which all migratory policies
are based. This should involve an analysis of experiences and good practices that can be applied
more generally.
• Secondly, through the promotion of agreements on cooperative management between countries,
to maximize the developmental impact of migratory flows. This would lead to mutual support
on public policies on legal emigration.

6. The key to reaching this level of agreement is to provide the incentives for sending countries of
migrants to participate in such a collective action. It might prove to be difficult for such mutual cooperation
to be limited to the field of migration. If so, it should expand cooperation to other fields of international
relations in order to reasonably manage migration. More effective developmental cooperation needs to
be generated through trade, the sharing of technology, the treatment of debt, and international finances.
Definitively, the dilemma faced by the northern countries is either to contribute more actively towards
“exporting development” to the South, or else to end up “importing” the consequences of the lack of
development in the South. These all point to the need to improve the levels of coherence in public policies in
relation to the development objectives.

7. The remittances sent by emigrants constitute an important source of financing that may be useful
to development processes in countries and communities that migrants come from. However, it is possible to
improve the impact of this source of financing through the following measures:
• Reducing the transaction costs of remittance transfers, facilitating access by emigrants to formal
financial channels and increasing the competition in those markets.
• Facilitating control over remittances by the people who generate them in order to reduce the
agency problems that seem to be associated with them. This requires steps to empower migrants
themselves in their relations with financial institutions, both in the countries where they work
and in their countries of origin.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 53

• Defining public stimuli to encourage more productive use of remittances for development
purposes while respecting the private nature of the funds. This goal could also affect develop-
ment aid policy through emigrants contributing development aid and technical assistance to
their communities of origin.

8. Emigration is highly selective, affecting most intensively the young, the most dynamic, and the best
trained members of a population. Emigration incurs costs for developing countries in terms of an invest-
ment already made in the training of human capital. This loss may have a negative effect both in terms of
the growth potential of the countries of origin and their chances for consolidating goods institutions, since
human capital plays a decisive role in both processes. To avoid these negative effects, work needs to be under-
taken to:
• Revise the most aggressive policies that selectively aim at attracting qualified human resources
from developing countries, especially countries and sectors where an outpouring of people could
seriously affect the well being (health, for example) of those populations.
• Review the current internationalization of higher education and the way in which its attraction
of students from the developing world frequently feeds the phenomenon of the loss of highly
qualified personnel.
• The international community should support efforts by developing countries on training, inves-
tigation, and the improvement of the professional environment in order to allow professionals
to find an adequate route to progress and personal promotion in their own countries.
• More use should be made of temporary contracts with stimuli for emigrants to return to their
countries of origin. Such formulas could turn temporary migration into another stage of profes-
sional training from developing countries, without the loss of human capital in their country of
origin.
• Finally, consideration must be given to the possibility of paying compensation to countries of
origin in cases where developed countries are actively attracting well-qualified professionals away
from developing countries.

9. Emigration can culturally enrich a society so long as work is done to achieve mutual adaptation
(for the emigrant to fit into the host society, and for the host society to adapt to the new arrivals), as well as
to achieve the full social integration of the emigrant. Emigration can contribute towards the creation of a
valuable transnational society and towards promoting cooperation between civil societies, above and beyond
national borders. This is one of the developmental initiatives that migrant communities have implemented
with the involvement of other organizations from civil society. Tt is invaluable and should be supported by
public authorities.

10. The crisis is having multiple effects on international migration. Firstly, it has increased unemploy-
ment to above average among immigrants in some OECD countries, not only due to the greater precarious-
ness of immigrant labour ties, but also due to their concentration in certain sectors of business, such as
construction or some services, that were hit particularly badly by the crisis. This has not, however, happened
in all cases. Secondly, due to the nature and duration of immigrant contracts, migrants tend to have less
social protection in the event they lose a job, which means the social costs of the crisis are often higher for
them. Thirdly, the effect that the crisis has had on labour conditions in destination countries has slowed mi-
gration and led various governments to announce significant cuts in immigration quotas. Fourthly, the crisis
has also affected remittances, which fell in volume in 2009; however, the forecasts point to a rapid recovery
54 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

in years to come. Lastly, the most worrying effect of the current crisis is that it has generated anti-immigrant
sentiment among certain social and political groups in host countries. The immigrant is seen as a rival to
residents in the search for work, or as an additional burden to public services. Such perceptions have often
been translated into a more restrictive tone in migration rules, and into a greater presence of discrimination
and xenophobia, even in consolidated democracies.

Bibliography
Acosta, P. (2006): “Labor supply, school attendance, and remittances from international migration: The case of El Salvador”, Policy
Research Working Paper 3930, World Bank.
Acosta, P., P. Fajnzylber, and J. Humberto López (2007): “The impact of remittances on poverty and human capital: Evidence from
Latin American household surveys”, in Ozden, C. and M. Schiff (2007), International Migration, Economic Development
and Policy, World Bank and Palgrave Macmillan.
Adams, R.H. (1993): “The economic and demographic determinants of international migration in rural Egypt”, Journal of
Development Studies 30 (1), 146-67.
Adams R.H. (1998): “Remittances, investment, and rural asset accumulation in Pakistan”, Economic Development and Cultural
Change, October, 155-173.
Adams, R.H. (2003): “International migration, remittances and the brain drain: A study of 24 labour-exporting countries”, World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3069, June.
Adams, R.H. (2005a): “Remittances, selection bias and poverty in Guatemala”, mimeo, World Bank.
Adams, R.H. (2005b): “Remittances and poverty in Ghana”, mimeo, World Bank
Adams, R.H (2006): Remittances, Poverty and Investment in Guatemala”, in Ozden, C. and M. Schiff (2006), International
Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain, New York, Palgrave Macmillan.
Adams, R.H. and J. Page (2003): “International migration, remittances and poverty in developing countries”, Policy Research Working
Paper 3179, World Bank.
Adams, R.H and A. Cuecuecha (2010): “The economic impact of international remittances on poverty and household consumption
and investment in Indonesia”, Policy Research Working Paper 5433, World Bank.
Alonso, J. A. (ed) (2004): Emigración, pobreza y desarrollo, Madrid, Editorial Catarata.
Alonso, J.A. (2010): “La lengua en la selección de los mercados de destino”, in J.A. Alonso and R. Gutiérrez (dirs), Emigración y
lengua. El papel del español en las migraciones internacionales, Barcelona, Editorial Ariel.
Alonso, J.A and R. Gutiérrez (dirs) (2010): Emigración y Lengua. El papel del español en las migraciones internacionales, Barcelona,
Editorial Ariel.
Anderson, K. and W. Martin (2005), Agricultural Trade Reform and the Doha Development Agenda, World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Barham, B. and S. Boucher (1998): “Migration, Remittances and Inequality: Estimating the Net Effects of Migration on Income
Distribution”, Journal of Development Economics, 55 (2), pp. 307-331.
Barret, A. and Ph. O’Connell (2001): “Is there a wage premium for returning Irish migrants?”, Economic and Social Review, 32: 1-21.
Bauman, Z. (2003): Comunidad. En busca de seguridad en un mundo hostil, Editorial Siglo XXI, Madrid.
Beine, M. F. Docquier, and H. Rapoport (2008): “Brain drain and human capital formation in developing countries: Winners and
losers”, Economic Journal, 118 (528), pp. 631-652.
Beine, M, F. Docquier and M. Schiff (2008): “Brain drain and its determinants: A major issue for small states”, IZA Discussion Paper
3398, Institute for Study of Labor.
Bergin, P. and R. Glick (2007): “Global prices dispersion: Are prices converging or diverging?”, Journal of International Money and
Finance 26 (5), pp. 703-729.
Berthélemy, J.C., M. Beuran and M. Maurel (2009): “Aid and Migration: Substitutes or complements?, World Development, 37 (10),
pp. 1589-1599.
Betts, A. (ed) (2011): Global Migration Governance, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 55

Bhagwati, J. (1991): “Free traders and free immigrationists: strangers or friends?”, Working Paper nº 20, April, Russell Sage
Foundation, New York.
Bhagwati, J. (2003): “Borders beyond control”, Foreign Affairs, vol 82, nº 1, pags 98-104.
Bhagwati, J. and K. Hamada (1974): “The brain drain, international integration of markets for professionals and unemployment:
A theoretical analysis”, Journal of Development Economics, 1 (1), pp: 19-42.
Bhagwati, J. and W. Dellalfar (1973): “The brain drain and income taxation”, World Development, 1 (1-2), pp. 94-101.
Borjas, G. (1992): “Ethnic capital and intergenerational mobility”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 123-50.
Borjas, G. (1994): “The economics of immigration”, Journal of Economic Literature, 32, December, 1667-717.
Borjas, G. (1995): “The economic benefits from immigration”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, nº 9, 3-22.
Borjas, G. (1995): “Ethnicity, neighbourhoods, and human-capital externalities”, American Economic Review, vol 85, nº 3, 365-90.
Borjas, G. (1999): “Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration: Lessons for the European Union”, World Bank
Technical Paper 438.
Borjas, G. and B. Bratsberg (1996): “Who leaves? The outmigration of the foreign-born”, Review of Economics and Statistics 78:
165:76.
Carrington, W.J. and E. Detragiache (1998): How big is the brain drain?, IMF Working Paper 98/102, International Monetary Fund.
Caselli, F. and J. Feyrer (2007): “The marginal product of capital”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122 (2), pp. 535-568.
Cebrián, M. (2009): “Los determinantes de los flujos migratorios internacionales”, Principios. Estudios de Economía Política,
14, pp. 49-70.
Cami, R., C. Fullenkamp, and S. Jahjah (2005): “Are immigrant remittances flows a source of capital for development?”, IMF Staff
Papers 52 (1): 55-81, International Monetary Fund.
Cinar, D. and F. Docquier (2004): “Brain drain and remittances: Consequences for the source countries”, Brussels Economic Review
47 (1), pp. 103-118.
Clark, X., T.J. Hatton and J.G. Williamson (2002): “Where do US immigrants come from? Policy and sending country
fundamentals”, NBER Working Paper 8998.
Clemens, M. (2010): “A Labor Mobility Agenda for Development”, Center for Global Development, Washington, D.C.
Clemens, M., C. Montenegro and L. Pritchett (2008): “The Place Premium: Wage differences for identical workers across the US
border”, CGD Working Paper 148, Washington, D.C., Center for Global Development.
Dessai, M.A., D. Kapur and J. McHale (2001): “The fiscal impact of the brain drain: Indian emigration to the US”, Weekly Political
Economy Discussion Paper, Harvard University.
Docquier, F. and A. Marfouk (2004): Measuring the international mobility of skilled workers (1990-2000)”, Policy Research Working
Paper 3381, World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Docquier, F. and A. Marfouk (2006): “International Migration by Education Attainment, 1990-2000”, in Ozden, C. and M. Schiff,
International Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain, New York, Palgrave Macmillan.
Docquier, F. and F Rapoport (2004): “Skilled migration - The perspective of sending countries”, Policy Research Working Paper 3381,
World Bank.
Domingues Dos Santos, M. and F. Postel-Vinay (2003): “Migration as a source of growth: The perspective of a developing country”,
Journal of Population Economics, 16 (1), pp.161-175.
Dumont, J.C. and G. Lemaître (2004): “Counting immigrants and expatriates in OECD countries: A new perspective”, mimeo,
OECD.
Ellerman, D. (2003): “Policy Research on Migration and Development”, World Bank Policy Research Paper, 3117, Washington, D.C.
Faini, R. (2001): Development, Trade, and Migration, International Monetary Fund, mimeo.
Faini, R. and A. Venturini (1994): Migration and growth. The experience of Southern Europe”, CEPR Discussion Papers, 964.
Gammeltoft, P. (2002): “Remittances and other financial flows to developing countries”, Working Paper 02/11, Centre for
Development Research, Copenhagen.
Ghosh, B. (2007): “Managing migration: towards missing regime”, in A. Pécoud and P. Guchteneire (eds.), Migration without
borders: Essays on the free movement of people, United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization
(UNESCO) and Berghahn, Paris.
Ginannone, D. and M. Lenza (2009): “The Feldstein-Horioka Fact”, NBER Working Paper 15519, National Bureau of Economic
Research.
56 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Görlich, D. T., O. Mahmoud and Ch. Trebesch (2007): “Explaining Labour Market Inactivity in Migrant-Sending Families:
Housework, Hammock or Higher Education”, Kiel Working Paper 1391, Kiel Institute for World Economy.
Grubel, H.B. and A.D. Scott (1966): “The international flow of human capital”, American Economic Review, 56 (1-2), pp: 268-274 .
Hamilton, B. and J. Whalley (1984): “Efficiency and distributional implications of global restrictions on labour mobility”,
Journal of Development Economics 14; 61-75.
Hanson, G.H. and C. Woodruff (2003): “Emigration and educational attainment in Mexico”, mimeo, University of California.
Haque, N.U. and S-J. Kim (1995): “Human capital flight: Impact of migration on income and growth”, IMF Staff Papers 42 (3),
pp. 577-607, IMF.
Hatton, T. (2005): “Explaining trends in UK immigration”, Journal of Population Economics, 18, pp. 719-740.
Hatton, T.J. (2007): “Should we have a WTO for international migration?”, International Migration, April, pp. 339-383.
Hatton, T. and J. Williamson (1998): The Age of Mass Migration: Causes and Economic Impact, New York, Oxford University Press.
Hatton, T. and J. Williamson (2003): “What fundamentals drive world migration?”, Discussion Paper 2003/23, WIDER.
Hatton, T. and J. Williamson (2005): Global migration and the World Economy. Two Centuries of Policy and Performance, MIT Press,
Cambridge, Mass.
Harris, J.R. and M. Todaro (1970): “Migration, employment, and development: A two sector analysis”, American Economic Review,
60, 126-42.
Hirschman, A.O. (1977): Salida, voz y lealtad, Fondo de Cultura Económica, Mexico.
Hoschschild, A.R. (2001): “Las cadenas mundiales del afecto y asistencia y la plusvalía emocional”, in A. Giddens and W. Hutton
(eds), En el límite. La vida en el capitalismo global, Madrid, Tusquets Editores.
IADB-MIF (2004): “Sending money home: Remittance to Latin America and the Caribbean”, Washington, D.C.
IMF (2005): World Economic Outlook: Globalization and external imbalances, Washington, D.C.
Jaeger, D. (2000): “Local labour markets, admission categories, and immigrant location choice”, Hunter College, New York.
Johnson, H. (1968): “An internationalist model”, in W. Adams, The Brain Drain, Macmillan, New York.
Kapur, D. and J. McHale (2005): Give us your best and brightest, Center for Global Development, Washington, D.C.
Karemera, D., V.I. Oguledo and B. Davis (2000): “A gravity model analysis of international migration to North America”,
Applied Economics, 32: 1745-55.
Katz, E. and O. Stark (1984): “Migration and Asymmetric Information: Comment”, American Economic Review, 74, 533-34.
Ketkar, S. and D. Ratha (2001): “Development financing during a crisis: Securitization of future receivable”, Policy Research Working
Paper 2582, World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Kolowski, R. (2009): “Global mobility regimes”, paper presented at the Global Mobility Regimes Workshop, 27 April, New York.
Lewis, W. A. (1969): “Aspects of Tropical Trade”, Wicksell Conference, Stockholm, Almqvist and Wicksell
Lewis, W. A. (1983): Crecimiento y fluctuaciones, 1870-1913, Mexico, Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Li, X. and McHale, J. (2009): “Emigration and Institutions”, Working Paper, Galway, National University of Ireland.
Lindert, P.H. and J.G. Williamson (2001) “Does globalization make the world more unequal?”, NBER Working Paper 8228,
National Bureau of Economic Research.
López-Córdova, E. (2005): “Globalization, Migration and Development: The role of Mexican Migrant Remittances”, Economía, 6,
pp. 217-256.
López, R. and M. Schiff (1998): “Migration Skill Composition of the Labor Force: The Impact of Trade Liberalization”, Canadian
Journal of Economics, 31 (2), pp. 318-336
Lucas, R.E.B. and O. Stark (1985): “Motivations to Remit: Evidence from Bostwana”, Journal of Political Economy, 93 (5),
pp. 901-918.
Maddison, A. (2001): The World Economy. A millennial perspective, OECD, Development Centre Studies, Paris.
McKenzie, D.J. (2006): “Beyond Remittances: The Effects of Migration on Mexican Household”, in Ozden, C. and M. Schiff,
International Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain, New York, Palgrave Macmillan.
McKenzie, D.J. and H. Rapoport (2006): “Can Migration Reduce Educational Attainment? Evidence from Mexico”, Policy Research
Working Paper n. 3952, World Bank.
Massey, D., R. Alarcón, J. Durand and H. González (1987): Return to Aztlan: The Social Process of International Migration from
Western Mexico, Berkeley, Los Angeles University of California Press.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 57

Massey, D., L. Goldring and J. Durand ((1994): “Continuities in Transnational Migration: An Analysis of Nineteen Mexican
Communities”, American Journal of Sociology 99 (6), pp. 492-533.
Massey, D. and E. Parrado (1998): “International migration and business formation in Mexico”, Social Science Quarterly, 79,
pp. 1-20.
Mayda, A.M. (2007): “International Migration: A panel data analysis”, Discussion Paper 07, Centre for Research and Analysis of
Migration.
Mesnard, A. and M. Ravaillon (2001): Wealth distribution and self-employment in a developing country”, CEPR Discussion Paper
3026, Center for Economic Policy Research.
Meyer, J.B. and M. Brown (1999): “Scientific diasporas: A new approach to the brain drain”, Discussion Paper, nº 41, Management
of Social Transformations, MOST.
Milanovic, B. (2011): The Haves and the Have-Nots. A Brief and Idiosyncratic History of Global Inequality, New York, Basic Books.
Mishra, P. (2005): “Emigration and brain drain: evidence from the Caribbean”, mimeo, IMF.
Mohapatra, S; D. Ratha, and A. Silwal,(2010): “Outlook for remittances low: 2011-2012: recovery after crisis, but risks lie ahead”,
Migration and Development Brief, 13, World Bank.
Mora, J. and E. Taylor (2006): “Determinants of Migration, Destination and Sector Choice: Disentangling Individual, Household,
and Community Effects”, in Ozden, C. and M. Schiff, International Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain,
New York, Palgrave Macmillan.
Moreno, J. (204): “Los determinantes de la inmigración internacional en España: evidencia empírica 1991-1999”, Working Paper 9,
Instituto de Estudios Fiscales.
Moreno, J. and G. López-Casanova (2006): “Los determinantes de la inmigración internacional en España”, Investigaciones
Regionales, 9, pp. 25- 30.
Moses, J.W. and B. Lettnes (2002): “The economic cost to international labour restrictions”, WIDER Conference, September.
Mountford, A. (1997): “Can brain drain be good for growth in the source economy?”, Journal Development Economics, 53 (2),
pp. 287-303.
Mundell, R. (1968): International economics, Macmillan, New York.
Munshi, K. (2003): “Networks in the Modern Economy: Mexican Migrants in the US Labor Market”, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 118, pp. 549-597.
Murphy, R., A. Shleifer and R. Wishny (1989): “Industrialization and the Big Push”, Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1003-1026.
Nussbaum, M. (2000): Woman and Human Development: The Capabilities Approach, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Orozco, M. (2004): “Oportunidades y estrategias para el desarrollo a través de las remesas”, in J.A. Alonso (ed), Emigración, pobreza y
desarrollo, Editorial Catarata, Madrid.
O’Rourke, K.H. (2001): Globalization and Inequality: Historical Trends, Trinity College, Dublin, CEPR and NBER.
O’Rourke, K.H. and J.G. Williamson (1999): Globalization and History, MIT Press Cambridge Mass.
Ottaviano, G. and G. Peri (2008): “Immigration and national wages: Clarifying the theory and empirics”, Department of Economics
Working Paper, University of California.Ozden, C. and M. Schiff (2006), International Migration, Remittances and the
Brain Drain, New York, Palgrave Macmillan.
Ozden, C. and M. Schiff (2007), International Migration, Economic Development and Policy, World Bank and Palgrave Macmillan.
Parsons, C.R., R. Skeldon, T.L. Walmsley and L.A. Winters (2007): “Quantifying International Migration: A Database of Bilateral
Migrant Stocks”, in Ozden, C. and M. Schiff, International Migration, Economic Development and Policy, World Bank and
Palgrave Macmillan.
Passel, J. and D. Cohn (2008): “Trends in unauthorized immigration: Undocumented inflow now trails legal inflow”,
Washington, D.C., Pew Hispanic Center.
Patinkin, D. (1968): “A nationalist model”, in W. Adams, The Brain Drain, Macmillan, New York.
Pedersen, P.J., M. Pytlikova, and N. Simth (2004): “Selection on networks effects? Migration flows into 27 OECD countries”, IZA
DP, nº 1104.
Perloff, J.M., L. Lynch, and S.M. Gabbard (1998): Migration of seasonal agricultural workers”, American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, 80 (1), pp. 154-164.
PNUD (2009): Informe sobre el Desarrollo Humano, 2009. Superando Barreras: Movilidad y Desarrollo Humano, PNUD,
Mundiprensa.
58 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Portes, A. (2008): “Migration and social change: Some conceptual reflection”, CMD Working Paper 08-04, The Center for Migration
and Development, Princeton University.
Pritchett, L. (2006): Let Their People Come. Breaking the Gridlock on Global Labor Mobility, Washington, D.C., Center for Global
Development.
Puri, S. and T. Ritzema (1999): “Migrant worker remittances, microfinance and the informal economy: prospects and issues”,
Working Paper nº 21, ILO, Geneva.
Rajan, R. and A. Subramanian (2005): “GAT undermines aid’s impact on growth?”, NBER Working Paper 11657, National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Ratha, D. (2003): Worker remittances: An important and stable source of external development finance”, Global Development
Finance, 2003: 157:75.
Ratha, D. and Mohapatra, S. (2009): Migration and Development, Brief, 9, World Bank.
Rosenstein-Rodan, P. (1943): “Problems of Industrialization of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe”, Economic Journal 53, 202-211.
Schiff, M. (1998): Trade, migration and welfare: The impact of social capital, Development Economics Department, World Bank.
Schiff, M. (2006): “Brain Gain: Claims about its Size and Impact on Welfare and Growth are Greatly Exaggerated” in Ozden, C. and
M. Schiff, International Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain, New York, Palgrave Macmillan.
Sjaastad, L.A. (1962): “The costs and returns of human migration”, Journal of Political Economy, 70, 80-93.
Solimano, A. (2001): International migration and the global economic Order: An overview, Macroeconomics and Growth Development
Economics Research Group, World Bank.
Stark, O. (1984): “Rural-urban migration in LDCs: A relative deprivation approach”, Economic Development Change, 32 (3),
pp. 475-86.
Stark, O. (2003): “Rethinking the brain drain”, World Development, 32 (1): 15-22.
Stark, O. (2005): “The new economics of the brain drain”, World Economics, 6 (2), pp. 137-140.
Stark, O. and D.E. Bloom (1985): “The new economics of labor migration”, American Economic Review, 75 (2), pp. 173-178.
Stark, O. and Chau, N.H. (1998): “Human capital formation, asymmetric information and the dynamic of international migration”,
Economic Series 52, Institute of Advanced Studies.
Stark, O., C. Helmenstein and A. Prskawetz (1997): “A brain gain with brain drain”, Economic Letters, 55 (2), pp. 227-234.
Stark, O., C. Helmenstein and A. Prskawetz (1998): “Human capital depletion, human capital formation, and migration: A blessing
of a curse”, Economic Letters 60 (3), pp. 363-367.
Stark, O. and D. Levhari (1982): “On migration and risk in LDCs”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol 31, nº 1,
191-96.
Stark, O. and R. Lucas (1988): “Migration, remittances, and the family”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 36: 465-81.
Stark, O. and J.E. Taylor (1989): “Relative deprivation and international migration”, Demography, 26, pp. 1-14.
Stark, O. and J.E. Taylor (1991): “Migration incentives, migration types: The role of relative deprivation”, Economic Journal, 101
(408), pp. 1163-1178
Stark, O., J.E. Taylor and S. Yitzhaki (1986): “Remittances and inequality”, Economic Journal, 96, pp. 722-740.
Stark, O. and S. Yitzhaki (1988): “Labour migration as a response to relative deprivation”, Journal of Population Economics, 1, 57-70.
Stiglitz, J.E. (1974): “Alternative theories of wage determination and unemployment in LDCs: The labour turnover model”,
Quarterly Journal of Economics vol. 88, nº 2, 194-227.
Taylor, J.E. (1986): “Differential Migration, Networks, Information and Risks”, in O. Stark (ed), Migration Theory, Human Capital
and Development, Greenwich, JAI Press.
Taylor, J.E. (1987): “Undocumented Mexico-US Migration and the Returns to Households in Rural Mexico”, American Journal of
Agricultural Economics, 69 (3), pp. 626-638.
Taylor, J.E. (1992): “Earnings and Mobility of Legal and Illegal Immigrant Workers in Agriculture”, American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, 74 (4), pp. 889-896.
Todaro, M. P. (1969): “A model of labour emigration and urban unemployment in less developed countries”, American Economic
Review, vol 59, nº 1, 138-148.
Trachtman, J.P. (2009): “The international law of economic migration: Towards the fourth freedom”, Institute for Employment
Research, Michigan, W.E. Upjohn.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 59

UN (2000): Replacement Migration: Is it a Solution to Declining and Ageing?, United Nations publication, sales No. E.01.XIII.19.
UNDP (2009): Overcoming Barriers: Human Mobility and Development, Human Development Report, New York.
Van der Mensbrugghe, D. and D. Roland-Holst (2009): “Global Economic Prospect for Increasing Developing Country Migration
into Developed Countries”, Human Development Research Paper 2009/50, UNDP.
Vidal, J.P. (1998): “The effect of emigration on human capital formation”, Journal of Population Economics, 11 (4), pp. 589-6000.
Vogel, D. and V. Kovacheva (2009): “Calculation Table 2005: A Dynamic Aggregate Country Estimate of Irregular Foreign
Residents in the EU in 2005”, at http://irregular-migration.hwwi.net.
Walmsley, T.L. and L.A. Winters (2005): “Relaxing the Restrictions on the Temporary Movements of Natural Persons: A Simulation
Analysis”, Journal of Economic Integration 20 (4), pp. 688-726.
Williamson, J.H. (1997): Globalization and inequality: past and present”, World Bank Research Observer 12: 117:35.
Williamson, J.G. (2006): Globalization and the Poor Periphery Before 1950, Cambridge, MIT Press.
Woodruff, Ch. and R. Zenteno (2001): “Remittances and microenterprises in Mexico”, University of California.
Wong, K.-Y. and C.K. Yip (1999): “Education, economic growth and brain drain”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,
23 (5-6), pp. 699-726.
World Bank (2006): Global Economic Prospects, 2006: Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration”, Washington, D.C.,
World Bank.
Yang, D. (2008): “International Migration, Remittances and Household Investment: Evidence from Philippine Migrants´Exchange
Rate Shocks”, Economic Journal, 118, pp. 591-630.
Yang, D. and H. Choi (2007): “Are remittances insurance? Evidence from rainfall shocks in the Philippines”, World Bank Economic
Review, 21, pp. 219-248.
Yang, D. and C. Martínez (2006): Remittances and poverty in migrants’ home areas: Evidences from the Philippines”, in C. Ozden
and M. Schiff, International Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain, New York, Palgrave Macmillan.
60 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

Annex: Models for determining migratory flows

a) Emigration to the United States


Annex table 1 shows the results of the estimation of Clark et al. (2002), as used by Hatton and Williamson
(2005). The dependent variable is, in this case, the immigration rate to the United States during the period
1971-1998, which is estimated through the weighting of the emigrant population in the United States on the
total population of origin. That immigration rate seems negatively related: to the quotient between the GDP
per capita of the country of origin and that of the United States (which expresses the distance between the re-
spective levels of development); to the distance to Chicago (which is an approximation of the costs of transpor-
tation); to the Mediterranean character of the country (which increases those costs); and to the existing poverty
level in the country of origin, measured as a quotient of the Gini index and the square of the per capita income
of the country (which acts as a limiting factor to emigration, as Faini and Venturini, 1992, suggest).

Variables that emerge as positively related to the rate of migration are: the educational level of people
(approximated through years in the school system, compared to those in the United States); a country’s
youth demographic (measured by the percentage of the population aged 15 to 29); the level of inequality
(approximated through the premium on qualified work); and the size of the diasporas from the country in
question that is resident in the United States (which limits the risk and access costs of the emigrant). Both
the size of the diasporas and the inequality level present decreasing marginal returns, so that the coefficient
of that same variable squared is also significant but appears with a negative sign. Among this collection of
variables, a dummy variable is included in relation to whether the country belongs to the English-speaking
area, with the aim of capturing the effect that a common language could have on lessening integration costs.

The method followed is a pool of data, estimated through ordinary minimum squares. The number
of observations of countries and years considered is 2,268. Some regional and temporary dummies are also
included which do not show up here.
Annex table 1: Explanation of the immigration rate to the U.S., 1971-1998

Variable Coefficient t-stad Sense of the variable


Constant -11.95 35.9
Ratio, per capita income origin country/U.S. -1.80 - 9.5 Relation between income levels
Ratio, school years in origin country/U.S. 2.61 12.7 Relation between educational levels
15-29 years in population of origin (percentage) 2.71 2.7 Demographic dynamism of country of origin
Ratio Gini indexes origin/U.S. 4.17 7.1 Premium for labour qualification
Ratio Gini indexes squared -1.57 6.5 Non-linear effect of the previous variable
Distance from Chicago to origin -0.18 12.3 Access costs to host country
English-speaking origin 1.11 15.4 Reduction of integration costs
Country without access to sea -0.31 7 Costs of leaving country of origin
Diaspora of the country in the U.S. 42.91 10.7 Social networks in host country
Diaspora squared -182.94 6.5 Non-linear effect of the previous variable
Ratio index Gini/GDPpc squared -0.36 3.9 Level of poverty (threshold effect)
Temporary dummies
Regional dummies
R2 Adjusted 0.77
Source: Hatton, T. and J. Williamson (2005): Global Migration and the World Economy: Two Centuries of Policy and Performance,
Cambridge MA, MIT Press (p: 239).
The method followed is a pool of data, estimated through ordinary minimum squares. The number of observations of countries and
years considered is 2,268. Some regional and temporary dummies are also included which do not show up here.
International Migration and Development: A review in light of the crisis 61

b) Emigration to Spain
Emigration to Spain is a relatively recent phenomenon, which makes it difficulties to estimate. Despite these
limitations, there have been a group of studies that have tried to identify factors that determine emigration
flows to Spain. As internationally, there are also differences in the methods used and the periods that the
data refer to. Casado et al. (2005) study emigration in the period 1989-99 and apply a panel model of fixed
effects as an analysis procedure; Moreno (2004) studies the period 1991-99, applying both OLS as well as a
panel of random effects; Márquez et al. (2004) extend the period to 1993-2002 and use panel data with fixed
effects; Moreno and López-Casanovas (2006) look at the period 1994-2004, using generalised minimum
squares; and, finally, Cebrián (2009) studies the period 1995-2007, applying panel data both to the general
flow of emigrants and to each of the elements by gender.

Following the approach of Clark et al. (2002), the estimate presented here was carried out by Alonso
(2010) on immigration during the first decade of the new millennium(?). The migration rate seems to be
negatively related to: the degree of proximity of the GDP per capita of the country of origin to that of Spain
(relpib), which measures the relation between the development level of the country of origin and that of the
destination country; the distance from the capital of the country of origin to Madrid (distesp), which ap-
proximates access costs; and the rate of growth of the GDP of the country of origin (crecq), which measures
progress in the period previous to the decision to migrate. The level of poverty of the country also appears
with a negative sign, as was to be expected, but none of the variables employed to capture this relationship is
statistically significant: neither the rate of poverty (pobreza) nor the quotient of the Gini index between the
GDP per capita squared (pobreza2). The total number of the emigrant population from that same country
that have previously settled in Spain (stock) has a positive impact on the migration rate, confirming the

Annex table 2: Explanation of migration to Spain


Emigrants from developing countries
(1 (2 (3) (4) (5) (6)
(t estad.) (t estad.) (t estad.) (t estad.) (t estad.) (t estad.)
Relpib: relationship between GDP pc, in PPP, -3.065 -5.761 -6.704 -6.344 -4.914 -4.655
between origin and destination (-1.985) (-3.413) (-3.403) (-3.336) (-2.854) (-2.722)
Stock: emigrant population of the country in 0.056 0.061 0.085 0.235 0.258 0.262
2000 (4.830) (4.723) (5.184) (4.253) (4.551) (5.222)
Lesp: Spanish as official language 3.659 3.790 2.710 2.206 2.017 1.856
(6.417) (6.356) (4.174) (3.454) (3.456) (3.148)
Distesp: distance between Madrid and the -0.0002 -0.0002 -0.0002 0.0002 -0.0002 -0.0001
capital of the country of origin (-3.276) (-2.577) (-2.139) (-2.322) (-2.315) (-1.867)
Pojo85: percentage of the population of the -0.091 -0.103 -0.098 -0.073 -0.056
country under 15 in 1985 (-4.070) (-3.867) (-4.148) (-2.814) (-1.860)
Ginior: Gini index of the country of origin 0.059 0.060 0.049 0.041
(2.339) (2.527) (2.124) (1.790)
Stock2: emigrant population of the country, -33.84 -37.29 -38.00
squared (-3.032) (-3.276) (-3.698)
Mar: access to sea 1.430 1.462
(3.085) (3.200)
Crecq: growth of the GDP of the country of -0.117
origin during the five years previous to the (-2.022)
period
R2 Adjusted 0.481 0.549 0.641 0.701 0.745 0.759
Number of observations 58 58 46 46 46 46
Source: Alonso, 2010 (MCO, with coefficients consistent with heteroscedasticity).
62 CDP Background Paper No. 11(E)

accumulative nature of the phenomenon; however, that effect is submitted to decreasing returns, as revealed
by the negative sign associated with that same variable squared (stock2). The level of inequality of the country
of origin (ginior) also has a positive influence, which seems to suggest that inequality encourages popula-
tions to seek opportunities outside their countries. And, finally, having Spanish as the official language—the
same language as that of the destination country—appears as a notably significant variable in explaining the
immigration rate to Spain, as was expected. Variables associated with the level of training of the people do
not appear as significant, regardless of whether the rate of literacy or the average years of study of the popula-
tion is used. Nor does the variable measuring the institutional quality of the country appear as significant,
although the sign of the coefficient is the correct one. Despite this, the explanatory capacity of the model is
high given that it explains 75% of the variation of the variable.

You might also like