Robots Micro
Robots Micro
Robots Micro
net/publication/385218225
CITATIONS READS
0 6
1 author:
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Mario Arturo Ruiz Estrada on 25 October 2024.
Abstract
This short academic note provides an overview of the role of humanoid robots (HR) in the
economy from a microeconomic perspective. In the first section, we present a general
introduction to robots. The second section offers a brief history of robots. The third section
focuses on the basic requirements for building a humanoid robot (HR). In the fourth section,
we delve into a microeconomic analysis of the impact of humanoid robots (HR) on firms,
specifically regarding cost, revenue, and profit maximization. Additionally, this research
emphasizes that humanoid robots (HR) are likely to create two possible outcomes, both of
which require adaptation: job disruption versus job relocation and adaptation. We highlight key
aspects of the emerging role of humanoid robots (HR) as a potential and effective substitute for
human labour across various production sectors, as well as the profound changes occurring in
the labour market.
1. Introduction
The idea of robots (West, 2018) is quite confusing and not well understood by most
knowledgeable people. We need to start with automation as the basic premise of robotics. The
primary concept of automation is reducing human intervention in the production process to
increase productivity and decrease dependency on workers for the generation of goods or
services for the market. The origin of automation lies in the use of basic tools as extensions of
our arms or bodies in the production process (Cilekoglu, Moreno, and Ramos, 2021).
The second stage of automation involves the creation and use of machines to facilitate
production, improving efficiency with the aim of reducing production costs (total, average, and
Full Copyrights under Econographication Virtual Laboratory (EVL) © 2024
marginal). This enables the production of higher-quality goods and larger quantities, lowering
prices in the market, which in turn generates faster and significant revenue in the short term.
The ultimate goal is to generate substantial profits (by maximizing sales and minimizing
production costs) and achieve rapid wealth accumulation in a sustainable manner.
The third stage of automation is the transition from mechanical machines (operated by workers)
to fully autonomous machines (controlled by computers and advanced software) that require
minimal human labour in the production process. These machines offer high productivity
(through standardization and large-scale production) and efficiency (by ensuring quality and
volume).
The fourth stage involves the use of fully automatic, highly precise robots controlled by
computers and advanced software, again with minimal human involvement. These robots
achieve large-scale productivity (through standardized production of large volumes) and
efficiency (through record production times).
The fifth and final stage of full automation involves the use of humanoids—robots with human-
like features—equipped with artificial intelligence (AI), sensors, microchips, micro-sensors,
advanced materials, fast-charging batteries, and sophisticated structures. These humanoids can
assess situations and take actions in real time without any human input, ultimately eliminating
the need for workers in the production process entirely (Dautenhahn, 2007).
1. Full-mechanical and fully-manual – Robots are powered and controlled entirely by human
force, requiring full human intervention.
2. Semi-mechanical and semi-manual – Partial human intervention is required, with the use of
parts and components powered by less human force to assist in the control and operation of the
robot, the main source to supply energy was based on steam and coal.
3. Electric and fully-autonomous – Minimal human intervention is needed, as robots are
controlled and operated primarily by computers, the main source to supply energy to the robots
is from electricity.
To shift economies toward advanced technology, education systems must ensure that 60% of
graduates focus on science and engineering fields. This emphasis is vital for building a strong
foundation in robotics and automation. Constructing any robot humanoid (HR) requires
meeting basic conditions and conducting specialized research and development in the
following areas:
This research strongly recommends that the development of artificial intelligence (AI) for
humanoids robots (HR) be renamed as the Central Neural Artificial Intelligence Box (CNAI-
Box). This system would interconnect the hardware and software of humanoids robots (HR),
enabling them to analyse information, process data, and take actions based on pre-established
parameters. It is essential to have a mechanism in place to disconnect any robot humanoid
(HR)in case of an uncontrolled situation.
4. The impact of Humanoids Robots (HR) from Microeconomics Perspective (the firm
side):
In the beginning, we can say that humanoid robots (HR) are entering the circular flow of the
economy, where they interact with firms and households in the market. The primary goal of
firms is to produce and supply goods and services for household consumption. In turn,
household spending on these goods and services becomes revenue for the firms, creating an
automated cycle. These transactions take place in the goods and services market.
On the other hand, the market for factors of production consists of labour, land, capital, and
entrepreneurship. These factors are provided by households to firms, and in return, firms
compensate households through various forms of income: wages (for labour), rent (for land),
interest (for capital), and profit (for entrepreneurship). For firms, these payments represent
production costs, but for households, they are sources of income that enable them to spend on
goods and services in the market.
Full Copyrights under Econographication Virtual Laboratory (EVL) © 2024
If we introduce humanoid robots (HR) to replace labour in the production process (Graetz and
Michaels, 2018)., we see a dramatic shift in this equation. Labor (Barth, Røed, Schøne,
Umblijs, 2020) becomes less relevant to firms, reducing their dependence on human workers
(Montobbio, Staccioli, Virgillito, and Vivarelli, 2020), which could lead to a significant
decrease in the demand for labour from households. This, in turn, may cause mass
unemployment (Barbieri, Mussida, Piva, and Vivarelli, 2019) in the labour market. To address
this issue, we propose two new concepts: the job disruption effect and the job relocation and
adaptation effect.
The job disruption effect refers to the immediate, negative impact of humanoid robots on the
labour market, potentially displacing workers across various industries. On the other hand, the
job relocation and adaptation effect involve the challenges and opportunities created as workers
are forced to adapt to new roles in the evolving market.
Addressing the job relocation and adaptation effect requires a fundamental shift in education
systems (from elementary to high education) to foster creativity and human interaction, which
are essential to competing with humanoid robots (hardware) and artificial intelligence
(software) (Ruiz Estrada, Park, and Staniewski, 2023). Rapid adaptability and constant
creativity are the most powerful tools labour can use to survive in the modern market, ensuring
that this factor of production remains active and relevant in the long run. To observe how
humanoids robots (HR) are going to transform the entire economy from a microeconomic
perspective, we begin by noting that the intensive use of humanoids robots (HR) will push the
production possibilities frontier (PPF) higher than the average PPF achieved through labour-
intensive production with less capital. Efficiency levels can increase significantly, allowing for
the production of two or more goods simultaneously, thus lowering opportunity costs.
In terms of demand and supply, there may be an initial overreaction, but in the long run, this
could result in an optimal equilibrium for firms and households. Adjusting price and quantity
equilibrium may face some challenges at the outset. It’s important to note that one of the main
variables that can shift supply is technology—in this case, humanoids robots (HR). Additionally,
the producers surplus is likely to expand dramatically compared to a system relying on more
labour and less capital.
From a production cost perspective, humanoids robots (HR) can significantly reduce total costs
(variable costs plus fixed costs), particularly by lowering variable costs more than fixed costs.
This is largely due to the reduction in labour required for the production process of any firm.
Average total costs (ATC) and marginal total costs (MTC) will undergo rapid changes in the
short run, as marginal total costs may initially exceed average total costs. However, this will
eventually lead to economies of scale, where constant returns to scale will increase
substantially in the long run due to the intensive use of humanoids robots (HR). It can be argued
that with humanoids robots, diseconomies of scale—where ATC rises as output increases—are
unlikely, as humanoids robots (HR) help maintain lower costs even with increased output.
In the case of profit maximization, humanoids robots (HR) can reduce total costs, allowing firms
to offer lower prices, which in turn can boost sales and increase total revenue. As a result, profit
maximization with humanoids robots (HR) is achievable through high total revenues (driven by
increased sales from firms using humanoids robots (HR) intensively in the production process)
combined with lower production costs, benefiting both firms and households through reduced
prices in the market.
Full Copyrights under Econographication Virtual Laboratory (EVL) © 2024
5. Conclusion
In conclusion, we believe that the use of humanoid robots (HR) in the near future is an
unavoidable reality, prompting a shift from job disruption to job relocation and adaptation. To
prevent unemployment and keep labour as an active factor in the production equation, the
continuous development of human creativity and interaction (HCI) is essential. This will allow
us to compete with humanoid robots (HR) and artificial intelligence (AI), which must be
supported by innovative educational reforms from elementary to higher education.
However, we have found that firms will achieve faster and higher profit maximization in the
short term with the intensive use of humanoid robots (HR), as labour dependency decreases.
Production costs will shift from variable to fixed. Depreciation, energy expenses (electricity),
and maintenance will become consistent, leading to predictable monthly and yearly fixed costs.
Finally, profit maximization occurs when a firm selects an output level where marginal revenue
equals marginal cost. This rule applies to all types of businesses, including oligopolies and
monopolies. The optimal point is reached when marginal revenue (sales) is higher and marginal
cost (due to mass production and economies of scale) is lower in the short term. We assume
that humanoid robots will not lead to diseconomies of scale.
Reference
Barbieri, L., Mussida, C., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2019). Testing the Employment
Impact of Automation, Robots and AI: A Survey and Some Methodological Issues. IZA -
Institute of Labor Economics.
Barth, E., Røed, M., Schøne, P., & Umblijs, J. (2020). How Robots Change Within-
Firm Wage Inequality. IZA - Institute of Labor Economics.
Cilekoglu, A. A., Moreno, R., & Ramos, R. (2021). The Impact of Robot Adoption on
Global Sourcing. IZA - Institute of Labor Economics.
Dautenhahn, K. (2007). Socially Intelligent Robots: Dimensions of Human-Robot
Interaction. Philosophical Transactions: Biological Sciences, 362(1480), 679–704.
Graetz, G., & Michaels, G. (2018). ROBOTS AT WORK. The Review of Economics
and Statistics, 100(5), 753–768.
Montobbio, F., Staccioli, J., Virgillito, M. E., & Vivarelli, M. (2020). Robots and the
Origin of Their Labour-Saving Impact. IZA - Institute of Labor Economics.
Ruiz Estrada, M.A., Park, D., Staniewski, M. (2023). Artificial Intelligence (AI) can
change the way of doing policy modelling, Journal of Policy Modeling, 45(6): 1099-1112.
West, D. M. (2018). ROBOTS. In The Future of Work: Robots, AI, and Automation
(pp. 3–18). Brookings Institution Press.